The current system of corporate taxation in the United States treats debt and equity financing of firms differently. Interest payments, unlike dividends, are deducted from the corporate income tax and, therefore, enjoy a tax advantage. Firms with higher corporate tax rates have an incentive to increase leverage. Although most firms face the same statutory tax rate, effective corporate tax rates may vary greatly because of differences across firms in the ability to shield profits from the corporate tax.1 A firm with higher investment tax credits, accelerated depreciation allowances, or tax loss carryforwards faces lower effective corporate tax rates than an identical firm without these nondebl tax shields.

Abstract

The current system of corporate taxation in the United States treats debt and equity financing of firms differently. Interest payments, unlike dividends, are deducted from the corporate income tax and, therefore, enjoy a tax advantage. Firms with higher corporate tax rates have an incentive to increase leverage. Although most firms face the same statutory tax rate, effective corporate tax rates may vary greatly because of differences across firms in the ability to shield profits from the corporate tax.1 A firm with higher investment tax credits, accelerated depreciation allowances, or tax loss carryforwards faces lower effective corporate tax rates than an identical firm without these nondebl tax shields.

The current system of corporate taxation in the United States treats debt and equity financing of firms differently. Interest payments, unlike dividends, are deducted from the corporate income tax and, therefore, enjoy a tax advantage. Firms with higher corporate tax rates have an incentive to increase leverage. Although most firms face the same statutory tax rate, effective corporate tax rates may vary greatly because of differences across firms in the ability to shield profits from the corporate tax.1 A firm with higher investment tax credits, accelerated depreciation allowances, or tax loss carryforwards faces lower effective corporate tax rates than an identical firm without these nondebl tax shields.

A large number of studies attempt to empirically establish the relationship between nondebt tax shields and financing choices of firms. Titman and Wessels (1988) and Bradley, Jarrell, and Kim (1984), among others. fail to find significant tax effects. Mackie-Mason (1990a) shows that it is important to consider incremental financing decisions, rather than aggregate debt-equity ratios. If effective tax rates of firms change over time, aggregate debt-equity ratios are the result of financing decisions made with different tax incentives. He relates tax loss carryforwards to the probability of issuing debt versus equity, given that the firm chooses to use external financing, and finds that firms with more tax loss carryforwards and, hence, lower expected effective tax rates are significantly less likely to issue debt. This finding supports the tax hypothesis of capital structure choice.

MacKie-Mason’s approach has two major shortcomings. The sample is limited to firms that issue either debt or equity publicly and, hence, does not consider the full menu of financing available to each firm.2 In addition, the discrete choice approach discards valuable information about the magnitude of debt or equity issues. Both shortcomings make the obtained coefficients difficult to interpret.3

The previous literature has focused on relating proxies for expected corporate tax rates to firms’ financing choices without explicitly testing the quality of their tax proxies. In this paper explicit behavioral assumptions are made about the process governing the formation of firms’ expectations. This approach provides a direct test of the effect of the proxies used in the previous literature on the expected corporate tax rate. The paper uses a two-step approach. First, expected effective corporate tax rates are estimated using information about current tax loss carryforwards, investment tax credits, and current effective tax rates, as well as other observable firm characteristics. In the second stage, this measure is related to the firms’ incremental debt financing.

In addition, the paper attempts to address some of the other shortcomings of the previous literature by considering all financing choices available to the firm, as well as by estimating tax coefficients for a sample containing all major manufacturing firms, regardless of their financial decisions or industry. Estimated expected tax rates are found to have a substantial effect on the amount of debt issued by firms in all specifications. Factors influencing effective corporate tax rates, like statutory tax rates, the magnitude of investment tax credits, and accelerated depreciation allowances, are likely to have at least a moderately large effect on the supply of debt and equity by firms and, hence, on capital markets.

I. Estimation of Expected Effective Corporate Tax Rates

Although the corporate income tax is generally a flat tax, even firms with identical profits in a given period might face different effective tax rates. Firms are allowed to carry profits and losses forward as well as backward to smooth their tax burden over time.4 Moreover, some firms might benefit from investment tax credits or accelerated depreciation allowances, which tend to decrease effective tax rates. By the same token, firms’ expectations about future tax payments depend on past profits, as well as on future and current investment tax credits, and future extraordinary expenses (discontinued operations).

There have been several different attempts to model firms’ ability to shield profits and the resulting effective tax rates. Bradley, Jarrell, and Kim (1984) calculate the 20-year average of annual depreciation plus investment tax credits divided by average earnings. The authors regress this proxy of firms’ effective tax rates on the firms’ debt-to-value ratio and find a significantly positive coefficient, which is taken as evidence against the tax hypothesis of capital structure choice. Titman and Wessels (1988) in a more elaborate empirical model, but with a similar measure, find insignificant tax effects.

MacKie-Mason (1990a) points out that investment tax credits might not be a good predictor of lower future effective tax rates because they might be positively correlated with more profitable investment opportunities. Firms with more profitable investment opportunities, however, are less likely to be tax exhausted. This reasoning might explain Bradley, Jarrell, and Kim’s (1984) estimated positive and significant relationship between investment tax credits and debt financing. MacKie-Mason (1990a) attempts to address this problem by interacting investment tax credits with a measure of the firms’ likelihood of tax exhaustion (Altman’s (1968) bankruptcy predictor) and finds the expected negative and significant effect. In addition, the author proposes tax loss carryforwards as a variable that will unambiguously indicate lower future tax rates and finds that firms with tax loss carryforwards are significantly less likely to issue debt. This is evidence in favor of the tax hypothesis of capital structure choice.

