Would “Cold Turkey” Work in Turkey?
Author:
Oya Celasun https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Oya Celasun in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. R. G Gelos
Search for other papers by Mr. R. G Gelos in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4362-676X
, and
Mr. Alessandro Prati
Search for other papers by Mr. Alessandro Prati in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

Oya Celasun is an Economist in the Research Department, R. Gaston Gelos is an Economist in the Western Hemisphere Department, and Alessandro Prati is a Deputy Division Chief in the Research Department; all are with the International Monetary Fund. The authors wish to thank Richard Clarida, Mark Griffiths, Juha Kähkönen, Ratna Sahay, Antonio Spilimbergo, Carlos Végh, an anonymous referee, and the Editor for helpful comments and discussions, and the Research Department of the Central Bank of Turkey for useful suggestions.

When inflation rates in a country are persistently high, observers often believe that the inflation process has become “inertial,” posing an obstacle to disinflation. Using an innovative approach, we assess the empirical validity of this argument for the case of Turkey. We find that the current degree of inflation persistence in Turkey is lower than in Brazil and Uruguay prior to their successful stabilization programs. More significantly, expectations of future inflation are more important than past inflation in shaping the inflation process, providing little evidence of “backward-looking” behavior. Using survey data, we find that inflation expectations, in turn, largely depend on the evolution of fiscal variables. [JEL E31, E52]

Abstract

When inflation rates in a country are persistently high, observers often believe that the inflation process has become “inertial,” posing an obstacle to disinflation. Using an innovative approach, we assess the empirical validity of this argument for the case of Turkey. We find that the current degree of inflation persistence in Turkey is lower than in Brazil and Uruguay prior to their successful stabilization programs. More significantly, expectations of future inflation are more important than past inflation in shaping the inflation process, providing little evidence of “backward-looking” behavior. Using survey data, we find that inflation expectations, in turn, largely depend on the evolution of fiscal variables. [JEL E31, E52]

Bringing down inflation from persistently high levels while avoiding economic disruption remains one of the most important challenges for policymakers in many developing countries. The critical question in a disinflation attempt is how quickly inflation will respond to a tightening in monetary policy. If agents are predominantly forward looking and the monetary tightening is credible, actual and expected inflation will quickly adjust to the new regime and the output costs will be small, even if disinflation is rapid—that is, if a “cold turkey” policy is adopted.1 By contrast, if agents’ price-setting behavior is backward looking because of wage and price indexation or adaptive expectations, disinflation will need to be more gradual to minimize output losses. For this reason, it is important to be able to assess the extent to which inflation has an “inertial” component. Methodological questions on how to address this problem have therefore received significant attention in the academic literature.2

Turkey is an ideal case study for these issues, because it has experienced persistently high inflation since the 1970s. In contrast to many other high-inflation countries, which at some point experienced hyperinflation, Turkey’s inflation has never exploded, with annual inflation rates hovering around stable but gradually increasing plateaus, ranging from 40 percent to 120 percent over the last decade. This persistence has led many to believe that inflation is largely driven by inertia, with entrenched inflation expectations posing an obstacle to any disinflation attempt. In fact, the failure of the 2000 stabilization program supported by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) has been attributed by many to the presence of inflation inertia.3

We find little empirical support for this argument. First, the univariate properties of inflation dynamics show that the current degree of inflation persistence in Turkey is lower than that of Brazil and Uruguay prior to their successful stabilization programs. Second, using a framework similar to that in Galí and Gertler (1999), and employing both price and survey data, we find that expectations of future inflation are more important than past inflation in shaping the inflation process. Third, an examination of the determinants of inflation expectations shows that expectations depend largely on the evolution of fiscal variables.

Contrary to a widely held view, these findings suggest that backward-looking contracts do not pose a serious constraint to the disinflation process. Indeed, authorities could effectively control the speed of the disinflation by adopting and maintaining policies that influence expectations of future inflation. Moreover, since inflation is determined to a large extent by forward-looking behavior, output costs associated with a rapid disinflation program are likely to be relatively low. A credible fiscal consolidation is probably the key to reducing inflation, because inflation expectations will decline only if the public perceives that the need to monetize fiscal deficits or inflate away the debt stock has come to an end.

