Abstract
The IMF Research Bulletin, a quarterly publication, selectively summarizes research and analytical work done by various departments at the IMF, and also provides a listing of research documents and other research-related activities, including conferences and seminars. The Bulletin is intended to serve as a summary guide to research done at the IMF on various topics, and to provide a better perspective on the analytical underpinnings of the IMF’s operational work.
Agnès Belaisch
In January 1999, mounting pressure on the Brazilian exchange rate forced the authorities to float the real. The new government, which had just taken office, undertook to devise policies that would lead the country out of the crisis and protect it against further turbulence. In the years that followed, the government would establish the credibility of its new inflation targeting framework and implement a fiscal adjustment that would allow Brazil to weather the substantial shocks that have recently struck emerging market economies. During this time, the IMF supported Brazil through a Stand-By Arrangement negotiated in the aftermath of the Russian default, followed by a second program negotiated in the summer of 2001. Recent IMF research on Brazil has focused on these difficult policy challenges; this article provides an overview of the research.
Brazil’s crawling-peg exchange rate regime came under attack in the latter half of 1998, partly as a result of financial turmoil in other emerging markets. The Russian default in August 1998 resulted in significantly curtailing access to international capital markets for many emerging markets.1 In a period of presidential elections, the Brazilian Central Bank (BCB) increased short-term interest rates from 19 to 43 percent in two months to fend off a speculative attack on the real and defend the exchange rate band. However, without other supporting policy adjustments, the loss of credibility of the exchange rate regime was so strong that a large IMF program approved in December could not reverse it. After a significant loss of reserves, the BCB allowed the real to float in mid-January 1999. In the following months, inflation was selected as a formal nominal anchor and Brazil became the first inflation targeting country with an IMF-supported adjustment program. IMF staff research focused on identifying the parameters of decision making under this new monetary framework.
One key element for the BCB was to be able to determine the timing and scope for preemptive policy action when inflation was expected to deviate from its targeted path (Leone, 1999).2 Schwartz (1999; Rabanal and Schwartz, 2000a) asks whether the low pass-through of the depreciation of the real to domestic prices following the float is a structural feature of the economy or only reveals a long lag in price adjustments.3 His vector autoregression (VAR) model confirms that the exchange rate pass-through is smaller in Brazil than in other countries due to the low reliance of the economy on imports and a large output gap—it is, however, more rapid. How could monetary policy affect aggregate demand rapidly? Rabanal and Schwartz (2000b), using a VAR model, find that the overnight interbank rate (Selic) is the most effective instrument to affect aggregate demand rapidly, and that the transmission of policy works primarily through a bank lending channel.4
Another crucial ingredient of successful inflation targeting is the ability to announce reliable inflation forecasts. Rabanal and Schwartz (2000c) show that VAR and Bayesian VAR models are useful tools in the case of Brazil; today these types of models complement the structural model used by the BCB to forecast inflation.5 Building on the experience of Brazil, Blejer and others (2001) analyze the adjustment to program conditionality necessary when a country adopts inflation targeting.6
This new monetary framework could not have worked without accompanying fiscal reform. In 1999, the government crafted a new institutional fiscal framework aimed at improving fiscal management and ensuring sustainability. Zandamela (1999) and de Mello (2002a) assess how borrowing limits, spending rules, and sanctions embedded in the Fiscal Responsibility Law (FRL) imposed fiscal discipline at the different levels of government.7 Ramos (2000) simulates the medium-term path of fiscal expenditure and revenue, casts it in a macroeconomic framework, and concludes that, if the FRL is respected, projected public deficit and debt would be sustainable.8 De Mello’s (2002b) VAR model shows that, in the spirit of the FRL, Brazil’s impressive fiscal adjustment since the float is the result of a common retrenchment effort by central and subnational governments and public enterprises.9 Despite such recent progress, Ramos and Tanner (2002) find no evidence yet of monetary dominance—where fiscal deficits adjust to changes in public liabilities in order to limit debt accumulation—in Brazil.10 In related work, Goldfajn (1998) examines the implication of recent macroeconomic developments in Brazil on the structure of its public debt.11
