Selective Credit Controls in Greece: A Test of Their Effectiveness

Selective credit policies are introduced in many countries to influence the composition of aggregate expenditure and real resource allocation.1 One general argument against the use of such policies is that they lack effectiveness.2 According to this argument, redirection of financial flows will not necessarily have the desired effects on the real sector of the economy because of the fungibility of financial assets and liabilities. The extent to which such fungibility is empirically relevant may vary among countries depending on institutional arrangements.

Abstract

Selective credit policies are introduced in many countries to influence the composition of aggregate expenditure and real resource allocation.1 One general argument against the use of such policies is that they lack effectiveness.2 According to this argument, redirection of financial flows will not necessarily have the desired effects on the real sector of the economy because of the fungibility of financial assets and liabilities. The extent to which such fungibility is empirically relevant may vary among countries depending on institutional arrangements.

Selective credit policies are introduced in many countries to influence the composition of aggregate expenditure and real resource allocation.1 One general argument against the use of such policies is that they lack effectiveness.2 According to this argument, redirection of financial flows will not necessarily have the desired effects on the real sector of the economy because of the fungibility of financial assets and liabilities. The extent to which such fungibility is empirically relevant may vary among countries depending on institutional arrangements.

The consensus emerging from numerous empirical studies of the U.S. economy appears to be that government efforts to allocate credit can at best be effective only in the very short run, as a countercyclical policy for selected economic sectors such as residential construction (see Kearl, Rosen, and Swan (1975) and Hamburger and Zwick (1977)). In the longer run, portfolio substitutions, financial innovations, or even outright evasion are likely to undermine the effectiveness of these policies.3 Of course, this evidence from the U.S. economy is not necessarily relevant for other countries in which the financial system may be much more centralized and the scope for evasion of credit controls consequently limited.

The purpose of this paper is to assess the effects of a particular type of credit control that has been used in Greece, a country with a less developed, highly centralized financial system. The credit control in question consists in increasing the supply and lowering the cost of long-term loans relative to short-term loans, thus to stimulate fixed capital formation while discouraging speculative activities. Such policies have also been employed in most developing countries as well as in some Western European countries (see Hodgman (1976)).

The paper develops a model of the firm’s financing decision that helps derive the conditions under which this kind of policy will be successful. The model implies that lengthening the average maturity of a firm’s debt will succeed in stimulating investment spending when the policy is viewed as temporary but will be completely ineffective when the policy is thought to be permanent. In the latter case, firms will tend to adjust their patterns of financing in a way that neutralizes the selective credit policy.

The estimation of an empirical version of the model provides support for these findings. From balance-sheet data of Greek industrial firms, the paper derives estimates of investment functions during the mid-1970s, a period in which the Greek authorities intensified their efforts to restrict selectively the supply of short-term credit. The estimates suggest that shifts in the firms’ patterns of financing tended to offset the impact of the authorities’ credit policy.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section I gives a brief description of the institutional setting in the Greek financial sector and of the conduct of selective credit policies. Section II develops a microeconomic model of the firm’s investment and financing decisions, which allows a systematic evaluation of the effectiveness of interest rate and loan supply policies. In Section III, pooled cross-sectional time-series data are used to estimate investment functions for Greek industrial firms and to test for any systematic changes in the firms’ behavior in response to selective tightening of short-term credit supply. Concluding remarks are presented in Section IV.

I. The Greek Financial Sector

This section describes the workings of the Greek financial system, highlighting some of the elements that may seem to enhance the effectiveness of selective credit policies.4 Of particular significance in this regard are the low level of development of the capital market and the authorities’ tight control over the banking system.

The Capital Market

The securities market accounts for a very small fraction of external financing in the Greek economy. New issues of stocks and bonds constitute an insignificant source of funds for the private nonfinancial sector, which meets most of its financing requirements by borrowing from the banking system.

The relative importance of the securities market is illustrated in Table 1, which presents data on the values of new security issues and the flow of bank credit over the period 1968–84. The value of total gross security issues amounted to about 13 percent of the total flow of bank credit during that period, whereas issues by private nonfinancial enterprises accounted for less than 1 percent of the flow of bank credit to the private sector. In the equity market, more than half the new shares during the whole period were issued by financial institutions in the years 1976–80. Issues by public enterprises and the central government dominated the bond market until 1973, when the government started to finance a large part of its deficit with treasury bills.5 During 1973–77 financial institutions and public enterprises accounted for the bulk of new bond issues, and since 1978 only financial institutions have issued new bonds. Among members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Greece had the lowest ratio of total security issues to gross domestic product (GDP) during the period 1968–77 (Table 2).

