This paper uses provincial time series data from the People’s Republic of China to empirically investigate two propositions relating to economic development: (i) that economic takeoff—or an acceleration in economic growth—is associated with inflows of foreign direct investment (FDI), possibly through technological transfer; and (ii) that takeoff is accompanied, at least in the short term, by widening income inequality. The results indicate that FDI flows have increased the rate of convergence in per capita incomes across China’s provinces. However, the pattern of FDI, which has gone mainly to the relatively wealthy provinces, has caused different provinces to converge toward different steady states. [JEL 04, 011, 018]

Abstract

This paper uses provincial time series data from the People’s Republic of China to empirically investigate two propositions relating to economic development: (i) that economic takeoff—or an acceleration in economic growth—is associated with inflows of foreign direct investment (FDI), possibly through technological transfer; and (ii) that takeoff is accompanied, at least in the short term, by widening income inequality. The results indicate that FDI flows have increased the rate of convergence in per capita incomes across China’s provinces. However, the pattern of FDI, which has gone mainly to the relatively wealthy provinces, has caused different provinces to converge toward different steady states. [JEL 04, 011, 018]

Economic takeoff is often associated with technological transfer from other countries, largely through foreign direct investment (FDI). Also, economic development is often linked with rising inequality, at least in the short term. The logic tying these two ideas together is straightforward—relatively prosperous countries or regions tend to receive more FDI because they have the existing infrastructure to support such projects. Hence, inequality across countries or regions widens as a result of FDI, which in turn helps achieve economic takeoff.

Cross-country empirical analysis of these propositions, however, is complicated by institutional and policy differences across countries, which can render comparisons problematic. As such caveats do not apply across regions of the same country, provincial-level data from China over the past two decades can be used to provide interesting empirical insight into these propositions relating to the process of economic development.1, 2

China’s growth performance since the initiation of market-oriented reform in 1978 has been impressive. Real GDP has grown by an average annual rate of almost 10 percent; real per capita output has averaged 8¼ percent a year. This economic takeoff has coincided with large inflows of FDI, which have averaged over US$40 billion (5½ percent of GDP) annually in recent years. At the same time, however, the variation in economic performance across provinces has widened, particularly since the late 1980s. After declining in the late 1970s and 1980s, the dispersion of (the natural logarithm of) provincial per capita incomes increased steadily in the 1990s (Figure 1).3 In 1978, real per capita income in the richest province was around six times that of the poorest; by 1997, the multiple had risen to almost eight (Table 1). Similarly, the pattern of FDI across provinces and regions has differed sharply. The coastal region, for example, saw FDI inflows averaging over 9 percent of regional GDP during 1993–97, while FDI in the western and southeastern regions averaged only 1–2 percent over the same period.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Provinces’ Real Per Capita Incomes, 1978–97

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2002, 004; 10.5089/9781589061224.024.A004

Table 1.

Regional Real Per Capita Income

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

The apparent widening disparity across China’s provinces—or groups of provinces—raises the question of whether provincial per capita incomes have diverged and, if so, why? This paper investigates the variation in economic performance across provinces and empirically examines whether the poorer provinces grew faster than the richer ones, which would suggest that all the provinces were converging to the same steady-state real per capita income level.4 In addition, the paper investigates the role of FDI and other structural and policy factors—including the share of investment in provincial GDP, the dominance of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) in industrial output, and the role of the banking system—on economic growth over the period 1978–97.

The analysis presented in this paper indicates that absolute convergence—convergence of real per capita incomes in all provinces to the same steady-state level—does not appear to hold over the past two decades, although there appears to be evidence of conditional convergence—that is, convergence of provincial per capita incomes to their own steady states. While structural characteristics of the provincial economies—such as the share of investment to GDP and the share of SOEs in industrial output—have had some effect, the regional disparities appear to be influenced primarily by the relative importance of FDI to the region. Indeed, the inclusion of an FDI variable in the regressions results in a sizable increase in the estimated rate of convergence of each region to its own steady state.