This paper extends the approach taken by MacKie-Mason in that the effect of tax shields on future tax rates is explicitly modeled. Using U.S. panel data, we estimate several measures of expected taxes under different assumptions about the process of expectation formation of the firm. This approach affords a direct test of the effect of the proxies used by previous authors on future effective tax rates.

Previous studies have assumed that the financing and investment decisions of firms are independent (see, e.g., MacKie-Mason, 1990a, and Gentry, 1994).5 The same approach is adopted here and firms are assumed to follow a two-step decision process. Specifically, in each period, firms make an investment decision first. Given this investment, firms decide how to finance it and also whether to adjust their capital structure. Firms can adjust their capital structure by issuing debt to repurchase shares, or by issuing equity to retire debt. In each period, firms form expectations about the discounted present value of the tax payments in each future period associated with the returns generated by the new investments, given their information set at time t. This can be written as

Eti[PVtax,i]=h(Iti),

where PVtax, i represents the discounted present value of the tax payments of the investments of firm i at time t, A is the expectations operator, and I, denotes the information set of firm i at time t.

It is not possible to calculate PVtax, i directly, because one does not have information on the firms’ individual investment projects, their returns, and associated tax payments. Hence, four different proxies are proposed that are calculated on the basis of different assumptions about the rate at which the firm discounts the future. All proxies are estimated using a simple rational expectations approach. First, the firm is assumed to only look one period into the future and we present two consistent estimators for that case. Second, firms are assumed to have a horizon of five years. Two estimators are presented for that case as well. Each model is discussed in turn.

Model I: Actual One-Period-Ahead Tax Rates

Kennan (1979) shows that under the assumption of rational expectations, the actual value can be used as a proxy of the expectation. Hence, the actual effective corporate lax rate of firm i in period t+ 1, τt +,1, i, can be used as a proxy for the expected effective corporate tax rate, Ar+1, i], and under the additional assumption that firms assign a discount factor of infinity to all periods after t + 1, τ,t +1, i is also a proxy for Eti[PVtax, i].6

Model II: Linear Prediction of One-Period-Ahead Tax Rates

Alternatively, in order to obtain Etit + ti a simple linear projection can be used.7 Holden, Peel, and Thomson (1985) show that consistent estimates of the expected effective corporate tax rates, given the information available to firm i at lime t, can be obtained by using the predicted values from the estimating equation

τt+1,i=α0+αi+αt+α1τti+α2Xti+ηti,(1)

with Çα1;Ç <1 to ensure stationarity. The effective corporate tax rates in period t + 1 for firm i is denoted by τt+1, i, and Xti represents the vector of variables in the information set of firm i at time t. The specification allows for effects across time and firms.

Hsiao (1986) shows that the estimated parameters obtained from a two-factor fixed effects estimation of equation (1) are inconsistent, because a lagged dependent variable appears as one of the explanatory variables and, therefore, τt, i and the error term of equation (1) might be correlated. The magnitude of the problem decreases with the length of the panel (i.e., the number of observations for each firm). In addition, the interpretation of the results from estimating equation (1) depends upon assumptions about the “endowed” effective tax rate of each firm i.

Hsiao (1986) gives a consistent feasible generalized least squares estimator for the case when τ0i is independent of the unobservable firm-specific effect, a,, where τ0i represents the initial effective tax rate of firm i in period 0. Intuitively, this estimator implies that the initial observation for each firm i is drawn from some distribution that is common to all firms, and the impact of τ0i on subsequent effective tax rates of the firm gradually diminishes over time and eventually disappears.8 Whereas this model and Model I described in the previous subsection should yield very similar proxies for Etit + ti Model II has the additional benefit of enabling us to test the ability of measures of firms’ debt and nondebt tax shields to predict future effective tax rates.

Model III: Linear Prediction of Undiscounted Five-Peri od-A head Tax Rates

It is likely that firms, when making decisions concerning long-term financing instruments, form expectations about effective tax rates more than one period into the future. The number of periods is arbitrarily fixed at five.9 Consider the case when firms do not discount effective tax rates occurring up to five years into the future and assign a discount factor of infinity to all tax rates at period t+6 and beyond. A consistent estimator is then obtained, namely,

Eti[s=15τt+s,i5],(2)

by using equation (2) in place of Etit+1,i] in equation (1). The variables contained in the information set of firm i at time / are then regressed on the unweighted average of the actual effective tax rates at t+1, t+2,,t;+5 and use the predicted values of this regression. The same specification and explanatory variables as in the previous model are used.

Model IV: Linear Prediction of Discounted Five-Period-Ahead Tax Rates

Next consider the case when firms discount lax payments accruing further out into the future more heavily than more current tax payments. Hence, instead of the unweighted average of tax rates proposed above, the following weighted average is used:

s=151sτt+s,is=151s.(3)

Expression (3) implies that the discount factor is increasing at a decreasing rate as firms look farther into the future. The expression has the additional convenient property that it yields a single tax rate and its coefficient can be easily interpreted.10 Expression (3) is used in place of the dependent variable in equation (1). The same econometric methodology and explanatory variables are used as in Model III.

Determinants of Future Effective Tax Rates

It is difficult to completely and accurately account for all variables in firms’ information sets. To minimize the arbitrariness of this choice, Xti of equation (1) includes proxies for effective corporate tax rates that previous studies have used (see MacKie-Mason, 1990a, and Titman and Wessels, 1988).

