Back Matter
Author:
Ms. Era Dabla-Norris
Search for other papers by Ms. Era Dabla-Norris in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ruud de Mooij
Search for other papers by Ruud de Mooij in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Andrew Hodge
Search for other papers by Andrew Hodge in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Jan Loeprick
Search for other papers by Jan Loeprick in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Dinar Prihardini
Search for other papers by Dinar Prihardini in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Alpa Shah
Search for other papers by Ms. Alpa Shah in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Sebastian Beer
Search for other papers by Sebastian Beer in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Sonja Davidovic
Search for other papers by Sonja Davidovic in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Arbind M Modi
Search for other papers by Arbind M Modi in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Fan Qi
Search for other papers by Fan Qi in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Annex 1. Methodology

Pillar 1, Amount A

Revenue estimates are derived using data in country by country reports (CbCR). In 2017, more than 60 tax jurisdictions have required large MNEs headquartered in their jurisdictions to report on their income, taxes paid, and other indicators of economic activity such as employment, assets, and sales by origin (for both related and unrelated parties) on a country by country basis. Of these, 25 countries have publicly released their CbCRs on an aggregate basis.

Estimating sales by destination begins with sales by origin for each parent-country and affiliate-pair from the CbCR data (say, sales of US MNE affiliate located in Mexico). Ten the export share is applied to determine the component that is exported and the component that is sold domestically in Mexico. The export share is taken either from the OECD Analytical Activities of MNEs database (differentiating between exports by domestic MNEs and foreign MNEs) or from the country’s national accounts. For the exported component, the bilateral trade matrix, from the World Bank’s World Integrated Trade Solution, of the producing country (that is, Mexico), is used to approximate the destination of these exports. These exports are then summed by destination country. The exports are then added to the domestic sales made by a US MNE affiliate in that country (if any). For example, Mexican exports to Nicaragua would be added to any US MNE affiliate sales made directly in Nicaragua.

To estimate the revenue effects of Amount A, the authors first aggregate the global profits and losses of MNEs by headquarter country. Sales to unrelated parties are also aggregated by MNE headquarter country. Aggregate routine profit is then defined as 10 percent of aggregate unrelated party sales. The difference between profit and routine profit is defined to be the residual.

A portion (20 percent) of the residual is then allocated to each jurisdiction based on that jurisdiction’s share of sales by destination for that MNE headquarter country. For example, India’s share of US MNEs residual profit is determined by its share of US MNE sales.

Since Amount A is a reallocation of the tax base, jurisdictions must also relinquish part of their taxing right. That is, each jurisdiction is assumed to “contribute” to the pool of residual profit to be reallocated. This contribution is in proportion to the jurisdiction’s current share of residual profit. In practice, each group can nominate the affiliate(s) and hence jurisdiction(s) that will pay the new tax liability under Amount A.

For each jurisdiction, the tax base under Amount A is the difference between their allocation of residual profit under sales by destination and their current allocation of the residual. To estimate tax revenue effects, the authors assume that the statutory CIT rate is applied to this tax base.

The total change in revenue for a jurisdiction is the sum of revenue changes across each headquarter country included in the dataset (that is, 25 countries).

Formulary Apportionment

Revenue estimates are derived using data from published country by country reports, as well as data from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) on the activities of US MNEs.

US Bureau of Economic Analysis

The BEA publishes annual data on the aggregate finances and operations of US-based MNEs, with separate statistics for US parent companies and their foreign affiliates in 199 countries. For majority-owned affiliates in 52 countries, there is detailed information on the foreign income tax paid, the profit they report, and the level of fixed assets in each country. It is data on these affiliates that are used for this analysis.

Regarding information on sales, the BEA provides information on sales by origin as well as partial data on sales by destination. Specifically, for each country where an affiliate is located, it reports goods and services supplied to unafliated persons in either the United States, the host country, or other foreign countries. For about 10 percent of sales to unafliated persons, the destination country is not specified in the BEA data. However, in the benchmark survey years, data are provided on the destination region (that is, Canada, Europe, Latin America and Other Western Hemisphere, Africa, Middle East, and Asia-Pacific) for these sales. To allocate sales to countries within each region specified by the BEA, data on bilateral exports is used.

