Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows:Evidence from the European Union
Author:
Mr. Giovanni Dell'Ariccia
Search for other papers by Mr. Giovanni Dell'Ariccia in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This paper analyzes the effects of exchange rate volatility on bilateral trade flows. Through use of a gravity model and panel data from western Europe, exchange rate uncertainty is found to have a negative effect on international trade. The results seem to be robust with respect to the particular measures representing exchange rate uncertainty. Particular attention is reserved for problems of simultaneous causality, stemming from the endogenous behavior of monetary authorities. The negative correlation between trade and bilateral volatility remains significant after controlling for the simultaneity bias.

Abstract

This paper analyzes the effects of exchange rate volatility on bilateral trade flows. Through use of a gravity model and panel data from western Europe, exchange rate uncertainty is found to have a negative effect on international trade. The results seem to be robust with respect to the particular measures representing exchange rate uncertainty. Particular attention is reserved for problems of simultaneous causality, stemming from the endogenous behavior of monetary authorities. The negative correlation between trade and bilateral volatility remains significant after controlling for the simultaneity bias.

One main argument against flexible exchange rates has been that exchange rate volatility could have negative effects on trade and investment. If exchange rate movements are not fully anticipated, an increase in exchange rate volatility, which increases risk, will lead risk-averse agents to reduce their import/export activity and to reallocate production toward domestic markets. This paper provides some estimates of the importance of these effects in the European Union.

The trade issue has played an important role in the debate on the European Monetary System (EMS) and the European Monetary Union (EMU). The EMS was established with the intent of controlling exchange rate volatility and avoiding large misalignments among European currencies. One of the stated purposes was to reduce exchange rate uncertainty to promote intra-EU trade and investments. The discussion on the transition to EMU, and in particular the idea of a “two-speed” European Union, where “virtuous” countries would switch to using the euro from the beginning and other countries would join later, involves similar issues. One major concern is that a partial monetary union would have negative effects on the trade flows of the countries joining the single currency at a second stage. The idea is that, as is the case for customs unions, a partial monetary union could divert trade away from nonmember countries. However, there is not strong or unambiguous empirical evidence to support these views. A quite extensive literature has tested the effects of exchange rate regimes on trade, but the results are not always significant and they change across studies.1 Moreover most papers use only cross-sectional or time-series data instead of a panel, and just a few use bilateral data.

The analysis in this paper includes only Western European countries, allowing gathering of both trade and financial data across time as well as across countries, instead of using cross-sections only. This enables us to deal in a new manner with some of the problems met in the previous literature. There are other reasons to limit the scope of this study to Europe. The theoretical foundations of the gravity model assume identical and homothetic preferences across countries and rely heavily on the concept of intra-industry trade.2 European countries are relatively homogeneous in terms of technology, factor endowments, and per capita income, so the model seems particularly appropriate for this case. Moreover, as Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1995) note, the relationship between trade and other economic characteristics might be different for industrial and developing countries. Thus restricting the sample to Western European countries minimizes problems due to country-specific factors. Finally, the actual perspective of a single currency regime for the EU makes this set of countries the natural target for this kind of study.

The paper tests the effects of exchange rate volatility on trade using different measures and techniques, with particular attention to the simultaneous causality problem that may arise in these kind of studies. If central banks make an effort to stabilize the exchange rate with their main trade partners, a negative correlation between exchange rate volatility and trade would appear from the data, but this should not be construed to mean that trade reacts negatively to exchange rate instability. The use of panel data facilitates dealing with this problem in a way that explicitly takes into account the behavior of the central banks. If the central bank stabilizing strategy does not change over the period considered, it can be treated as a country-pair specific effect and it can be eliminated by using a fixed-effect model.

The empirical evidence in this paper supports the view that exchange rate uncertainty depresses international trade. However, according to the results, the negative effect of exchange rate volatility on trade is very small. The results are robust with respect to the particular measures chosen to represent uncertainty. They also show that the negative correlation between exchange rate volatility and bilateral trade remains significant when one controls for simultaneous causality. However, they reject the hypothesis of the absence of a simultaneity bias.

I. Gravity Models

The gravity model has been widely used in empirical work in international economics.3 The microeconomic foundations of this model can be directly linked to the theory of trade under imperfect competition, and more specifically to intra-industry trade theory, but the characteristics of this approach are consistent with most theoretical models of trade.4 In a gravity model the volume of trade between two countries increases with the product of their GDPs and decreases with their geographical distance. The idea is that countries with a larger economy tend to trade more in absolute terms, while distance represents a proxy for transportation costs and it should depress bilateral trade. In general, a per capita income variable is included to represent specialization; richer countries tend to be more specialized, and thus they tend to have a larger volume of international trade for any given GDP level. Models often include a number of dummy variables to control for different factors that might affect transaction costs. For example, a common border, language, or membership in a customs union are suppose to decrease transaction costs and to promote bilateral trade. This paper includes a proxy to represent exchange rate uncertainty. In the actual estimation this variable will take different forms: the standard deviation of the first differences of the logarithmic exchange rate, the sum of the squares of the forward errors, and the percentage difference between the maximum and the minimum of the nominal spot rate. The pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) regression is

log ( T R A N D E i j t ) = γ t + β 1 log ( G P D i t G P D j i ) + β 2 l o g ( D I S T i j ) + β 3 log ( p o p i t p o p j i ) + β 4 B O R D i j + β 5 E U i j t + β 6 L A N G i j + β 7 v i j t + ε i j t ,

where TRADE is the gross bilateral trade (Exports + Imports) between countries i and j at time t. EU represents membership in the European Union (1 when both countries j and i are in the union at time t, 0 otherwise), and BORDER and LANG represent respectively a common border and language. The variable v represents the proxy for uncertainty about the bilateral exchange rate between country i and j at time t. Note that the intercept has to be allowed to change over time. Indeed, following the model in Helpman (1987), any change in world aggregate GDP will be captured by the intercept.5 This implicitly imposes a restriction on the “third-country” coefficient—in other words, assuming, for example, that the trade between Germany and Italy reacts in the same way to a change in U.S. or French incomes.

A major advantage of using panel data is the ability to control for possibly unobservable country-pair individual effects. Such omitted effects, if correlated with the included regressors, would bias the OLS estimation. This papers considers a standard model assuming that the latent individual effect is a time-invariant random variable. That regression reads

log ( T R A N D E i j t ) = γ t + α i j + β 1 log ( G P D i t G P D j i ) + β 2 l o g ( D I S T i j ) + β 3 log ( p o p i t p o p j i ) + β 4 B O R D i j + β 5 E U i j t + β 6 L A N G i j + β 7 v i j t + ε i j t ,

where αij stands for the individual effect. The use of panel data allows one to control for cultural, economical, and institutional country-pair specific factors that are constant over time and are not explicitly represented in the model. Note that in the fixed-effects specification any time-invariant country-pair specific effect will be captured by the dummy αij.