Tax loss carryforwards are the portion of past losses that can be offset against future profits to decrease effective tax rates. Hence, tax loss carryforwards capture most of the information about the earnings history of the firm that is relevant for future effective tax rates. Tax loss carryforwards (scaled by sales) could be expected to be a predictor of lower future effective tax rates (see also MacKie-Mason, 1990a).

Auerbach and Poterba (1987) find that firms have a low probability of moving from a nontaxable to a taxable state and vice versa. Therefore, current effective tax rates as a predictor of future effective tax rates are used. Firms with currently low tax rates could be expected to also have low future tax rates and we expect to find a positive relationship between current and future tax rates.

As described above, previous research has not found the expected negative relationship between investment tax credits and future effective tax rates, because firms with larger investment tax credits might be more profitable and face higher taxes. Controlling for current tax status, a firm with higher investment tax credits (scaled by sales) can be expected to face lower future effective tax rates. In addition, we follow MacKie-Mason (1990a) and interact investment tax credits with Altman’s (1968) predictor of bankruptcy. The bankruptcy predictor is also included by itself, since a firm close to bankruptcy can clearly expect to pay lower effective tax rates.

Depreciation (scaled by sales) is another measure of tax shields that might be available to the firm. Firms with large depreciation expenses are more likely to face lower effective tax rates in the future compared with otherwise identical firms with lower depreciation expenses.

If a firm has issued substantial amounts of debt in the past, it might face lower effective tax rates because its high interest payments decrease reported profits. Hence, the debt-total asset ratio is included as an explanatory variable in equation (1).

Finally, following MacKie-Mason (1990a), we include two measures of the variability of the firm’s earnings as explanatory variables. The more variable the firm’s earnings, the more of its profits the firm might be able to shield from taxes by carrying losses forward to offset profits. A negative coefficient is expected on both variables.

II. Data

Sample Selection

This study uses annual firm level Compustat data spanning 1979 to 1991. The sample includes manufacturing firms (SIC codes 2000 to 4900) traded at either the New York Stock Exchange or the American Stock Exchange, that are covered by the Compustat industrial tape. The total sample size is 16,930 for the sample period, which represents 1,300 firms. Some firms do not have any data in some periods, however. To generate a balanced panel, all firms with missing years are deleted.11 The primary sample has 929 firms with complete data for 13 years, which yields 12,077 observations. For missing values of important variables, firm-specific or industry-specific means are used.12 The firms in the sample represent 78 percent (1990, all firms) or 62 percent (1990, for the balanced panel) of the total market value of all firms traded at either the New York Stock Exchange or the American Stock Exchange.13

Other Data Considerations

This paper considers the effect of taxes on incremental financing (the change in the level of debt). The tax rate that most accurately reflects firms’ incentives is the marginal effective corporate tax rate. Marginal effective tax rates of the investment projects of firm i in period r are not observed in the data, but rather average effective tax rates. Therefore, the average effective tax rate is used as a proxy for the marginal rate.

Marginal tax rates might differ dramatically from average tax rates for firms reporting a loss and for firms with tax loss carryforwards. The effect of tax loss carryforwards in the empirical specifications is controlled for, but it is impossible to accurately calculate effective tax rates for firms reporting a loss in a given period, because effective tax rates arc defined as income tax payments divided by profits before taxes. Effective tax rates for these firms are coded as follows: firms reporting losses, yet with positive tax payments, are coded with the statutory tax rate (365 cases). We suspect that the firms reported a small positive profit for tax purposes, but due to differences between financial and tax accounting, reported a loss for financial purposes.14 We assume that the profit reponed for tax purposes is taxable at the statutory rate. Firms reporting a loss and receiving a refund are coded with the negative statutory corporate tax rate (1,394 cases). We also assume that these firms have unused tax shields, which should be reflected in their effective tax rate.15 For all other firms, effective tax rates are obtained by dividing actual income tax payments by profits before taxes, interest, and discontinued operations (15,154 cases). 16

An additional problem arises if a firm has earnings close to zero. In that case even a small tax payment may result in extremely high effective tax rates. This is evident from the maximum of 6,600 percent and the minimum of-39,000 percent reported in Table A1. It is possible that these extremely high or low effective tax rates could have a disproportionate influence on the results. Therefore, the tax variable is split into two variables: a “good” tax rate, which is equal to the effective tax rate if the effective tax rate is between zero and one, and zero otherwise, and a “bad” lax rate, which is equal to the effective tax rate if the effective tax rate is outside the range of zero and one, and zero otherwise. The primary specifications use this split variable.

Auerbach and Poterba (1987) point out that there might be a large discrepancy between the profits that are reported for financial purposes recorded in the Compustat data, and profits reported for tax purposes, which are not publicly available. The first source of discrepancy arises from differences in depreciation allowances. For the computation of financial profits, firms use straight-line depreciation, while for tax purposes firms are allowed to include accelerated depreciation allowances. Therefore, profits reported in Compustat will be higher than in the tax returns. Firms’ effective tax rates consequently will be lower in Compustat data than for tax purposes, because tax payments are calculated using lower profits. Accelerated depreciation allowances are designed to increase investment by lowering the taxes firms pay on investments. Whereas when using the effective tax rate calculated from financial statements, it is possible to capture the incentives intended by the policymaker, the measure is clearly not an accurate reflection of the “true” effective tax rate faced by the firm. This is an important caveat to keep in mind.