Table 1.

Security Issues and Flow of Bank Credit in Greece, 1968–84

(In millions of drachmas, current prices)

article image
article image
Sources: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Financial Statistics, and Greece, Bank of Greece, Monthly Statistical Bulletin, various issues.

The figures in columns 9, 10, and 11 are first differences of the respective outstanding stocks of consolidated bank credit, excluding credit to the central administration.

Table 2.

Security Issues on Various Greek Domestic Markets, 1966–77

(In percentage of gross domestic product)

article image
article image
Source: OECD, Financial Statistics (1978, Vol. 12. Pt. I).

1968–75 average.

1968–74 average.

1968–73 average.

The low level of activity in the capital market can be attributed to the inadequacy of both the supply of and the demand for securities. Large industrial firms have little incentive to issue securities because they can usually meet all their financing needs by borrowing from commercial banks on favorable terms.6 Individual investors may be reluctant to hold corporate shares owing to the family character of most private companies and the uncertainty over their dividend policies. This uncertainty derives from the fact that the directors of the board of such companies are usually members of the controlling family, allowing them to inflate their salaries at the expense of profits.7 Larger institutional investors, such as pension funds, mutual funds, and insurance companies are either prohibited by law from holding private securities or have insufficient resources to make any significant contribution to the level of activity in the stock exchange (Bitros (1981, p. 461)).

The Banking System and Credit Policy

The Greek banking system consists of the Bank of Greece (the central bank), 13 locally owned commercial banks, 20 subsidiaries of foreign banks, 3 investment banks, and 4 state-controlled specialized credit institutions. The Bank of Greece, in addition to performing the usual functions of a central bank, provides funds for the specialized credit institutions and occasionally engages in direct lending to the private sector. Commercial banks obtain most of their funds by attracting deposits and extend loans to most economic sectors. The local banks also own or have interests in some major insurance companies and industrial and tourist enterprises as well as in the investment banks, which engage in long-term financing and participate in the equity capital of industrial enterprises. Finally, the specialized credit institutions obtain most of their funds from the central bank, which also dictates how these funds are to be used.8 As a result, the assets of these institutions consist mainly of loans to agriculture, long-term loans to industry, housing loans to low-income groups and public employees, and loans to public utilities and public enterprises.9

Unlike the specialized credit institutions, the commercial banks, which supply about 50 percent of total bank credit, have considerable discretion over their operations. Monetary and credit policies are thus intended mainly to control commercial bank behavior, through a wide range of rules and regulations. This control is enhanced by the highly oligopolistic structure of the banking system and by state ownership of the two largest commercial banks. These two banks also hold controlling interests in five smaller commercial banks, giving them effective control of around 70 percent of commercial banking activity.

The general objectives of the regulatory policies for commercial banks have remained relatively unchanged, although the details of bank regulations have varied over time. In addition to controlling aggregate demand, the monetary authorities also seek to encourage what are perceived to be desirable economic activities at the expense of less desirable ones. Accordingly, credit policies in general aim to encourage agriculture, small-scale manufacturing, industrial investment, and export and tobacco trade while discouraging speculative investment in real estate, import and domestic trade, and consumer expenditure.

The monetary authorities have pursued these allocative goals with a combination of direct restrictions on the portfolio policies of commercial banks, interest rate ceilings on deposits and loans, and ceilings on the supplies of certain types of credit. Each type of policy is discussed below in turn.

Direct Restrictions on Portfolio Policies of Commercial Banks

Banks are required to deposit a fraction of their deposits in a non-interest-bearing account with the central bank and to invest an additional fraction in treasury bills and government bonds. In addition, specified fractions of total deposits are earmarked for the long-term financing of fixed-capital formation, for loans to handicraft enterprises, and for the financing of other favored sectors; if banks fall short of these targets, any unused balance of the designated amounts is to be deposited with the central bank at a low interest rate. Altogether, these compulsory uses of funds amount to more than 70 percent of total commercial bank deposits and constitute the authorities’ principal instrument of control over the liquidity and credit allocation of the banking system.

Deposit and Loan Rate Ceilings

The authorities set ceilings on commercial bank deposit and loan rates in an effort to influence the demand for various types of deposits and loans.10 These ceilings have been in effect through most of the 1970s and early 1980s. Beginning in 1973, the rate of inflation rose to levels consistently above deposit rates, and usually above most loan rates. The authorities attempted to close the gap between the rate of inflation and the level of interest rates by raising all interest rate ceilings in 1978, but this gap widened again during 1979–81 as inflation accelerated (Table 3). Inflation moderated thereafter, but most real loan rates remained negative through 1983, becoming slightly positive only in 1984, while real deposit rates remained negative throughout the 1973–84 period.

