Asymmetry in the U.S. Output-Inflation Nexus
Author:
Mr. Peter B. Clark
Search for other papers by Mr. Peter B. Clark in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Douglas Laxton
Search for other papers by Mr. Douglas Laxton in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
David Rose https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by David Rose in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This paper presents empirical evidence supporting the proposition that there is a significant asymmetry in the U.S. output-inflation process. The important policy implication of this asymmetry is that it can be very costly if the economy overheats because this will necessitate a severe tightening in monetary conditions in order to re-establish inflation control. The empirical results presented in the paper show that the conclusions regarding asymmetry are robust to a number of tests for sensitivity to changes in the method used to estimate potential output and in the specification of the Phillips curve,

Abstract

This paper presents empirical evidence supporting the proposition that there is a significant asymmetry in the U.S. output-inflation process. The important policy implication of this asymmetry is that it can be very costly if the economy overheats because this will necessitate a severe tightening in monetary conditions in order to re-establish inflation control. The empirical results presented in the paper show that the conclusions regarding asymmetry are robust to a number of tests for sensitivity to changes in the method used to estimate potential output and in the specification of the Phillips curve,

This paper presents empirical evidence supporting the proposition that there is a statistically significant and large asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips curve, namely, that excess demand conditions are much more inflationary than excess supply conditions are disinflationary. This asymmetry implies that potential output—defined as the level of output that can be attained, on average, in an asymmetric stochastic economy—lies below what could be attained in the same economy without shocks. The measure of excess demand that is appropriate for an asymmetric Phillips curve, therefore, cannot have a zero mean; rather, this mean must be negative if inflation is to be stationary. The proper measure of excess demand needs to be taken into account in estimation in order to obtain unbiased tests of a restriction to linearity. Failure to do so can explain why some other researchers may have been misled into falsely accepting the linear model. The conclusions regarding the presence of asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips curve are shown to be robust to a number of tests for sensitivity to changes in the specification.

The paper sketches some of the implications of this asymmetry for monetary policy, using a small macro model calibrated to reflect the properties of the U.S. data. Simulations of this model contrast the effects of delaying the monetary response to a demand shock obtained from a linear model with those from a model with the estimated asymmetric Phillips curve. The simulations show that if the output-inflation process is linear, then there is no strong case for a speedy monetary policy response to a shock that creates excess demand. Dramatically different results emerge if the economy features the type of asymmetry revealed in the estimation results, namely, delaying the response results in higher inflation and necessitates a significantly stronger monetary tightening to bring inflation back under control. This model thus predicts that the seeds of large contractions are sown when the monetary authority temporizes in dealing with rising inflation and allows conditions of excess demand to become entrenched.

A key policy insight from the analysis is that the degree to which potential output in a stochastic asymmetric economy lies below that obtainable without shocks depends on the variability of output, and hence on the degree of success of the monetary authority in stabilizing the output cycle. Indeed, the results reported in the paper show that policies that allow the economy to overheat periodically can have very significant and deleterious effects on the level of potential output. Moreover, as linear models of the output-inflation process predict that there are small costs from overheating, these results suggest that there could be significant output costs associated with basing monetary policy on the predictions of a linear model.

I. Introduction

In modern economies output levels may not be so rigidly constrained in the short run as they used to be when large segments of output were governed by facilities such as the old hearth steel furnaces that had rated capacities that could not be exceeded for long without breakdown. Rather, the appropriate analogy is a flexible ceiling that can be stretched when pressed, but as the degree of pressure increases, the extent of flexibility diminishes,

Allan Greenspan (1995), p. 257

The decision to tighten the stance of U.S. monetary policy in 1994 was based on a view that there could be large costs associated with allowing the U.S. economy to overheat. In several statements to Congress, Federal Reserve Chairman Greenspan presented a strong case that if U.S. monetary policy were not tightened, the inflationary risks associated with exceeding potential output would be large, and the process of containing these inflationary forces would then require a much more severe tightening of monetary conditions in the future.

This view appears to be based on a model with an asymmetric outputinflation nexus in which inflation responds more to positive output gaps than it does to negative gaps.1 If this view of the world is correct, then allowing the economy to produce in excess of its potential will be costly because monetary tightening and large negative output gaps will be required later to rein in inflationary pressures. Indeed, as Clark, Laxton, and Rose (1995a) show, policy rules that fail to guard against overheating will result in significantly larger monetary business cycles and permanent losses in output. Moreover, policy rules that guard against the emergence of excess demand will reduce the variance of aggregate demand and raise the mean level of output.

This view of the business cycle is significantly different from that embodied in linear models of the output-inflation process. Indeed, linear models suggest that there are small costs or perhaps even some benefits from delaying interest rate hikes in the face of positive aggregate demand shocks (Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995)).

Despite the obvious importance of this issue for the conduct of monetary policy, there is little econometric evidence available for the United States that supports the view that capacity constraints imply that there is an important nonlinearity in the output-inflation nexus.2 Indeed, Braun (1984) and Gordon (1994), for example, claim that there is no evidence of nonlinearity in the U.S. data, while Eisner (1994) presents evidence that inflation may respond more to negative gaps than to positive gaps.3 The linear models estimated by Braun and Gordon imply that the average level of output will be independent of the parameters in the monetary policy rule, while Eisner’s model predicts that policies that increase the variance of output will actually raise the average level of output.

In this paper, we present evidence of significant asymmetry in the U.S. output-inflation nexus. We argue that the contrary empirical work noted above has been biased against finding evidence of asymmetry, in part because of the way that researchers have measured the output gap and specified how it should enter the Phillips curve. As the basic notion behind the Phillips curve is that inflation is driven by an unobservable output gap, it is not surprising that the econometric results and policy conclusions of different studies have been sensitive to the methods that were used to identify these output gaps.4 As we shall argue, however, it is not so much the measurement of the gaps that causes the problem as the specification of how those measures should enter the Phillips curve. In a stochastic economy with an asymmetric Phillips curve, the gaps that enter the Phillips curve cannot have zero means, as generated by standard detrending techniques. We show that taking this into account is crucial for identifying the output-inflation nexus and for avoiding bias in econometric tests for the presence of asymmetry.

