Nonlinear Effects of Inflation on Economic Growth
Author:
Mr. Michael Sarel
Search for other papers by Mr. Michael Sarel in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This paper examines the possibility of nonlinear effects of inflation on economic growth. It finds evidence of a significant structural break in the function that relates economic growth to inflation. The break is estimated to occur when the inflation rate is 8 percent. Below that rate, inflation does not have any effect on growth, or it may even have a slightly positive effect. When the inflation rate is above 8 percent, however, the estimated effect of inflation on growth rates is significant, robust, and extremely powerful. The paper also demonstrates that when the existence of the structural break is ignored, the estimated effect of inflation on growth is biased by a factor of three,

Abstract

This paper examines the possibility of nonlinear effects of inflation on economic growth. It finds evidence of a significant structural break in the function that relates economic growth to inflation. The break is estimated to occur when the inflation rate is 8 percent. Below that rate, inflation does not have any effect on growth, or it may even have a slightly positive effect. When the inflation rate is above 8 percent, however, the estimated effect of inflation on growth rates is significant, robust, and extremely powerful. The paper also demonstrates that when the existence of the structural break is ignored, the estimated effect of inflation on growth is biased by a factor of three,

It is now widely accepted that inflation has a negative effect on economic growth. This negative effect, however, was not detected in data from the 1950s and the 1960s. Based on those data, the view that prevailed in the economic profession was that the effect of inflation on growth was not particularly important. Until the 1970s, many studies found this effect to be nonsignificant, and in fact some found it to be positive. In general, the empirical evidence was, at best, mixed,1 The change in view came only after many countries experienced severe episodes of high and persistent inflation in the 1970s and the 1980s. These high-inflation episodes were usually associated with a general decline in the macroeconomic performance and with balance of payments crisis. As more data became available on these episodes, studies repeatedly confirmed that inflation had a negative effect on economic growth.2 This effect was shown to be statistically significant, albeit of a small magnitude, and it was one of the very few variables influenced by macroeconomic policy found to affect growth rates. As a result of these new conclusions, the dominant view regarding the effects of inflation changed radically. Currently, many economists are convinced that inflation is undesirable and that it should be avoided completely. They propose policy measures and institutional changes to guarantee low inflation. One favorite suggestion is to establish independent central banks with a clear mandate to keep inflation levels within a specific range, usually defined as consistent with price stability. Such proposals have been adopted in New Zealand and in Canada, and are being discussed in many other countries.

The abrupt change in the view regarding the effects of inflation on growth raises three important questions: (1) Why did it take so long and so many studies to uncover such an obvious link between two of the most important and most closely watched macroeconomic variables? (2) As the estimated effect of inflation on growth is relatively small, should the results of these studies affect policy priorities and institutional arrangements? (3) If a specific range for inflation is to be adopted as a policy target and included in legislative measures, what should this range be?

Motivated by these questions, this paper explores the possibility of nonlinear effects of inflation on economic growth, and finds evidence of a structural break in the function that relates growth rates to inflation. When inflation is low, it has no significant negative effect on economic growth; the effect may even be slightly positive. But when inflation is high, it has a powerful negative effect on growth. The structural break is estimated to occur where the average annual rate of inflation is 8 percent.

The existence of such a structural break can explain why the negative effect of inflation on economic growth was not detected for such a long time: before the 1970s, there had been few episodes of high (i.e., beyond the structural break) inflation. It also suggests a specific target for policy: keep inflation below the structural break. Most important, the existence of a structural break implies that previous studies seriously underestimated the negative effects of higher rates of inflation on economic growth. This paper demonstrates that if the existence of the structural break is ignored, the estimated effect of higher rates of inflation on economic growth decreases by a factor of three. Taking the structural break into account, the paper finds evidence that the negative effects of high inflation on growth are much more powerful than previous studies had estimated.

The paper is organized as follows: Section I presents the data that are used in the empirical tests. A preliminary test is performed in Section II to uncover the general shape of the function that relates growth rates to inflation. This test involves estimating the effects of twelve inflation groups on growth. The results of this preliminary test raise the possibility that the function contains a structural break. In Section III we perform the main test, which estimates the point of the structural break, its level of significance, and the two inflation effects, below and above the structural break. Additional tests are performed in Section IV as variations to the main test. Section V presents concluding remarks and policy implications.