To estimate the revenue effects of formulary apportionment, profits and losses declared in each jurisdiction are first aggregated to determine the tax base at the global level. This is then apportioned to each jurisdiction using its share of the factor under consideration. For example, under the employment factor, India’s share of global US MNE profit is determined by its share of total employment by US MNEs. The tax rate applied to this tax base is either the Effective Tax Rate (ETR) calculated from the data, or where the ETR is an outlier, the statutory tax rate for that country is used.

Country by Country Reports

The same CbCR data set used to estimate the revenue effects under Amount A is also used to estimate the revenue effects of FA.

To estimate the revenue effects of formulary apportionment, profits and losses declared in each jurisdiction are aggregated by MNE headquarter country to determine the tax base. This is then apportioned to each jurisdiction using its share of the factor under consideration, by MNE headquarter country. For example, India’s share of a Chinese MNEs profit is determined by its share of Chinese MNE sales. The tax rate applied to this tax base is either the ETR calculated from the data on profit-making firms, or where the ETR is an outlier, the statutory tax rate for that country is used.

Annex 2. Detailed Formulary Apportionment Results

This annex shows the revenue effects of formulary apportionment for individual economies. The table on the next page presents the change in CIT revenue collected from MNEs if there is global adoption of formulary apportionment (percent of GDP). The results are presented based on various apportionment factors, using the CbCR data set. For example, the Employment column shows the change in total CIT revenue from MNEs, if the share of employees in each economy is used to allocate the consolidated profit of the MNE.

Annex Table 2.1.

Detailed Formulary Apportionment Results

article image

References

  • Aslam, Aqib, and Alpa Shah. 2017. “Taxation and the Peer-to-Peer Economy.” In: Sanjeev Gupta, Michael Keen, Alpa Shah, and Geneviève Verdier (eds.), Digital Revolutions in Public Finance. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aslam, Aqib, Alpa Shah. 2020. “Tec(h)tonic shifts: Taxing the Digital Economy.” IMF Working Paper No. 20/76, Washington, DC.

  • African Tax Administration Forum (ATAF). 2020. Suggested Approach to Drafting Digital Services Tax Legislation, https://events.ataftax.org/index.php?page=documents&func=view&document_id=79

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan, Michael P. Devereux, Michael Keen, and John Vella. 2017. “Destination-Based Cash Flow Taxation.” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation WP 17/01, Oxford, UK.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Avi Yonah, Reuven. 2020. ‘What’s Everyone’s Problem with DSTs?Tax Notes International, Letters to the Editor, December 7, 2020.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beer, Sebastian, and Jan Loeprick. 2015. Profit shifting: drivers of transfer (mis) pricing and the potential of countermeasures. International Tax and Public Finance 22(3): 42651.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beer, Sebastian, Ruud de Mooij, Shafk Hebous, Michael Keen, and Li Liu. 2020. “Exploring Residual Profit Allocation.” IMF Working Paper No. 20/49, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Crossref
    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourreau, Marc, Bernard Caillaud, and Romain De Nijs. 2018. “Taxation of a Digital Monopoly Platform.” Journal of Public Economic Theory, Special Issue on Taxation in the Digital Economy 20(1): 4051.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brondolo, John, and Mark Konza. 2021. “Administering the Value-Added Tax on Imported Digital Services and Low-Value Imported Goods.” IMF Technical Notes and Manuals, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cui, Wei. 2018. “The Digital Services Tax: A Conceptual Defense.” Mimeo (Allard School of Law at the University of British Columbia).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cui, Wei. 2021. Digital Services Taxes in Developing Countries. Remarks made at IMF/WB Spring Meetings Conference on International Taxation.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cui, Wei, and Nigar Hashimzade. 2019. “The Digital Services Tax as a Tax on Location-Specific Rent.” CESifo Working Paper Series No. 7737.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dale, Stephen, and Venise Vincent. 2017. “The European Union’s Approach to VAT and E-Commerce.” World Journal of VAT/GST Law 6(1): 5561.

    • Crossref
    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Mooij, Ruud A., Li Liu, and Dinar Prihardini. 2019. “An Assessment of Global Formula Apportionment.” IMF Working Paper No. 19/213, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael P., Alan J. Auerbach, Michael Keen, Paul Oosterhuis, Wolfgang Schön, and John Vella. 2019. “Residual Profit Allocation by Income.” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation Working Paper WP19/01, Oxford, UK.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ecommerce DB. 2019. “In-Depth: B2B E-Commerce 2019.” Statista, New York.