Table 3.

Selected Interest Rate Ceilings on Commercial Bank Deposits and Loans in Greece, 1971–84

(In percent per year)

article image
Source: Greece, Bank of Greece, Monthly Statistical Bulletin, various issues.Note: Interest rates are end of period: loan rates include commission.

The structure of Greek deposit and loan rates reflects the authorities’ policy objectives rather than market preferences or expectations. The term structure of deposit rates is designed to encourage demand for longer-term time deposits, which carry interest rates 1 to 2 percentage points higher than the rates on savings deposits (Table 3). In contrast, long-term loan rates have been 0.5 to 5.0 percentage points lower than short-term rates, in conformance with the authorities’ efforts to encourage formation of fixed capital. Similarly, loans to import and domestic trade have cost 3 to 14 percentage points more than loans to export and tobacco trade, reflecting the authorities’ view that the former tend to finance speculative, nonproductive activities. In May 1983, the authorities undertook to simplify and rationalize this loan rate structure by raising the rates on some of the previously subsidized loan categories. Currently, three different rates apply to about 90 percent of credit to the private sector, and the margins between these rates have been substantially narrowed. Since 1966, this policy of differential loan rates has been complemented with a system of differential reserve requirements and reserve withdrawals on the various types of commercial bank loans. This system was designed to equalize the banks’ nominal rates of return from all loan categories, thereby to ensure that banks would have no incentive to undermine the authorities’ policy.

Credit Ceilings

The monetary authorities set upper limits on the size of specific types of loans as well as on the overall supply of credit to certain sectors of the economy. Beginning in the early 1970s, total short-term credit—supplied by commercial banks for the financing of industry, mining, and domestic and import trade—was subject to periodically revised ceilings, whereas credit to export and tobacco trade and long-term credit for the formation of fixed capital were unrestricted (Table 4). This policy, complemented by a suspension of housing loans, was intended to curtail inflationary pressures without depressing the level of activity in the more productive sectors of the economy. The policy of selectively restricting short-term credit was abandoned in 1976, when the authorities began imposing ceilings on total private sector credit instead. The allocation of credit has since been left to the discretion of commercial banks, within the limits set by the aforementioned compulsory investment requirements.

Table 4.

Ceilings for Growth Rate of Commercial Bank Credit in Greece, 1971–75

article image
Sources: Greece, Bank of Greece, Monthly Statistical Bulletin, and OECD, Economic Surveys: Greece, various issues.

Restricted credit includes short-term credit to industry and mining as well as credit to import and domestic trade; unrestricted credit includes long-term credit to industry and mining as well as credit to export and tobacco trade.

Effectiveness of Selective Credit Policies

The foregoing discussion suggests that the Greek authorities should be able to direct the flow of financing to the private sector with relative ease. Credit is channeled almost exclusively through the highly regulated and centralized banking system, which is mostly state-owned. As a result, the authorities have direct or indirect control over the terms, conditions, and quantities of credit allocated to the various sectors of the economy.

Nevertheless, there is evidence suggesting that, despite the apparent strict regulation of the Greek banking system, the effectiveness of selective credit controls has been limited by the ability of lenders and borrowers to behave in a way that frustrates the authorities’ goals. Although most of the banking system is state owned, banks have often tried to evade credit regulations, acting as if they were profit-maximizing firms.11 A notable example of this behavior is the banks’ tendency to increase the supply of high interest rate loans, in violation of the spirit of the authorities’ loan rate policy. This type of behavior prompted the authorities to institute the system of asset reserve requirements and reserve withdrawals referred to above, but the resultant equalization of effective nominal loan rates may not have been sufficient to prevent the behavior in question.12

Borrower behavior may also tend to undermine the effectiveness of credit controls. For example, firms may divert their own funds in order to finance restricted activities; in this regard, trade credit is widely known to have played a primary role in Greece.13 Similarly, firms may have been able to break the presumed linkage betwen fixed-capital formation and long-term credit by changing their patterns of financing so as to offset changes in the pattern of credit supplies.

This paper focuses on the implications that the latter type of firm behavior had for the effectiveness of the Greek authorities’ credit policies during the mid-1970s. In an effort to underscore the potential and the limitations in using the term structure of loan supplies and loan rates as a selective credit control, the next section presents a theoretical model of industrial firms’ financing decisions.