I. The Data

This paper uses data on population, GDP, consumer price indices, terms of trade, real exchange rates, government expenditures, and investment rates. Two databases are used as inputs for this study, the “Penn World Table 5.5” database and the “World Tables” database.3

The CPI and the terms of trade data are used to reduce the problem of negative correlation between inflation and growth rates, which is not directly caused by inflation effects on growth. It is better to use CPI data than implicit GDP deflators in this type of study because changes in GDP deflators are, by construction, negatively correlated with the growth rates.4

The terms of trade data are used to eliminate the negative correlation between growth and inflation that is caused by external supply shocks.5

Combining the two databases, a joint panel database is produced. This database contains continuous annual information for 87 countries, during the period 1970–90.6 The 20-year sample period is divided into four equal periods of 5 years each, obtaining a total of 248 observations.7 For each 5-year period, between the year t and the year t + 5, the growth rates of output per person, population growth rates, inflation rates, and rates of change in the terms of trade are defined as the average logarithmic annual changes during the period:8

g r o w t h ( t , t + 5 ) = log ( y t + 5 / y t ) 5 ,
N ( t , t + 5 ) = log ( p o p t + 5 / p o p t ) 5 ,
( t , t + 5 ) = log ( P t + 5 / P t ) 5 ,

and

δ T O T ( t , t + 5 ) = log ( T O T t + 5 / T O T t ) 5 ,

An interesting (but not so important) question is how to treat the observations with a negative inflation rate. One possibility is to argue that the effect of inflation around zero is monotonic, and therefore to leave these observations as they are. Another option is to argue that what really matters for growth is price stability, and therefore the relevant variable is the absolute value of inflation (or some monotonic transformation of that value). A third possibility is to ignore these observations altogether. Finally, the fourth possibility is to treat these observations just as being close to zero, as a compromise between the first two approaches. This study chooses to take this last approach and substitutes an inflation rate of 0.1 percent for the negative observations.9

A less interesting (but more important) question is whether it is better to use a transformation of the inflation rate than simply to use the rate itself. Figures 1 and 2 present, respectively, the histograms of the distribution of the inflation rate and of its logarithmic transformation. As these figures make clear, the rate of inflation has a very asymmetric distribution (the lowest tenth of its range contains 88 percent of the observations). Using this variable would place an enormous weight on the very few observations with the highest inflation rate. The logarithm of inflation, on the other hand, has a much more balanced distribution. In the remainder of this paper, therefore, the logarithmic transformation of the inflation rate will be used.

II. A Preliminary Test

This section makes a first attempt to uncover nonlinear features in the function that relates economic growth to inflation. In order to find the general shape of this function, the 348 inflation observations are divided into 12 equal groups of 29 observations each. The groups contain increasingly higher inflation observations.10 Each inflation group except Group 6 is assigned a dummy variable.

Then, an OLS regression is estimated for the growth rate on the inflation dummies, on country dummies (except the first country, Algeria), on period dummies (except the first period, 1970–75). and on the other explanatory variables that are usually used in growth regressions, such as the log of initial income per person (LY), the population growth rate (N), government expenditures as a percent of GDP (GOV). and the rate of change in the terms of trade (ΔTOT).11

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

The Distribution of Inflation

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A007

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

The Distribution of the Log of Inflation

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A007

The results of the regression (except the estimated coefficients for the country and the period dummies) are presented in Table 1, Regression 1. An F-test rejects at the 1 percent confidence level the hypothesis that the 86 country dummies are equal to zero. This rejection implies that country-specific effects are important in explaining the growth rates. The same is true about an F-test for the three period dummies. Nevertheless, Regression 2 in Table 1 presents the results of a regression that includes neither country dummies nor period dummies. The estimated coefficients of the different inflation groups represent the effect on growth of each group relative to Group 6, which is used as a reference.12

Figure 3 describes the estimated coefficient and the corresponding standard error for each inflation group, as reported by Regression 1. An important feature of the data emerges in the results presented in Table 1 and in Figure 3: the effects of inflation on economic growth may contain a structural break. When inflation is low, there are no significant differences in the coefficients of different inflation groups. In other words, it does not make a significant difference to the growth rates if inflation is low, very low, or zero. When inflation is high, on the other hand, moving to a higher inflation group has a dramatic impact on the growth rates. For example, the difference in the effect on growth rates between the highest inflation group and Group 6 is estimated to be close to 4 percentage points—more than twice the sample’s average growth rate.