  • Group of Twenty (G20). 2018. “Toolkit for Measuring the Digital Economy.” G20 Secretariat.

  • Herrero, Alicia G., and Jianwei Xu. 2018. “How Big is China’s Digital Economy?Bruegel Working Paper Issue 04, Bruegel, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hvistendahl, Mara. 2019. “China’s Tech Giants Want to Go Global. Just One Ting Might Stand in Their Way.” MIT Technology Review, December 19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, and Zhiyao (Lucy) Lu. 2018. “The European Union’s Proposed Digital Services Tax: A De Facto Tarif.” Policy Briefs PB18–15, Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kinda, Tidiane. 2019. “E-Commerce as a Potential New Engine for Growth in Asia.” IMF Working Paper 19/135, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Crossref
    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2018a. “Regional Economic Outlook. Asia and Pacifc—Asia at the Forefront: Growth Challenges for the Next Decade and Beyond.” Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2018b. “The Digital Revolution in Asia: Disruptor or New Growth Engine (or Both)?Regional Economic Outlook: Asia and Pacific Background Paper No. 4, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2019. “Corporate Taxation in the Global Economy.” IMF Policy Paper, Washington, DC.

  • Kind, Hans J., Marko Köthenbürger, and Guttorm Schjelderup. 2008. “Ef-ciency Enhancing Taxation in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of Public Economics 92(5–6): 153139.

    • Crossref
    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Köthenbürger, Marko. 2020. “Taxation of Digital Platforms,” EconPol Working Paper 41, ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • KPMG. 2021. Taxation of the Digitalized Economy – Developments Summary. https://tax.kpmg.us/articles/2021/tracking-digital-services-taxes-developments.html. Accessed on May 24, 2021.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laubscher, H. 2018. “The Prime Difference between Amazon and Alibaba.” Forbes.com, December 28.

  • McKinsey Global Institute. 2019. “Digital India: Technology to Transform a Connected Nation.” March 27.

  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2017. International VAT/GST Guidelines. Paris.

  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2019. “The Role of Digital Platforms in the Collection of VAT/GST on Online Sales.” Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2020a. “Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Report on the Pillar One Blueprint.” Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2020b. “Model Rules for Reporting by Platform Operators with respect to Sellers in the Sharing and Gig Economy.” Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schindler, Dirk, and Guttorm Schjelderup. 2010. “Profit Shifting in Two-Sided Markets.” International Journal of the Economics of Business 17(3): 37383.

    • Crossref
    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sedik, Tahsin Saadi. 2018. “Asia’s Digital Revolution.” Finance & Development 55(3).

  • Statista. 2020. “Digital Market Data Sheet.” New York.

  • United Nations. 2008. International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities Rev. 4. New York.

  • United States Trade Representative (USTR). 2021. Section 301 Investigation – Report on India’s Digital Services Tax, January 2021.

  • World Bank. 2021. World Development Report: Data for Better Lives. Washington, DC.

  • Xu, Feifei. 2016. “Alibaba vs. Amazon: A business model comparison.” Louvain School of Management, Université Catholique de Louvain, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

A second pillar in these discussions deals with the introduction of an effective global minimum tax.

1

The ICT sector is measured using industry-level national accounts data and the relevant International Standard Industrial Classification codes (G20 2018, United Nations 2008) for computer programming and information services (Div. 62 63); telecommunications (Div. 61); publishing and broadcasting (Div. 58 60); and manufacturing of computer, electronic, and optical products (Div. 26).

2

Although fully comparable data are not available, McKinsey Global Institute (2019) estimate that India’s ICT sector accounted for around 7 percent of GDP in 2017–18, mainly reflecting IT and digital communications services.

1

Some countries consider the DSTs discussed in the following section, merely as an interim solution until international agreement is achieved. Indeed, countries such as Belgium, Czech Republic and Hungary have delayed the implementation of their DSTs, anticipating agreement on a multilateral solution can be reached by mid-2021.

2

The OECD-IF argues that not all the residual is generated by the market jurisdiction (for example, some reflects risk-taking by the MNE), hence only a portion of the residual profit is reallocated.