Even with the adoption of a flexible exchange regime, the persistence of large current account deficits remains a concern for macroeconomic growth and stability. Rossi (2000) simulates the IMF’s multicountry dynamic model (Multimod) and concludes that continued fiscal discipline and progress in developing an import substitution industry would increase confidence in the Brazilian economy, reduce debt spreads, and ensure medium-term external sustainability.12 Paiva (2000) analyzes external sustainability by looking at the nature and destination of foreign direct investment (FDI) in Brazil, which as a percentage of GDP grew sevenfold during 1995–99.13 He finds that, because FDI responded positively to structural reforms, it would remain a reliable source of finance even after privatization inflows subside and would continue to increase productivity, exports, and output. Estimating a gravity model, Bannister (2002) demonstrates that integration with Mercosur has benefited Brazil’s exports; however, further trade liberalization by Brazil and its partners would be required to stimulate manufacturing trade.14
During this stabilization period, growth has remained weak and IMF research has endeavored to analyze which policies could lay the groundwork for growth-enhancing economic performance. Maia and Perez (2000) find that state-owned banks fare much worse than their private sector counterparts, and that the government’s ongoing plan to privatize or liquidate these banks would improve the soundness and profitability of the system.15 Also, credit remains low as a share of GDP, and Belaisch (2002) finds that a lack of competition in the banking system could help explain the high level of lending interest rates.16 A low savings rate represents a serious impediment to higher and more sustainable growth in Brazil, and Paiva and Jahan (2002) find that further fiscal consolidation and financial deepening would be likely to raise private savings in the long run.17
Brazil has one of the highest levels of income inequality in the world and, as a result, allocates considerable resources to social programs. In the process of fiscal retrenchment associated with ongoing reforms, the IMF views as critical the need to strengthen social policy instruments while looking for ways to make them more cost effective. Gupta and others (1999) and de Mello (2000c, 2000d) review the effectiveness of various social programs and conclude that they do not provide adequate social protection: better targeting of benefits, rather than increased spending, would allow a more effective expansion of the safety net.18
I. Goldfajn and T. Baig, “The Russian Default and the Contagion to Brazil,” IMF Working Paper 00/160, 2000. Also see I. Goldfajn and E. Cardoso, “Capital Flows to Brazil: The Endogeneity of Capital Controls,” IMF Working Paper 97/115, 1997.
A. Leone, “Inflation Targeting in the Brazilian Setting,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 99/97, 1999.
G. Schwartz, “Price Developments After the Floating of the Real: The First Six Months,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 99/97, 1999; P. Rabanal and G. Schwartz, “Exchange Rate Changes and Consumer Price Inflation: 20 Months After the Floating of the Real,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000a.
P. Rabanal and G. Schwartz, “Forecasting Inflation in Brazil: How Useful Are Time Series Techniques?” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000b.
P. Rabanal and G. Schwartz, “Testing the Effectiveness of the Overnight Interest Rate as a Monetary Policy Instrument,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000c.
M. Blejer, A. Leone, P. Rabanal, and G. Schwartz, “Inflation Targeting in the Context of IMF-Supported Adjustment Programs,” IMF Working Paper 01/31, 2001.
R. Zandamela, “Brazil: The Fiscal Responsibility Law,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 99/97, 1999; L. de Mello, “Brazil’s Fiscal Adjustment: An Overview of ‘Fiscal Responsibility’ Reforms and Legislation,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 02/12, 2002a.
A. Ramos, “Medium and Long-Term Fiscal Sustainability in Brazil: 2000–10,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000.
L. de Mello, “Fiscal Consolidation in Brazil: How Much Is Due to the Subnational Governments and Public Enterprises?,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 02/12, 2002b.
A. Ramos and E. Tanner, “Fiscal Sustainability and Monetary versus Fiscal Dominance: Evidence from Brazil, 1991–2000,” IMF Working Paper 02/5, 2002.