II. Exchange Rate Volatility Measures

If purchasing power parity (PPP) held, domestic and foreign trade would not systematically involve a different degree of uncertainty. However, exchange rates experience significant and persistent deviations from PPP.6 adding an exchange risk component to import/export activities. Then an increase in exchange rate uncertainty may lead risk-averse firms to reduce their foreign activity, reallocating production toward their own domestic markets.7 With regard to this, the relevant type of exchange rate risk will depend on the model of exporting/importing firm that we have in mind. On the one hand, exporting firms may sign short-term export contracts in foreign currency. Then, assuming that costs in the firm’s own currency are known at r—1, the only uncertainty arises from the nominal exchange rate: the firm does not know its revenue in domestic currency at t- l.8 In this situation forward exchange rate markets represent an effective way to hedge against uncertainty. Short-term contracts are available for all the major currencies and they are relatively cheap.9 On the other hand, firms might have some sort of long term commitment to the export activity. These kind of firms have to sustain sunk costs to enter particular foreign markets and are interested in the relationship between their costs and the price that they can charge on those markets. In this case what matters is the real exchange rate: firms are interested in the evolution of their revenues relative to their costs.10 To hedge against this kind of uncertainty is much more difficult. Forward markets are not complete in terms of maturity, and the future exchange needs might not be known precisely at the moment of the decision. Hence, real exchange rate uncertainty may play an important role in determining firms’ import/export choices.11

The first problem in estimating the effects of exchange rate uncertainty on trade is choosing an appropriate variable to represent instability.12 The literature has used a number of measures of exchange rate volatility and variability as a proxy for risk. Some papers used the standard deviation of the percentage change of the exchange rate or the standard deviation of the first differences of the logarithmic exchange rate.13 This latter measure has the property of being zero in the presence of an exchange rate that follows a constant trend, and it gives a larger weight to extreme observations (consistently with the standard representation of risk-averse firms).14 Others consider the average absolute difference between the previous period forward rate and the current spot to be the best indicator of exchange rate risk. The advantage of this measure is that, under a target zones regime, or under pegged but adjustable exchange rates, it would pick up the effect of the presence of a “peso problem” or the lack of credibility of the official parity. Another possibility is to use the percentage difference between the maximum and the minimum of the nominal spot rate over the t years preceding the observation, plus a measure of exchange rate misalignment. This index stresses the importance of medium-run uncertainty. The idea is that large changes in the past generate expected volatility.15 It is worth noting that the measures proposed as proxies for risk are backward-looking, the assumption being that firms use past volatility to predict present risk. Then, even if one could restrict the choice to a particular measure, there would still be many options: daily, weekly, or monthly changes; which temporal window; etc. Consequently, this paper tests the model using different variables: the standard deviation of the first difference of the logarithmic exchange rate, the sum of the squares of the forward errors, and the percentage difference between the maximum and the minimum of the nominal spot rate.16 Moreover, it uses different temporal windows, and both real and nominal exchange rates.

A problem of simultaneous causality may arise using some of these measures. Central banks could systematically try to stabilize the bilateral exchange rate with their most important trade partners. In this ease exchange rate volatility cannot be treated as an exogenous variable. Exchange rate volatility and trade would be negatively correlated, but the direction of causality would be uncertain, and OLS would provide a biased estimation. In other words, with an OLS regression it would not be possible to distinguish between the effects of investors’ risk aversion and the effects of central bank policies. This concern is confirmed by Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1998), who find that monetary authorities are more likely to intervene on the exchange rate when trade links are strong. Instrumental variable estimators represent a solution to this problem. Frankel and Wei (1993) use the standard deviation of the relative money supply as an instrument for the exchange rate volatility. Their justification is that relative money supplies and bilateral exchange rates are highly correlated, but monetary policies are less affected by trade considerations than exchange rate policies. Unfortunately, this solution presents the problem that for many European countries exchange rate stability has been an important determinant of the monetary policy.17 However, the forward error is not a target of central banks’ policies and somehow reflects exchange rate uncertainty. The sum of the squares of the forward errors (definedas the difference between the log of the three-month forward rate and the log of the spot rate three months later, using “end-of-the-month” data) is correlated with the standard deviation of the spot rate and thus it represents an instrument for exchange rate volatility.

The availability of panel data allows a different approach to solving the simultaneous causality problem. The idea behind the simultaneity bias is that central banks try to stabilize the bilateral exchange rate against their countries’ main trade partners. If that is the case, the exchange rate volatility becomes a function of the share of the bilateral trade between the two countries over their total trade

v i j t = λ i j t - β ( T i j t T i . t ) - γ ( T i t j T j i ) + η i j t .

where the terms p and y represent the stabilization effort functions of the two central banks. In this context, if the bilateral trade shares were constant over time, one could write

ν i j t = λ i j t + θ i t + η i j t .

In that case the central bank factor could be treated as a country-pair fixed effect. Then the central bank effect would be captured by the country-pair dummy, and the fixed effects specification of Regression (2) would give unbiased estimates. One can imagine central banks following a more general and less accurate rule, in which the stabilization effort depends on the order of magnitude of the bilateral shares, and not on their exact value. In such a case the trade shares would not need to be perfectly constant, but only more or less stable over time. In other words, countries would only need to maintain their relative importance as trade partners. This is actually the case for the sample in this paper: trade shares are not strictly constant over time, but for every country the relative size of its trade partners remains more or less the same over the period considered.

III. Empirical Evidence

The sample period covers 20 years from 1975 to 1994. The countries included are the current 15 EU countries (with Belgium and Luxembourg taken as a whole)18 and Switzerland, for a total of 2,100 observations. The source for the trade data is the OECD database: bilateral data for both import and export flows are available. The GDP data are also from the OECD. The original data were expressed in current prices and different currencies. In order to be used in a multiperiod gravity model they had to be deflated and converted to a common currency.19 There were two possible ways to proceed. One could first convert the data into a common currency and then use the deflator for that currency to express the data in constant prices, or, alternatively, one could first deflate the data with each country deflator and then convert them to a common currency. If PPP applied, the two procedures would be equivalent. However, since PPP often fails, the second procedure seems superior. Indeed, as different countries have different consumption baskets, the second procedure has the advantage of applying the right deflators to each country’s data. For similar reasons the paper uses only export data to compute the gross bilateral trade flows.20 The available export (import) deflators are based on a basket that reflects a country’s total export (import).21 However, with this paper’s data the correct deflator should use baskets reflecting the bilateral flows between each pair of countries. It seems reasonable to assume that the bias introduced by using the “aggregate” deflator is smaller for export data than for import data. The idea is that, for each country, the goods it exports to different countries are more homogenous than the goods it imports from different countries. Distances are represented by air distances between capital cities.22 This paper uses different proxies to represent exchange rate uncertainty: the standard deviation of the first differences of the logarithm of the monthly average bilateral spot rate, the sum of the squares of the forward errors, and the percentage difference between the maximum and the minimum of the nominal spot rate. Exchange rate data are end-of-month observations from the IFS. Analogous measures are used for the real rate that is constructed using CPI indexes from the IFS.23 The dummy EU is included to control for the progressive enlargement of the union: this variable has value one for country pairs and years for which both countries are EU members. An additional dummy LANGUAGE represents country pairs with a common language.