3

For economists, routine returns may resemble a normal return on investment and “residual” profits, resemble rents (earnings in excess of the minimum required by the investor).

4

For instance, the Made in America Tax Plan would bring the international minimum tax provisions (GILTI and BEAT) closer in line with the OECD-IF’s Pillar 2 proposal. The plan envisages a higher minimum tax rate of 21 percent compared to the OECD-IF.

5

The definition of consumer-facing business is not yet finalized.

6

However, as noted above using consolidated data, digital firms account for a sizeable share of residual profits, with the ICT sector alone responsible for 16 percent of total residual profits. Hence the analysis presented here should be viewed as illustrative. Indeed, digital firms are deemed to have greater opportunities for profit shifting, given the importance of intangibles in their production process

7

Although the share of residual profit is evenly shared across the three continents, affiliates located in Asia tend to be more profitable than their counterparts in other regions, earning a return on tangible assets of 17 percent. The median affiliate in Europe earns a 15 percent return, and those in the Americas and Middle East earn a return of 8.5 percent. The lowest returns are observed in Africa, with a return on assets of only 4 percent.

8

Results are presented in OECD (2020a) as the percentage change in CIT revenue. IMF staff converted this change in CIT revenue into percentage points of GDP for ease of comparison with the other results presented in this paper.

9

The top 100 largest MNE groups by revenue have revenue greater than USD 67 billion, with an average revenue of USD 127 billion, and an average residual of USD 1.7 billion. The headquarters of these MNE groups are dispersed equally across Asia, Europe, and the Americas. The average size, in terms of revenue, in each region is similar, but the average MNE group headquartered in the Americas have more than twice the residual profit (USD 3.4 billion) of the average Asian MNE (USD 1.6 billion). The average residual profit of European is the lowest at USD 305 million.

10

For these estimates, residual profit is defined as profit above 10 percent of unrelated party sales. Only 20 percent of this residual is reallocated based on the share of destination sales in each jurisdiction. The estimates assume that this reallocation is “funded” by countries relinquishing the residual profit to which they currently have taxing rights.

11

High global revenue thresholds result in common DSTs, effectively capturing mainly important US MNEs, which has been argued to create de facto discrimination (see Hufbauer and Lu 2018, and USTR 2021). The effective targeting of US MNEs by DSTs, however, is a consequence of their market dominance and may be temporary (Avi Yonah 2020).

12

This type of tax is typified by the 2018 European Commission draft directive for the taxation of digital services, versions of which have subsequently been unilaterally introduced by EU members. The proposed DST, which has since served as a model for a number of EU members states, imposes a 3 percent levy on revenues from certain specified digital activities, which users have “co-created.”

13

In cases where a double tax treaty does not allow for the creation of a virtual PE, an “electronic transaction tax” is supposed to be applied, though this measure is not yet effective/specified.

14

Rents—that is, earnings in excess of normal required returns—are an attractive tax base because they can be taxed without distorting a company’s behavior. However, taxing rents is difficult in practice, since some costs are hard to observe and provide deductions for and many sources of rent are not location specific; therefore, taxing them risks driving them elsewhere.

15

ATAF (2020) proposes a hybrid approach that would deal with abuse risks by determining the DST charge as the higher amount between the direct payments made and a country’s share in apportioned global segment revenue of a company in scope (for instance, the share of a country’s advertising views in global total advertising views).

16

Potentially contributing to further market concentration in the tech sector.

17

In 2018 the EU Commission proposed a DST of 3 percent on the gross revenue from activities relying on user participation such as selling online advertising space and intermediary activities that allow users to interact and sell goods and services.

18

And the potential Asian user base and revenue is much larger, as Facebook is not (yet) operating in China.

19

The Statista surveys cover market participants as well as consumers—for India, Indonesia, Thailand, and Vietnam. Reported results for the other economies are extrapolated using indicators of purchasing power of consumers and digital maturity in the economy. E-commerce includes sale physical goods via a digital channel (from all types of devices) to a private end user (B2C) with cross-border purchases attributed to the country of the buyer. E-services capture sales of services and digital goods (event ticket reservation, dating, food delivery, etc.) with an online checkout process. Digital media captures spending on audiovisual media contents and applications distributed online. Digital advertising captures advertisement spending for online channels. (Statista 2020).