On methodological grounds, our paper innovates by making extensive use of survey data. While survey data have previously been used in the literature, we go one step further by attempting to explain the formation of expectations, explicitly distinguishing between fiscal and monetary factors.4

The main aim of this paper, however, is to answer a policy question; for this reason, we do not restrict ourselves to a single empirical approach, but present the results from various alternative methods, hoping to assemble a body of convincing evidence supporting our conclusion.

I. Macroeconomic Setting in 1990–2003

High inflation and volatile economic growth have been defining features of the Turkish economy over the last few decades (Figures 1 and 2). Against a background of low and declining inflation in most other countries, including many of the formerly chronic-inflation cases of Latin America, Turkish inflation averaged 80 percent per year in 1991–99. While a number of stabilization attempts were made throughout the decade, for most of the 1990s disinflation was not on the forefront of the policy agenda.5

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

12-Month CPI Inflation, Turkey, 1991–2003

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2004, 003; 10.5089/9781589063518.024.A004

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

GDP Growth, Turkey, 1991–2002

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2004, 003; 10.5089/9781589063518.024.A004

Turkey entered the 1990s with a newly liberalized capital account, strong capital flows, and expansionary fiscal policies financed to a significant extent by monetary expansion. When the government attempted to increase the share of direct monetary financing to curb interest payments in early 1994, the loss of confidence in the lira and the reversal of capital inflows were swift, and a major currency crisis ensued. An IMF-supported program stemmed the crisis, but the program went off-track in mid-1995. Nonetheless, capital flows to emerging markets were substantial in 1995–97, and the Turkish economy enjoyed strong economic growth on the back of short-term capital inflows.

Although the aftermath of the 1994 crisis was characterized by incomplete structural reform efforts and the absence of a credible nominal anchor to coordinate inflation expectations, progress was made in some areas. The balance on the primary fiscal account averaged a surplus of 2.2 percent in 1994–97, as opposed to a deficit of 0.8 percent in 1990–93 (Figure 3). Central Bank financing of the fiscal deficits was gradually reduced and eliminated from 1997 onward. Nonetheless, the improvement in the primary balance was partly reversed after 1996, and the overall deficit of the public sector—the primary deficit plus interest payments—remained high. This reflected also the high interest bill due to the uncertainty associated with the path of inflation and incomplete confidence in the fiscal policy adjustments. Monetary policy remained accommodating, subordinating any quest of inflation reduction to the goal of stabilizing the financial markets toward a smooth functioning of the government domestic borrowing process. Inflation, as a result, ratcheted up to around 100 percent at end-1997.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Overall and Primary Deficit, Turkey, 1990–2002

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2004, 003; 10.5089/9781589063518.024.A004

By the end of the decade, Turkey’s increasingly exceptional status among emerging markets in experiencing high and volatile inflation led to heightened perceptions of the cost of these high inflation rates. The resulting broadened consensus on the desirability of disinflation and macroeconomic stabilization paved the way for the disinflation efforts starting in 1998.

The government adopted a gradualist stabilization program in early 1998, targeting an inflation rate of 50 percent by end-1998. The Russian financial crisis in August 1998 led to severe capital outflows and a massive increase in public sector borrowing costs, but the monetary program was by and large maintained, and inflation was brought down to about 70 percent at end-1998.

The year 1999 witnessed two severe earthquakes, a continued compression of foreign capital, and a gross domestic product (GDP) decline of 4.7 percent. Against a background of unwieldy borrowing conditions, the government adopted an ambitious exchange rate-based disinflation program in December 1999, adopting a crawling peg of the lira against a basket of 1 U.S. dollar and 0.77 euro, and targeting a consumer price index (CPI) inflation rate of 25 percent by the end of 2002. A sizable fiscal retrenchment was achieved, but the exchange rate came under severe pressure as a result of a liquidity shortage in the banking sector in November 2000. The peg was broken in February 2001 following renewed pressures in the banking sector and a massive outflow of foreign capital.

Despite a rebound of inflation following the devaluation and the switch to a floating exchange rate regime in February 2001, inflation was on a declining path in 2002–03, and the fiscal stabilization was sustained, underpinned to a sizable extent by the long-postponed structural reforms.