I. Goldfajn, “Public Debt Indexation and Denomination: The Case of Brazil,” IMF Working Paper 98/18, 1998.
M. Rossi, H. Faruqee, and S. Mursula, “Medium-and Long-Term Current Account Stability in Brazil,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000.
C. Paiva, “Foreign Direct Investment and Transnational Enterprises in Brazil,” in Brazil Selected Issues” IMF Staff Country Report 00/251,2000.
G. Bannister, “Brazil and Mercosur: Identifying Trade Creation and Trade Diversion,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 02/12, 2002.
G. Maia and L. Pérez, “Restructuring Brazil’s State-Owned Financial System,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251,2000.
A. Belaisch, “Bank Intermediation and Competition in Brazil,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 02/12, 2002.
C. Paiva and S. Jahan, “An Empirical Study of Private Savings in Brazil,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 02/12, 2002.
S. Gupta, R. Gillingham, and L. de Mello, “Strengthening Social Policy Instruments,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 99/97, 1999; L. de Mello, “Social Spending in Brazil: Recent Trends in Social Assistance and Insurance,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000c; idem, “Social Spending in Brazil: Education and Health Care,” in Brazil Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report 00/251, 2000d. Also see C. Benedicts, “Income Distribution and Social Expenditure in Brazil,” IMF Working Paper 97/120, 1997.
International Conference on National Poverty Reduction Strategies
Summary by Gita Bhatt
The IMF and World Bank organized and held an international conference on poverty reduction strategies in Washington, DC, on January 14–17, 2002. The conference was part of a joint review of the poverty reduction strategy papers (PRSPs) approach and brought together country officials from almost all eligible low-income countries, representatives from donor organizations, and civil society representatives to discuss experiences and lessons learned in the PRSP process. A half-day session was also devoted to reviewing the IMF’s concessional lending window for low-income countries—the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF).
Ideas and proposals were the purpose and the product of the conference. Reflecting the extensive consultation (including four regional events) that had already taken place, the international conference refined and reinforced the main messages that had been emerging from stakeholders and partners. Chief among these messages was a strong endorsement of the PRSP approach, which all agreed had made important progress in a relatively short time. The PRSP gave central focus to poverty reduction, strengthened participation in policy making, and provided a single strategy around which development partners could align their development assistance.
The conference simultaneously highlighted many areas where improvements were needed, with greater efforts required on moving beyond refining the participatory process to focusing on content and effective implementation of countries’ strategies. In his opening remarks, IMF Managing Director, Horst Köhler, noted that poverty reduction takes time and sustained effort, and he cautioned that while we need to be “ambitious” in our objectives, we must be “realistic” in our methods. Recurring themes during the conference included the importance of building the capacities of governments and civil society; the need to set realistic goals and targets, especially growth targets, and manage expectations; the need to factor external shocks into country strategies, and for the international community to revisit the availability and flexibility of instruments to deal with the shocks; the desirability of considering alternative policy choices in the PRSP process; and the importance of flexibility to allow for different country starting points.
The various discussions centered around several key aspects of the PRSP, notably its call for broad participation and country ownership, comprehensive policy actions rooted in an analysis of country needs, and supportive actions, such as better alignment of donor assistance with the PRSP goals and effective monitoring that would allow everyone to gauge the progress being made. The following points raised the most interest and debate among participants.
Participation. The PRSP approach was acknowledged as contributing to more open dialogue within governments and with, at least, some parts of civil society than had previously existed. As the same time, the need to strengthen and institutionalize participatory processes, with respect to a broad range of domestic stakeholders as well as development partners, was stressed. The importance of involving parliamentarians in the preparation, approval, and monitoring of country strategies was also noted.