III. The Main Test

The previous section presented evidence that the function that relates economic growth to inflation may contain a structural break. This finding raises at least three questions:

Table 1.

The Estimated Coefficients of the Inflation Groups

article image
Notes: (1) The dependent variable is the average growth rate of output per person. (2) The number of observations is 348. (3) The method of estimation is OLS. (4) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. (5) Regression 1 does not report 86 country dummies and 3 period dummies.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Effects of Different Inflation Groups on Growth

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A007

(1) At what level of inflation does the structural break occur?

(2) Is the break significant?13

(3) What is the estimated value of the inflation effect on growth on either side of the structural break?

This section answers these three central questions, using a simple estimation technique. First, it defines

Π* = the rate of inflation at which the structural break occurs.

DD = 1 if Π > Π*, 0 otherwise,

and

EXTRA = DD[log(Π)–log(Π*)].

Then, an OLS regression is estimated for the growth rate on the two variables log Π and EXTRA, in addition to the usual explanatory variables. When inflation is low (Π < Π*), EXTRA =0 (by construction) and the effect of inflation on growth is estimated by the coefficient of log Π. However, when inflation is high (Π > Π*), the relevant estimator is the sum of two coefficients: the coefficient of log Π and the coefficient of EXTRA, The coefficient of EXTRAestimates the difference in the inflation effect on growth between the two sides of the structural break, and its t-statistic value tests whether or not the structural break is significant.14

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Goodness-of-Fit for Different Structural Breaks

Citation: IMF Staff Papers 1996, 001; 10.5089/9781451957099.024.A007

We are now in a position to answer the second and the third questions raised at the beginning of this section, but we still have to answer the first—at what level of inflation does the structural break occur? Assuming that the error variance is equal for the entire inflation range, we can estimate the regression for different values of Π* and choose as the breakpoint the value of Π* that minimizes the sum-of-squared residuals from the regression. This is equivalent to picking the Π* that maximizes R2,Figure 4 presents the results of iterating the regression for different values of Π*. It shows that the value of R2is maximized when Π* = 8.0 percent.

Regression 1 in Table 2 assumes a value of 8 percent for Π*. The last row of the table calculates the implied effect of inflation when Π > Π*. Using the variance-covariance matrix of the regression’s coefficients, we also calculate the standard error of this effect and report its t-statistic. The results of Regression 1 confirm that there is indeed a significant structural break at an inflation level of 8 percent. The t-statistic for EXTRA makes possible to reject at the 1 percent confidence level the hypothesis of equal effects of inflation (below and above 8 percent). When the inflation rate is less than 8 percent, its effect is positive, but very weak and statistically insignificant. On the other hand, the effect of inflation when it is greater than 8 percent is not only significant at the 1 percent confidence level, but also extremely powerful. The coefficient of –0.0248 for log Π can be interpreted to mean that the annual growth rate decreases by 1.7 percentage points (the equivalent of the average growth rate in the sample) when the inflation rate doubles. The results of the regression also confirm our prior expectations about the other included variables.

Table 2.

Regressions for the Main Test

article image
Notes: (1) The dependent variable is the average growth rate of output per person. (2) The number of observations is 348. (3) The method of estimation is OLS. (4) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. (5) Regressions 1 and 2 do not report 86 country dummies and 3 period dummies.

Regression 2 reports, for comparison, the results in the case in which the EXTRAvariable is not included. It demonstrates how ignoring the existence of the structural break makes a huge impact on the estimated effect of inflation on economic growth. By not including the variable EXTRAas a regressor. Regression 2 estimates the effect of inflation on economic growth, conditional on this effect being the same throughout the inflation spectrum. In the case of high inflation (Π > Π*), the estimated effect of inflation in Regression 2 is only one third of the effect estimated by Regression 1. Another look at Figure 3 provides a simple intuition for this important result: when Π> Π*, Regression 1 estimates the slope of the function that relates economic growth to inflation, but only for the range of inflation where this slope is steep. Regression 2, on the other hand, estimates an average slope over the whole inflation spectrum, including the range where the slope of the function is close to zero or even slightly positive. Therefore, a large bias occurs in the estimated effect of inflation in Regression 2, as well as in all the other studies that ignore the existence of the structural break.