Table 1 describes the results of Regression (1) using various measures to represent exchange rate uncertainty. The intercept was allowed to change over time and robust standard errors were estimated. All coefficients have the expected sign and are significant at the 1 percent level. Moreover, the results seem to be robust. Most coefficients are similar for the different regressions, suggesting that the four measures of exchange rate uncertainty are in some way equivalent (the regression using the sum of the squares of the forward errors as exchange rate volatility measure is on a sub-sample of countries that does not include Portugal). It is worth noting the relative importance of having a common language in determining trade flows. Even after controlling for GDP, population, membership in the EU, and a common border, countries speaking the same language trade between each other 24 percent more than those that do not share a common language. The exchange rate volatility coefficient is small, but not irrelevant. From the nominal exchange rate standard deviation coefficient, a total elimination of exchange rate volatility in 1994 would have determined a 12 percent increase in trade,24 a 13 percent increase using the real exchange rate measure, and a 10 percent increase using the forward error.25 It is interesting to note that the results for nominal exchange rate volatility are very close to the results for real volatility. This outcome is not particularly surprising given that in the sample there is a strong correlation between nominal and real exchange rate volatility (see Figure 1).

Table 1.

Regression (1): Pooled Regression

article image
Note: All coefficients are significant at the 1 percent level. Standard errors are in parentheses. Sources: OECD; IFS.

The results of Table 1 are statistically significant and seemingly do not depend on the variable chosen to represent exchange rate uncertainty. Nonetheless, the validity of these results could be questioned for the presence of simultaneity bias in Regression (1) when using the standard deviation of the exchange rate change. Central banks are likely to try to stabilize the exchange rate vis-a-vis their main trading partners. In such a case, even if exchange rate uncertainty had no negative effect on trade flows, there would be a negative correlation between exchange rate volatility and trade at a bilateral level. To solve this problem the forward error can be used as an instrument for exchange rate volatility: in particular, the sum of the squares of the three-month logarithmic forward error as an instrument for the standard deviation of the first differences of the logarithmic spot rate. This variable is not controlled by central banks and it is positively correlated with this paper’s measure of exchange rate volatility. Note that the forward exchange rate was not available for Portugal, so the regression with instrumental variables uses only a subsample of14 countries (1,820 observations).26 Also here the constant was allowed to change over time and errors were estimated controlling for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Real and Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility

(as from Standard Deviation of Exchange Rate Change)

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1999, 001; 10.5089/9781451973686.024.A005

Table 2 describes the results of the regression using instrumental variables (two-stage generalized least squares) and the results of the standard regression on the same countries (without Portugal). All coefficients still have the right sign, they are significant at the 1 percent level, and their size does not change with respect to the results of Table 1. For the instrumental variable estimation the results are more or less the same, suggesting that the negative correlation between exchange rate volatility and trade is not determined solely by the simultaneous causality bias. In other words, the negative correlation between exchange rate variability and trade does not depend, or at least does not depend entirely, on central banks’ policies.

It is possible to test the null hypothesis of absence of simultaneous causality using a Hausman specification test. If the hypothesis is verified, OLS are unbiased and consistent, but they are biased in the presence of simultaneous causality, while the instrumental variable (IV) estimator is unbiased and consistent under both the null and the alternative hypothesis. From the results of the Hausman test we can reject at the 10 percent level the hypothesis that the estimator in Table 1. is unbiased. This result is thus consistent with the presence of a simultaneity bias. Nevertheless, the results obtained with the instrumental variable estimation are still valid and confirm the existence of a negative relation between bilateral exchange rate volatility and trade flows.

Table 2.

Regression (1): Instrumental Variables

article image
Note: All coefficients are significant at the 1 percent level. Standard errors are in parentheses. Reduced sample excluding Portugal. Sources: OECD; IFS.

The existence of unobserved country-pair specific effects may bias the results of Regression(1). Then, to further test the robustness of these findings, one can use the simple model proposed in Section II. In the fixed effect model any individual effect will be captured by the country-pair dummy. Then, to the extent that the trade shares are stable over time, the fixed effect estimator will also take care of the simultaneity bias.27 The “central bank effect” has to be constant over time in order to be captured by the country-pair specific dummies. This paper considers both fixed-effect and random-effects estimations. The random-effect model has the obvious advantage of allowing the estimation of the coefficients of time-invariant variables. However, if individual effects are not drawn from the same distribution, the random effect estimates are not consistent. Table 3 reports the results of Regression (2).

In Table 3 the sample is the complete set of 15 countries for the first four columns and ihe subset without Portugal for the regression with the forward errors. These results seem to confirm the previous findings. The GDP and population coefficients have the right sign and are still positive at the 1 percent level with all three measures of exchange rate volatility. The EU dummy coefficient is positive and statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

Table 3.

Regression (2): Random ana Fixed Effects Estimations

article image
Note: One asterisk signifies significance at the 1 percent level; two at the 5 percent level; three at the 10 percent level. Sources: OECD; IFS.

The Hausman test rejected the unbiasedness of the random-effect estimator at the 5 percent level. Hence, the random-effect coefficients could be biased, and one should rely solely on the fixed-effects estimator. However, the main focus of this paper is on the exchange rate volatility coefficient that is very similar for fixed-effect and random-effect estimations. The exchange rate volatility coefficient is still negative. It is significant at the 1 percent level for all three different measures and for both fixed-effect and random-effect estimations. However, according to these estimates the size of the effect of volatility on trade is very small. A total elimination of exchange rate volatility in 1994 would have increased trade only by 3 or 4 percent (equivalent to the average annual growth rate of bilateral trade in the sample). Nevertheless, these results are consistent with the idea that a negative correlation between exchange rate volatility and trade exists and that at least a part of it is not spurious correlation caused by central bank stabilization policies. They also suggest that country-specific effects play an important role, advising against the use of pooled OLS estimations.

To test the efficacy of this method in eliminating simultaneous causality, a Hausman test was performed. Also in this case the instrumental variable was represented by the forward error measure. The test could not reject the hypothesis of unbiasedness of the OLS fixed-effect estimator. The result is then consistent with the assumption that the central banks factor is stable over time and is eliminated by using the fixed-effect model.