Content. Many participants focused on the enormous challenge of deciding how best to prioritize among sectors and design policies to achieve growth beneficial to the poor. There was recognition that the international community’s knowledge of what policies can best reduce poverty is incomplete—and that improving knowledge in this area would be critical to improving the well-being of the poor. In this regard, better understanding of the sources of sustainable growth and strengthening the linkages between policies and poverty outcomes were critical. Finally, there was strong emphasis on the need for development partners, including the World Bank and the IMF, to assist countries in their efforts to improve their public expenditure management systems so that poverty reducing spending could be effectively delivered and monitored, to undertake systematic poverty and social impact analyses of major policy choices, and design offsetting compensatory measures. In each of these areas, conference participants called for further research and the development of better analytical tools.
Alignment. Nearly all bilateral and multilateral donors have agreed to the principle of aligning their assistance programs with PRSPs. However, participants noted that much remains to be done to achieve this objective. There is a pressing need for donors to reduce the cost to low-income countries of mobilizing and utilizing aid so that both aid resources and limited country capacity can be used more effectively. This includes harmonizing and simplifying reporting requirements and aligning assistance with national cycles of government decision making, including the budget. More information on medium-term aid commitments and greater predictability of aid flows, especially to those countries implementing sound policies, would help low-income countries better plan and implement their strategies.
The PRGF. Has the design of PRGF-supported programs been faithful to the objective of poverty reduction and growth? Participants noted that efforts to streamline structural conditionality, to increase budget allocations for spending that is beneficial to the poor, and to provide more flexible fiscal frameworks were proceeding well. In other areas, however, more progress and more rapid actions were needed. In particular, many civil society participants wanted more evidence that the PRGF-supported programs were, in fact, drawn from and consistent with countries’ PRSPs. They also suggested that the openness and transparency of PRGF-supported programs could be bolstered through discussions of alternative policy scenarios, greater analysis of their poverty and social impact, and more elaboration in IMF staff reports about the policy dialogue and policy choices considered in program design.
What is the PRSP Approach?
In September 1999, the IMF and World Bank adopted a new approach to help developing countries better position themselves to speed up growth and eradicate poverty. An important element of this approach has been a refocusing of development assistance—beyond the operations of the IMF and the World Bank—around national poverty reduction strategy papers (PRSPs), which more than 60 countries are now developing and implementing. The objectives of the PRSP approach—all of which are directed toward the fundamental goal of poverty reduction—are to ensure country ownership of poverty reduction strategies; develop strategies that take a comprehensive, long-term perspective; strengthen participation in policy making, including by tapping the views of a broad cross section of society, especially the poor; focus on results that matter for the poor; and foster domestic and external partnerships that improve the effectiveness of development assistance.
Details about the conference proceedings and the resulting staff papers on the PRSP and PRGF reviews can be found on the IMF website at http://www.imf.org/External/NP/prgf/2002/list.htm.
Visiting Scholars at the IMF, January–March 2002
Philippe Bacchetta; Study Center Gerzensee, Switzerland
Michael Bordo; Rutgers University
Giancarlo Corsetti; University of Rome III, Italy
Morris Goldstein; Institute for International Economics
Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas; Princeton University
David Hummels; Purdue University
Graciela Kaminsky; The George Washington University
Michael Keane; Yale University
Ari Kuncoro; University of Indonesia, Indonesia
Philip Lane; Trinity College Dublin, Ireland
Ronald MacDonald; University of Strathclyde, U.K.
Dalia Marin; University of Munich, Germany
Stephen Morris; Yale University
Anthony Musonda; Bank of Zambia, Zambia
Zafar Nasar; Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Pakistan
A.F. Odusola; NCEMA, Nigeria
Arvind Panagariya; University of Maryland
William Perraudin; Birbeck College, U.K.