The econometric identification problem is especially problematic in small samples, where “small” refers to the number of observations of cycles. Moreover, if policymakers became more successful in preventing their economies from overheating, and thereby reduced the frequency of sharp outbreaks of inflation followed by painful corrections, identifying the existence or importance of capacity constraints, at least from the relationship between output and inflation, would become correspondingly more difficult. In fact, it is episodes with major policy errors that give the econometrician the clearest information.5

Given the limited U.S. experience with inflationary surges, one obvious empirical strategy is to draw on a much larger set of monetary policy errors by using data from different countries. In this vein, Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) show that if one assumes that the Phillips curve is identical in each of the G-7 economies, then there is fairly strong evidence of asymmetry. In a recent paper, Turner (1995) relaxes this identification restriction and finds that there is some evidence of asymmetry in the Phillips curves of three of the seven major industrialized countries, including the United States.6

This paper builds on Turner’s work using U.S. data. One advantage of focusing on the U.S. data is that survey measures of inflation expectations are available and have been found to have significant predictive content for inflation—see Roberts (1994b and 1994c). The availability of such measures is important for two reasons. First, it makes it easier to distinguish between intrinsic dynamics and expectational dynamics. This separation is important for models that are constructed for policy experiments because, as is now well understood from the literature on the “Lucas critique,” it can be seriously misleading to assume that expectations formation will remain the same in the face of a change in monetary policy. It is also important for econometric work; recent evidence by Evans and Wachtel (1993), Laxton, Ricketts, and Rose (1994), and Ricketts and Rose (1995) suggests that traditional fixed-parameter reduced-form models may inaccurately characterize inflation expectations. Second, the use of survey measures of inflation expectations eliminates the econometric problems associated with using instrumental variables in models with forward-looking behavior and allows one to focus more clearly on issues concerning the role of the output gap in inflation dynamics.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section II we provide some empirical evidence that (unlike the earlier studies by Braun and by Gordon) confirms Turner’s finding that there is significant evidence of asymmetry in the U.S. data. Section III contains a simple macroeconomic model of the U.S. output-inflation process. We compare some predictions of a linear version of this model with those of our asymmetric version. In Section IV, we provide some further tests of the robustness of our conclusions, discuss some of the implications of our results for policy analysis, and explore several important methodological issues in the specification and estimation of Phillips curves. Finally, Section V provides a brief summary of our conclusions.

II. The U.S. Phillips Curve

The Basic Linear Model

The essential notion of the Phillips curve is that inflation is driven by inflation expectations and the output gap. The simplest form of the model can be written as

π t = π t + 1 e + β g a p t + t π ,

where π is inflation, πe is expected inflation, gap is the output gap (or the unemployment gap), and ∈π represents a stochastic disturbance term.7 The disturbance term also includes special factors (other than aggregate excess demand conditions and expectations) that can affect the inflation process from time to time. This could include, for example, cost-push factors such as an exogenous increase in wage demands or a change in the price of crude oil.

equation (1) is often motivated by appealing to costly price level adjustment, as in the models of Calvo (1983) or Rotemberg (1987), for example. Strictly speaking, however, these models consider price levels and not inflation rates. The simple theoretical framework has been extended by some authors (e.g., Cozier (1989)) by assuming that the changein prices is costly to adjust. In our view, however, Buiter and Miller (1985) and Roberts (1994c) describe this appropriately when they refer to it as “slipping a derivative” into the firm’s optimization problem.

The simple form of the model in equation (1) implies that the main source of inertia in inflation dynamics is rigidities in expectations. If combined with an assumption of model-consistent or rational expectations, the model implies that inflation can, in principle, be adjusted without cost. In other words, an announced reduction in the target inflation rate can be achieved without any output costs, as long as the expected inflation term in equation (1) moves one-for-one with the announced change in the target. For this to be so, however, one needs more than simple consistency with the predictions of a dynamic model; full credibility of the announced policy change is necessary.

Experience suggests that it is impossible to reduce inflation without creating a negative output gap. This can be rationalized through either one of two simple extensions to the above discussion. One extension adds the notion of intrinsic dynamics to equation (1), as would be suggested by a model with costly price adjustment. The sources of intrinsic dynamics could also take the form of overlapping wage contracts (e.g., Taylor (1980)). In either case, this would imply that an additional term in the lag(s) of inflation would have to be added to equation (1). The second extension focuses on how expectations are formed. If there is a backward-looking element to expectations formation, and we reinterpret expectations in equation (1) as the model-consistent component of overall expectations, then another rationalization of additional lags emerges. In other words, additional lags in equation (1) can arise either from intrinsic elements of inflation dynamics, which are independent of expectations, or from inertia in expectations formation itself (a backward-looking component), or both.8

Although there are differing interpretations of precisely why, there seems to be reasonably broad agreement among researchers working in this area that the simple model must be extended to account for inertia over and above what is possible in equation (1).9 The resulting model is often referred to as the “backward- and forward-looking components” model (Buiter and Miller (1985)). In this model, inflation in any time period is tied down, at least partially, by historical conditions (the backward-looking component), while the forward-looking component responds to new information about the future in a model-consistent fashion. The extended dynamic model can be written as

π t = A ( L ) π t 1 + B ( L ) π t + 1 e + β g a p t + t π .

This version of the linear model provides the starting point for our extension to include asymmetry and the null hypothesis in tests of restriction to linearity of the asymmetric alternative.10

Extending the Model for Asymmetric Effects

The most straightforward test of state-dependent asymmetry is to add positive output gaps to the model and test if the estimated parameter(s) on the additional term(s) can help explain inflation. Robert Gordon (1994) provides some econometric evidence of this nature by augmenting his simple, backward-looking, inflation-unemployment model with positive unemployment gaps. Although Gordon focuses his attention on Eisner’s version of asymmetry—that inflation falls more when the economy is in a recession than it rises when the economy is booming—his statistical evidence can be easily reinterpreted as a test for asymmetry arising from capacity constraints. Gordon’s results reveal no statistical evidence in favor of either form of asymmetry.

These results stand in sharp contrast with some recent empirical results reported by Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995), who found strong empirical evidence for the major industrial countries that positive output gaps have more powerful effects on inflation than negative output gaps. One possible reconciliation of these results could be insufficient business cycle variation in the U.S. data for researchers to be able to say anything with confidence about the role of capacity constraints on the basis of U.S. experience alone. However, since Turner (1995) finds evidence of significant asymmetry in the U.S. data, and we report corroborating evidence in this paper, it appears that the explanation must be found in another element of the methodology.

One of the points argued by Laxton, Meredith, and Rose is that it is critical for econometricians to recognize the implications of asymmetry for the measurement of the output gaps that enter the Phillips curve in order to identify properly the asymmetric model. In particular, the mean value of the gap that enters the Phillips curve will be negative under the assumption of convexity and positive under the assumption of concavity in the functional form.11 Laxton, Meredith, and Rose demonstrate, in the context of the pooled G-7 data, that failing to recognize this point will bias test results toward not rejecting a restriction to linearity. Turner takes this into account in his specification and tests, and we show below that the Laxton, Meredith, and Rose conclusions regarding tests for linearity carry over to applications with the U.S. data.