As noted earlier there is no “right” measure of exchange rate volatility. Accordingly, this paper further tests the robustness of the previous results using a different time window for the measures. Table 4 reports the results of Regression (1) using a two-year window to compute the various exchange rate volatility variables. The results are consistent with the previous ones, confirming a negative effect of volatility on trade. Note that an instrumental variable estimation is used given the outcome of the Hausman test on the previous results. All coefficients have the expected sign and are significant at the 1 percent level.

Finally, some analysis is conducted on the effects of third-country volatility on trade; for example, what happens to trade flows between France and Italy when the volatility between the franc and the deutsche mark increases? However, multicollinearity problems meant that the contribution of third-country volatility could not be isolated. As in Wei (1996), the coefficient was not significant and had the wrong sign, 28

The evidence in this section shows a negative correlation between exchange rate volatility and trade flows. With the results presented here the hypothesis that the behavior of the central banks has no role in determining the negative correlation between volatility and trade can be rejected. However, the results of estimations that are robust to simultaneous causality bias support the hypothesis that firms, reacting negatively to volatility on foreign currencies markets, determine a decrease in the volume of international trade when the exchange rate becomes more volatile.

IV. The ERM Effect

Table 4.

Regression (1): Two-Year Window

article image
Note: All coefficients significant at the 1 percent level. Standard errors arc in parentheses. Sources: OECD; IFS.
Table 5.

Regressions (4): The “Third Country” Effect

article image
Note: One asterisk signifies significance at the 1 percent level; two at the 5 percent level; three at the 10 percent level. Standard errors are in parentheses. Sources: OECD; IFS.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Lira/Deutsche Mark Exchange Rate Volatility with and without ERM

Percentage change

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1999, 001; 10.5089/9781451973686.024.A005

Most observers viewed the 1992/93 crisis of the EMS (or more precisely, of the Exchange Rate Mechanism) as a stop in the process of economic integration of the European countries. The purpose of the EMS was to reduce exchange rate volatility among member currencies to promote trade and economic convergence, and the ERM was actually successful in reducing both nominal and real exchange rate volatility (this is especially true for the period 1987-92).29 Thus, following the results from the previous section, the ERM should have had a positive effect on the bilateral trade between EU member countries. If the end of the ERM meant a diminished exchange rate stability, a reduction in intra-EU trade could be expected. In this section the framework presented in the previous sections is used to try to estimate the effects of the ERM on trade. A dummy was constructed equal to 1 for pairs in which both countries are members of the ERM and 0 otherwise.30 The resulting equation is

log ( T R A D E i j t ) = γ t + α i t + β 1 log ( G D P i t G D P j t ) + β 2 log ( D I S T i j ) + β 3 log ( p o p i t p o p j t ) + β 4 B O R D E R i j + β 5 E U i j t + β 6 L O N G i j + β 7 E M R i j + β 8 m i j + ε i j t ,

In this way the ERM dummy captures the stabilizing role that the ERM had on the currencies of member countries. On the other hand, if one is interested in the effect that the ERM had per se, not only through the reduction of exchange rate volatility, the equation becomes

log ( T R A D E i j t ) = γ t + α i t + β 1 log ( G D P i t G D P j t ) + β 2 log ( D I S T i j ) + β 3 log ( p o p i t p o p j t ) + β 4 B O R D E R i j + β 5 E U i j t + β 6 L O N G i j + β 7 E M R i j + β 8 v i j t + ε i j t ,

A negative sign on the ERM dummy coefficient would mean that the mechanism’s role in reducing uncertainty went beyond the induced reduction in volatility.

The results of both regressions are presented in Table 6. All the us2ual coefficients still have the right sign and are still significant. The ERM coefficient has the wrong sign. For the fixed-effect model it is significant at the 5 percent level when controlling for exchange rate volatility, and at the 10 percent level when alone. For the random-effect estimation it is significant at the 5 percent level in the regression with the real volatility measure and with the forward-errors measure. It is not significant in the regression with nominal volatility and when alone. On the one hand, this result seems surprising and conflicts strikingly with the findings in Section III. Indeed, ERM membership should decrease uncertainty and thus increase trade. On the other hand, a large literature addressed the issue of the credibility of the ERM and rejected the full credibility hypothesis for most cases.31 From that point of view, the result in this section can be reconciled with those in the rest of this paper. If, for most periods and countries, the exchange rate target zones were not credible, one should not expect a significant effect of the ERM dummy on trade flows. At the same time, a non-credible ERM would generate expectations of relatively large realignments, to which agents might react particularly negatively.32 In other words, agents might find a system of discrete changes, that are typically large over a short period, more harmful than similar, but more gradual changes under a system of flexible rates.

Table 6.

Regressions (3a) and (3b): The ERM Effect

article image
Note: One asterisk signifies significance at the 1 percent level; two at the 5 percent level; three at the 10 percent level. Standard errors are in parentheses. Sources: OECD; IFS.

An alternative, but not very appealing, explanation is provided by political economy. Brada and Mendez (1988) suggest that countries with fixed exchange rate regimes are more likely to use trade restrictions to defend their trade balance. They find some evidence that countries with fixed rates trade less than countries with floating rates. However, in our context this effect seems very unlikely because most countries in the sample (all countries in the ERM) are EU members.

V. Conclusions

This paper tests the relationship between exchange rate uncertainty and trade with data from Western European countries. The analysis uses different variables as proxies for uncertainty, all of which gave consistent results. There was evidence of a small but significant negative effect of bilateral volatility on trade.

The problem of a possible simultaneity bias was addressed in two different ways, and both instrumental variables and fixed effects over time gave results consistent with the hypothesis of a negative effect of exchange rate uncertainty on trade. Nevertheless, a Hausman specification test rejected the hypothesis that no simultaneity bias exists.

Further research in this area should look at more disaggregated data. It is more difficult to find financial instruments to hedge against exchange rate risk when the time horizon becomes longer. Then EMU might have a different impact across industries. In sectors where the export activity requires large investments, trade should prove more sensitive to exchange rate volatility than in sectors characterized by “short-term” exports.33 For the same reasons, exchange rate stability might be more important for foreign direct investments than for trade flows.34

Appendix I. EU-EMS Chronology

Apr. 1951 European Coal and Steel Community—Treaty of Paris

Mar. 1957 European Economic Community—Treaty of Rome (6 countries)

Aug. 1971 End of the Bretton Wood System

Mar. 1972 Introduction of the Snake (Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands)

May 1972 Denmark, the UK, and Norway join the Snake.

Jun. 1972 Denmark and the UK exit the Snake.

Oct. 1972 Denmark rejoins the Snake.