Raghuram Rajan; University of Chicago
Assaf Razin; Tel Aviv University, Israel
Andrew Rose; University of California at Berkeley
Nouriel Roubini; New York University
Kenneth Singleton; Stanford Graduate School of Business
Robert Townsend; University of Chicago
Elias Udeaja; University of Ibadan, Nigeria
George von Furstenberg; Fordham University
Beatrice Weder; University of Mainz, Germany
Conference on Macroeconomic Policies and Poverty Reduction
Summary by Catherine Pattillo
The IMF Research Department organized and held a Conference on Macroeconomic Polices and Poverty Reduction in Washington, DC, on March 14–15, 2002.* Key themes included: aid effectiveness and the debt burden in low-income countries, trade reform and inequality, the role of financial institutions in poverty reduction, poverty and distributional consequences of financial crises and large shocks, and the politics of fiscal expenditures for the poor. The conference agenda and brief descriptions of the papers follow.
Aid and Debt
Odious Debt
Michael Kremer and Seema Jayachandran (Harvard University)
Discussant: Raquel Fernandez (New York University)
Aid and Fiscal Management
Aleš Bulíř and Timothy Lane (IMF)
Discussant: Alberto Alesina (Harvard University)
Trade and Inequality
Trade Reforms and Income Inequality in Colombia
Orazio Attanasio (University College London), Pinelopi Goldberg (Yale University), and Nina Pavcnik (Dartmouth College)
Discussant: T.N. Srinivasan (Yale University)
Finance and Poverty
Safety Nets and Financial Institutions in the Asian Crisis: The Allocation of Within-Country Risk
Robert Townsend (University of Chicago)
Discussant: Abhijit Banerjee (MIT)
Do Rural Banks Matter? Evidence from the Indian Social Banking Experiment
Robin Burgess (London School of Economics) and Rohini Pande (Columbia University)
Discussant: Jonathan Morduch (New York University)
Poverty and Distributional Effects of Crises and Large Shocks
Financial Crises, Poverty, and Income Distribution
Emanuele Baldacci, Luiz de Mello, and Gabriela Inchauste (IMF)
Discussant: Ceclia Garćia-Peñalosa (GREQAM)
Growth, Shocks, and Poverty During Economic Reform: Evidence from Rural Ethiopia
Stefan Dercon (Oxford University)
Discussant: Angus Deaton (Princeton University)
Crises and Political Economy of Safety Nets
Economic Shocks, Wealth, and Welfare
Elizabeth Frankenberg (UCLA), James P. Smith (RAND), and Duncan Thomas (UCLA)
Discussant: François Bourguignon (World Bank)
Who Is Protected? Theory and Evidence on the Incidence of Fiscal Expansions and Contractions
Martin Ravallion (World Bank)
Discussants: Michael Keen (IMF) and Lant Pritchett (Harvard University—JFK School of Government)
Kremer and Jayachandran argue that sovereign debt, incurred without the consent of the people and to benefit the elite, should be considered odious and that successor governments should not be responsible for repayment. In a sovereign debt model, they show how an international institution, in denouncing a regime as odious, could create an equilibrium whereby creditors would stop odious lending because successor governments would not be held responsible or suffer a reputational penalty by refusing to repay the debt. If the institution declared debt odious ex ante of the debt being incurred, and by a supermajority, potential problems of alleged favoritism to debtors by the institution and possible drying up of the loan market for other countries could be avoided.
Bulir and Lane show that foreign aid is more volatile than domestic fiscal revenue, particularly for countries heavily dependent on aid. Aid is also procyclical, so that, rather than smoothing out cyclical shocks, it tends to exacerbate them. In addition, official aid commitments are more likely to be in excess of aid disbursements rather than less, even for countries with ‘on-track’ programs. The authors then discuss the implications of these findings for short-term fiscal policy management.
Attanasio, Goldberg and Pavcnik find that trade liberalization in Colombia was associated with greater wage inequality and an increase in the relative wages of skilled workers. Tariff reductions work their way through the economy and contribute to the following: increased returns for the college educated, lower industry premiums for sectors with higher shares of unskilled workers, and a shift of the labor force toward the informal sector. However, trade liberalization explains only a small share of the worsening wage inequality.