II. What Do We Know About Wage and Price Indexation?

Although there is a perception that a significant share of wage and price contracts in Turkey are indexed to past inflation, there is little comprehensive documentation of the nature of indexation in various sectors of the economy. The contract length in the small fraction of the private sector covered by collective bargaining (about 350,000 workers) is typically two years, with six-month backward indexation. The wages of the vast majority of workers are negotiated on a firm-by-firm basis, and little is known about the contracts’ nature, except that their length is usually six months. The 2000 program agreed on with the IMF included a shift in the inflation adjustment of civil service sector wages and pensions from a backward-looking mechanism to a forward-looking adjustment in line with projected inflation rates, with catch-up clauses. Currently, salaries of civil servants and blue-collar workers in the public sector are adjusted twice a year. Little is documented about other indexation mechanisms in the economy. Interestingly, Shiller (1997) cites Turkey as a puzzling example of a country with high and variable inflation without substantial indexing.

There is some inertia in public sector price adjustments, possibly contributing to inflation persistence. The government budget uses a backward-looking revaluation coefficient based on the average annual increase in the wholesale price index (WPI) to determine many taxes and user fees. Prices of utilities, medical supplies, and many food items are controlled by the government; the exact extent to which inflation adjustments in these areas are characterized by systematic inertial (i.e., backward-looking) behavior is not fully clear.

The time-series behavior of CPI subindices suggests that, in important non-tradable sectors of the economy, prices tend to be adjusted with lags of several month. We find that housing, health, and education prices appear to be the most sluggish, while prices of food, clothing, and housewares are the most flexible.6 The nontradable sector price increases seem to be set largely based on past inflation. The left-hand panels in Figure 4 show, as we would expect in such a case, that the ratio of the index of slowly adjusting prices (housing, health, education) to the overall CPI increases as inflation declines from end-1997 to end-2000, and diminishes when inflation accelerates in 2001. The right-hand panels in Figure 4 show that the ratios of those price categories that are more flexible than the average move in the same direction as the inflation rate.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Inflation Inertia and the Components of the CPI Index

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2004, 003; 10.5089/9781589063518.024.A004

Note: The term “s.a.” stands for “seasonally adjusted.”

III. Persistence: A Univariate Analysis

How important is inflation persistence in the aggregate? A univariate analysis of inflation dynamics indicates that inflation persistence in Turkey during 1994–2002 was small in both relative and absolute terms. We first estimated a simple regression of monthly CPI inflation on its lag and a linear trend for the period January 1994–February 2002. We then computed Andrews’s (1993) median unbiased estimator of the first-order autoregressive parameter and obtained the half-life estimates shown in Figure 5 by replicating this procedure on rolling samples of 60 observations.7 The estimated half-life of a unit shock to CPI inflation (the length of time needed to halve the magnitude of the original shock) is only about one month and has been relatively stable over time, remaining between 0.8 and 1.3 months over the last three years (top panel of Figure 5).8

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Inflation Persistence in Turkey, Uruguay, and Brazil

(Median unbiased half-life estimates of a unit shock and 90 percent confidence band)

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2004, 003; 10.5089/9781589063518.024.A004

Note: The solid lines represent the median unbiased half-life estimates of a unit shock, and the dotted lines represent the limits of the 90 percent confidence bands. See footnote 9 on the confidence bands of the estimates for Brazil.

CPI inflation in Turkey is also less persistent than in Uruguay and Brazil prior to their successful inflation stabilizations. Uruguay, like Turkey, had a history of high but relatively stable inflation before embarking on a successful stabilization program at the beginning of the 1990s, after inflation reached a peak of 140 percent. The middle panel in Figure 5 shows that in Uruguay, the half-life of a unit shock prior to stabilization was similar to or marginally higher than that of Turkey in February 2002. The case of Brazil is also of interest because it was a country with extensive backward wage and price indexation before the 1994 stabilization. This is reflected in half-life estimates between four and seven months (bottom panel in Figure 5).9

Although inflation persistence in Turkey is small, half-life estimates are always significantly different from zero (top panel in Figure 5), suggesting that further analysis is warranted. Univariate persistence may be due to backward-looking price setting, but it is also consistent with forward-looking behavior. Serial correlation in the variables that drive inflation, such as exchange rate depreciation or money growth, would reconcile univariate persistence and forward-looking behavior. The next section assesses the relative importance of backward- and forward-looking behavior by estimating a multivariate regression that nests both hypotheses.