II. A Model of the Firm’s Investment and Financing Decisions

This section develops a model of the firm’s behavior in order to determine the conditions under which the policy of lengthening the average maturity of loans and lowering the cost of long-term credit to the private sector will have the desired effect of encouraging formation of fixed capital. If fixed-capital formation is indeed more strongly affected by long-term than by short-term credit, then there is reason to believe that this policy will be successful. One of the aims of the model is to establish the nature of the relationship between the term structure of a firm’s debt and its asset composition.14

Accordingly, a distinction is made between fixed capital, which includes structures and machinery and equipment, and circulating or working capital, which includes advances to workers before actual sales, inventories of finished goods, goods in process and raw materials, and trade credit. Because of the time and adjustment costs associated with acquisition and installation, the quantity of a firm’s fixed capital is changed far less frequently than its holdings of circulating capital. If the firm chooses to match the maturities of its assets and liabilities, then long-term loans will be more closely linked to fixed capital, whereas short-term loans will be more closely associated with working capital. This choice, however, does not necessarily imply that a relative increase in the supply of long-term loans will encourage the acquisition of fixed assets. In the firm’s point of view, long-term credit may be a perfect substitute for revolving short-term credit. Thus, a permanent change in the term structure of the firm’s debt in favor of long-term loans may only affect the firm’s liability composition, leaving its asset composition unchanged.

The Model

To determine the firm’s behavior in response to selective credit policies, it is useful to set up the firm’s optimization problem (see Wood (1975)). Following other studies, fixed and working capital are treated as separate factors of production.15 The criterion for the effectiveness of credit controls is the extent to which the controls succeed in stimulating the firm’s demand for fixed capital and in discouraging its demand for circulating capital.

Firms are assumed to maximize expected profits net of financing costs over a two-period horizon. They hold the same amount of fixed capital but may vary their holdings of working capital over the two periods. On the liability side, firms can obtain long-term loans with a two-period maturity in the beginning of the first period; they can obtain short-term loans with a one-period maturity in the beginning of each period. Equity capital is exogenous and constant throughout the two periods. Firms determine the composition of their assets and liabilities on the basis of the interest rates or the supplies (or both) of short- and long-term loans, which are known at the beginning of the first period, and on the basis of the interest rate or the supply (or both) of short-term loans that are expected to prevail in the beginning of the second period. To simplify the analysis, it is assumed that there is no uncertainty about future credit market conditions.

In more formal terms, each firm chooses its fixed-capital stock (KFt), its long-term borrowings (LLt), and its short-term borrowings (LSt and LSt+1) so as to maximize the present discounted value of its profits (P) subject to its technological and balance-sheet constraints. One then has

max P=(RtLStrtsLLtrtl)+[1/(1+r)](Rt+1LSt+1rt+1sLLtrtl),(1)

subject to

LSt+LLt+EtKFtKCt=0(2)
LSt+1+LLt+EtKFtKCt+1=0(3)
Rt=Ft(KFt,KCt)(4)
Rt+1=Ft+1(KFt,KCt+1).(5)

A key to the symbols used is provided in Table 5.

Table 5.

Key to Symbols Used

article image

Equation (1) gives the firm’s profits as a function of revenues (net of labor costs and depreciation) and of financing costs. Equations (2) and (3) are the firm’s balance-sheet constraints for periods t and t + 1, respectively. Finally, equations (4) and (5) give the firm’s revenue functions, which represent the technical relationships between net revenue and productive inputs (fixed and working capital), in periods t and t + 1, respectively. Labor is not included as a separate input because it is subsumed in working capital, which includes advances to workers before output sales.

Selective Credit Controls and the Firm’s Investment Decision

When the authorities exercise direct control over both the cost and the availability of credit, interest rates may be inconsistent with loan market equilibrium. For any given supply of credit, artificially low rates will generate excess demand, and excessively high rates will result in excess supply. As a consequence, the effectiveness of credit policies depends crucially on whether loans are in excess demand or in excess supply at the time that the policies are initiated. Loan rate increases will have little effect on expenditure when these rates are artificially low, whereas loan supply increases will fail to stimulate spending when the cost of credit is too high for borrowing to be worthwhile.

On the basis of the optimization framework presented earlier, one can discuss the effects of selective credit controls on the firm’s investment decision, distinguishing between the cases of excess supply and excess demand for loans. In each case it is assumed that actual loan transactions are determined by the short side of the market. The firm borrows exactly as much as it wishes when there is excess supply of loans, and exactly as much as is supplied when there is excess demand.