A second discrepancy between financial and tax data might arise from the treatment of discontinued operations and other large “extraordinary” write-offs and expenses. Auerbach and Poterba (1987) point out that a firm, by discontinuing an unprofitable operation and writing it off, might report a substantial loss in its financial statement but receives no tax benefit from the transaction. In this case financial profits are lower than the profits reported to the tax authorities, leading to overly high effective tax rates for these firms. Therefore, when calculating effective tax rates, the Compustat variable “discontinued operations” was added back to the profit variable.

III. Estimated Effective Tax Rates

Results from the first-stage estimation of effective future tax rates are presented in Table 1. Although these results are primarily used to generate the predicted values used in the estimation of incremental debt-asset ratios, they are also of independent interest. The estimated coefficients are very similar for all three models. Current effective tax rates are an important predictor of future effective tax rates. An increase in current effective tax rates of 1 percentage point is associated with a 0.48 to 0.68 percentage point increase in future effective tax rates, using the coefficient on the “good” tax rate variable. Table A2 in the Appendix reports results for specifications using a single tax rate. It is evident that if the tax rate is not split, the effect of current tax rates on future tax rates would be substantially smaller, which is likely due to the exceptionally high and low tax rates in the sample.

It is surprising that tax loss carryforwards appear to be correlated with higher future effective tax rates when controlling for current tax rates, although the coefficients are very small and insignificant. It appears that tax loss carryforwards do not contain much additional information when controlling for current effective tax rates.

Contrary to MacEie-Mason (1990a). investment tax credits arc significantly negatively related to lower effective corporate tax rates. The second measure of nondebt tax shields used, depreciation divided by sales, is also a strong predictor of lower future effective tax rates, despite the fact that the depreciation variable is likely to be incorrectly measured because of its failure to allow for accelerated depreciation allowances.

Table 1.

Estimation of Effective Tax Rates

article image
Notes: Definitions and descriptive statistics are in the Appendix. Recall that Model I uses actual one-period-ahead effective tax rates. Model II is a random effects model, estimated by feasible generalized least squares; Models III and IV are estimated by two-factor fixed effects. Standard errors are in parentheses. One asterisk and two asterisks represent significance at the 10 percent and the 5 percent level, respectively.

Similarly, firms with a greater variance in earnings (Types A and B) tend to have lower effective tax rates, which presumably is a reflection of their greater ability to shield current profits with losses from previous periods. The current debt-total assets ratio is associated with significantly lower effective tax rates. This is an interesting result, because at first glance it appears to contradict the hypothesis that higher taxes should be associated with more debt financing. Debt-total asset ratios, however, are the cumulative result of a large number of financing decisions and, hence, the coefficient should be interpreted as reflecting the greater amount of interest tax shields of highly leveraged firms. The estimated coefficient on Altman’s (1968) bankruptcy predictor is negative, as expected, but the coefficients are small and not significant.

Poterba (1992) shows that effective corporate tax rates reached their peak in 1980 at 42.6 percent (the statutory tax rate in 1980 was 46 percent) and declined subsequently, with the exception of 1987 when effective tax rates increased from 30 percent in 1986 to 37 percent in 1987(in 1988, the effective tax rate decreased back to 30 percent). This pattern is roughly reflected in the negative coefficients for most periods after 1980 (the omitted category). All other coefficients are insignificant, although most have the predicted sign.

IV. Estimation Of Financing Decisions

As a second step the measures of the firms’ expectation of future effective tax rates obtained in the previous section are related to a continuous measure of the firms’ financing decision. MacKie-Mason (1990a) first pointed out that it is important to use measures of incremental financing decisions rather than debt-equity ratios, because the debt-equity ratio of the firm is the sum of many financing decisions and changing expectations about future tax rates. A simple measure of incremental financing of firms is the change in total debt scaled by the firms’ total assets. This dependent variable permits one to calculate elasticities of debt financing with respect to effective corporate tax rates and obtain a more accurate picture of the magnitude of tax effects on firms’ financing decisions.17

If firms with higher expected lax rates have lower total assets, we might mistakenly interpret an estimated positive coefficient as evidence in favor of the tax hypothesis. Therefore, the level of total assets is included separately as an explanatory variable. Similarly, if firms with higher effective tax rates have more profitable investment opportunities, the tax coefficient would be biased upward. A measure of the firms’ current investment is included to control for this effect.

The estimating equation for firms’ financing decision is of the form

Dt+1i=β0+βi+βt+β1E^ti[PVtax,i]+β2Ati+ϵti,

with the restriction

i=1Nβi=t=1Tβt=0,

and where Dt +i represents the change in total debt divided by the level of total assets for firm i in period t + 1, and Êti[PVtax, i] denotes the respective proxy used for the expected discounted tax rates associated with the investment of firm i. To account for the effect of very high or low effective lax rates (see also the second part of Section II), we split Êti[PVtax, i] into two variables: a “good” tax rate that is equal to the predicted value of Models II to IV estimated previously if the predicted value is between zero and one. and zero otherwise, and a “bad” tax rate that is equal to the predicted value if the predicted value is outside the range of zero and one, and zero otherwise.

Ati represents the vector of variables measuring alternative theories of capital structure choice. These variables and the underlying theories are discussed below. We estimate a two-factor fixed effects model allowing for effects across time and firms.