With this issue in mind, we specify an asymmetric Phillips curve as follows:

π t = A ( L ) π t 1 + B ( L ) π t + 1 e + β g a p t * + γ g a p p o s t * t π .

where gap*=y-y¯+α and gappos* represents the positive values of these adjusted gaps. The variable y is the log of output and we define y¯ to be potential output, that is, the level of output that is attainable on average in an economy subject to continual shocks.12 Thus, the gap measured as y-y¯ will have a mean of zero in targe samples. In an economy with a linear symmetric Phillips curve, this would also be an appropriate property for the gap measure used in the Phillips curve. However, with asymmetry where positive gaps have larger effects than negative gaps—if γ>0 in equation (3)—and assuming that there is some variance in aggregate demand conditions, α must be less than zero for inflation to be bounded. In other words, the gap that enters a convex asymmetric Phillips curve must have a negative mean.

equation (3) embodies the simplest empirical form of asymmetry—a piecewise linear function with the possibility of a kink at the point where gap* begins to exert upward pressure on inflation. We think of this representation as an approximation of any convex functional form. Its advantage is that we can test for asymmetry in a very simple and direct manner. Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) argue that there are advantages to more complicated functions with marginal convexity. We do not dispute this but, with the limited data available to identify the nature of the function, we prefer to keep the empirical exercise as simple as possible. equation (3) allows us to test for the presence of asymmetry, which is our prime objective here. Although we go on to use this particular model for some policy experiments, both here and in an earlier paper (Clark, Laxton, and Rose (1995a)), we consider this work illustrative. For policy analysis, it may be appropriate to assume alternative functional forms.

So far, we have not taken a stand on how one should measure potential output in practice. In any study of the Phillips curve, the choice of a measure of the output gap is very important. We shall show, however, that for the issues addressed here, it becomes less important once proper care has been taken to specify the functional form of the Phillips curve to be consistent with the hypothesis being tested. We report results using a variety of methodologies. To begin, however, we follow Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1994) and measure the trend level of output using a simple two-sided moving average filter of actual output. In their study with annual data, they measure trend output as a five-year, centered-moving average of actual output (a two-year horizon, forward and backward). In this paper, we use the same approach but report results for a range of alternative horizons (the parameter k in equation (4) below) in the two-sided filter. We later test the sensitivity of our conclusions to this methodology by repeating the estimation with a number of alternative measures of the output gap.

y ¯ = 1 2 k + 1 [ y t + i = 1 k ( y t + i + y t i ) ]

With this filter, a small value of k implies that potential output is highly correlated with actual output and, at the limit, when k =0, potential output is equal to actual output at all points in time. This calibration would be consistent with an extreme real-business-cycle view of the world, where prices adjust instantaneously to changes in excess demand. In such a world, it obviously makes no sense to estimate a Phillips curve. At the other extreme, a large value of k would be consistent with a view that most of the variation in observed output at business cycle frequencies is associated with movements in the output gap and not with potential output. Because there is considerable uncertainty about the role of demand and supply shocks in the economy and because imposing a false restriction can result in invalid statistical inferences, one way to proceed is to report results, and hypothesis tests, for a wide range of values of k.13 This is the strategy we adopt.

As emphasized above, this (or any mean zero) measure of the output gap may be a seriously biased proxy for the gap that is appropriate for use in the Phillips curve. It is to correct for this potential bias that we introduce the level shift to the filter measures of the output gap for use in the identification of the Phillips curve. This level shift is assumed to be fixed over our sample period and is estimated as the parameter α14. If short-run capacity constraints are truly a feature of the U.S. economy, imposing a zero value on α will bias γ toward zero and bias standard tests for the presence of asymmetry toward false rejection.15 We will show that this point is of the utmost importance in assessing the empirical evidence.

Is There Asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips Curve?

In this subsection, we report estimates of the U.S. Phillips curve and tests for whether it has significant asymmetry. We begin with our specification and tests and then turn to supporting evidence in the form of documentation of what happens when the logical implications of asymmetry are not taken into account in the estimation and testing.

Unbiased Tests for Asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips Curve

Table 1 reports the results of estimating our model with a determined simultaneously along with the other parameters. We report estimates for values of kranging from 2 to 16 (quarters). Because we want to hold the estimation period fixed to see how alternative gap measures perform in explaining the same data on inflation, the sample for the dependent variable (for all regressions) must end in 1990:4. (The two-sided filter with k= 16, requires data on actual output for the years 1991 to 1994.)

The details of the model to be estimated are provided at the top of Table 1. We wanted to keep the model parsimonious, because in such a small sample it is difficult to identify more than a few key parameters with any precision. This led us, for example, to limit the output gap effects to contemporaneous measures. Second, we use the Michigan Survey measure of inflation expectations. We knew from the work of Roberts (1994b and 1994c) that this measure is useful in explaining movements in actual inflation, but the most important reason for using a survey measure is, we think, that having a forward-looking element to expectations is important in estimation as well as in policy analysis. The use of the survey measure allows us to avoid the difficult econometric issues implied by explicit model-consistent expectations (e.g., the use of instrumental variables, as in Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995)). We chose a specification that includes the contemporaneous value of one-year-ahead inflation expectations as well as four lags, where each lag is assumed to have the same weight. In addition, a lagged inflation term was added to allow for intrinsic inertia in inflation dynamics.16

Table 1.

A Simple Asymmetric Model of the U.S. Output-Inflation Nexus

(t -statistics in parentheses)

article image

The results in Table 1 were obtained using nonlinear least squares in RATS. The value of kthat minimizes the standard error of the inflation equation is 12 quarters. This estimate suggests that variation in the output gap, as opposed to potential output, is the dominant source of variation in output at business cycle frequencies. Based on this preferred model, there is clear evidence that positive gaps have larger effects on inflation than do negative gaps. Indeed, the estimated total coefficient on the positive gaps (β + γ) is 1.1 or about five times greater than the coefficient on the negative gaps (ß alone). This is a very similar finding to that reported in Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995).

The estimated value of α is — 1.3; this implies that the gap* measures that are used in the Phillips curve are 1.3 percentage points smaller than the gaps based on our simple filter. Figure 1 illustrates the results for the asymmetric model. In this case, “potential” output in the top panel is raised by 0.013, relative to the trend measure from the filter, so that we can illustrate the “gaps” that enter the Phillips curve. It is important to remember that this level of output is not attainable in the stochastic economy.

The estimated value of δ is just under 0.6, leaving a weight of just over 0.4 on the lagged value of inflation. Regardless of how one chooses to interpret these coefficients (see the discussion in the previous subsection), the results suggest that there is important inertia (a backward-looking component) in inflation dynamics. There is also, however, an important forward-looking component that enters through the expectations.

Examination of the residuals from the preferred estimation indicated that there was some minor autocorrelation, primarily at the third lag. For this reason we have used the robust standard errors option in RATS to obtain the t -tests reported in parentheses. Note that the t -test for γ indicates that the simple restriction to linearity (γ = 0) is strongly rejected and that this result is robust over a wide range of values of k, Note, further, that α is strongly and significantly different from zero, a result that is also robust to substantial variation in k, Finally, we report a Wald test of the joint restriction, α, γ = 0, which imposes the full conditions of the linear null hypothesis. This test is performed on the condition that ß is strictly positive, a hypothesis that is not rejected by a direct test.17 It indicates that the joint restriction is rejected at the 99.9 percent confidence level for our preferred result.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Interpreting U.S. Inflation with an Asymmetric Model

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

Biased Tests for Asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips Curve

In discussing the motivation for including the shift effect captured by the parameter α in our model, we argued that this was essential in order to obtain unbiased tests for the presence of asymmetry. We now return to this important issue. Table 2 reports some econometric estimates of the same model under the assumption that α = 0, again for a range of values of k, The standard errors for the t -statistics (reported in parentheses) are again computed using the robust errors option of RATS.

