Abstract
The IMF Research Bulletin, a quarterly publication, selectively summarizes research and analytical work done by various departments at the IMF, and also provides a listing of research documents and other research-related activities, including conferences and seminars. The Bulletin is intended to serve as a summary guide to research done at the IMF on various topics, and to provide a better perspective on the analytical underpinnings of the IMF’s operational work.
By Stephen P. Tokarick
Thirty years ago, it was not uncommon to analyze economic developments within or across countries without much reference to international trade. That’s no longer the case. Globalization has prompted many countries to attach greater importance to the role of international trade in the process of economic development. World trade flows have grown faster than GDP over the last several decades, making it virtually impossible for individual countries to escape the consequences of world developments. This article selectively surveys recent IMF research on trade issues in three broad areas: (1) the effects of trade and trade policies; (2) the relationship between trade, growth, and inequality; and (3) the effects of trade liberalization in financial services.
Effects of Trade and Trade Policies
Does trade reform—often seen as a key component of structural reform—tend to improve welfare and growth? Does it also help the reforming country’s trading partners? A number of studies have demonstrated that trade barriers are quite costly to the countries that impose them. Wang (2001) investigated the impact of tariffs and nontariff barriers (NTBs) on imports of manufactured goods across 70 countries. He finds that a 1 percentage point increase in a tariff rate reduces imports by 2 percent, and that NTBs also significantly reduce imports. Tokarick (2003) used a general equilibrium trade model to show that the cost of support provided to farmers in Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries is substantial. He finds that if all OECD countries removed support to their agricultural sectors—both tariffs and subsidies—world welfare would increase by about US$100 billion (in 1997 dollars), with about 92 percent of these gains going to the advanced countries themselves. Li (2003) finds that trade liberalization has an important impact on real exchange rates. Real exchange rates generally depreciate after a country opens to trade, although there is evidence to suggest that noncredible liberalizations lead to real-exchange-rate appreciations.
A number of studies have evaluated the progress in trade liberalization on a regional basis. For the Caribbean region, Egoume Bossogo and Mendis (2002) find that greater integration among countries in the Caribbean common market (CARICOM) has stimulated both intraregional trade and trade between CARICOM countries and those outside the region. For the Middle East and Africa, the picture is a bit different. Al-Attrash and Yousef (2000) find that there is considerable scope for expanding intra-Arab and Arab trade with the rest of the world, using a gravity model. Blavy (2001) reaches a similar conclusion regarding trade in the Mashreq region (Egypt, Jordan, Israel, Lebanon, and Syria). Subramanian and Tamirisa (2001) find that Africa, especially Francophone Africa, is underexploiting its trading opportunities, that is, trading less than would be predicted from a gravity-type model.
One way that advanced countries have often tried to spur development in poor countries is to grant trade preferences to these countries, often in the form of lower tariffs applied to their exports. Mattoo, Roy, and Subramanian (2002) examined how the African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA), which offers trade preferences to certain African exports to the U.S. market, would affect Africa. They concluded that the benefits to Africa could be large, but these benefits would be diminished by the onerous rules of origin that are part of AGOA.
All of the above studies examined the effects of trade policies in a static context. Recent contributions to trade theory have emphasized that changes in trade policies can lead to dynamic gains, through changes in productivity, technological change, and induced investment. Jonsson and Subramanian (2000) studied episodes of trade liberalization in South Africa since the early 1970s. They found evidence that trade liberalization contributed significantly to the growth process by raising total factor productivity (TFP).