V. Other Theories of Capital Structure Choice

Most alternative theories of capital structure choice are based on the idea that managers, stockholders, and bondholders of the firm have diverging interests and incomplete information, and are unable to completely monitor each other. Unfortunately, there is currently no theory that unifies the tax approach to capital structure choice with approaches based on asymmetric information. This paper is primarily concerned with tax effects, but the failure to control for these alternative theories may bias the estimates. Hence, proxies for several alternative theories that others have found to be significantly related lo firms’ financing decisions are introduced into the empirical specification.18 Because we are following MacKie-Mason (1990a) very closely in the choice and definition of these proxies, only a very brief description of the variables and their predicted effect on the amount of debt financing is needed.

Myers and Majluf (1984) and Myers (1984) propose a model that is concerned with the decision between external (bond issues, stock issues) versus internal financing (bank loans, retained earnings), and not with the choice between debt and equity. The relative infrequency of stock and bond issues is explained with a simple “lemons” model. If managers have information about the firm that investors do not, firms will only be able to issue stock at a discount. Hence, firms will issue stock only as a last resort after having explored all other possible sources of funds. In the remainder of the paper, this theory is referred to as the signaling hypothesis.

Since Myers’s (1984) and Myers and Majluf’s (1984) theory is concerned with the choice between external and internal financing, retained earnings scaled by total assets are included as an explanatory variable. Asymmetric information increases the cost of public issues of either debt or equity. The inclusion of retained earnings as an explanatory variable controls for internal equity financing. Conditioning on retained earnings, the equity alternative (stock issues) should be more affected by the lemons problem than the debt alternative (bank loans and bond issues) measured by the dependent variable. If internal and external equity financing are imperfect substitutes. firms with more retained earnings will use less debt financing.

According to the traditional view on dividend taxation, dividends are costly signals to the current shareholders.19 If a firm pays dividends, new shareholders might view a dividend-paying firm more favorably than a non-dividend-paying firm. Controlling for retained earnings, a dividend-paying firm should use less debt finance, because it is able to issue equity more cheaply (the variable is coded as one if firms pay dividends). Along similar lines, investors will require a smaller lemons premium if the stock price recently increased, which also might signal a well-performing firm (MacKie-Mason, 1990a). Hence, we use the previous year’s change in the firm’s stock price as an explanatory variable.

Myers (1977) presents a model in which a large amount of outstanding debt causes underinvestment in new projects, because managers require the investment to generate a sufficiently large return not only to satisfy the debt payments (including principal) but also to generate an incremental return for the stockholders. The first best condition would only require that the investment generates an acceptable return on the incremental investment, and, hence, there is underinvestment. Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue in a related model that firms with large debt burdens may take excessive risks because the stockholders gain if the risk succeeds, but only the bondholders lose if it fails. Hence, it should be very costly for these firms to issue any new debt.

Proxies related to this set of agency theories measure moral hazard and hence are related to the amount of debt already issued f MacKie-Mason, 1990a and 1990b). The ratio of plant and equipment to total assets indicates the relative importance of the assets already committed. Agency theory predicts that it should be cheaper to raise additional debt for firms with more assets committed. In addition, the firm’s research and development expenditures as well as its advertising expenditures, whose values depend on future investment decisions (see Bradley, Jarrell, and Kim, 1984, and MacKie-Mason, 1990a), are used to measure the amount of intangible assets in the firm. If there are more intangible assets in the firm, there might be a greater potential for moral hazard and, hence, agency theory predicts that firms with larger research and development expenditures or larger advertising expenditures use less debt financing.

Jensen (19X6) considers the opposite case in which firms with large amounts of free cash flow and few profitable investment opportunities might invest in projects with submarket returns, because that will keep the control of the funds with the managers. Stockholders, in an attempt to increase the amounts of funds that flow out of the firm might want to swap stocks for bonds. We follow MacKie-Mason (1990a) in the choice of proxies for these theories related to investment inefficiencies. According to Jensen (1986), firms with a lot of free cash flow and few profitable investment opportunities have an incentive to choose debt. We include Auerbach’s (1985) measure of cash deficit after average dividends and investment expenditures as a measure of “free cash How.” In addition, we attempt to account for differences in profitable investment opportunities by using the ratio of the market value of equity and the book value of equity as an explanatory variable. If a firm has a large number of profitable investment opportunities, that should be reflected in a high market value of equity relative to the book value. All three hypotheses are lumped together and labeled “agency theory” in the remainder of this paper.

Firms might use less debt because of the direct and indirect costs associated with bankruptcy. Again following MacKie-Mason (1990a), two measures of the variability of firms’ earnings, as well as Altman’s (1968) bankruptcy indicator, are included as independent variables into the specification.

Definitions of all variables are reported in the Appendix, and summary statistics are in Table A1.

VI. Estimation Results for Firms’ Financing Decisions

Table 2 reports results from two-factor fixed effects models using the predicted values of Models II to IV as proxies for firms’ expectations. Recall that Model I uses the actual one-period-ahead effective tax rate. The dependent variable is the change in debt divided by the firms’ total assets. All four proxies for expected effective tax rates are positively related to the amount of debt issued by firms. The estimated coefficients are significant at any conventional significance level in all four models. Firms with higher expected effective tax rates use more debt financing. Firms issue debt on average at a rate of about 1.8 percent of their total assets in every period. If all firms paid the statutory income tax rate on all profits, this ratio would increase to 3.1 percent. In contrast, if there were no corporate income tax the ratio would decrease to -0.3 percent, that is, firms would issue equity to repurchase debt.

Table 2.

Expected Tax Rutes and Finuncitig Decisions

article image
Notes: Definitions and summary statistics are in the Appendix. The dependent variable is the change in debt divided by total assets. Two-factor fixed effects model. Fixed effects for firms and periods not reported. Standard errors are in parentheses. One and two asterisks represent significance at the 10 and the 5 percent level, respectively.