In this case, the value of k that minimizes the standard error of the inflation equation is 8. This still has substantial smoothing of the data in the implied profile of trend output, but less than in the model of Table 1. The relative weight estimated on the forward- and backward-looking components of the dynamics is not much affected by the restriction on a. However, the preferred model here has two noteworthy features that are very different. First, the econometrician would reject the hypothesis that γ >0 at the usual confidence levels and conclude that there was no compelling evidence of asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips curve. Second, the coefficient on the output gap is statistically significant, so there is evidence that inflation is related to the output gap—a Phillips curve exists. Again, these results are robust over a substantial range of values of k.

Figure 2 provides a graphical representation of the linear Phillips curve when we impose α, γ = 0 and choose the model that maximizes the fit of the inflation equation. The regression results are shown in the second line of Table 2 with k =9. which gives the best fit under these restrictions. The top panel of the chart plots our filter measure of potential output. The middle panel presents the percent change in the CPI measured at annual rates along with the Michigan Survey measure of one-year-ahead CPI inflation expectations. The bottom panel presents the difference between inflation and its backward- and forward-looking components, πt-δπ¯te-(1-δ)πt-1, and the contribution of the output gap, as measured by the coefficient times the output gap, βgap,, As can be seen in the chart, there is a tendency for the linear model to underpredict inflation during the two inflationary episodes in the 1970s when there was large and persistent excess demand.

Table 2.

Some Biased Tests of Asymmetry

(t –statistics in parentheses)

article image
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Interpreting U.S. Inflation with an Linear Model

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

In conclusion, we find evidence of significant asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips curve, confirming the result in Turner (1995) (and the result in Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) for the pooled G-7 data). A major distinguishing feature of this work, which sets it apart from other work that finds no such evidence for the U.S. data, is the explicit attention to the implications of asymmetry for the manner in which the gaps must enter the estimated Phillips curve. It is clear that procedures that do not allow for the logical implications of the alternative hypothesis can produce biased results in tests of restriction(s) to the null hypothesis. We maintain that the failure of some researchers to account for how the output gap should enter the Phillips curve in an asymmetric world has biased their test results toward false rejection of the presence of asymmetry. We have shown that the results of tests for asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips curve are changed dramatically toward not rejecting the linear null hypothesis if a is suppressed, echoing a similar result shown by Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) for the major industrialized countries. We return to this issue in Section IV.

III. Asymmetric Versus Linear Models of the Inflation Process

This section provides a brief discussion of some properties of the estimated linear and asymmetric models of inflation dynamics described in Section II. In particular, we compare the trade-offs faced by a monetary authority in dealing with a shock to aggregate demand, using deterministic simulations of a small model of the macroeconomy and the policy control process. The model, which is essentially the same as that used in Clark, Laxton, and Rose (1995a), is sketched out below.

As the simulations embody model-consistent expectations, the monetary policy reaction function plays a key role in conditioning the overall dynamics of the economy. Indeed, the essential task of the monetary authority in the model is to act so that inflation and inflation expectations are eventually anchored to the target rate of inflation.

The simulations compare the consequences of delaying the monetary response to a demand shock in the two versions of the model. They show that, in contrast to the linear case, where delay is relatively costless, in a world with asymmetric inflation dynamics, delaying interest rate hikes in the face of excess demand results in a substantial cumulative output loss because the monetary authority is then forced to impose a more severe monetary reaction in order to reign in the higher inflationary pressures. Indeed, an important prediction of the asymmetric model is that large recessions are caused by policy errors that allow the economy to overheat and that the eventual tightening in monetary conditions is only a proximate cause.

A Simple Model of the U.S. Output-Inflation Process

The equations of the model are listed in Table 3. In addition to the two versions of the Phillips curve and some definitions, the model has two equations: one that describes the dynamics of the output gap and the mechanism by which monetary policy influences aggregate demand, and another that describes a policy reaction function designed to keep inflation in the neighborhood of a chosen target level.

The equation for output dynamics has two features that are important for these experiments. First, there are lags in the effect of the monetary control variable. Second, there is an autoregressive propagation structure that, all else being equal, initially amplifies the effects of shocks to aggregate demand and then sustains them for some time. The monetary control variable in the model, i.e., the variable that provides the transmission mechanism for monetary policy, is a short-term real interest rate. We treat the Federal Reserve funds rate as the policy instrument, but it is an ex ante real interest rate that enters the demand equation. The model is specified with a two-quarter delay before changes in the real interest rate begin to have an influence on aggregate demand. Thereafter, the effect builds such that after five to six quarters, a persistent real interest rate hike of 100 basis points that is sustained for four quarters would reduce the output gap by 0.4 percentage points. The propagation of demand shocks is represented by a second-order autoregressive structure. All else being equal, the effects of a shock are amplified in the second period and then die out slowly. These properties are roughly consistent with the evidence from both reduced-form models of the transmission mechanism (e.g., Roberts (1994a)) and more structural models (e.g., Mauskopf (1990)).

Table 3.

A Small Simulation Model of the U.S. Output-Inflation Process

article image

These properties of output dynamics and the monetary policy transmission mechanism have an important implication for the design of monetary policy rules—monetary policy cannot offset completely the effects of shocks. There will be cycles in economic activity and there will be temporary deviations of inflation from its target level. This makes it especially important for the monetary authority to be forward-looking in its actions. The particular forward-looking policy reaction function that we use is a variant of the rule considered by Bryant, Hooper, and Mann (1993). In setting the short-term interest rate, the monetary authority acts to raise the real rate that enters the output equation when inflation is expected to be above the target level three quarters ahead or there is excess demand in the economy. The particular calibration adopted is designed to ensure that inflation remains in the region of the target level and returns to the target level within a reasonably short period (two years) following a shock to aggregate demand.

The Effects of Delaying Monetary Response to a Demand Shock

The simulations show what happens when there is an impulse shock of 1 percent to aggregate demand, i.e., when a 1 percentage point output gap opens on impact and there are no further shocks.18 We compare the consequences of delaying the monetary policy response by just one quarter for the two versions of the model. The delay is implemented by simply holding the U.S. Federal Reserve funds rate at its control value for one quarter (i.e., the normal reaction function is turned off for one quarter and then operates normally).19 The results from the model with a linear Phillips curve are shown in Figures 3 (no delay) and 4 (delay). Figures 5 and 6 show the comparable results from the model with asymmetry.