I. Absolute and Conditional Convergence

There is a growing literature on convergence of per capita incomes across and within countries. If economies possess similar levels of technology and have similar preferences, then the neoclassical growth model predicts that all provinces would converge to similar levels of real per capita income in the steady state. This is known as absolute β convergence. Convergence of per capita incomes in this model is driven by the assumption of diminishing returns to capital. When the stock of capital is low, each addition to capital stock generates large increases in output. These increments tend to decrease as the stock of capital increases. Accordingly, if the only difference between economies is the initial level of capital stock, the neoclassical growth model predicts that poorer economies will grow faster than rich ones. Regions with lower starting capital-labor ratios will have higher per capita growth rates.

The empirical evidence suggests that convergence is absolute within homogeneous groups of economies. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991, 1992a, 1992b) examine data for the U.S. states from 1880–1990, for Japanese prefectures over the period 1930–90, and for the regions of eight European countries from 1950–90. They find that convergence is absolute in that it applies when no other variable other than the initial level of per capita income is held constant. Cashin and Sahay (1996) examine convergence within India and find that variations in the steady state values across states are not significant, implying absolute convergence.

If economies vary in their saving rates and technologies, then the neoclassical growth model predicts conditional β convergence—provincial per capita incomes still converge, but this convergence is conditional on each economy’s own steady state. Across countries, the accumulated empirical evidence suggests that convergence is conditional—after taking into account the effects of the rate of investment and public policies on per capita growth.5 In most cases, the empirical work does not provide robust estimates for the effects of a specific government policy on growth, but it shows that the overall package of policies matters a great deal. The tendency towards convergence is even stronger when a measure of human capital in the form of educational attainment and health is included as an explanatory variable.6

Thus, if all the provinces of China have similar levels of technology and similar preferences, then they would converge to the same level of per capita income in the steady state (absolute convergence). If, on the other hand, provinces’ technologies vary—possibly on account of their ability to attract FDI—they would not be expected to converge to the same steady state, at least as long as their attractiveness to FDI remained varied.7

Capital and labor mobility—or openness—affect the rate of convergence. For example, the availability of foreign finance makes it easier to acquire physical capital. With the associated increase in the capital stock, diminishing returns set in faster than they would in a closed economy. Hence, the speed of convergence is greater in open economies than in closed ones.8

The evidence from China suggests that mobility of labor and capital across provinces in China has been limited by policies.9 For instance, permission for households to move from rural to urban areas has been restricted, and capital mobility has also been dampened through tax policies and state control over bank lending. Therefore, with partial capital and labor mobility, output convergence across provinces is likely to be more gradual. However, policies have also sought to directly redistribute incomes from relatively rich regions to poorer provinces, thereby boosting the rate of convergence. Thus, a relevant question for China is whether policies have, in total, contributed to the equalization of provincial per capita incomes.

Previous empirical studies of provincial economic performance and convergence in China include Bell, Khor, and Kochhar (1993) and Zhao (1998). Bell, Khor, and Kochhar, using the real annual average provincial growth rate during 1981–90, find that poorer provinces tended to grow faster than richer ones. This finding appears to depend critically on the sample period, however, during much of which there was a rapid expansion in agricultural output following the liberalization of the agricultural sector. Indeed, as Figure 1 indicates, the dispersion of provincial per capita incomes narrowed considerably during this period, before increasing steadily in the 1990s. Bell, Khor, and Kochhar also find that the proportion of nonstate sector output in total output was positively related to growth, while there was not a statistically significant relationship in their growth regression between FDI and growth.10 Zhao observes that the evolution of the ratio of real per capita GDP in the richest province to that in the poorest province was Ushaped, and empirically investigates the role of capital mobility in explaining this trend. She finds that capital mobility across China’s provinces was relatively limited during the 1980s and 1990s (see Appendix II).

Very recent work using our dataset by Graham and Wada (2001) and Aziz and Duenwald (2001) generally supports and extends our findings. Graham and Wada empirically assess whether inflows of FDI may have been associated with an acceleration in total factor productivity (TFP) growth, possibly resulting from technology transfer embodied in FDI inflows. They conclude that FDI has indeed contributed to growth in the provinces and regions of China—particularly the coastal region—that received sizable flows of this type, beyond what would be expected from higher rates of capital formation enabled by the FDI. Aziz and Duenwald investigate the implications of alternative convergence tests on our results. Using the methodology suggested by Quah (1997) to more fully exploit information contained in the data, they compute kernel estimates of the relative income distribution of China’s provinces. Their results—that the distribution of relative incomes is clustering toward two separate relative income clubs, with the coastal provinces (which received the most FDI) gravitating towards a higher per capita income mode than the other provinces—are consistent with our finding of conditional convergence.