The country dummies group and the period dummies group are both significant at the 1 percent confidence level. However, we also look at the case in which these dummies are not included. In this case, the Π* that maximizes R2is 10.1 percent. Regression 3 does not include dummies and assumes that Π* = 10.1 percent. It reports results that are very similar to the results of Regression 1. The main difference is that the negative effect of inflation above Π* is about 35 percent weaker than in Regression 1 (but still twice the estimate of Regression 2).

IV. Additional Tests

This section performs additional tests as variations to the main test. One reason for these additional tests is to increase our understanding of the effects of inflation on economic growth. A second reason is to use changes in the specifications of the regression to check the robustness of the earlier results regarding the nonlinear effects of inflation on economic growth.

Table 3 presents results of regressions that use only observations from the last 3 periods (1975–90). These regressions assume that the structural break occurs when the rate of inflation is 8 percent. Regression 1, which presents the basic results, is the equivalent of Regression 1 in Table 2. The results here confirm our previous conclusions. The main difference is that the estimated effect of inflation when Π is greater than 8 percent is weaker than before (although the structural break remains significant). Regressions 2 and 3 in Table 3 include, respectively, log Π lagged for one period, and first-differences in log Π. The estimated coefficients of these variables are not significant. Changes in the inflation rate, at least between the five-year periods used in this study, do not appear to have any effect on growth. Also, including these additional variables has no significant effect on the estimated coefficients of the other variables in the regression.

Table 4 again uses all four periods, and includes additional explanatory variables. Regression 1 presents the basic results (reported previously in Table 2, Regression 1). Regression 2 includes the investment rate (as percent of GDP, measured in PPP 1985 dollars). Including the investment rate may help identify how inflation affects growth. If inflation reduces growth only indirectly, by reducing capital accumulation, we would expect to find a much weaker direct inflation effect once the investment rate is included as an explanatory variable. But the results of Regression 2 demonstrate that, even controlling for the investment rate, the inflation coefficient remains strong and significant, and it retains about 88 percent of its previous value. One possible interpretation of this result is that inflation affects growth mainly through its harmful effect on efficiency and productivity. Regression 3 includes the real exchange rate, defined as the average deviation from PPP in the dollar price of GDP, compared to the United States (based on the data in PWT 5.5). The real exchange rate has no significant effect on growth and its inclusion does not change in any way the estimated effect of inflation on growth.

Table 3.

Regressions with Lagged Inflation

article image
Notes: (1) The dependent variable is the average growth rate of output per person. (2) The number of observations is 261. (3) The method of estimation is OLS. (4) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. (5) 86 country dummies and 2 period dummies are not reported.
Table 4.

Regressions with Additional Variables

article image
Notes: (1) The dependent variable is the average growth rate of output per person. (2) The number of observations is 348. (3) The method of estimation is OLS. (4) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. (5) The regressions do not report 86 country dummies and 3 period dummies.

Table 5 repeats the procedure from Table 2, using the same raw data, but dividing the observations differently. Now, instead of four periods of five years each, the data are divided into five periods of four years each, for a total of 435 observations.

The results reported in the three regressions of Table 5 should be compared with the results reported in Table 2, for the case of five-year periods. The results of Table 5 confirm all the previous conclusions. In particular, they confirm the existence of a significant structural break. Also, the estimated point of the break in Regression 1 (7.9 percent) is very close to the previous estimate (8.0 percent). The results of Table 5 also reinforce the conclusion that ignoring the existence of the structural break has a huge effect on the estimated effect of inflation; the estimated effect based on Regression 2 is one fifth of that predicted by Regression 1! There is one notable exception, however: now the positive effect of inflation at low levels of inflation is statistically significant.

Table 5.

Regressions with Four-Year Periods

article image
Notes: (1) The dependent variable is the average growth rate of output per person. (2) The number of observations is 435. (3) The method of estimation is OLS. (4) t-statistics are reported in parentheses. (5) Regression 1 does not report 86 country dummies and 4 period dummies.