If the economy is linear, the effects of delay are relatively innocuous. With an immediate response amounting to a 270 basis point increase in the short-term interest rate in the first quarter, inflation peaks at about 1 percentage point above control, and there is a cumulative gain of output of about 2 percent. With a delayed monetary response, there is a larger hike in short-term interest rates, and inflation edges slightly higher, peaking at about 1.3 percentage points above control, but the cumulative gain in output is even larger, amounting to about 2.5 percent by the end of the simulation. These results show that if the world is linear, there is no strong case for aggressive monetary resistance to inflationary demand shocks. While the monetary authority may be concerned to see inflation rise above the target by more and for a longer period of time, it would be difficult to argue that there are any real costs to delaying interest rate hikes when output exceeds potential output.

The picture looks quite different if there are capacity constraints that result in asymmetry in inflation dynamics. Despite a much stronger policy response in the no-delay scenario, with short-term interest rates up by over 400 basis points in the first quarter, inflation peaks at about 2 percentage points above control. While the course of output is roughly similar over the first few quarters, the task of reining in the higher inflationary consequences of the same shock in this model requires a much deeper secondary contraction and the elimination of any cumulative gain in output. In fact, there is a small cumulative loss of output.

The consequences of delaying the monetary response to the shock are much more dramatic in this case. Short-term interest rates must be raised substantially higher to combat the cumulating inflationary pressures, as expectations respond to the more sustained excess demand and rising inflation. Inflation now peaks at 3 percentage points above control. To bring inflation back under control in this environment requires a much more severe contraction. Indeed, the cumulative change in output is now substantially negative because a large contraction is needed to counteract the inflationary effects that are caused by the initial temporary boom.

The model with asymmetry has many of the predictions that most central bankers highlight when discussing the fundamental role of monetary policy. It provides a clear and compelling reason for forward-looking action by the monetary authority to forestall any tendency for the economy to move into excess demand. To fail to do so necessitates even tougher action later on to keep inflation in check, with unfortunate but unavoidable macroeconomic consequences. Monetary authorities’ apparent preoccupation with inflation reflects a concern about the consequences for the real economy: to temporize on inflation is to force the economy to suffer both a cumulative loss of output and more extreme variation in economic conditions.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Linear Model Responses to a Temporary I Percent Positive Demand Shock

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Linear Model Responses to a Temporary 1 Percent Positive Demand Shock: Delayed Monetary Policy Response

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Asymmetric Model Responses to a 1 Percent Positive Demand Shock

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Asymmetrie Model Responses to a 1 Percent Positive Demand Shock: Delayed Monetary Policy Response

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

IV. Some Issues in the Specification and Estimation of Phillips Curves

On Methods of Measuring Potential Output and Their Implications

This study might be criticized on the grounds that it has relied on an ad hoc, two-sided, moving average filter to measure potential output. In principle, it would be preferable to specify a dynamic structural model that nested both the linear and asymmetric views of the world, and to derive model-consistent measures of the output gap under both hypotheses. This would place the models on an equal statistical footing and, in principle, permit a clear that it would be possible to identify many more parameters and to discriminate between more complex models, given the limited number of observations of business cycles available in the data. We leave this as an interesting topic for future research.20 We would be remiss, however, if we did not check whether our results stand up if we use other univariate techniques to measure potential output. This could be important; Harvey and Jaeger (1993), for example, have shown that reliance on simple filters may induce spurious relationships in regressions.21 A related example is provided in Laxton, Shoom, and Tetlow (1992). They show that the use of simple univariate filters to measure gaps can cause spurious change-in-the-gap terms to have significant coefficients in estimated Phillips curves in cases where the true data generating process has only pure level gap effects.22 Thus, there is a risk that our use of the two-sided moving average filter to measure potential output has somehow biased our results in favor of the asymmetric model.

Harvey and Jaeger (1993) present a trend-plus-cycle or unobserved components (UC) model that is quite flexible and encompasses many other popular detrending procedures. For our purposes, their model can be thought of as a simple reduced form of a more general dynamic stochastic structural model of the U.S. economy. They show that the Hodrick and Prescott (1981) filter and the two-sided moving average filter used in this paper are generally suboptimal for estimating trends of economic variables.23 Indeed, they show that estimates from the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter are optimal—in the class of univariate filters—only under very specific parameterizations, which vary from case to case. Using several economic series as examples, they show how the arbitrary use of the HP filter can result in biased estimates of the cyclical component and can even induce spurious correlations and regression results when the variables are detrended this way. These potential problems also apply to our filter.

Harvey and Jaeger also argue that their model has several advantages over simple time trends or segmented time trends. Despite the fact that it is impossible to discriminate between deterministic segmented time trends and stochastic representations of output in small samples, they argue that the latter is preferable because segmented time trends are based on arbitrary assumptions on when the trends break.24

The validity of their general argument notwithstanding, Harvey and Jaeger show that in the particular case of the U.S. GNP their model produces estimates that are very similar to the HP (λ= 1,600) estimates. They conclude (p, 236) that this “suggests that the HP filter is tailor-made for extracting the business cycle component from U.S. GNP.” The bottom panel of Figure 7 shows the estimates obtained from the Harvey and Jaeger unobserved components (UC) model along with the estimates obtained from the HP filter with X set equal to 1,600.25 It is evident that the Harvey-Jaeger conclusion is not altered by the change in the output measure; the two methods produce very similar estimates of the U.S. GDP output gap.

Another common procedure for providing trend estimates and gap measures is to fit polynomial, often quadratic, trend lines to the data. For example, Roberts (1994c) reports estimates of inflation models that use quadratic time trend approximations to measure potential output.

Table 4 reports estimates of our inflation model based on these alternative estimates of the output gap. Again, to give some indication of the bias associated with using pure measures of central tendency in deriving gap measures for estimating the Phillips curve, we report results with and without the α shift effect. Equation (2a) in Table 4 reports the estimates for our model with the Harvey-Jaeger output gaps. Note that the fit of the model is slightly better with the Harvey-Jaeger gaps than in our best result. In our estimation, both γ and β are slightly larger than in Table 1. Moreover, all the parameters are statistically significantly different from zero, and a Wald test indicates that we can reject the joint restriction that α,β = 0 with considerable confidence. Equation (2b) reports the results when α is imposed to be equal to zero. In this case, the estimate of the coefficient on the positive output gaps (γ) falls from 1.092 in the unrestricted model to 0.331 in the restricted model. In addition, the coefficient on the output gap (β) rises from 0.281 in the unrestricted model to 0.403 in the restricted model. This confirms the direction of bias from the Monte Carlo evidence reviewed above. Moreover, as in our exercise using the simple filter, an econometrician would not be able to reject the hypothesis γ = 0 at the traditional high levels of confidence, although with these results an objective researcher might think long and hard about the risks of assuming that this gave license to throw the gappos* variable out of the model.