Results for specifications in which the expected tax rate is not split are reported in Table A3. Not splitting the variable leads to substantial understatement of tax effects for Models I and II and to a slight overstatement for Models III and IV.

The results presented in Table 2 provide some support for agency theory as an explanation for financing decisions of firms, especially in Models III and IV. Firms with more free cash flow, as measured by Auerbach’s (1985) cash deficit variable, tend to use more debt, although the effect is only statistically significant at the 5 percent level in Models III and IV. This evidence is consistent with the idea that stockholders attempt to discipline managers through the interest obligations. Research and development expenditures are positively correlated (and significant in three of the four models) with firms’ incremental debt financing, which is inconsistent with agency theory. The estimated coefficient for advertising expenditures is not significantly different from zero in any specification. It appears, however, that firms with more growth opportunities and, therefore, higher ratios of the market value of equity to the book value of equity, use significantly (at the 5 percent level in two specifications) less debt finance, which is consistent with the predictions of the agency theory. The estimated coefficients are the same sign as MacKie-Mason’s with the exception of research and development expenditures, for which MacKie-Mason obtained a negative coefficient.

There is no evidence supporting the signaling hypothesis. The estimated coefficients on dividend-paying firms and on the change in stock price are all positive and two are significant at the 5 percent level. The result contradicts the notion that dividends or increases in stock prices are perceived as favorable signals by investors and, hence, decrease the cost of stock issues. MacKie-Mason also finds a positive coefficient on dividends, but obtains the expected negative coefficient on the change in the stock price. These findings support results obtained by Loderer and Mauer (1992), who test whether equity-issuing firms are more likely to pay or increase dividends than nonissuing firms. If dividends were an important signal to shareholders, firms who planned to issue stock should be more likely to start paying dividends or increase dividend payouts preceding the issue. The evidence presented in Loderer and Mauer contradicts that idea.

The evidence on the bankruptcy hypothesis is somewhat supportive. The variance of earnings, Type A. has the expected negative sign and is statistically significant. In addition, when it is interacted with Altman’s (1968) bankruptcy predictor, it remains negative and significant in two specificalions.

The variance of earnings. Type B, is positive and insignificant in all but one specification.

The significantly positive coefficient on the investment variable confirms the earlier suspicion that firms with larger investment projects issue more debt. There does not appear to be a significant relationship between the level of total assets and financing; the coefficients on the total asset variable are insignificant.

In summary, important and statistically significant tax effects have been found using four different proxies for expected effective tax rates. Some support for the agency theory of capital structure choice and for bankruptcy costs is also found. The evidence provides no support for the signaling hypothesis.

Recall that to generate a balanced panel we dropped all firms with incomplete sets of data. This leads to the exclusion of 4,853 observations or approximately 400 firms. Column 1 of Table 3 reports probit results for the probability of remaining in the balanced sample. The dependent variable is equal to one if the firm is in the balanced panel. Firms with complete sets of data face significantly higher effective tax rates, their earnings are less variable, and they are less likely to declare bankruptcy, have significantly less free cash flow, have higher market values relative to their book values, and are much more likely to pay dividends. In addition, firms in the balanced sample invest more, have more retained earnings, and are larger.

Given the significant differences between the two groups we present results using Model I (actual one-period-ahead tax rates as the measure of firms’ expected tax rate) for the unbalanced panel in column 2 of Table 3. These results cannot be directly compared to Table 2, because they are obtained using ordinary least squares regression (with time and industry dummies) and, therefore, do not allow for fixed effects across firms. Nevertheless, the similarity of most estimated coefficients across Tables 2 and 3 can be taken as suggestive evidence that the results in Table 2 are not driven by sample selection bias.

VII. Conclusion

This paper uses a simple rational expectations approach to estimate firms* expectations of future effective tax rates. Using a large Compustat panel data set of U.S. firms, we find that current average effective tax rates have substantial predictive power for the estimation of expected corporate tax rates. Moreover, controlling for current effective tax rates, investment tax credits, and depreciation are powerful predictors of lower future effective tax rates.

In the second stage, the estimated expected tax rates are related to U.S. firms’ incremental debt-total asset ratios, controlling for other theories of capital structure choice. The results obtained support the notion that firms take expected effective tax rates into consideration when choosing between debt and equity to finance their investment projects and corroborate earlier findings in MacKie-Mason (1990a). In contrast to MacKie-Mason, however, we have been able to estimate tax effects for firms that represent most of the corporate market value at the New York and American stock exchanges. It was also possible to make fairly accurate statements about the magnitude of the effects and find that they are quite substantial. An increase in expected effective tax rales (due to increases in statutory rates, changes in depreciation allowances, or the reintroduction of the investment tax credit) would, given the results obtained in this paper, have a large effect on the commercial debt and equity markets in the United States. For example. if all firms paid the current statutory corporate tax rate (that would represent a tax increase of between 10 to 15 percentage points), the value of annual debt issues would increase by 72 percent (or 1.4 percentage points; from 1.8 percent to 3.1 percent).

Table 3.

Probit and Unbalanced Panel Results

article image
Notes: Definitions and summary statistics are in the Appendix, The dependent variable for the probit model is whether the firm is included in the balanced panel (1 if included). For the unbalanced panel the model is estimated by ordinary least squares with time and industry dummy variables. Standard errors are in parentheses. One and two asterisks represent significance at the 10 percent and the 5 percent level, respectively.