In another related recent study, Wei and Wu (2001) empirically assess the relation between openness and rural-urban income inequality in Chinese cities and their adjacent rural areas during 1988–93. Defining openness as the ratio of exports to GDP, and allowing for endogeneity by using distance to major seaports as an instrument for openness, they find that while average openness increased and overall rural-urban inequality also went up during this period, the correlation across cities was negative. Together with our results, this would seem to suggest that within-province inequality has improved while interprovincial inequality has worsened. However, such an interpretation is subject to at least two qualifications. First, the Wei and Wu results are based on a much shorter time period. Indeed, as illustrated in Figure 1, much of the rise in the dispersion of average per capita incomes across provinces took place after the period studied by Wei and Wu. Second, special economic zones, which received a large share of China’s total FDI inflows, were excluded from Wei and Wu’s sample. The direction in which this exclusion might affect their result is not clear.

II. Regional Economic Performance

The basic estimation sample covers 28 provinces and municipalities over the period 1978 to 1997.11 The output data used are provincial GDP in constant (1992 yuan) prices based on provincial price deflators.12 These estimates are divided by the provincial population estimates to get provincial real GDP per capita, which is used as a proxy for real per capita income.13 For analytical purposes, the data are also divided into nonoverlapping intervals of five years each—1978–82, 1983–87, 1988–92, and 1993–97. Using the rate of growth of per capita output over a fiveyear interval rather than a single year provides a simple means of smoothing out short-run cyclical fluctuations in the rate of capacity utilization. This helps ensure that this variable approximates output growth at the average rate of capacity utilization.14 Averages of the explanatory variables over the five-year intervals are used in the estimation procedures.

It is convenient for analytical purposes to divide the provinces and municipalities of China into six geographic regions—northern, northeastern, coastal, southeastern, southern, and western. The northern region consists of Hebei, Shanxi, and Inner Mongolia, as well as the municipalities of Beijing and Tianjin. The northeast, which comprises Liaoning, Jilin, and Heilongjiang provinces, has a higher concentration of state-owned industry than the rest of the country. The coastal region—consisting of the municipality of Shanghai and the provinces of Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong, and Hainan—has been the recipient of the bulk of foreign direct investment (FDI), particularly from Hong Kong SAR. The southeastern provinces—Anhui, Jiangxi, Henan, Hubei, and Hunan—are adjacent to the coastal region and have received an increasing share of FDI in recent years. The southern region, which includes Guangxi, Sichuan, Guizhou, and Yunnan, is more dependent on the agricultural sector than the other regions. Finally, the western region, comprising Tibet Autonomous Region, Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai, Ningxia, and Xinjiang, accounts for around one half of China’s land area but only 7 percent of its population.15

Growth Performance

Economic performance, as measured by the growth in real GDP per capita, has varied significantly across regions and over time (Table 2). For China as a whole, real per capita GDP growth averaged 6 percent in the early post-reform period (1978–82), but picked up markedly in 1983–87 following the introduction of market-oriented reforms in the agricultural sector. Per capita income growth slowed during 1988–92, but picked up again in 1993–97 after the launch of a major investment drive in the coastal region.

Table 2.

Regional Per Capita Income Growth Rates

(annual average; in percent)

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Data cover 1985–97.

Data cover 1984–97.

While the coastal region grew at a faster pace than the rest of the country in each of the four subperiods, the relative performance of the other regions varied. For example, growth in the southeastern region exceeded the national average only in the first and last subperiods, while that in the northern and northeastern regions exceeded the national average only in the last subperiod. As a result, the relative position of the regions in terms of the average level of real per capita GDP has shifted, and each region’s share in China’s overall GDP has changed (Table 3). The share of the coastal region, for example, has risen from around one third in the late 1970s to over 40 percent in recent years.

Table 3.

Regional Economic Indicators, 1978–97

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Data cover 1985–97.

Data cover 1984–97.