Jan. 1973 Denmark, Ireland, and the UK become members of EEC

Feb. 1973 Italy exits the Snake.

Jan. 1974 France exits the Snake.

Jul. 1975 France rejoins the Snake.

Mar. 1976 France exits the Snake.

Mar. 1979 EMS starts (Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, and Netherlands

with 2.25 percent margins, Italy with 6 percent).

Jan. 1981 Greece joins EEC.

Jan. 1986 Portugal and Spain join EEC.

Jun. 1989 Spain joins the EMS with 6 percent margins.

Jan. 1990 The margin for the Italian lira is narrowed to 2.25 percent.

Oct. 1990 Unification of Germany. The UK joins the ERM with 6 percent margins.

Feb. 1992 Maastricht Treaty on European Union.

Apr. 1992 Portugal joins ERM with 6 percent margins.

Sep. 1992 Italy and the UK suspend participation in the ERM.

Jan. 1993 Single European Market.

Aug. 1993 ERM margins widened to 15 percent.

Jan. 1995 Austria, Finland, and Sweden join the EU.

REFERENCES

  • Akhtar, M.A., and R. Spence Hilton, 1984, “Effects of Exchange Rate Uncertainly on German and U.S. Trade,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review, Vol. 9 (spring) pp. 716.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arize, Augustine, 1996, “Real Exchange-Rate Volatility and Trade Flows: The Experience of Eight European Economies,” International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 5 (No. 2), pp. 187205.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bahmani-Oskooee, Mohsen, and Sayeed Payesteh, 1993, “Does Exchange Rate Volatility Deter Trade Volume of LDCs?” Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 18 (December), pp. 189205.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bailey, Martin, George Tavlas, and Michael Ulan, 1986, “Exchange Rate Variability and Trade Performance: Evidence from the Big Seven Countries,” Weltwirtschaftliches-Archiv, Vol. 122 (No. 3), pp. 46677.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen, 1995, “Is Regionalism Simply a Diversion? Evidence from the Evolution of the EC and EFTA,” CEPR Discussion Papers, No. 1294, (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen, 1998, “Exchange Rate Volatility and Intervention: Implication of the Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 45 (August), pp. 191209.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergstrand, Jeffrey, 1989, “The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor-Proportions Theory in International Trade,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71 (September), pp. 14353.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brada, Josef, and Jose Mendez, 1988, “Exchange Rate Risk, Exchange Rate Regime, and the Volume of International Trade,” Kyklos, Vol. 41 (No. 2), pp. 26380.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brodsky, David, 1984, “Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates, and the Measurement of Exchange Rate Instability,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 16 (May), pp. 295306.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campa, Jose, and Linda Goldberg, 1995, “Investment in Manufacturing, Exchange Rates and External Exposure,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 38 (May), pp. 297320.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chowdhury, Abdur, 1993, “Does Exchange Rate Volatility Depress Trade Flows? Evidence from Error-Correction Models,” Review of Economics and Statistics,Vol. 75 (November), pp. 700706.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, 1988, “Exchange Rate Variability and the Slowdown of Growth in International Trade,” Staff Papers, Vol. 35 (March), pp. 6384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, and Guy Verfaille, 1988, “Exchange Rate Variability, Misalignment, and the European Monetary System,” in Misalignment of Exchange Rates: Effects on Trade and Industry, ed. By Richard C. Marston, NBER Project Report Series (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 77100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Jeffrey Frankel, 1988, “The Flexible Exchange Rate System: Experience and Alternatives,” in International Finance and Trade in a Polycentric World, ed. by Silvio Borner, (Basingstoke, England: MacMillan in association with International Economic Association).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission, 1990, “One Market, One Money: An Evaluation of the Potential Costs and Benefits of Forming an Economic and Monetary Union,” European Economy, Vol. 44 (October), pp. 3347.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey, 1992, “Is Japan Creating a Yen Bloc in Asia and the Pacific?” NBER Working Papers No. 4050 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey, and Steven Phillips, 1992, “The European Monetary System: Credible at Last?” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 44, (October), pp. 791816.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey, and Shang-Jin Wei, 1993, “Trade Blocs and Currency Blocs,” NBER Working Papers, No. 4335 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Froot, Kenneth A., Michael Kim, and Kenneth Rogoff 1995, “The Law of One Price Over 700 Years,” NBER Working Papers, No. 5132 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gagnon, Joseph, 1993, “Exchange Rate Variability and the Level of International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 34 (May), pp. 26987.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giovannini, Alberto, 1990, “European Monetary Reform: Progress and Prospects,” Brooking Papers on Economic Activity: 2, pp. 21774.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, Linda, and Charles Kolstad, 1995, “Foreign Direct Investment, Exchange Rate Variability and Demand Uncertainty” International Economic Review, Vol. 36 (November), pp. 85573.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helpman, Elhanan, 1987, “Imperfect Competition and International Trade: Evidence from Fourteen Industrial Countries,” in International Competitiveness, ed. by A. Michael. Spence and Heather A. Hazard, (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hooper, Peter, and Steven Kohlhagen, 1978, “The Effect of Exchange Rate Uncertainty on the Prices and Volume of International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 8 (November), pp. 483511.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 1984, The Exchange Rate System: Lessons of the Past and Options for the Future, IMF Occasional Paper No. 30 (Washington: IMF).

  • Kenen, Peter, and Dani Rodrik, 1986, “Measuring and Analyzing the Effects of Short-Term Volatility in Real Exchange Rates,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68 (May), pp. 31115.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kim, Kiheung, and WooRhee Lee, 1996, “The Impact of Korea’s Exchange Rate Volatility on Korean Trade,” Asian Economic Journal, Vol. 10 (March), pp. 4560.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1991, “The Move Toward Free Trade Zones,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, Vol. 76 (November/December), pp. 526.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lanyi, Anthony, and Esther Suss, 1982, “Exchange Rate Variability: Alternative Measures and Interpretation,” Staff Papers, Vol. 29 (December), pp. 52760.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Peree, Eric, and Alfred Steinherr, 1989, “Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Foreign Trade,” European Economic Review, Vol, 33 (July), pp. 124164.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pozo, Susan, 1992, “Conditional Exchange-Rate Volatility and the Volume of International Trade: Evidence from the Early 1900s,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 74 (May), pp. 32529.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stokman, A.C.J., 1995, “Effect of Exchange Rate Risk on Intra-EC Trade,” De Economist, Vol. 143, No.I, pp. 4154.

  • Svensson, Lars E. O., 1991, “The Simplest Test of Target Zones Credibility,” Staff Papers, Vol. 38 (September), pp. 65565.