Using panel data for the crisis period in Thailand, Townsend finds that regional and idiosyncratic shocks are even more important than macro shocks in explaining consumption and investment changes. The author uses the theory of optimal allocation of risk bearing as a benchmark against which to evaluate the role of the financial system, financial sector reforms, and safety net policies. The limited risk-reallocation role played by financial institutions, including commercial banks and the primary agricultural development bank, was partly a function of financial sector policies which contributed to distortions. Money lenders and the informal sector were also not able to help smooth investment during this period.
Burgess and Pande challenge the conventional view that large-scale government intervention in credit markets is ineffective and ends up benefiting elites. They study the Indian “social banking experiment,” 1969–92, when government policies favored the expansion of bank branches into previously “unbanked” locations, and find that the policy helped reduce rural poverty and inequality. After observing a trend break, where states with more banking locations in 1961 saw faster growth in bank locations before 1977 (the turning point in social banking policy), but slower growth after 1977, they ask whether diversification, poverty and inequality also exhibit a similar trend break. The authors also use an instrumental variables approach to try and control for factors, such as income growth, which affect both potential bank profitability in “unbanked” locations and the diversification and welfare outcomes.
Baldacci, de Mello, and Inchauste use both cross-country macro data and micro data, from before and after the 1994–95 Mexican crisis, to ask how poverty and income distribution is affected by financial crises. The cross-country analysis compares precrisis and postcrisis average changes in welfare indicators in countries which experienced crises, relative to a control sample of countries which did not experience crises. They find an increase in poverty and a worsening of income distribution after crises, transmitted through inflation, unemployment, lower growth and reduced government spending. The Mexican data also show increases in poverty postcrisis, although inequality did not increase because of a disproportionate decline in the income of the wealthiest.
Dercon analyzes the determinants of consumption growth and poverty changes in Ethiopia during the 1990s, a period of economic reform. The theoretical framework is a farm income-generation model used to analyze the links among changes in fixed endowments, relative prices, and shocks and the effects on consumption. Dercon finds that reforms, including the liberalization of agricultural prices, helped some households grow out of poverty. Among the poor, those with better endowments of land, labor, and access to roads were better able to take advantage of the opportunities that reforms provided. Common and idiosyncratic shocks matter greatly for consumption, suggesting imperfect risk-sharing, credit, and savings opportunities.
The 1998 Indonesian crisis marked a dramatic and unexpected reversal of economic growth—real GDP fell by about 15 percent in one year. Brandenburg, Smith, and Thomas provide evidence of how households attempted to smooth out the effects of large, unanticipated shocks, and evaluate the consequences of those strategies for welfare indicators. They find that households adopted many mechanisms by which they adjusted to the crisis and maintained consumption, or exploited the new opportunities that arose for some. Households reorganized living arrangements, increased labor supply, and deferred expenditure on some goods. Rural households sold gold to smooth consumption—one of the only assets whose value did not decline with the collapse of the rupiah and spiraling inflation.
Ravallion asks who is protected when crises or reforms result in large budget cuts. He shows that the answer is theoretically ambiguous, depending on a “utility effect,” that is, how quickly the marginal utility of the non-poor’s spending on the poor declines relative to spending on themselves as compared with a “power effect.” The paper then draws on micro-based empirical studies of social programs in India, Bangladesh, and Argentina, which study how the incidence of spending varies with the aggregate level of spending. Ravallion finds that spending on the non-poor is protected from budget cuts and targeting worsens during fiscal contraction. The paper also discusses the policy implications for designing effective safety net policies.
The conference concluded with a panel discussion on “Poverty Reduction: What Are the New Ideas?” featuring Anne Krueger (IMF), Nicholas Stern (World Bank), Montek Ahluwalia (IMF), Santiago Levy (Instituto Méxicano des Seguro Social), and Nancy Birdsall (Center for Global Development).
* Organizing Committee: Ashoka Mody, Ratna Sahay, and Catherine Pattillo.Proceedings of IMF conferences and seminars, including agenda and papers, can be obtained through the “Conferences, Seminars and Workshops” link at the Research at the IMF website at http://www.imf.org/research.