The data also indicate a strong positive relation between initial income and the pickup in growth during the post-reform period. As illustrated in Figure 2, the increase in average growth between 1978–82 and 1993–97 was smallest for the initially poorest southern region, and greatest for the initially richest northeastern and northern regions.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Regions’ Initial Income and Per Capita Growth Increases

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2002, 004; 10.5089/9781589061224.024.A004

Economic Structure

A marked transformation in China’s economic structure has taken place since the late 1970s. The share of the agricultural sector in GDP has fallen by some 10 percentage points to 20 percent. At the same time, the ratio of total investment to GDP has risen steadily, accompanied by an expansion in investment spending both by state enterprises as well as the nonstate sector.

While the structural transformation at the national level was generally reflected in developments in each of the regions, there was significant variation in the timing, pattern, and extent of transformation across regions. For example, reform of the agricultural sector was initially introduced in Anhui province in 1978, and later adopted in almost all rural farm households by 1984.16 Consequently, the regions with the largest agricultural sectors (southern and southeastern) at the start of the reform process experienced the steepest declines in agriculture’s share in regional GDP (Table 4). By contrast, regions where the agricultural sector was relatively small at the outset (northern and northeastern) witnessed a much smaller decline in its share in regional GDP.

Table 4.

Agriculture’s Share in GDP

(In percent)

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Data cover 1985–97.

Data cover 1984–97.

Regional differences in the pattern of investment were even more pronounced. The share of total investment in GDP increased sharply in the northern and coastal regions over the period as a whole but less so in the other areas. The western region had the highest share of investment in total output at the start of the sample period (40 percent of GDP), which rose to 50 percent (Table 5). Despite the relatively high investment ratio, however, the large share of output produced by state-owned enterprises (SOEs)—about 75 percent—and constraints in their reform may have led to a buildup of inventories. In the northern and northeastern regions, much of the rise in the investment rate was also on account of SOEs, while the increase in the coastal region was mainly due to the nonstate sector.

Table 5.

Ratio of Total Investment to GDP

(In percent)

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Data cover 1990–97.

Data cover 1992–97.

The preponderance of SOEs in provincial economies has varied across regions as well. Although data on the share of state enterprises in total industrial output are available only from the late 1980s (Table 6), these indicate a sharp decline in the importance of the state sector in the coastal and southeastern regions. By contrast, SOEs have continued to account for the majority of industrial output in the northeastern and western regions.

Table 6.

Share of State-Owned Enterprises in Total Industrial Output

(In percent)

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Policies Affecting Economic Performance

Despite restrictions on internal capital mobility, policies have been geared toward attracting capital and technology from abroad. There was a marked shift in China’s foreign investment policies in the second half of the 1980s, including the introduction of special tax incentives to encourage investment in certain industries. FDI flows increased sharply from less than US$1 billion in 1983 to over US$40 billion in 1997. The inflows showed a dramatic increase in the coastal region, where they rose to over 9 percent of provincial GDP and accounted for an important source of investment spending (Table 7). More recently, the northern and northeastern regions have also seen a sizable increase in FDI inflows. As illustrated in Figure 3, initially rich provinces have tended to attract relatively greater inflows of FDI.

Table 7.

Ratio of Foreign Direct Investment to GDP

(In percent)

article image
Sources: State Statistical Bureau; The Gross Domestic Product of China, 1952–95; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Provinces’ Initial Income and FDI Inflows

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 2002, 004; 10.5089/9781589061224.024.A004

An important mechanism for reallocating financial capital across provinces has been the pattern of lending by the banking system, which until the mid–1990s was subject to credit quotas set by the State Planning Commission (SPC) in conjunction with the People’s Bank of China (PBC). Credit quotas for each province were established on an annual basis to meet policy objectives. Banks in provinces with quotas that were high in relation to their deposit growth financed their lending by borrowing from the PBC, while banks in provinces where credit quotas were relatively tight ended up having to maintain high excess reserves with the PBC. As a result, there was a close link between the credit plan and central bank lending, and the PBC played an important role in redistributing financial resources across provinces.