IV. The Relative Importance of Backward-Versus Forward-Looking Behavior

The distinction between backward- and forward-looking price-setting behaviors is important from a policy point of view because the output costs of a rapid disinflation would tend to be higher with backward-looking behavior.10 By contrast, forward-looking price setters would quickly take into account the implications for inflation of a credible change in the monetary regime, thus making the costs of disinflation relatively small. In this section, after describing the empirical model, we use two alternative measures of inflation expectations—actual future inflation and survey inflation forecasts—to assess the degree of forward-looking pricing behavior in Turkey. We find that, although past inflation contributes to explaining current inflation dynamics, expectations of future inflation play a much more important role.

Empirical Model

We estimate an empirical model that nests the possibility of both backward- and forward-looking price-setting behavior. Traditional models of price stickiness with purely forward-looking agents do not generate inflation persistence. The Calvo (1983) model can be modified by assuming that only a fraction of the firms in the economy are forward looking, while the rest are backward looking.11 As in the original Calvo (1983) model, only a fraction of firms are assumed to change prices every period, while the rest keep prices constant. Forward-looking firms have rational expectations, and backward-looking price setters use a rule of thumb: they update the average new price in the most recent round of price adjustments by the most recently observed inflation rate. The resulting inflation rate in period t, πt equals

π t = ( 1 δ ) π t 1 + δ E t π t + 1 + λ ( V t * P t ) , ( 1 )

where Vt* corresponds to the logarithm of the price a forward-looking firm would select for period t if it were able to reset its price in each period, and Pt is the logarithm of the aggregate price level. The firms are assumed to be monopolistically competitive and therefore choose Vt* as the (logarithm) of a markup over nominal marginal costs, in deviation from steady state. The term Vt* - Pt then corresponds to the level of real marginal cost and is often proxied by the level of excess demand.12 We extend Celasun’s (2001) specification for the nontradables component of the Turkish CPI to the overall CPI, and we include in the equation terms proxying for marginal costs for tradable goods as well as the excess demand for nontradable goods and services. The degree of inflation inertia is governed by the parameter, 1-δ. The higher the share of backward-looking price setters, the larger is the weight 1-δ on the lagged inflation term. Similar equations can be motivated by other models that explain inflation persistence, such as Chadha, Masson, and Meredith (1992), Fuhrer and Moore (1995), Jadresic (2000), and Holden and Driscoll (2001).13

Estimates with Actual Future Inflation

We first estimate equations for Turkish CPI inflation, proxying expected future inflation rates with actual future inflation rates. Given that the measurement error introduced by using such a proxy is not orthogonal to the actual future realization of the inflation rate, the appropriate estimation technique involves using instrumental variables that are orthogonal to the expectational error. Moreover, the error term in this case follows an MA(1) process and is not necessarily homoscedastic, so we use the generalized method of moments (GMM) to take into account the structure of the error term. In addition to the lagged and future inflation terms, we include terms proxying for the marginal costs and the excess demand of the tradable and nontradable components of the CPI, respectively—the real wage (rwage) and the real exchange rate (rer)—and as a proxy for nontradables excess demand, the relative price of tradables with respect to nontradables in the CPI index (trntr) and the imports-to-GDP ratio (imp).14, 15 We do not impose any restrictions on the coefficients of these terms, letting them be determined by the data.16 Our set of instruments include three lags of inflation and all the other variables in the equation, three lags of the nominal interest rate, and a dummy variable for the second quarter of 1994 to account for the effect of the April 1994 crisis. The constant term in the equation is allowed to vary in the two subsamples, 1990: Q1–1994: Q1 and 1994: Q2–1998: Q1. The equation estimated for 1990: Q1–1998: Q1 is as follows, with standard errors in parentheses:17

π t = 0.38 π t 1 + 0.62 ( 0.08 * * ) E t π t + 1 + 0.44 ( 0.11 * * ) r e r t + 0.34 ( 0.09 * * ) r w a g e t + 0.62 ( 0.17 * * ) t r n t r t + 0.39 ( 0.05 * * ) i m p t . ( 2 )

The weight on expected future inflation is significant and positive but below one, and not statistically distinct from 0.5. All the four driving variables also enter the equation in a statistically significant manner, with the expected sign. Hansen’s J-statistic has a p-value of 0.378, implying that the instruments and the model are valid. To examine whether the degree of inflation inertia changed over time as a result of the recent disinflation efforts, we extend the sample by adding recursively one quarter of observations at a time, through 2001: Q4.