There is some evidence that agency and bankruptcy costs have an important influence on the amount of debt issued, but no evidence to support Myers’s (1984) signaling hypothesis. All of these findings are consistent with the previous literature.

It is very difficult to unambiguously reject or support any of the alternative theories of the financing decision of firms, because the choice of proxies is always somewhat arbitrary. It appears useful to attempt to unify these theories with the tax hypothesis, in part because it is likely that there are important interactions between the signaling, agency, and tax hypotheses. To develop an integrating theory of capital structure, choice remains an important avenue for future research.

Corporate tax revenues have declined steadily since World War II in the United Stales. It would be incorrect, however, to conclude that corporate taxes therefore have little importance for corporate decisions. This paper, and Gropp (1995) for German firms, have presented evidence that the distortionary effect of corporate taxation on firms* financing is very likely substantial both in Germany and in the United States.

APPENDIX

Definitions

Tax loss carryforward = (hook tax loss carryforward)/sales

Investment tax credit = investment tax credits/sales

Depreciation = depreciation/sales

EBIT = earnings before interest payments and taxes

Bankruptcy predictor is Alunan’s (1968) bankruptcy predictor excluding the ratio of market equity to book debt

Bankruptcy predictor = 3.3 AIT/(total assets) + 1.0 sales/(total assets = 1.4 (retained earnings)/(total assets) + 1.2 (working capital)/(total assets)

R & D expenditures = research and development expenditures/sales (if R&D is missing. the variable is coded as zero)

Table A1.

Summary Statistics

article image
Note: Definitions of all variables are in the Appendix.

Advertising expenditures = (advertising expenditures)/sales (if advertising expenditures are missing, the variable is coded as zero)

EBIDT = earnings before interest, depreciation, and taxes

Variance of earnings, Type A = standard deviation of (EBIDTt, - EBIDTt-1) divided by mean of total assets for the sample period

Variance of earnings, Type = standard deviation of (EBIDTt, - EBIDTt-1)/EBIDTt-1

Fraction of assets in plant and equipment = (plant-accumulated depreciation)/(total assets-current liabilities)

Free cash flow = {capital expenditures + average dividends - {cash flow + capital expenditures c [(total debt)/(net assets)] }/(net sales), where average dividends are the mean dividends during the sample period

Table A2.

Additiottal Results for the Estimation of Expected Tax Rates

article image
Notes: Definitions and descriptive statistics are in the Appendix. Recall that Model I uses actual one-period-ahead tax rates. Mode) II is a random effects model, estimated by feasible least squares; Models III and IV are estimated by two-factor fixed effects. Standard errors are in parentheses. One asterisk and two asterisks denote significance at the 5 percent and the 10 percent level, respectively.
Table A3.

Additional Results for the Financing Decision

article image
Notes: Definitions and descriptive statistics are in the Appendix. The dependent variable is the change in debt divided by total assets. Two-factor fixed effects model. Fixed effects for firms and periods not reported. Standard errors are in parentheses. One asterisk and two asterisks denote significance at the 5 percent and the 10 percent level, respectively.

Market value of equity/book value of equity = [(end of year slock price)*(number of shares outstanding)]/(book value of common and preferred stock)

Current debt-total) assets ratio = (long-term debt)/(total assets)

Dividend paying firm = 1 if firm pays dividends either on common or preferred stock; 0 otherwise

Change in stock price = (stock price beginning of current year) - (stock price beginning of previous year)

Investment = [(change in fixed assets) + depreciation J/(total assets)

Net assets = total assets - current payables

EBTDO = learnings before [axes ami discontinued operations

Current effective tax rates = (income taxes paid)/<EBITDO< if <EBITDO<< 0

Current effective tax rates = statutory corporate tax rate if EBITDO < 0 and (income taxes paid) >0

Current effective tax rates = -(statutory corporate tax rale) if EBITDO <0 and (income taxes paid) <0

Change in debt divided by total assets = (total debtt+1 - total debtt)/(total assetst)

Investment = investment/total) assets

Retained earnings = retained earnings/total assets

REFERENCES

  • Alunan, E., 1968, “Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 23 (September), pp. 589609.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Altshuler, Rosaline, and Alan J. Auerbach, 1990, “The Significance of Tax Law Asymmetries: An Empirical Investigation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105 (February), pp. 6186.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., 1985, “Real Determinants of Corporate Leverage,” in Corporate Capital Structures in the United States, ed. by Benjamin F. Friedman (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 12543.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., and James M. Poterba, 1987, “Tax Loss Carryforwards and Corporate Tax Incentives,” in The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation, ed. by Martin S. Feldstein (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 30537.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bradley, Michael, Gregg A. Jarrell, and E. Han Kim, 1984, “On the Existence of an Optimal Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Finance, Vol.39 (July), pp. 85778.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fullerton, Don, 1984, “The United States,” in The Taxation of Income from Capital: A Comparative Study in the United Slates, the United Kingdom, Sweden, and West Germany, ed. by Mervyn A. King and Don Fullerton (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 193267.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genlry. William M., 1994, ’Taxes, Financial Decisions and Organizational Form: Evidence from Publicly Traded Partnerships,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 53 (February), pp. 22344.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gropp, Reint E., 1995, “Local Taxes and Capital Structure Choice” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Holden. K., D.A. Peel, and John L. Thomson, 1985, Expectations: Theory and Evidence (London: Macmillan).