  • Viaenc, Jean-Marie, and Casper de Vries, 1992, “International Trade and Exchange Rate Volatility,” European Economic Review, Vol. 36 (August), pp. 131121.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wei, Shang-Jin, 1996, “Intra-National versus International Trade: How Stubborn Are Nations in Global Integration?” NBER Working Paper No. 5531 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

Giovanni Dell’Ariccia is an Economist in the Developing Countries Studies Division of the Research Department. This paper is partly based on work done for the author’s Ph.D. dissertation at MIT. He thanks Andrew Bernard, Rudi Dornbusch, Mike Mussa, Karen Swiderski, Jaume Ventura, two anonymous referees, and all the participants in the MIT International Breakfast and the Conference on International Trade and Market Structures in Le Mans for useful suggestions. He is particularly grateful to Dave Riker for extensive and helpful comments, and to Fabio Fornari and Sandro Giustiniani who provided most of the data. Financial support by Banca Nazionale del Lavoro is gratefully acknowledged.

1

For example, Bahmani-Oskooee and Payesteh (1993), Bailey, Tavlas, and Ulan (1986), and Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978), find no evidence of a negative effect of volatility on trade. Wei (1996) in his work on OECD countries finds that volatility coefficients have the wrong sign. Frankel and Wei (1993) and Kenen and Rodrik (1986) find conflicting results. While Kim and Lee (1996), Stokman (1995), Chowdhury (1993), and Peree and Steinherr (1989) find significant evidence of a negative relation. For a discussion see IMF (1984), or European Commission (1990). The existence of conflicting evidence is consistent with Gagnon (1993), who suggests that the likely impact of volatility on trade should be small.

2

See Helpman (1987).

3

See, for example, Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1995), Frankel (1992), and Krugman (1991).

4

Helpman (1987) uses a Dixit/Stiglitz imperfect competition model to obtain the relation between gross trade and GDPs. Bergstrand (1989) generalizes this model to include Hecksher-Ohlin trade.

5
Assume two differentiated products X and Y, and homothetic preferences identical in every country. Then, in the completely specialized case, imports of country k from country j would be
IMPkj=sk(pxXj+pyYj),
where sk is country k’s share in world spending (and its share of world income in the absence of trade imbalances) and A} and Y-} are the outputs of goods X and Y produced in country j (the time index is omitted here). The symmetric is true for the imports of country j from country k. Thus the total gross trade is
Tkj=sk(pxXj+pyYj)+sj(pxXj+pyYk)=skGDPj+sjGDPk
Rewriting,
Tkj=sksjGDPworld+sjskGDPworld=2GDPjGDPkGDPworld
And, when one takes logs, any change in the world GDP will be captured by the constant.
7

This result holds under certain conditions; see De Grauwe (1988). When those conditions are violated, the sign of the elasticity of trade flows with respect to exchange rate volatility is ambiguous. Exchange rate volatility creates a positive option value for firms that have the opportunity to choose whether to sell on the domestic or on foreign markets.

8

The expected utility from profit at time t - 1 for the exporting firm will be Et-1Uπt=Et-1U((qt|t-1)(pt*|t-1)et-(pt|t-1)) where the price in foreign currency is fixed at time t - 1, and where, assuming production occurs between t - 1 and t, quantity produced and costs are known at time t - 1. In this context Viaene and de Vries (1992) show that the effect of exchange rate volatility with well-developed forward markets is ambiguous.

9

Nonetheless, studies show that only a small, but increasing, part of international trade is actually hedged on forward markets. See Dornbusch and Frankel (1988), and European Commission (1990).

10

Assuming that costs are a function of domestic prices, for these firms future expected profits are a function of domestic prices, foreign prices, and the exchange rate, thus real profits are a function of the real exchange rate E0U(tπt)(1+r)-tE0U(t(pt*et-Ct(pt))(1+r)))-t)E0U(tπtpt(1+r)-t)=E0U(t(pt*et-Ct(pt))pt(1+r)-t)

11

These considerations suggest that the next step in this kind of study should be to look at more disaggregated data. It seems important to be able to discriminate the effects of exchange rate volatility across industries characterized by different import/export structures.

12

For a discussion of exchange rate volatility measures, see Brodsky (1984), Kenen and Rodrik (1986), and Lanyi and Suss (1982).

13

See Brodsky (1984), Kenen and Rodrik (1986), and Frankel and Wei (1993).

14

The underlying assumption is that a constant trend would be perfectly anticipated and would not affect uncertainty. An alternative variable some authors have used is the standard deviation of the level of the nominal exchange rate. This measure relies on the underlying assumption that the exchange rate moves around a constant level. In the presence of a trend this index would probably overestimate exchange rate uncertainty. For similar measures see Akhtar and Hilton (1984), Bailey, Tavlas, and Ulan (1986), and Hooper and Kohlhagen (1978).

16

All these variables are constructed using end-of-period exchange rate monthly data from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics (IFS).

17

This is especially true for the countries participating in the ERM.

18

Austria, Belgium and Luxembourg, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.

19

For the conversion PPP values from the OECD series were used; very similar results were also obtained by converting all the data to U.S. dollars.

20

Note that, at least in theory, country j’s imports from country k is equal to country k’s exports to country j, so import and/or export data could be used to compute the bilateral gross trade.

21

These are IFS data.

22

Exceptions are Frankfurt for Germany and Milan for Italy. The source for all distance data is Alitalia.

23

There is no monthly price index for Ireland. The monthly real exchange rate was constructed using the quarterly price index and assuming the inflation rate constant within the quarter.

24

The average standard deviation of the monthly nominal exchange rate change in 1994 was about 0.55 percent.

25

This compares with an average bilateral trade annual growth rate of 3.5 percent for the sample period.

26

For all the other countries it was possible to construct a forward rate using short-term interest rates. The source was IFS.

27

Trade shares are very stable in the sample. The only big change is in Spain/Portugal share. For each country, trade partners were ranked by their share in the country’s total trade and then the rankings for 1975 and 1994 were compared. They were very similar for all countries. The overall average place change between rankings was 0.9 places. No change had taken place in 42 percent of the cases, and the maximum change had been five places.

28

A variable representing the exchange rate volatility of the two currencies with respect to all the others was included log(TRADEijt)=γt+αit+β1log(GDPitGDPjt)+β2log(DISTij)+β3log(popitpopjt)+β4BORDERij+β5EUijt+β6LONGij+β7vij+β8mij+εijt, where mijt = ∑i≠j vijt wijt + ∑j≠i wijt, with weights wijt represented by relative GDPs. If the trade diversion hypothesis is valid the sign of (B8 should be negative. Table 5 reports the results for Regression (4) with real and nominal exchange rate volatility. Most coefficients have more or less the same values as in Regression (1). However, for both cases there is probably a multicollinearity problem. The correlation between the bilateral exchange rate volatility and the volatility with the rest of the countries in the sample is above 0.9. Then it is not possible to determine the contribution of the two variables separately. Indeed, the “third country” volatility coefficient is not significant and has the wrong sign.