Figure 6 presents the estimates of the backward-looking coefficient 1–δ for CPI inflation obtained by gradually extending the sample period.18 The estimates show some evidence of inflation inertia, but the weight on lagged inflation falls from about 40 percent in the 1990: Q1–1998: Q1 sample to less than 15 percent in the full sample, suggesting that price setters’ behavior has become increasingly forward looking. Possibly, this is the result of the disinflation strategy followed in recent years, in particular the switch to forward-looking wage setting in the public sector mentioned above.19

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Turkey: Backward-Looking Behavior in CPI

(Recursive GMM estimates of lagged inflation coefficient and 95 percent confidence band)

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2004, 003; 10.5089/9781589063518.024.A004

Note: The shaded area covers the period of exchange rate based stabilization (ERBS).

Estimates with Survey Inflation Forecasts

We obtain broadly similar results when estimating equations in which survey CPI inflation expectations from Consensus Forecasts are used in lieu of expected inflation.20 Survey data allow us to depart from the rational expectations assumption made above and bypass the need to use the GMM. For Turkey, Consensus’s forecasts for average inflation in the current year and the following year are available on a monthly basis for the period 1995:1–1998:05 and bimonthly since then. In addition, since 1998:05, Consensus has been providing expectations data for the six individual months ahead, on a bimonthly basis. We estimate regressions for seasonally adjusted monthly and bimonthly inflation for 1998:05–2002:02 and semiannual and annual inflation for 1995:01–2002:02.21 For the inflation regressions for monthly or bimonthly inflation, Consensus data exist only for two years at a bimonthly frequency, reducing the number of observations. For those regressions that assume either six-month or one-year contracts, we have more than seven years of data at a monthly frequency.22 As a measure of excess demand, we use a seasonally adjusted series of capacity utilization, which is available on a monthly basis.

In most specifications, the estimates using survey forecast data reinforce the notion that inflation persistence does not have its main origin in backward looking behavior (Table 1). In the regressions with forecast horizons of six months and one year, the coefficient on lagged inflation is statistically indistinguishable from zero. In the estimates with a forecast horizon of one and two months, the evidence is more mixed. However, these regressions have small sample size and low explanatory power relative to those with six-monthly and annual inflation, casting doubt on the reliability of the estimates.23

Table 1.

CPI Inflation Regressions with Survey Data

(Newey-West standard errors in parentheses)

article image
Notes: *Denotes significance at the 5 percent confidence level. The set of instrumental variables include the constant term, inflation forecast, and the current value and three lags of the capacity utilization rate.

Granger-causality tests provide another indication that price setters are forward looking. Granger-causality tests are essentially tests of temporal precedence. If price setters were mainly backward looking, then changes in inflation would Granger-cause changes in inflation expectations, and not vice versa. However, the pattern is the opposite: for all horizons, we cannot reject the hypothesis that inflation expectations Granger-cause actual inflation, but the hypothesis that actual inflation Granger-causes inflation expectations can be rejected at the usual confidence levels (not shown).

V. What Determines Inflation Expectations?

As inflation expectations appear to play a dominant role in the price-setting mechanism, we conduct an empirical investigation of their determinants. We run two types of regressions to explain consensus forecasts of average inflation over the following 12 months. In the first set of regressions (first two columns of Table 2), we try to explain inflation expectations with a set of standard variables: monetary growth, the difference between the overnight rate and the deposit rate (to measure the stance of monetary policy), capacity utilization (to proxy for excess demand), lagged inflation, and exchange rate changes.24, 25 In addition, to assess whether inflation expectations are driven by expectations of monetization of fiscal deficits, we include the primary balance and the change in the nominal debt stock (both as ratios to GDP) as fiscal variables. In the second set of regressions (last two columns in Table 2), we relate inflation expectations to expectations about the size of the fiscal deficit. As data on fiscal expectations are available only since May 1998 at a bimonthly frequency, the number of observations in this case is much smaller. Moreover, given that fiscal balance expectations might be endogenous (at a minimum because inflation expectations affect interest rates and, thus, expected fiscal balances), we also estimate this specification with instrumental variables.26

Table 2.