21

Assuming that 40 percent of the e-commerce, 70 percent of digital media, 100 percent of digital advertising, 10 percent of e-services, online tourism and online mobility revenues estimated by Statista are in scope and applying the rates of the Indian DST (2 percent on gross revenue in scope, 6 percent on gross advertising revenue).

22

The European Commission has estimated annual revenue yield from its DST for member states of EUR 5 billion (<0.01 percent of EU GDP). France expects to collect EUR 400 million from the DST in 2020 (0.02 percent of GDP). The United Kingdom estimates that its DST will raise GBP 275 million (0.01 percent of GDP) in 2020–21 rising to GBP 440 million (0.02 percent of GDP) in 2023–24. USTR (2021) finds an equally moderate tax revenue potential when assessing tax liabilities for US firms as a result from the Indian DST: in aggregate, the 86 US firms that are likely in scope of the Indian DST “may face tax payments in excess of USD 30 million per year.”

23

By January 2021, more than 30 countries had enacted, held public consultations on policy proposals, or announced their intention to introduce unilateral direct tax measures aimed at digital services, see KPMG (2021).

24

For instance, Malaysia expanded the scope of its tourism tax charged per room per night in 2020 to cover accommodation booked through online platforms and will impose the tax on resident and nonresident digital platform service providers from July 2021.

25

Similar to tariffs announced following an investigation of France’s DST. These were announced in July 2020, scheduled to go into effect in January 2021 (but have been temporarily suspended).

26

The African Tax Administration Forum (ATAF) for instance proposed model legislation for Digital Services Taxes to its member states.

27

Other policy alternatives, such as a destination-based cash-flow tax, are discussed in IMF (2019) and Auer-bach and others (2017).

28

These alternatives, initially proposed by tax practitioners and academics, have gained traction with policy makers (for example, the G24’s proposal for fractional apportionment), outlined in the Intergovernmental Group of 24’s submission to the OECD on possible solutions to the tax challenges of digitalization. India was the first to propose such a solution, which was then endorsed by other members.

29

FA is commonly used to distribute CIT revenue at the subnational level, for instance, in countries such as Canada, Germany, Japan and the United States. The European Commission has proposed such an approach for the EU, in the form of the ‘Common Consolidated Tax Base’, wherein the weights are a composite of sales, assets, employment, payroll, and data.

30

See de Mooij and others (2019) for a detailed discussion of the benefits and drawbacks of formulary apportionment.

31

FA regimes generally have special treatment only for the extractives and financial sectors.

32

A discussion of negative residuals can be found in Beer and others (2020).

33

The following analysis is based on Beer and others (2020).

34

Routine profits correspond broadly to a normal return on investment. Commonly, a return to tangible assets is chosen at a level which is sufficiently high to encompass a return to all assets (including intangibles).

35

There could be an incentive to sell to a third-party distributor located in a low-cost jurisdiction. Sourcing rules could be introduced to mitigate this new form of tax avoidance.

1

As provided for in the OECD (2017) VAT guidelines. A major reform along these lines was introduced in the EU in 2015 to ensure taxation at destination on intra-EU supplies, which previously was based on origin (the location of the supplier). See Dale and Vincent (2017).

2

Requiring the individual consumers to register and fulfill the necessary steps to remit VAT on a one-of purchase on the internet is challenging (see Box 4).

3

Without an agent or bill of entry that would help identify VAT and customs duty payments due and the responsible taxpayer.

4

Levelling the playing field is preferable to pursuing this objective with new tax incentives for digital startups. In Vietnam, for instance, in 2020 incentives aimed at innovative startups were introduced, including a reduction of the corporate tax rate to 10 percent for 30 years (Decree No.94/2020/ND-CP).

5

The customer’s location is commonly determined by a combination of the information on the customer’s payment profile (credit card information, bank account details), residence (billing address or home address), and their internet access (the internet protocol of the device used or the country code of their SIM card [if transaction made through a mobile device], location of the consumer’s fixed landline). Most countries require two pieces of nonconficting information to make this determination.