29

See, for example, Figure 2. For a detailed analysis see De Grauwe and Verfaille (1988).

30

This approach has the advantage of avoiding the simultaneous causality problem. The decision to enter the ERM concerns a country’s general policy more than simply its trade policy.

31

See Giovannini (1990), Svensson (1991), and Frankel and Phillips (1992).

32

A way to address this issue might be to control for the credibility of the bilateral target zones and construct a “credible ERM” dummy. One would first have to define a measure of credibility, and then could construct a variable taking the value 1 when the commitment to the bilateral parity is credible, and 0 otherwise. The quoted literature relies on tests based on forward rates (or interest rate differentials) first proposed in Svensson (1991). The basic idea is that if the forward rate is outside the band, the target zone cannot be fully credible.

33

Stokman (1995) uses disaggregated, but not bilateral, data to estimate the effects of exchange rate volatility on the intra-EU exports of five European countries.

34

See Campa and Goldberg (1995) or Goldberg and Kolstad (1995) for some evidence on the relationship between exchange rate volatility and foreign direct investment.

Volume 46 Index

Volume 46 (1999) comprises three issues, as follows:

March, pages 1-106

June, pages 107-246

September/December, pages 247-341

Authors

  • Aylward, Lynn. Countries’ Repayment Performance Vis-à-Vis the IMF: A Response to Backer 242

  • Backer, Arno. Countries’ Repayment Performance Vis-à-Vis the IMF: A Comment on Aylward and Thorne 238

  • Baig, Taimur, and llan Goldfajn. Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis 167

  • Barajas, Adolfo, Roberto Steiner, and Natalia Salazar. Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia, 1974-96 196

  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Ronald MacDonald. Deviations of Exchange Rates from Purchasing Power Parity: A Story Featuring Two Monetary Unions 89

  • Beddies, Christian H. Monetary Policy and Public Finances; Inflation Targets in a New Perspective 293

  • Berg, Andrew, and Catherine Pattillo. Are Currency Crises Predictable? A Test 107

  • Carranza, Luis, and Chorng-Huey Wong. Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further Empirical Results 225

  • Crafts, Nicholas. East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis 139

  • Dell’Ariccia, Giovanni. Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows: Evidence from the European Union 315

  • Goldfajn, llan, and Taimur Baig. Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis 167

  • Hardy, Daniel, and Ceyla Pazarbasioglu. Determinants and Leading Indicators of Banking Crises: Further Evidence 247

  • MacDonald, Ronald, and Bayoumi, Tamim. Deviations of Exchange Rates from Purchasing Power Parity: A Story Featuring Two Monetary Unions 89

  • Mauro, Paolo, and Antonio Spilimbergo. How Do the Skilled and the Unskilled Respond to Regional Shocks? The Case of Spain 1

  • Montenegro, Claudio E., and Abdelhak S. Senhadji. Time Series Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis 259

  • Pattillo, Catherine, and Andrew Berg. Are Currency Crises Predictable? A Test 107

  • Pazarbasioglu, Ceyla, and Daniel Hardy. Determinants and Leading Indicators of Banking Crises: Further Evidence 247

  • Ramaswamy, Ramana, and Robert Rowthorn. Growth, Trade, and Deindustrialization 18

  • Rowthom, Robert, and Ramana Ramaswamy. Growth, Trade, and Deindustrialization 18

  • Salazar, Natalia, Adolfo Barajas, and Roberto Steiner. Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia. 1974-96 196

  • Spilimbergo, Antonio, and Paolo Mauro. How Do the Skilled and the Unskilled Respond to Regional Shocks? The Case of Spain 1

  • Steiner, Roberto, Adolfo Barajas, and Natalia Salazar. Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia, 1974-96 196

  • Tamirisa, Natalia. Exchange and Capital Controls as Barriers to Trade 69

  • Vamvakidis. Athanasios. Regional Trade Agreements or Broad Liberalization: Which Path Leads to Faster Growth? 42

  • Wong, Chomg-Huey, and Luis Carranza. Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further Empirical Results 225

Titles

  • Are Currency Crises Predictable? A Test 107

  • Countries’ Repayment Performance Vis-à-Vis the IMF: A Comment on Aylward and Thorne 238

  • Countries’ Repayment Performance Vis-à-Vis the IMF: A Response to Backer 242

  • Determinants and Leading Indicators of Banking Crises: Further Evidence 247

  • Deviations of Exchange Rates from Purchasing Power Parity: A Story Featuring Two Monetary Unions 89

  • East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis 139

  • Exchange and Capital Controls as Barriers to Trade 69

  • Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows: Evidence from the European Union 315

  • Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis 167

  • Growth, Trade, and Deindustrialization 18

  • How Do the Skilled and the Unskilled Respond to Regional Shocks? The Case of Spain 1

  • Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia, 1974-96 196

  • Monetary Policy and Public Finances: Inflation Targets in a New Perspective 293

  • Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further Empirical Results 225

  • Regional Trade Agreements or Broad Liberalization: Which Path Leads to Faster Growth? 42

  • Time Series Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysts 259

Subjects

  • To facilitate electronic storage and retrieval of bibliographic data, IMF Staff Papers has adopted the subject classification scheme of the Journal of Economic Literature(Nashville, Tennessee).

  • C Mathematical and Quantitative Methods

  • C12 Hypothesis Testing

  • Deviations of Exchange Rates from Purchasing Power Parity: A Story Featuring Two Monetary Unions. By Tamim Bayoumi and Ronald MacDonald 89

  • C2 Econometric Methods: Single Equation Models

  • C22 Time-Series Models

  • Time Series Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis. By Abdelhak S. Senhadji and Claudio E. Montenegro 259

  • C23 Models with Panel Data

  • Deviations of Exchange Rates from Purchasing Power Parity: A Story Featuring Two Monetary Unions. By Tamim Bayoumi and Ronald MacDonald 89

  • C32 Time-Series Models

  • Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further Empirical Results. By Chorng-Huey Wong and Luis Carranza 225

  • E Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics

  • E21 Consumption; Saving

  • Time Series Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis. By Abdelhak S. Senhadji and Claudio E. Montenegro 259

  • E24 Employment; Unemployment; Wages

  • How Do the Skilled and Unskilled Respond to Regional Shocks? The Case of Spain. By Paolo Mauro and Antonio Spilimbergo 1

  • E43 Determination of Interest Rates; Term Structure of Interest Rates

  • Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia, 1974—96. By Adolfo Barajas, Roberto Steiner, and Natalia Salazar 196