  • Hsiao, Cheng, 1986, Analysis of Panel Data (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

  • Jensen, Michael C, 1986, “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers,” American Economic Review; Papers and Proceedings. Vol. 76 (May), pp. 32329.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jensen, Michael C, and William H. Meckling, 1976, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 (October), pp. 30560.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kennan, John. 1979, “The Estimation of Partial Adjustment Models with Rational Expectations,” Econometrica, Vol, 47 (November), pp. 144155.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loderer, Claudio F., and David C. Mauer. 1992, “Corporate Dividends and Seasoned Equity Issues: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Finance, Vol.47 (March), pp. 20125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K., 1990a, “Do Taxes Affect Corporate Financing Decisions?” Journal of Finance, Vol. 45 (December), pp. 147193.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K., 1990b, “Do Firms Care Who Provides Their Financing?” in Asymmetric Information, Corporate Finance, and Investment, ed. by R. Glen Hubbard (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 63103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mauer, David C, and Alexander J. Triantis, 1994, “Interactions of Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions: A Dynamic Framework,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 49 (September), pp. 125377.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Myers, Stewart C., 1977, “Determinants of Corporate Borrowing,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5 (November), pp. 14775,

  • Myers, Stewart C., 1984, “The Capital Structure Puzzle,” Journal of Finance. Vol. 39 (July), pp. 57592.

  • Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf, 1984. “Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 13 (June), pp. 187221.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poterba, J., 1992, “Why Didn’t the Tax Reform Act of 1986 Raise Corporate Taxes?” in Tax Policy and the Economy, ed. by Lawrence H. Summers and David Bradford, pp. 4358.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Titman, Sheridan, and Roberto Wessels, 1988, “The Determinants of Capital Structure Choice,” Journal of Finance. Vol. 43 (March), pp. 119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Bureau of the Census, 1992, Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1992, (Washington: Government Printing Office, 112th ed.)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zodrow, George, 1991, “On the ”Traditional” and “New” Views of Dividend Taxation,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 44 (December), pp. 497509.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

Reint Gropp is an Economist in the Piscal Affairs Department. The author would like to thank John Karl Scholz, James Andreoni, Guy Meredith. Liant Ebrill, and especially David Mauer, for valuable comments and suggestions.

1

Income up to $l00,000 is taxed at a lower rate, which generally only concerns very small firms. This feature of the corporate tax system is ignored throughout this paper.

2

Bond and stock issues, as well as bank loans and retained earnings, compose the full choice menu of the firm.

3

Genlry (1994) compares the capital structure decision of pubficly traded partnerships and corporations in the United States oil and gas exploration indastries. He finds that partnerships, which are not subject to the corporate income tax. are significantly less likely to use debt financing, which provides support for the tax hypothesis. His estimates, however, only apply to one industry and cannot be generalized to reach conclusions about the whole population of firms in the United Stales. Gropp (1995) uses variation of local business tax rates in Germany and finds that taxes have a significant effect on the capital structure choice of German firms.

4

See Auerbach and Poterba (1987) and Altshuler and Auerbach (1990) for more institutional details about tax loss carryforwards and their effect on the effective corporate tax rates of firms.

5

This appears to be a reasonable assumption. Recently. Mauer and Triantis (1994) developed a model that suggests the feedback effects between financing and investment decisions are likely to be small.

6

This also describes the case when the investment only lasts one period.

7

This is a “rational” expectations model in the sense that firms use all information available to them to “rationally” predict This does not imply that this will yield a “rational” prediction of PVtax, i, unless the investment only lasts one period.

8

Alternatively, one could assume that ττi, o and αi are correlated. This has the undesirable consequence, however, that each firm i converges to some final tax rate that is primarily characterized by the unobservable effect αi. For further discussion, see Hsiao (1986).

9

In the empirical analysis below, three periods ahead yield very similar results.

10

The weights from expression (3) are 0.444 for period t + 1, 0.224 for period (t+ 2, 0.124 for t + 3.0.114 for t + 4. and 0.094 for period t + 5.

11

It simplifies the econometrics considerably to estimate Models II through IV using a balanced panel. Estimating the models for the unbalanced panel and allowing for fixed effects across firms and periods requires the estimation of a large number of additional parameters (see Hsiao, 1986). To assess the sensitivity of the results to the dropped firms, results for Model I are also reported with the unbalanced panel using ordinary least squares with time and industry dummies. These results are reported in Section VI.

12

Using this method rather than imputing missing values generally increases standard errors of the estimated coefficients.

13

The total market value of all slocks traded at the NYSE and the AMEX is approximately $2,961 billion (1990: see United States, Bureau of the Census, 1992), the market value of all stocks in the unbalanced panel in 1990 was $2,320 billion, and in the balanced panel $1,548 billion.

14

Other problems arising from differences in tax and financial accounting are discussed below.

15

Fullerton (1984) discusses this problem and reports that in previous studies estimating the effect of effective tax rates on investment, firms with losses were coded with their actual tax payments as proxies for effective tax rates. The approach taken here avoids the large outliers associated with that convention.

16

Discontinued operations are investments that the firm believes will not generate any return in the future and, therefore, are considered without value to the firm and are depreciated in their entirely for financial purposes. Firms are not allowed to depreciate these items fully for tax purposes. This is discussed below.

17

This continuous approach also docs not select firms based on their financing choice. More important, information about the magnitude of debt or equity issues is utilized, unlike in the discrete choice approach used by MacKie-Mason (1990a),

18

For a survey, see Titman and Wesscls (1988).

19

For a comprehensive summary of the “new” versus the “old” views on dividend taxation, see Zodrow (1991).

  • Collapse
  • Expand