V. Conclusions and Policy Implications

This paper has explored the possibility of nonlinear effects of inflation on economic growth. It found that the function that relates growth rates to inflation contains a structural break. When inflation is low, it has no significant negative effect on economic growth, and the effect may even be slightly positive. But when inflation is high, it has a negative effect on growth. This negative effect is robust, statistically significant, and very powerful. The point of the structural break was estimated to occur when the average annual rate of inflation is 8 percent.

If a structural break exists, failing to take it into account introduces a significant bias in the estimated effect of inflation. This paper has demonstrated that when the structural break is taken into account, the estimated effect of inflation on economic growth increases by a factor of three. The existence of such a structural break also suggests a specific numerical target for policy: always keep inflation below the structural break.

One possible interpretation of the empirical results of this paper is that when the inflation rate doubles (for example, a relatively moderate increase in inflation from 20 percent to 40 percent), the growth rate decreases by 1.7 percentage points. This difference of 1.7 percentage points is much higher than previous studies have estimated, and is exactly equal to the average worldwide growth rate of per capita income in the last two decades. In other words, it is the difference between sustained growth and stagnation. This interpretation implies that a macroeconomic policy to avoid high inflation is one of the best recommendations economists can make.

APPENDIX

Table A1.

Complete List of Countries

article image

REFERENCES

  • Barro, Robert J., “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (May 1991), pp. 40743.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhatia, Rattan J., “inflation. Deflation, and Economic Development,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 8 (November 1960), pp. 10114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, and William Easterly, “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1517 (Washington: World Bank, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Gregorio, José, “The Effects of Inflation on Economic Growth—Lessons from Latin America,” European Economic Review, Vol. 36 (April 1992), pp. 41725.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Gregorio, José, “Inflation, Taxation and Long-Run Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 31 (June 1993), pp. 27198.

  • Dorrance, Graeme S., “The Effect of Inflation on Economic Development,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 10 (March 1963), pp. 147.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Gregorio, José, “Inflation and Growth,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 13 (March 1966), pp. 82102.

  • Fischer, Stanley, “The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32 (December 1993), pp. 485512.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galbis, Vicente, “Money, Investment and Growth in Latin America, 1961–73,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 27 (April 1979), pp. 42343.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Harry G., “Is Inflation a Retarding Factor in Economic Growth?” in Fiscal and Monetary Problems in Developing States, Proceedings of the Third Rehoroth Conference, ed. by David Krivine (New York: Praeger, 1967). pp. 12130.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, and Sara J. Zervos, “What We Have Learned About Policy and Growth from Cross-Country Regressions,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 83 (May 1993), pp. 42630.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pazos, Felipe, Chronic Inflation in Latin America (New York: Praeger, 1972).

  • Sbordone, Argia, and Kenneth Kuttner, “Does Inflation Reduce Productivity?” Economic Perspectives, Vol. 18 (November–December 1994), pp. 214.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smyth, David J., “Inflation and Growth,” Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 16 (Spring 1994), pp. 26170.

  • Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston, “The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (May 1991). pp. 32768.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wai, U Tun, “The Relation Between Inflation and Economic Development: A Statistical Inductive Study,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 7 (October 1959). p. 30217.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, World Tables, on-line database (February 1995).

*

Michael Sarel is an Economist in the Southeast Asia and Pacific Department. He graduated from the Hebrew University of Jerusalem and received a Ph.D. from Harvard University. This paper was written while the author was in the IMF’s Research Department. He would like to thank Carmen Reinhart and Peter Wiekham for helpful discussions and comments.

1

This is documented, for example, by Bruno and Easterly (1995). They write (p. 4): “. . . Johnson in 1967 suggested that there was no conclusive empirical evidence one way or the other—as a series of studies in the IMF Staff Papersaround that time bear witness (Wai 1959, Dorrance 1963, 1966 and Bhatia (1960). Even for Latin America, where higher double-digit rates of inflation were experienced during that period, the evidence well into the 1970s was ambiguous (Pazos, 1972; Galbis, 1979).”