Determinants of CPI Inflation Expectations

(Dependent variable: mean Consensus forecast of average inflation over the following 12-months; Newey-West standard errors in parentheses)

article image
Note: *Denotes significance at the 5 percent confidence level.

There is evidence that fiscal variables play an important role in determining inflation expectations. The results suggest that market participants closely follow fiscal developments when forming inflation expectations. In particular, in the first two columns of Table 2, the primary balance and changes in the debt (lagged one month) do have the expected sign (higher debt and deficits are associated with higher inflation expectations) and are significant at the 5 percent level, even after controlling for a broad set of variables.27, 28 The two fiscal variables alone explain 43 percent of the variation in inflation expectations (not shown).

These results are confirmed by the second set of regressions (last two columns in Table 2), where the expectation about fiscal deficits significantly enters the regression, even when instrumented. Moreover, expected fiscal deficits remain significant in regressions explaining survey expectations even when we include expected M2 growth and expected GDP growth over the next 12 months as explanatory variables (not shown). The latter finding suggests that fiscal deficits affect inflation expectations, and not only because higher fiscal deficits increase expected money growth over a 12-month horizon. In addition, they increase the probability of monetization over a longer horizon, thereby augmenting, with a sufficiently forward-looking money demand, expected inflation also in the short run.

VI. Conclusion

Backward-looking behavior does not seem to pose a major obstacle to reducing inflation in Turkey. Instead, credible fiscal consolidation appears to be crucial for lasting disinflation. Inflation expectations are likely to decline only if the public perceives that the temptation to monetize fiscal deficits or inflate away the debt stock has come to an end. The fact that the improvements in the noninterest fiscal balance in 2000–01 have coincided with a marked drop in inflation expectations lends support to this view, although the lack of demand pressures following the February 2001 crisis is also likely to have contributed to the disinflation and the downward adjustment of inflation expectations. Concurrently, the authorities could consider policies aimed at eliminating residual forms of backward indexation in wages and prices (such as housing rents and health and education prices), which are likely to account for the remaining role of past inflation found in the econometric analysis.

The approach developed here has a broader applicability beyond the specific Turkish case. In particular, we believe that the use of survey data to assess the importance of backward-looking behavior in shaping the inflation process and the examination of the determinants of these expectations are useful tools to inform policymakers who face the task of reducing inflation from persistently high levels.

REFERENCES

  • Alper, C. Emre, and Ucer, Murat 1998, “Some Observations on Turkish Inflation: A Random Walk Down the Past Decade,” paper presented at the conference on “Stabilization in an Emerging Market: The Case of Turkey,” Istanbul, Bogazici University, January.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrews, Donald, 1993, “Exactly Median-Unbiased Estimation of First-Order Autoregressive/ Unit Root Models,” Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 1, pp. 13965.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Laurence, 1994, “What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio?” in Monetary Policy, ed. by G. Mankiw (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buiter, Willem H., and Clemens Grafe, 2001, “No Pain, No Gain? The Simple Analytics of Efficient Disinflation in Open Economies,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3038 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, 1983, “Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 38398.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos Végh, 1999, “Inflation Stabilization and BOP Crises in Developing Countries,” in Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. by John Taylor and Michael Woodford (Amsterdam: North-Holland), pp. 1531614.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Celasun, Oya, 2001, “Price Setting and Inflation Dynamics in Small Open Economies,” (Ph.D. dissertation; College Park, Maryland: University of Maryland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chadha, Bankim, Paul Masson, and Guy Meredith, 1992, “Models of Inflation and Costs of Disinflation,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 39 (June), pp. 395431.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas J. Sargent, 2002, “Evolving Post-World War II U.S. Inflation Dynamics,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dibooḡlu, Selahattin, 2001, “Inflationary Expectations and Costs of Disinflation: A Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey?” in Inflation and Disinflation in Turkey, ed. by A. Kibritcioglu, L. Rittenberg, and F. selcuk (Aldershot, England: Ashgate).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dotsey, Michael, 2002, “Pitfalls in Interpreting Tests of Backward-Looking Pricing in New Keynesian Models,” Economic Quarterly, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Vol. 88 (Winter), pp. 3750.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Durevall, Dick, 1999, “Inertial Inflation, Indexation, and Price Stickiness: Evidence from Brazil,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 60, No. 2, pp. 40721.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos Végh, 2002, “Modern Hyper- and High Inflations,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 40 (September), pp. 83780.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fuhrer, Jeffrey, and Gerald Moore, 1995, “Inflation Persistence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 1, pp. 12760.