  • E44 Financial Markets and the Macroeconomy

  • Determinants and Leading Indicators of Banking Crises: Further Evidence. By Daniel C. Hardy and Ceyla Pazarbasioglu 247

  • E52 Monetary Policy (Targets, Instruments, and Effects)

  • Monetary Policy and Public Finances: Inflation Targets in a New Perspective, By Christian H. Beddies 293

  • E61 Policy Objectives; Policy Designs and Consistency; Policy Coordination

  • Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further Empirical Results. By Chorng-Huey Wong and Luis Cairanza 225

  • E62 Fiscal Policy; Public Expenditures, Investment, and Finance; Taxation Monetary Policy and Public Finances: Inflation Targets in a New Perspective. By Christian H. Beddies 293

  • F International Economics

  • Fl Global Outlook

  • Growth. Trade, and Deindustrialization. By Robert Rowthom and Ramana Ramaswamy 18

  • F13 Commercial Policy; Protection’, Promotion; Trade Negotiations Exchange and Capital Controls as Barriers to Trade. By Natalia T. Tamirisa 69

  • F14 Country and Industry Studies of Trade

  • Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows; Evidence from the European Union. By Giovanni Dell’Ariccia 315

  • F17 Trade Forecasting and Simulation

  • Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows: Evidence from the European Union. By Giovanni DeH’Ariccia 315

  • Time Series Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis. By Abdelhak S. Senhadji and Claudio E. Montenegro 259

  • F21 International Investment; Long-Term Capital Movements

  • Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further Empirical Results. By Chorng-Huey Wong and Luis Carranza 225

  • F3International Finance

  • F30 General

  • Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis. By Taimur Baig and llan Goldfajn 167

  • F31 Foreign Exchange

  • Are Currency Crises Predictable? A Test. By Andrew Berg and Catherine Pattillo 107

  • Deviations of Exchange Rates from Purchasing Power Parity; A Story Featuring Two Monetary Unions. By Tamim Bayoumi and Ronald MacDonald 89

  • Exchange and Capital Controls as Barriers to Trade. By Natalia T. Tamirisa 89

  • Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows: Evidence from the European Union. By Giovanni Dell’Ariccia 315

  • F32 Current Account Adjustment; Short-Term Capital Movements

  • Policy Responses to External Imbalances in Emerging Market Economies; FurtherEmpirical Results. By Chorng-Huey Wong and Luis Carranza 225

  • F4 Macroeconomic Aspects of International Trade and Finance

  • F40 General

  • Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis. By Taimur Baig and Han Goldfajn 167

  • F41 Open Economy Macroeconomics

  • Policy Responses to External imbalances in Emerging Market Economies: Further

  • Empirical Results. By Chorng-Huey Wong and Luis Carranza 225

  • Time Series Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis. By Abdelhak S. Senhadji and Claudio E. Montenegro 259

  • F43 Economic Growth of Open Economies

  • Growth, Trade, and Deindustrialization. By Robert Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy. 18

  • Regional Trade Agreements or Broad Liberalization: Which Path Leads to Faster Growth?By Athanasios Vamvakidis 42

  • F47 Forecasting and Simulation

  • Are Currency Crises Predictable? A Test. By Andrew Berg and Catherine Pattillo 107

  • GFinancial Economics

  • G15 International Financial Markets

  • Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis. By Taimur Baig and Ilan Goldfajn 167

  • G21 Banks; Other Depository Institutions; Mortgages

  • Determinants and Leading Indicators of Banking Crises: Further Evidence. By Daniel C. Hardy and Ceyla Pazarbasioglu 247

  • Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia, 1974-96. By Adolfo Barajas, Roberto Steiner, and Natalia Salazar 196

  • J. Labor and Demographic Economics

  • J61 Geographic Labor Mobility; Immigrant Workers

  • How Do the Skilled and Unskilled Respond to Regional Shocks? The Case of Spain. By Paolo Mauro and Antonio Spilimbergo 1

  • LIndustrial Organization

  • L13 Oligopoly and Other Imperfect Markets

  • Interest Spreads in Banking in Colombia, 1974-96, By Adolfo Barajas, Roberto Steiner, and Natalia Salazar 196

  • N Economic History

  • N1 Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics; Growth and Fluctuations

  • N15 Asia including Middle East

  • East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis. By Nicholas Crafts 139

  • N2 Financial Markets and Institutions

  • N25 Asia including Middle East

  • East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis. By Nicholas Crafts 139

  • N3 Labor, Demography, Education, Income, and Wealth

  • N35 Asia including Middle East

  • East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis. By Nicholas Crafts 139

  • O Economic Development, Technological Change, and Growth

  • O1 Economic Development

  • Growth, Trade, and De industrialization. By Robert Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy 18

  • O3 Technological Change

  • Growth, Trade, and De industrialization. By Robert Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy 18

  • O11 Macroeconomic Analyses of Economic Development

  • East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis. By Nicholas Crafts 139

  • O47 Measurement of Economic Growth; Aggregate Productivity

  • East Asian Growth Before and After the Crisis. By Nicholas Crafts 139

  • O53 Asia including Middle East

  • The Uzbek Growth Puzzle. By Jeromin Zettelmeyer 274

  • P Economic Systems

  • P2 Socialist Systems and Transitional Economies

  • P27 Performance and Prospects

  • The Uzbek Growth Puzzle. By Jeromin Zettelmeyer 274

  • P52 Comparative Studies of Particular Economies

  • The Uzbek Growth Puzzle. By Jeromin Zettelmeyer 274

In statistical matter throughout this issue.

  • dots (...) indicate that ihe data are not available;

  • a dash (—) indicates that the figure is zero or less than half the final digit shown, or that the item does not exist;

  • a single dot (.) indicates decimals;

  • a comma (,) separates thousands and millions;

  • “billion” means a thousand million; and “trillion” means a thousand billion:

  • a short dash (-) is used between years or months (for example, 1998—99 or January-June) to indicate a total of the years or months inclusive of the beginning and ending years or months:

  • a slash (/) is used between years (for example, 1998/99) to indicate a fiscal year or a crop year;

  • a colon is used between a year and a number indicating a quarter within that year (for example, 1998:1); and

  • components of tables may not add to totals shown because of rounding.

The term “country,” as used in this publication, may not refer to a territorial entity that is a state as understood by international law and practice; the term may also cover some territorial entiiies that are not states but for which statistical data are maintained and provided internationally on a separate and independent basis.

Design; Luisa Menjivtu-Macdonald and Sanaa Elaroussi

  • Collapse
  • Expand
IMF Staff papers, Volume 46 No. 3
Author:
International Monetary Fund. Research Dept.
  • Figure 1.

    Real and Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility

    (as from Standard Deviation of Exchange Rate Change)

  • Figure 2.

    Lira/Deutsche Mark Exchange Rate Volatility with and without ERM

    Percentage change