6

The EU broadly defines the nature of in-scope digital or electronically supplied services to be covered under new VAT legislation. The EU VAT Directive, specifies electronically supplied services to mean “services delivered over the internet or an electronic network and the nature of which renders their supply essentially automated and involving minimum human intervention, and impossible to ensure in the absence of information technology.” A list of examples is provided in the accompanying VAT regulation, along with selected exclusions.

7

In some cases, exemptions are explicitly carved out for example, online gaming (Norway), professional services provided over email (EU), and the provision of education and health services through digital means, areas that are typically zero-rated in domestic legislation in these countries.

8

Other examples outside the region include Argentina and Costa Rica.

9

The Indonesian Directorate General of Taxation issued the first list in July 2020. This included companies in the spotlight of the digital tax debate, namely Amazon, Google, Netfix, and Spotify. Four subsequent lists were published between July and November, bringing the total number of in scope businesses to 46.

10

There are some exceptions. In Argentina, Azerbaijan, and Bangladesh, for example, the liability falls not on the non-resident supplier but on the local payment provider. Where that is the case, specification of transactions for which payment providers need to withhold VAT is required, likely narrowing the scope of covered supplies in practice. While this approach can thereby help address compliance management challenges, it is unlikely to be a desirable long-term solution in most countries. A hybrid approach is pursued in Costa Rica, where the government does allow voluntary compliance by companies on the in-scope list, but if they do not comply, the payment is withheld by card issuers (for example, Visa, MasterCard).

11

Tresholds for cross-border digital services for VAT registration are typically at the same level or below the domestic requirement for mandatory registration. Some countries do not include a threshold, even if one exists in domestic legislation (for example, Moldova), or a modified lower threshold may apply. As part of its general rules, Indonesia provides for a second threshold related to customer traffic levels, which is used in conjunction with the monetary threshold—the threshold is reached if the amount of traffic or access in Indonesia exceeds 12,000 users annually or 1,000 users monthly. As discussed above, currently, however, registration requirements are in practice limited to companies directly referenced in regularly published official lists.

12

No input credits can be claimed by foreign registrants in the simplified registration process. Consequently, abuse risks are less of a concern than with regular registrants. If a foreign service provider wants to claim input tax credits for supplies made in another country, the usual requirement is to establish a place of business in the country and to go through the regular registration process.

13

From July (January) 2021, the EU (and United Kingdom), require platforms to withhold and remit VAT on low-value parcels on behalf of sellers.

14

Australia introduced 10 percent GST on cross-border sales of services and digital products imported by Australian consumers on July 1, 2017, following enactment of Tax and Superannuation Laws Amendment Bill 2016. The budget initially estimated revenue collection of A$150 million during the first year (FY2017–18), followed by A$200 million in FY2018–19.

16

Applying the standard VAT rate and assuming that 100 percent of transactions of digital media content, 10 percent of all e-commerce transactions, 5 percent of digital advertising, and 15 percent of e-services, mobility and travel services captured by Statista are provided by unregistered remote suppliers to final consumers and/or unregistered registered entities. For details on the Statista survey see also discussion in section 2 on Digital Services Taxes.

17

In Croatia, for instance, a compliance management campaign launched in 2018 drew on a comparison of domestic tax returns with digital platform data regarding hotel and lodging accommodation sold on behalf of Croatian suppliers. About 40 percent of Croatian vendors using the platforms covered in the campaign either did not register or declared significantly less income for tax purposes than they received from platform-facilitated sales (World Bank 2021).

18

Recent guidance provided by OECD (2020b) on model reporting rules for platform operators provide a useful reference framework. See also OECD (2019) on the different approaches to leveraging the prominent role of digital platforms for the collection of VAT.

20

Trough the use of P2P platforms, increasingly efficient small businesses may better compete with and displace larger incumbents. If the rise of the sharing economy means that incumbents are being displaced and replacement P2P activity remains below tax thresholds, governments risk losing revenue as income and profits are dispersed across many smaller businesses instead of concentrated in large profitable companies (Aslam and Shah 2017).

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Digitalization and Taxation in Asia
Author:
Ms. Era Dabla-Norris
,
Ruud de Mooij
,
Andrew Hodge
,
Jan Loeprick
,
Dinar Prihardini
,
Ms. Alpa Shah
,
Sebastian Beer
,
Sonja Davidovic
,
Arbind M Modi
, and
Fan Qi