  • Galí, Jordi, and Mark Gertler, 1999, “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 44 (October), pp. 195222.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghezzi, Piero, 2001, “Backward-Looking Indexation, Credibility, and Inflation Persistence,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 53, No. 1, pp. 12747.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hamann, A. Javier, and Alessandro Prati, 2002, “Why Do Many Disinflations Fail?” IMF Working Paper 02/228 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Holden, Steinar, and John C. Driscoll, 2001, “A Note on Inflation Persistence,” NBER Working Paper No. 8690 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jadresic, Esteban, 2000, “Can Staggered Price Setting Explain Short-Run Inflation Dynamics?” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lim, Cheng Hoon, and Laura Papi, 1997, “An Econometric Analysis of the Determinants of Inflation in Turkey,” IMF Working Paper 97/170 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Metin, Kivilcim, 1998, “The Relationship Between Inflation and the Budget Deficit in Turkey,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 16, No. 4, pp. 41222.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1995, “International Currency Experience: New Lessons and Lessons Relearned,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution, pp. 11996.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roberts, John M., 1995, “New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 97584.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sargent, Thomas J., 1982, “The Ends of Four Big Inflations,” in Inflation: Causes and Consequences, ed. by Robert E. Hall (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 4197.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shiller, Robert, 1997, “Public Resistance to Indexation: A Puzzle,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution, pp. 159228.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stock, James H., 2002, “Discussion of Cogley and Sargent’s ‘Evolving Post-World War II U.S. Inflation Dynamics,’” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press), pp. 37987.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

The literature on stabilization is too large to be discussed here. See Sargent (1982) for a study of the process of ending hyperinflations and Calvo and Végh (1999) for an extensive discussion of inflation stabilization in developing countries. Fischer, Sahay, and Végh (2002) provide an overview of modern hyper-and high inflations, including disinflation episodes. Hamann and Prati (2002) study why many inflation stabilizations succeed only temporarily.

2

See, among many others, the discussions in Chadha, Masson, and Meredith (1992), Celasun (2001), Dotsey (2002), and Galí and Gertler (1999).

3

See the conference report of the 2001 conference of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) on Turkey under http://www.nber.org/crisis/turkey_report.html.

4

For an example of the use of survey data in the estimation of the Phillips curve, see Roberts (1995).

5

Unless otherwise noted, all data are from the Central Bank of Turkey.

6

Food prices carry the largest weight in the CPI (31 percent), followed by housing (26 percent), clothing (9.8 percent), transportation (9.3 percent), housewares (9 percent), health (2.9 percent), entertainment (2.9 percent), hotels and restaurants (2.8 percent), education (1.6 percent), and miscellaneous (4.5 percent.)

7

Stock (2002, p. 379–87), in a comment on Cogley and Sargent (2002), notes, “There are a variety of ways to measure persistence, none perfect.” He then goes on to use a median-unbiased estimation method similar to the one employed here.

8

We also repeated the analysis on quarterly data and obtained analogous results. For all these calculations, we modified a program that was originally written by Antonio Spilimbergo.

9

The bottom panel of Figure 5 does not show the upper bound of the confidence interval for the half-life of a shock to inflation in Brazil because the corresponding median unbiased estimator of the auto-regressive parameter was 1, suggesting that the Brazilian CPI inflation series could be nonstationary, as shown in other studies (see, for example, Durevall, 1999).

10

See, for example, the discussions in Ball (1994), Celasun (2001), or Buiter and Grafe (2001).

11

Similar specifications have been used by Obstfeld (1995), Galí and Gertler (1999), Celasun (2001), and Ghezzi (2001).