These flows of financial capital appear to have reflected redistributive policy objectives rather than consumption-smoothing or differences in rates of return on investment across provinces. Using data covering 1988–93, Lardy (1998) finds that the provincial share of industrial output produced by SOEs was the most important variable explaining variations in provincial loan to deposit ratios, with provinces with a high SOE concentration tending to have higher ratios. Since interest rates on loans were administered—generally well below market-clearing levels—and lending was not solely based on commercial factors, provinces with high loan ratios were, in effect, recipients of significant financial transfers. Data on loan-deposit ratios are available for the last two subperiods—1988–92 and 1993–97 (Table 8). The data indicate that the two regions with relatively high shares of industrial output produced by SOEs—the northeast and the west—had among the highest loan-deposit ratios.

Table 8.

Banking System Loan to Deposit Ratio

article image
Sources: Lardy (1998); People’s Bank of China; Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Data missing for 1994.

Data missing for 1994–96.

As regards fiscal policy, China started in 1979 to devolve authority from the central government to provincial and other forms of local government. The devolution of authority was accompanied by the provision of fiscal incentives. The unified revenue collection and spending system was replaced by a fiscal contracting system. Under the new system, local governments entered into long-term (usually five-year) fiscal contracts with higher level governments and many were allowed to retain 100 percent of the marginal revenue received. Jin, Qian, and Weingast (1999) show that the fiscal contracting system provided provincial governments with strong marginal fiscal incentives. They find a strong correlation between marginal budgetary revenue collection and marginal budgetary expenditure in the 1980s relative to the 1970s. They also find that higher marginal contractual revenue retention rates were associated with faster development of nonstate enterprises and more reform in state enterprises.

The data on provincial revenue and expenditure indicate a strong positive correlation between the provincial revenue to expenditure ratio with per capita income (Table 9). For example, the coastal region and the three municipalities—where per capita incomes are the highest—also have the highest revenue-expenditure ratios. At the same time, these ratios are lowest in the western and southern regions, where per capita incomes are also the lowest. This suggests that fiscal policy has also been used in a redistributive manner.

Table 9.

Fiscal Revenue to Expenditure Ratio

article image
Sources: World Bank (1994); People’s Bank of China; Almanac of China’s Finance and Banking, various issues; State Statistical Bureau; China Statistical Yearbook, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

Data missing for 1991.

Data cover 1988–97.

Data missing for 1993–94.

However, it is important to note several qualifications regarding the provincial fiscal data. First, these data are available only from 1983, and from three different sources that are occasionally inconsistent for overlapping years.17 Moreover, they do not appear to include revenue and expenditure by the central government in each province, which could significantly affect the measurement of the redistributive nature of national fiscal policy. To the extent that such taxation and spending were redistributive, their omission from the regression equation could understate the estimated speed of convergence. Finally, the impact of redistributive fiscal policy on growth would depend critically on the form of redistribution. For example, the growth implications of income transfers could be very different from those associated with infrastructure investment.

III. Estimation Results

The empirical analysis tests for convergence of per capita incomes across provinces by estimating a growth equation that is derived as a log-linear approximation of the transition path of per capita output around its steady state level.18 The equation, given below, specifies the average growth rate of per capita output over the interval t-T and t as a function of initial output and other variables.

ln(yit/yitT)=C(1eβT)ln(yitT)+xit+εit,(1)

where i indexes the province, T is the length of the observation interval, t is time period, yit-T is real per capita output at time t-T, the beginning of the subperiod, yit is real per capita income at time t, and β is the convergence coefficient. The convergence coefficient (β) indicates the rate at which yit-T approaches the steady state level of GDP per capita. A positive coefficient implies that the poorer provinces grow faster than the richer ones. The higher is β, the more rapid is the convergence to steady state. The variable C is the constant term common across provinces, xit includes the vector of other explanatory variables, and εit is an independent error term.