Visiting Scholars at the IMF, January–March 2003
Christopher Adam; University of Oxford, United Kingdom
Jushan Bai; New York University
Ernest Bamou; University of Yaoundé, Cameroon
Graham Bird; University of Surrey, United Kingdom
Michael Bordo; Rutgers University
Edward Buffie; Indiana University
Fabio Ghironi; Boston College
Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas; Princeton University
Joseph Joyce; Wellesley College
Grace Juhn; Harvard University
Bernadette Kamgnia; University of Yaoundé, Cameroon
Graciela Kaminsky; The George Washington University
Yevgeniya Kornienko; National Bank of Ukraine, Ukraine
Peter Maina; University of Nairobi, Kenya
Nancy Marion; Dartmouth College
John McDermott; Reserve Bank of New Zealand, New Zealand
Christopher Meissner; Cambridge University, United Kingdom
Enrique Mendoza; University of Maryland
Benjamin Ndong; Université Gaston Berger de Saint Louis, Senegal
Stephen O’Connell; Swarthmore College
Sawa Omori; University of Pittsburgh
Sergio Rebelo; Northwestern University
Andrew Rose; University of California, Berkeley
Massimo Sbracia; Bank of Italy, Italy
Christopher Sims; Princeton University
Barbara Stallings; Watson Institute, Brown University
Alex Taylor; Cambridge University, United Kingdom
Mark Taylor; Warwick University, United Kingdom
Robert Townsend; University of Chicago
Eric van Wincoop; University of Virginia
Yishay Yafeh; The Hebrew University, Israel
Trade, Growth, and Poverty
The relationship between greater openness to trade and rising income inequality, notably in advanced countries, has received a great deal of attention in recent years, partly because of the rapid increase in trade flows between industrial and many low-wage, developing countries in the 1980s and 1990s. Some researchers argue that the rapid rise in imports from low-wage countries has reduced the wages of unskilled workers relative to skilled workers in industrial countries. Tokarick (2002) decomposed the change in the skilled-unskilled wage gap in the United States between 1982 and 1996 into the portions that were attributable to changes in trade policy, factor supplies, and technology. Differences in the degree of skill-biased technical change across sectors is the main factor underlying the observed change in the wage gap in the United States; changes in trade policies had very little influence on the observed wage gap. When developments in a nontraded sector are considered, an expansion in trade, through a reduction in trade barriers, could narrow the wage gap. Bannister and Thugge (2001) study the link between trade reform and poverty and note that trade liberalization has an overall positive effect on the employment and income of the poor, but there may be winners and losers.
The relationship between trade, growth, and poverty has been the subject of heated debate in recent years. In a comprehensive survey of the literature, Berg and Krueger (2003) consider the effects of openness on both average income growth and the distribution of incomes for a given growth rate. The authors reach three conclusions: (1) a wealth of evidence supports that the principal cause of changes in absolute poverty is changes in average per capita income; (2) openness to trade is an important determinant of growth; and (3) growth associated with trade liberalization does not adversely affect the poor to any greater degree than growth in general does. Brunner (2003) argues that it is important to distinguish between the effects of trade openness on the level of income and on the growth rate of income. Using a panel data model, and instrumental variables to allow for trade and income being endogenous variables, he finds that a 1 percentage point change in trade is associated with a 1 percentage point change in average income, a finding that is significantly different from zero and robust to changes in alternative econometric specifications. Nonetheless, the estimated impact of trade on income growth is small and not robust to model specification. Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi (2002) find that institutions are more important than trade or geography in influencing long-run levels of income, with the positive impact of trade felt through its role in improving institutional quality.
Trade and Financial Sector Policies
As the various crises in recent years have shown, developments in a country’s financial sector can be transmitted to the real economy through financial intermediation and to other countries through international trade linkages. There is a large body of work on this issue, including Berger and Wagner (2002), Caramazza, Ricci, and Salgado (2000), and Imbs (2003). Recent IMF research on financial sector liberalization has largely focused on three issues: (1) the channels through which financial sector liberalization affect a country’s financial stability, (2) the effects of financial sector liberalization on the macroeconomy, and (3) the proper sequence of liberalization of financial services with other types of liberalization. A general conclusion is that trade liberalization could complement other financial reforms by enhancing the efficiency and quality of financial services (see, e.g., Tamirisa and others, 2000).
In two papers, Kireyev (2002a, 2002b) investigates the link between the liberalization of financial services across countries and the stability of their financial systems. He concludes that financial sector liberalization has generally promoted financial sector stability and should be seen as an efficient policy instrument for achieving a variety of macroeconomic goals. Valckx (2002) is cautionary though he reaches similar conclusions. He finds that financial sector liberalization may be associated with increased vulnerability to currency and banking crises—a short-term effect—that is attenuated over time as the effects of greater efficiency and resource allocation take hold.
Bhattacharya (2000) studies the different effects of financial sector liberalization depending on whether the capital account is open or closed. In the context of her general equilibrium model, she finds that when the capital account is open, financial sector liberalization leads to an increase in investment in the traded sector and exchange rate appreciation, while investment in the nontraded sector remains unaffected. This appreciation could offset some of the expansion in trade flows following a liberalization of trade in goods and, therefore, trade and financial sector reforms should not be undertaken simultaneously. Rather, she suggests that financial sector reform should be delayed until the traded sector can absorb the exchange rate appreciation.
References
Al-Attrash, Hassan, and Tarik Yousef, 2000, “Intra-Arab Trade—Is It Too Little?” IMF Working Paper 00/10.
Bannister, Geoffrey, and Kamau Thugge, 2001, “International Trade and Poverty Alleviation,” IMF Working Paper 01/54.