2

There are many studies that found support for this view. Some of the latest are Smyth (1994), Sbordone and Kuttner (1994), De Gregorio (1993), Fischer (1993), and De Gregorio (1992)

3

The “PWT 5.5” is an NBER update to “PWT 5.0,” a database described by Summers and Heston (1991). The “World Tables” database is an on-line database of the World Bank (World Bank (1995)). Most of the variables used in this paper are from the first database: annual data on population, output per person, government expenditures as percent of GDP, and investment as percent of GDP, all measured in PPP 1985 dollars. Annual data on consumer prices and on terms of trade indices are extracted from the second database.

4

Suppose, for example, that there are two periods and a measurement error overestimates the output volume in the second period. In this case, the growth rate between the two periods will be overestimated, while the change in the implicit GDP deflator between the two periods will be underestimated. If the output volume is underestimated in the second period, the growth rate between the two periods will be underestimated, while the change in the implicit GDP deflator between the two periods will be overestimated. In both cases, the measurement error will induce a negative correlation between real growth rates and GDP deflators. Because CPI indices are calculated independently of output volume, their use should prevent this problem.

5

Negative external supply shocks, such as an increase in oil prices in the case of industrialized countries, tend to increase inflation and to reduce growth, inducing a negative correlation between the two variables. Positive shocks increase growth and reduce inflation, again inducing a negative correlation between the two variables. Fischer (1993) recognizes this problem. He writes; “The inclusion of changes in the terms of trade as a regressor goes a long way towards dealing with this problem.” This study follows his advice and always controls for changes in the terms of trade.

6

The complete list of countries is presented in the Appendix. For some of the countries, the PWT 5.5 database does not contain observations for the year 1990; the last year of observations for these countries was 1989. In these eases, data on GDP, GDP deflators and population for the years 1989 and 1990 are extracted from the World Tables database. Then, these data are used to calculate the growth rates of real income per person and of population between 1989 and 1990. These rates are used to extend the PWT 5.5 database to 1990. This procedure is applied for the following 12 countries: Barbados, Ghana, Haiti, Iran, Jamaica, Korea. Malta, Myanmar, Niger, Seychelles, Sri Lanka, and Suriname.

7

Dividing the sample period into smaller periods has two advantages. First, it increases the number of observations. Second, it introduces a time dimension, making it possible to estimate country-specific effects. Making the subperiods too short, however, may cause problems related to business cycles and their effects on inflation. The division to five-year periods is chosen as a compromise and it also follows a standard practice in the empirical literature on economic growth.

8

When inflation is low, a logarithmic (continuous) rate is very similar to a discrete rate. But the two differ when inflation is high. A logarithmic rate of 50 percent, for example, corresponds to a cumulative discrete rate of 65 percent from one year to the next. All the rates discussed in this paper are annual averages of logarithmic rates.

9

The reason this problem is not very important is that the sample used in this study contains only two observations of negative inflation. Both observations occur in the period 1985-90: Burkina Faso (—0.5 percent) and Niger (—3.1 percent). The chosen corrective value of 0.1 percent corresponds to the smallest positive inflation observation in the sample.

10

Group 1. for example, contains inflation rates of less than 3.8 percent, while Group 12 contains inflation rates in excess of 39.3 percent.

11

The regressions in this section, as well as the regressions in the rest of this paper, basically confirm the stylized facts about the determinants of economic growth, as documented by many other studies, such as Barro (1991). The growth rate of income per person depends negatively on initial income, on the population growth rate, and on government expenditures and depends positively on changes in the terms of trade. Because this study concentrates on the effects of inflation on growth, the results concerning the other variables will not be further discussed.

12

A word of caution: here, as well as in the other sections of this paper, the results of the regressions are interpreted as measuring the marginal effects of inflation on economic growth. This interpretation has a long tradition, and has strong and direct policy implications, but is certainly not the only possible one. Levine and Zervos (1993), among others, raise important questions about this kind of interpretation.

13

In other words, is the effect of inflation on growth significantly different above the structural break from what it is below the structural break?

14

A similar spline function was estimated by Fischer (1993). Fischer divides his observations into three arbitrary groups (Table 8 in his paper). His variables are defined differently than the ones used in this study, and the technique he uses is also different. Using his specific division, he did not find significant effects of inflation on growth for any of the inflation groups, although he found evidence of negative effects in the whole sample.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
IMF Staff papers, Volume 43 No. 1
Author:
International Monetary Fund. Research Dept.