The usual role of the explanatory variables is to capture the structural characteristics of the economy that determine the steady state level of per capita income. Traditional variables included in the cross-country growth literature are the investment rate and educational characteristics. While time series data on educational characteristics by province or region were not available, we included the share of investment to provincial GDP and the private-public mix of production, as reflected in the share of SOEs in industrial output, in the regressions. As highlighted above, the dominance of SOEs in industrial production has varied sharply across the regions. Structural and institutional reforms that improve economic incentives and resource allocation and remove impediments to private sector development are likely to increase the productive capacity of the economy and have an effect on economic growth.19

The remaining variables included in the analysis are policy variables that appear to be particularly relevant in the Chinese context. These include the share of FDI flows to provincial GDP, the ratio of revenue to expenditure, and the ratio of bank loans to deposits.20 As noted earlier, higher FDI flows could imply either more openness, and thereby a higher rate of convergence, or access to different technology, implying convergence to a different steady state, at least in the short run. The rate of convergence would also be affected by the extent of the redistributive nature of bank lending and provincial fiscal policies.

The equation is estimated separately for each subperiod (1978–82, 1983–87, 1988–92, 1993–97) and for the entire sample period. The estimation results for each subperiod are based on iterative, nonlinear least squares that allow for heteroskedasticity in the subperiods. For the full sample, the estimates are derived using the seemingly unrelated regression approach (SURE), which also allows for correlation of the error terms across the subperiods. For comparison, pooled nonlinear regressions with regional and time dummies were also estimated over the corresponding sample period. As shown below, there is little difference in the full sample estimates except for the estimation results for the period 1988–97. Since data on all the explanatory variables are not available for the entire period, the estimation results are presented for different sample periods (Tables 10, 11, and 12).

Table 10.

Estimation Results, 1978–97

article image
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses; * denotes significance at the 5 percent level, ** at the 10 percent level.
Table 11.

Estimation Results, 1983–97

article image
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses; * denotes significance at the 5 percent level, ** at the 10 percent level.
Table 12.

Estimation Results, 1988–97

article image
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses; * denotes significance at the 5 percent level, ** at the 10 percent level.

These estimations use data on fixed investment owing to the divergence in the behavior of total and fixed investment in the last two subperiods.

Sample Period 1978–97

The first column of Table 10 shows the regression estimates of the convergence coefficient (β), based on equation (1) where the explanatory variables include only a constant and the log of each province’s initial per capita income in that subperiod. Rows 1–4 of column 1 present the results for each subperiod.

The estimate of β in the first subperiod, 1978–82, is 0.016 or 1.6 percent and is positively significant. This implies that 1.6 percent of the gap between current output per capita and the steady state per capita output is closed in one year. However, the estimates for the second and third subperiods are insignificant, while the estimated convergence coefficient in the fourth subperiod is negatively significant. Large FDI flows, which surged in the fourth period into the northern and coastal regions, may be viewed as a positive shock that benefited the richer provinces.21 If the estimate of β is constrained to be the same for all subperiods, the resulting joint estimate of β is 0.001 and is not significant. However, a Wald test for the equality of the coefficients across the subperiods rejects the hypothesis that β is stable over the subperiods.

Column 2 of Table 10 presents the estimated speed of convergence when regional dummies are incorporated. These dummies proxy for differences in the steady state levels of per capita income to which the provinces of China are converging. Six regional dummies are included for the different regions discussed before—the north, northeast, coastal, south, southeast, and west. The inclusion of regional dummies improves the fit of the estimated equations over the subperiods suggesting that regional differences are significant.22 The estimated value of the convergence coefficient over the subperiod 1978–82 increases from 0.016 to 0.02 and is positively significant. The estimated coefficient for the subperiod 1983–88 also becomes positively significant (β = 0.018). However, the coefficients in the third and fourth subperiods are insignificant. The estimate of the restricted β increases to 0.011 or an estimated rate of convergence of 1.1 percent. The Wald test for equality of the coefficients suggests that the hypothesis of a stable (5 across the subperiods can still be rejected at the 5 percent level, but not at the 10 percent level.

In contrast to the Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991, 1992a, and 1992b) results for U.S. states, Japanese prefectures, and eight European economies, these estimations do not provide support for the hypothesis of unconditional convergence. Rather, these results suggest that regions of China are converging to different steady state levels of per capita income.

Column 3 of Table 10 includes the ratio of total investment to provincial GDP in the estimations. While this coefficient is not significant for the subperiods, the hypothesis of equality of these coefficients across the subperiods cannot be rejected using the Wald test, and the restricted coefficient for total investment is positively significant. Moreover, the inclusion of this variable affects the e