Berg, Andrew, and Anne Krueger, 2003, “Trade, Growth, and Poverty: A Selective Survey,” IMF Working Paper 03/30.
Berger, Wolfram, and Helmut Wagner, 2002, “Spreading Currency Crises: The Role of Economic Interdependence,” IMF Working Paper 02/144.
Bhattacharya, Rina, 2000, ”Trade and Domestic Financial Market Reform Under Political Uncertainty: Implications for Investment, Savings, and the Real Exchange Rate,” IMF Working Paper 00/175.
Blavy, Rodolphe, 2001, “Trade in the Mashreq: An Empirical Examination,” IMF Working Paper 01/163.
Brunner, Alan, 2003, “The Long-Run Effects of Trade on Income and Income Growth,” IMF Working Paper 03/37.
Caramazza, Francesco, Luca Ricci, and Ranil Salgado, 2000, “Trade and Financial Contagion in Currency Crises,” IMF Working Paper 00/55.
Egoume Bossogo, Philippe, and Chandima Mendis, 2002, “Trade and Integration in the Caribbean,” IMF Working Paper 02/148.
Imbs, Jean, 2003, “Trade, Finance, Specialization, and Synchronization,” IMF Working Paper 03/81.
Jonsson, Gunnar, and Arvind Subramanian, 2000, “Dynamic Gains from Trade—Evidence from South Africa,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 48, No. 1, pp. 197–224.
Kireyev, Alexei, 2002a, “Liberalization of Trade in Financial Services and Financial Sector Stability (Analytical Approach),” IMF Working Paper 02/138.
Kireyev, Alexei, 2002b, “Liberalization of Trade in Financial Services and Financial Sector Stability (Empirical Approach),” IMF Working Paper 02/139.
Li, Xiangming, 2003, “Trade Liberalization and Real Exchange Rate Movement,” IMF Working Paper 03/124.
Mattoo, Aaditya, Devesh Roy, and Arvind Subramanian, 2002, “The Africa Growth and Opportunity Act and Its Rules of Origin: Generosity Undermined?” IMF Working Paper 02/158.
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi, 2002, “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions Over Integration and Geography in Economic Development,” IMF Working Paper 02/189.
Subramanian, Arvind, and Natalia Tamirisa, 2001, “Africa’s Trade Revisited,” IMF Working Paper 01/33.
Tamirisa, Natalia, Piritta Sorsa, Geoffrey Bannister, Bradley McDonald, Jaro Wieczorek, 2000, “Trade Policy in Financial Services,” IMF Working Paper 00/31.
Tokarick, Stephen, 2002, “Quantifying the Impact of Trade on Wages: The Role of Nontraded Goods,” IMF Working Paper 02/191.
Tokarick, Stephen, 2003, “Measuring the Impact of Distortions in Agricultural Trade in Partial and General Equilibrium,” IMF Working Paper 03/110.
Valckx, Nico, 2002, “WTO Financial Services Commitments: Determinants and Impact on Financial Stability,” IMF Working Paper 02/214.
Wang, Qing, 2001, “Import-Reducing Effect of Trade Barriers: A Cross-Country Investigation,” IMF Working Paper 01/216.
Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options
Manmohan S. Kumar, Taimur Baig, Jörg Decressin, Chris Faulkner-MacDonagh, and Tarhan Feyzioğlu
This study presents the IMF staff’s analysis of the causes, consequences, and risks of deflation. It develops a novel methodology for assessing and quantifying deflation risk and applies it to a wide range of industrial and emerging market economies. The following are the main findings:
Deflation is seldom benign and it is difficult to anticipate. Historically, deflation generally muted growth prospects, although its most severe effects were felt mainly during the Great Depression.
There is only a relatively small risk of global deflation or of a deflationary spiral, but, according to an Index of Deflation Vulnerability, there are increasing risks of a period of falling prices in some major economies and in several smaller ones. The risks occur against a background of postwar low inflation rates, large output gaps, the bursting of the equity price bubble, banking sector stresses in some economies, and declining credit growth.
Policies can be effective in warding off deflation, but only if preemptive, forceful, and sometimes unconventional steps are taken. It is better to prevent deflation than to try to cure it, and monetary policy must take the lead. Since the risks of deflation are asymmetric, policy must be attuned to deflationary impulses in a low inflation environment. Further, because these impulses can impede the monetary transmission mechanism, aggressive action is required. At the zero bound on nominal interest rates, unorthodox measures may be needed. Stimulatory fiscal policies and structural reforms, particularly those improving credit intermediation, can play an important complementary role.