Equation (3a) reports the results when we use the HP (λ = 1,600) filter to measure the output gaps. The results confirm the earlier indication that these gaps are not significantly different from the Harvey-Jaeger gaps from the unobserved components model. Indeed, the parameter estimates are almost identical to those in equation (2a). And, again, the case for asymmetry weakens when we impose α = 0.

In general, univariate techniques can be expected to produce very uncertain estimates of the true relative variance of the gap term. Consequently, it may be reasonable to presume that potential output is smoother than is implied by the HP (λ = 1,600) filter or the unobserved components model. To test the sensitivity of our results to this assumption we re-estimated our model with larger weights on the smoothness parameter of the HP filter. In the limit, an extremely high weight on smoothness implies that potential output is treated as a linear time trend. Equations (4a) and (5a) provide additional estimates when λ the HP smoothing parameter, is set equal to 10,000 and 100,000, respectively. Note that the fit of the inflation equation deteriorates as larger values of λ are imposed. Thus, a view that supply shocks are irrelevant for changing the growth rate of potential output is inconsistent with explaining the time series properties of both U.S. output and inflation.

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Harvey and Jaeger’s Measure of Potential Output

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A008

Table 4.

Tests with Alternative Measures of the Output Gap

(t-statistics in parentheses)

article image

For completeness, we also offer a result with a smaller value, λ = 500, which gives the supply component of shocks more weight so that the trend estimate follows the data somewhat more closely. The fit is not quite as good as with λ = 1,600, or the Harvey-Jaeger gaps, but the results look very much like those from these two estimations.

Our final alternative is a gap measure based on a simple quadratic time trend to measure potential output, as in Roberts (1994c), for example. These estimates are reported in Equations (7a) and (7b) of Table 4. Note that when we estimate our model with these gaps we obtain a positive estimate of α and a negative estimate of γ, although neither is significantly different from zero. This result is very similar to the finding of Eisner (1994) and has the exact opposite policy implications of short-run capacity constraints. Note, however, that this particular model has the worst fit of the models considered here.

The conclusion that emerges from these supplementary regressions is that, while the particular choice of a gap measure does matter to the details of the estimates, the overall case that there is an important asymmetry in the U.S. Phillips curve is quite robust. In particular, our conclusions are robust to testing with the Harvey and Jaeger (1993) measure of output gaps, which those authors have subjected to careful scrutiny and for which they claim some important optimality properties. What emerges very clearly from the results is that it is not so much the gap measure that matters, but how it is used in estimating the Phillips curve. Consistently, tests for asymmetry are shown to be seriously biased if the logical implications of the asymmetric model are not taken into account in the estimation.

Some Additional Robustness Tests

Two common criticisms of the work presented in Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) and in earlier drafts of this paper were that our a was merely capturing omitted influences that would normally be picked up in a free constant and that our asymmetry was likely a reflection largely of special effects associated with the major oil-price shocks. We now show that neither of these arguments stands up to scrutiny. The results we cite are reported in Table 5.

Is a Simply Capturing Omitted Variables?

No. When we add a free constant to the preferred model, using our filter, or to the Harvey-Jaeger estimation from Table 4, it is small and insignificantly different from zero. For example, the significance level of the restriction of this constant to zero is about 86 percent in the extension based on our simple filter. Moreover, none of our other conclusions are affected.

What this tells us, quite clearly, is that the estimation strongly prefers our interpretation and use of α to alter the form of the curvature in the Phillips curve over the competing hypothesis that it is capturing the influence of omitted variables. Moreover, as a bonus, the theoretically preferred specification with no exogenous component to inflation is entirely consistent with the data.

Table 5.

Tests with Constant Term and Oil Prices

(t-statisiics in parentheses)

article image

Is the Asymmetry Capturing the Particular Influence of Oil-Price Shocks?

No. When we add the rate of change of the relative price of crude oil to our preferred model or to the model with Harvey-Jaeger gaps, there are no changes in any of the conclusions. In fact, the case for asymmetry is strengthened. The new variable enters significantly and improves the fit of the equations. All the other coefficients become slightly better determined, and there are no important changes in any of the point estimates.26

V. Conclusions

In this paper, we present estimates of a simple asymmetric Phillips curve for the United States. We find that a restriction to a linear version of the model is strongly rejected. This confirms recent evidence presented by Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) using the pooled G-7 data and by Turner (1995) using the U.S. data.

We also show why other researchers may have been misled in reaching the opposite conclusion. Following arguments advanced in Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995), we demonstrate that in a stochastic economy the presence of an asymmetry in the Phillips curve has an important implication as to how output gaps should appear in the function to be estimated. In particular, we show that it is inconsistent to use mean-zero gaps in the estimation, as this vitiates the implementation of the asymmetric alternative hypothesis. We cite Monte Carlo evidence that the use of such gaps will bias standard statistical tests of the restriction to linearity, and we show that this is confirmed by the results with U.S. data.

We also provide a number of tests of the robustness of our conclusions. Our conclusions come initially from results based on output gaps obtained using a simple, two-sided moving average filter to measure potential output. However, we show that if the above implication of asymmetry is taken into account in the estimation and testing, then the precise method used to provide the measure of potential output and the mean-zero output gap does not matter as much. In particular, we show that if we use the Harvey Jaeger (1993) approach to derive gap measures or a variety of measures based on the Hodrick-Prescott filter, our conclusions are not affected.

We also show that our results stand up to a number of other tests for robustness. These include adding a free constant to the estimation and testing for the influence of changes in the relative price of crude oil.

The paper also discusses some issues in policy modeling. We are concerned that with the small samples of business cycle variation available to researchers, there will be significant limitations on one’s ability to measure important variables, such as potential output and expectations, and to discriminate among competing hypotheses. We would argue that policy analysis should not be conducted by the rules of classical econometrics and Occam’s razor. Most researchers who have opted for a linear null hypothesis because it could not be clearly rejected in their results could just as easily have argued that the same results were consistent at the same confidence levels with the presence of an important asymmetry. But our main point is that policy modeling should be concerned with the costs of policy errors, regardless of the specific strengths of one empirical case or another. We show here in a simple form, citing the more complete discussion in Laxton, Rose, and Tetlow (1993c), that policy errors arising from an incorrect assumption that the world is linear will be much more costly than the errors arising from making an error the other way around.

Another important point concerns the manner in which policy simulations are conducted. Some researchers, such as Robert Gordon (1994), appear to be willing to ignore completely the possibility that expectations have a forward-looking component. In our view, this is dangerous and can produce misleading policy advice. It is one thing to deal with the problem of representing expectations for historical estimation by using long distributed lags; it is quite another to assume that this procedure captures stable parameters that will be invariant to a policy shock. While we do not think that using distributed lags is an efficient estimation strategy, we might grudgingly accept it as part of an empirical strategy if survey measures were not available. However, we would reject completely the notion that simulations of the resulting models have anything useful to say about the implications of alternative policies. Indeed, such simulations are likely to be quite misleading.