12

Galí and Gertler (1999) argue that proxies for marginal costs should be used instead of an excess demand/output gap variable. See also the discussion in Celasun (2001). We will use both approaches below.

13

Chadha, Masson, and Meredith (1992) show that when δ is greater than 0.5, there is a money growth rate that keeps the output gap at zero along the disinflation path.

14

See Celasun (2001) on the motivation for the measure used to proxy nontradables excess demand.

15

All variables are in logarithms, and except for the real wage, in deviation from a linear trend. For the logarithm of the real wage, the quadratic trend was also statistically significant and therefore was used along with the linear one in detrending.

16

The presence of the real exchange rate term accounts for the possibility that a share of firms, most likely in the tradables sector, “index” their prices to the current and expected future domestic level of foreign prices (i.e., the exchange rate multiplied by foreign prices). We plan to test in future work whether some price setters index to the exchange rate in a backward-looking manner.

17

**Denotes significance at the 1 percent level.

18

The estimated coefficient on the relative price of tradables with respect to nontradables (trntr) is statistically indistinguishable from zero in samples that end after 1999: Q3, but all other variables in the equation remain statistically significant in driving inflation.

19

The results are broadly in line with findings by Dibooḡlu (2001) based on the GDP deflator.

20

We used the mean forecast of 15 different economic forecasters, including 13 Turkish and foreign private financial institutions, Istanbul Bilgi University, and the Turkish Industrialists’ and Businessmen’s Association.

21

The specification remains constant across the estimations. The equation for, say, n-monthly inflation includes n-months lagged n-monthly) inflation, expected n-month ahead inflation, and the n-month average of capacity utilization, as well as a constant term. We restrict the sum of the coefficients of lagged and expected future inflation to one, as in the GMM regressions.

22

Six-month and one-year average inflation expectations are computed using a weighted average of this year’s and next year’s expected inflation rate. In the case of six-month inflation, we assume that expected inflation was equal for the whole 12-month horizon. Given that these data are available only at a bimonthly frequency since May 1998, we interpolate data for the missing months.

23

The recursive estimates of the coefficient of lagged inflation (not shown) are quite stable since mid-1997.

24

We did not address the separate question of whether inflation expectations are rational. A quick examination suggests that survey forecasts are unbiased, but not efficient. The fact that lagged inflation helps explain expectations is not inconsistent with the earlier results, in which expectations of future inflation drive current inflation. It suggests that a reduced-form equation could express current inflation as a function of lagged inflation, an excess demand/marginal cost term, and other variables explaining expectation formation.

25

We subtract the slow-moving deposit rate from the overnight rate to control for the fact that the same level of policy rates can reflect a different stance of monetary policy, depending on the general level of nominal interest rates. Including the exchange rate as an explanatory variable is problematic, because, at least in periods in which it is floating, the exchange rate is a jump variable that captures inflation expectations. The qualitative results presented below are not affected by the exclusion of the exchange rate variable.

26

We use past changes in the debt stock as instruments for the forecast of the fiscal balance.

27

Several studies have analyzed econometrically the relationship between public sector deficits and inflation in Turkey (see, for example, Metin, 1998). See also Lim and Papi (1997) and Alper and Ucer (1998).

28

One might wonder whether the lagged inflation term is the regressor that explains most of the variation in inflation expectations. This does not seem to be the case. For example, in specification I, the R2 excluding lagged inflation is 0.55.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
IMF Staff Papers, Volume 51, No. 3
Author:
International Monetary Fund. Research Dept.
  • Figure 1.

    12-Month CPI Inflation, Turkey, 1991–2003

    (In percent)

  • Figure 2.

    GDP Growth, Turkey, 1991–2002

    (In percent)

  • Figure 3.

    Overall and Primary Deficit, Turkey, 1990–2002

    (In percent)

  • Figure 4.

    Inflation Inertia and the Components of the CPI Index

  • Figure 5.

    Inflation Persistence in Turkey, Uruguay, and Brazil

    (Median unbiased half-life estimates of a unit shock and 90 percent confidence band)

  • Figure 6.

    Turkey: Backward-Looking Behavior in CPI

    (Recursive GMM estimates of lagged inflation coefficient and 95 percent confidence band)