The limited policy experiments we present in this paper are designed to illustrate the power of the asymmetry hypothesis to provide a logic for monetary policy.27 We show that if the world is linear, then delaying the response to a positive demand shock may be beneficial if the metric is simply cumulative output. In such a world, a fast response is essential only for negative shocks. Thus the linear world produces asymmetric policy advice, i.e., take risks with inflation but not with disinflation. If this view of the world is wrong, however, as our evidence suggests, the consequences of such a policy will be higher volatility in the real economy and a lower average level of output. In the presence of asymmetry, it is critical to respond as quickly as possible to signs of excess demand because failure to do so results in much greater volatility in output and a lower average level of output over time. In this case, moreover, the policy advice is roughly symmetrical with respect to negative shocks. While delay is not as costly when there is excess supply, it is still preferable to act sooner rather than later.

REFERENCES

  • Andrews, Donald W.K., and Werner Ploberger, “Optimal Tests When a Nuisance Parameter Is Present Only Under the Alternative,” Econometrica, Vol. 62 (November 1994), pp. 138414.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Armstrong, John, Richard Black, Douglas Laxton, and David Rose, “A Robust Method for Simulating Forward-Looking Models,” Bank of Canada Technical Report No. 73 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, February 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, “Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic Fluctuations,” Economic Journal, Vol. 104 (March 1994), pp. 24761.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Braun, Steven N., “Productivity and the NIIRU (And Other Phillips Curve Issues),” Working Paper No. 34 (Washington: Economic Activity Section, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Braun, Steven N., “Estimation of Current-Quarter Gross National Product by Pooling Preliminary Labor-Market Data,” in Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 8 (July 1990), pp. 293304.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryant, Ralph C., Peter Hooper, and Catherine L. Mann, Evaluating Policy Regimes: New Research in Empirical Macroeconomics (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buiter, Willem, and Marcus Miller, “Costs and Benefits of an Anti-Inflationary Policy: Questions and Issues,” in inflation and Unemployment: Theory. Experience, and Policy-Making, ed. by Victor Argy and John Neville (London: Allen and Unwin, 1985), pp. 1138.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12 (September 1983), pp. 38398.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clark, Peter, Douglas Laxton, and David Rose (1995a), “Capacity Constraints, Inflation, and the Transmission Mechanism: Forward-Looking Versus Myopic Policy Rules,” IMF Working Paper 95/75 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, July 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clark, Peter, Douglas Laxton, and David Rose (1995b), “Asymmetry in the U.S. Output-Inflation Nexus: Issues and Evidence” IMF Working Paper 95/76 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, July 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cogley, Timothy, and James M. Nason, “Effects of the Hodrick-Preseott Filter on Trend and Difference Stationary Time Series: Implications for Business Cycle Research,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 19 (January/ February 1995), pp. 25378.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cozier, Barry V., “On the Aggregate Implications of Optimal Price Adjustment,” Bank of Canada Working Paper 89-4 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, November 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichenbaum, Martin, “Real Business Cycle Theory: Wisdom or Whimsy?” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 15 (October 1991), pp. 60726.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eisner, Robert, “A New View of the NAIRU,” Northwestern University Working Paper (Evanston, Illinois: Northwestern University, November 29, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Evans, Martin, and Paul Wachtel, “Inflation Regimes and the Sources of Inflation Uncertainty,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 25 (August 1993), pp. 475511.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fuhrer, Jeffrey C., and George R. Moore, “Monetary Policy Trade-offs and the Correlation Between Nominal Interest Rates and Real Output,” American Economic Review, Vol. 85 (March 1995), pp. 21939.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gordon, Robert, “Inflation and Unemployment: Where Is the NAIRU?” Paper presented to Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Meeting of Academic Consultants, December 1, 1994 (Washington: Federal Reserve System, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenspan, Allan, “Statement to the U.S. Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs,” February 22. 1995, printed in Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 81 (April 1995), pp. 34248.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harvey, Andrew C., and Albert Jaeger, “Detrending, Stylized Facts and the Business Cycle,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 8 (July/September 1993), pp. 23147.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hodrick. Robert J., and Edward C. Preseott, “Post-War U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation,” Carnegie-Mellon Discussion Paper No. 451 (Pittsburgh: Carnegie-Mellon University, May 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kultner, Kenneth N., “Using Noisy Indicators to Measure Potential Output,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper No. 1991-14 (Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, June 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laxton, Douglas, Guy Meredith, and David Rose, “Asymmetric Effects of Economic Activity on Inflation: Evidence and Policy Implications,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (Washington: IMF, June 1995), pp, 34474.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laxton, Douglas, Nicholas Ricketts, and David Rose, “Uncertainty, Learning and Policy Credibility,” in Economic Behaviour and Policy Choice Under Price Stability (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, June 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laxton, Douglas, David Rose, and Robert Tetlow (1993a), “Problems in Identifying Non-linear Phillips Curves: Some Further Consequences of Mismeasuring Potential Output,” Bank of Canada Working Paper 93-6 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, June 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laxton, Douglas, David Rose, and Robert Tetlow (1993b), “Is the Canadian Phillips Curve Non-linear?” Bank of Canada Working Paper 93-7 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, July 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laxton, Douglas, David Rose, and Robert Tetlow (1993c), “Monetary Policy, Uncertainty and the Presumption of Linearity,” Bank of Canada Technical Report No. 63 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, August 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laxton, Douglas, Kevin Shoon, and Robert Tetlow, “Should the Change in the Gap Appear in the Phillips Curve? Some Consequences of Mismeasuring Potential Output,” Bank of Canada Working Paper 92-1 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, January 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mauskopf, Eileen, “The Transmission Channels of Monetary Policy: How Have They Changed?” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 76 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December 1990), pp. 9851008.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nelson, Charles R., and Heejoon Kang, “Spurious Periodicity in Inappropriately Detrended Time Series,” Econometrica, Vol. 49 (May 1981), pp. 74151.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Perron, Pierre, “The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock, and the Unit Root Hypothesis,” Econometrica, Vol. 57 (November 1989), pp. 13611401.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ricketts, Nicholas, and David Rose, “Inflation, Learning and Monetary Policy Regimes in the G-7 Economies,” Bank of Canada Working Paper 95-6 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada, June 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roberts, John M. (1994a), “Evidence on the Monetary Transmission Mechanism: An Instrumental Variables Approach,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Working Paper (Washington: Federal Reserve System, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roberts, John M. (1994b), “New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27 (November 1995), pp. 97585.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roberts, John M. (1994c), “Is Inflation Sticky?.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Working Paper No. 152 (Washington: Economic Activity Section, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rotemberg, Julio J., “The New Keynesian Micro foundations.” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1987, ed. by Stanley Fischer (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1987), pp. 69116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, John, “Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88 (February 1980). pp. 123.

  • Tsiddon, Daniel, “On the Stubbornness of Sticky Prices,” International Economic Review, Vol. 32 (February 1991), pp. 6975.

  • Tsiddon, Daniel, “The (Mis)Behavior of the Aggregate Price Level,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 60 (October 1993), pp. 889902.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Turner, David, “Speed Limit and Asymmetric Inflation Effects from the Output Gap in the Major Seven Economies,” OECD Economic Studies, Vol. 24 (1995/I), pp. 5788.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

Peter Clark is currently on leave from the IMF at the London School of Economics. Douglas Laxton is an Economist in the IMF’s Research Department, and David Rose is a Research Adviser at the Bank of Canada. Peter Clark received a doctorate from MIT and David Rose received his Ph.D. from the University of Manchester. Douglas Laxton did his graduate studies at the University of Western Ontario. This paper has benefited from discussions with several individuals who attended seminars at the U.S. Federal Reserve Board of Governors, the Bank of Canada, and the International Monetary Fund.

1

We measure output gaps such that positive values are associated with excess demand and upward pressure on inflation. Some researchers follow Arthur Okun’s convention and define gaps the other way around.

2

There is, however, a growing literature that provides examples of how asymmetric aggregate properties can arise from agent behavior. See. for example. Ball and Mankiw (1994) and Tsiddon (1991 and 1993).

3

Eisner’s model uses unemployment gaps. He finds that a reduction in unemployment is less inflationary if the economy is booming and unemployment is initially below the natural rate than if unemployment is initially above the natural rate. The statement in the text assumes that there is a direct relationship between excess demand conditions in the goods market and excess demand conditions in the labor market.

4

Laxton, Rose, and Tetlow (1993a) present Monte Carlo evidence that reliance on traditional detrending techniques to measure gaps can explain why some researchers may have falsely rejected asymmetries.

5

Of course, asymmetry in the output-inflation nexus will have implications for other endogenous macro variables, such as interest rates. Indeed, one of the concerns voiced by U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Greenspan is that humping into capacity limits increases the uncertainty about future inflation and creates more volatility in financial markets.

6

The other countries for which Turner finds significant asymmetry are Canada and Japan. Laxton, Rose, and Tetlow (1993b) also provide evidence for asymmetry in the Canadian Phillips curve.

7

We focus on modeling price dynamics in this paper and our empirical work uses the output gap. This is not to deny that there are interesting issues in linking labor and output markets in macro models and discussions of inflation. However, we have chosen to keep our macro model as simple as possible and do not include a separate treatment of the labor market.

8

See Buiter and Miller (1985) or Fuhrer and Moore (1995) for further discussion of these issues.

9

Taylor (1980) was an important contribution to this literature.

10

In the simulations presented in Section III, we adopt the pure intrinsic dynamics interpretation of equation (2). That is, we simulate under the assumption of model-consistent expectations and treat the backward-looking component of the equation as coming entirely from intrinsic rigidities and not from expectations.

11

A formal proof of this can be found in Section (V.2 of Clark, Laxton, and Rose (1995b).

12

Output is measured in logarithms so that in a growing economy gaps constructed with a symmetric two-sided filter will have a zero mean in large samples.

13

See Eichenbaum (1991) for an excellent discussion of why econometric techniques cannot provide reliable estimates of the relative variance of demand and supply shocks. We pursue this issue in Section IV.

14

We have noted already and will argue more formally later in the paper that the extent of this shift will depend on the nature of the monetary reaction function and the consequent cyclical properties of the economy. There may be good reason to doubt that the same monetary reaction function has been operating throughout our estimation sample. However, we leave this complication to future research and interpret the estimated shift parameter as reflecting average historical behavior.

15

See Section IV for a discussion of the statistical properties of asymmetric models when researchers fail to account for their logical implications.

16

This choice of lag structure does not affect our conclusions. We obtain basically the same results if we estimate an unrestricted model with four lags on inflation and infation expectations or impose a triangular distribution on lagged inflation expectations.

17

The notional restriction on ß is necessary so that α is identified under the null hypothesis. This avoids the necessity to compute a more complicated test of the restriction when there is a nuisance parameter. See, for example, Andrews and Ploberger(1994).

18

The simulations reported here are deterministic. Although these types of experiments are useful for developing the basic intuition behind the model, they do not do justice to the full policy implications. See Clark, Laxton, and Rose (1995a) for a more extensive analysis of the policy implications of asymmetry in inflation dynamics in a stochastic environment.

19

These simulations were carried out using the “stacked time” algorithm in TROLL. See Armstrong, Black, Laxton, and Rose (1995) for a description of this algorithm and its properties.

20

Kuttner (1991) implements a Kalman filter procedure to provide model-consistent estimates of the gap when the Phillips curve is linear. An obvious extension of our work would be to develop a similar procedure that could be used for nonlinear models.

22

It is not uncommon for researchers to use such techniques and then discard level gap variables because their estimated coefficients are not significantly different from zero, despite the implications this has for monetary policy. The lack of any level gap effects in the Phillips curve is sometimes interpreted as evidence of hysteresis.

23

HP filter estimates (yt¯) are derived by minimizing the sum of squares of the gap Σ1t(yy-y¯t)**2 and a “smoother” λΣ1t-2[(y¯t+2-y¯t+1)-(y¯t+1-y¯t)]2.

Many users set the smoothness parameter, X, at 1,600 despite the fact that, in principle, the “optimal” value will depend on the properties of the particular series. HP (λ = 1,600) filtered values of U.S. GDP resemble closely those from a two-sided moving average filter with geometrically declining weights. Our simple filter is similar but has equal weights.

24

For an example of the segmented-trend approach, see Braun (1990), with details in Table A.2, p. 302.

25

We thank Paula De Masi and Michael Funke for supplying us with these estimates. The estimates in both cases are based on the level U.S. real GDP.

26

This conclusion also holds if we add further lags of the relative price of oil.

27

The policy implications of asymmetry are discussed in greater detail in Clark, Laxton, and Rose (1995a).

  • Collapse
  • Expand
IMF Staff papers, Volume 43 No. 1
Author:
International Monetary Fund. Research Dept.
  • Figure 1.

    Interpreting U.S. Inflation with an Asymmetric Model

  • Figure 2.

    Interpreting U.S. Inflation with an Linear Model

  • Figure 3.

    Linear Model Responses to a Temporary I Percent Positive Demand Shock

  • Figure 4.

    Linear Model Responses to a Temporary 1 Percent Positive Demand Shock: Delayed Monetary Policy Response

  • Figure 5.

    Asymmetric Model Responses to a 1 Percent Positive Demand Shock

  • Figure 6.

    Asymmetrie Model Responses to a 1 Percent Positive Demand Shock: Delayed Monetary Policy Response

  • Figure 7.

    Harvey and Jaeger’s Measure of Potential Output