The main results, discussed in detail in the next two subsections, can be summarized as follows. When loans are in excess supply, a fall in the long-term loan rate will stimulate or leave unchanged the firm’s demand for both types of capital. A rise in the short-term rate, however, will discourage demand for working capital, but it may encourage or discourage demand for fixed capital. When loans are in excess demand, a change in the maturity composition of loan supply in favor of long-term loans will stimulate demand for fixed capital only if this policy is viewed as transitory. If the policy is viewed as permanent, firms will tend to neutralize it by using more long-term loans to finance working capital.

Without Borrowing Constraints (Excess Supply of Loans)

In this case the firm is free to choose KFt, KCt, KCt+1, LLt, LSt, and LSt+1. The first-order conditions that are necessary for an optimum imply that, in general, the firm will not wish to hold nonzero amounts of LLt, LSt, and LSt+1 at the same time. (Formal proof of this and other propositions stated in the paper are available from the author on request.) In particular, if

rtl+[1/(1+r)]rtl<rts+[1/(1+r)]rt+1s,(6)

then either LSt = 0 or LSt+1 = 0; and if

rts+[1/(1+r)]rt+1s<rtl+[1/(1+r)]rtl,(7)

then LLt = 0. Only in the special case of equality between the terms on the left- and right-hand sides of inequalities (6) and (7) is it optimal for the firm to hold positive amounts of short- and long-term loans in both periods.

The intuitive explanation of these results is simple. Firms will always choose the cheapest way to finance their capital. When interest rates are administered, it is highly improbable that they are set so as to make firms indifferent as regards long- and short-term financing. Thus, in general, firms will finance all their capital either with revolving short-term credit or with long-term credit.16 The possibility of a combination of long-term and short-term financing for one of the two periods arises only because the firm’s capital requirements may differ over time. If the firm needs more funds in the second than in the first period, then it may find it optimal to obtain some short-term loans for the second period so as to avoid having an excess of funds in the first period. Similarly, the inability to prepay long-term loans may make it optimal to hold both short- and long-term loans in the first period.

As pointed out earlier, changes in the supply of loans will have no effect on the firm’s decisions because actual borrowing is demand determined. Interest rate changes, however, will alter the composition of assets and liabilities in a way that depends on the firm’s pattern of financing.

When the firm borrows positive amounts of short-term funds only in the first period (LSt+1 = 0), then it can be shown that, under plausible conditions, a rise in the long-term loan rate (rtl) will lower demands for long-term loans (LLt), fixed capital (KFt), and working capital (KCt). The effect on demand for short-term loans (LSt), however, is ambiguous, since a fall in LLt reduces total funds available in the second period. If fixed and working capital are complementary inputs, the firm finds it optimal to spread the decrease in resources between the two inputs; that is, one has

ΔKFt+ΔKCt+1=ΔLLt(8)
ΔKFt<ΔLLt.(9)

In the first period, long-term funds are supplemented with short-term funds, so that the firm can adjust working capital to the optimal level. Given ΔKFt, the size of the optimal change in first-period working capital ΔKCt will determine the sign of ΔLSt. In particular, ΔLSt is positive if and only if

ΔLLtΔKFt<ΔKCt.(10)

Similarly, a rise in the short-term loan rate rts will lower LSt and KCt but has ambiguous effects on KFt and LLt. The latter will be positively related to rts when the firm finds it optimal to offset part of the decrease in short-term funds with an increase in LLt, which by equation (8) must be associated with a rise in KFt if the two inputs are complementary. This case is of particular interest because it gives one possible justification for policies that are aimed to stimulate fixed-capital formation with high short-term and low long-term loan rates.

The effects of changes in rtl are analogous when the firm borrows short-term funds only in the second period (LSt = 0). Changes in rts, however, affect the firm’s financing decision only indirectly through their effect on expected future short-term rates (rt+1s). With static expectations—that is, if rt+1s = rts—the effects of changes in rts will also be analogous to those discussed above.

Finally, when the firm finances all of its capital with revolving short-term credit (LLt = 0), changes in the long-term loan rate have no effect on financing decisions. An increase in either the current or the expected future short-term rate, however, lowers the firm’s demand for each asset and liability unambiguously when the two inputs are complements, since a rise in the cost of short-term funds in any one of the two periods decreases demand for both fixed and working capital in that period. The lower level of fixed capital implies a lower marginal productivity of working capital in the other period and thereby lower levels of working capital and borrowing. The effect of changes in the current short-term rate will be even stronger if there is feedback from actual to expected future interest rates because this feedback will reinforce the effect of changes in current financing costs.

With Borrowing Constraints (Excess Demand for Loans)

In this case it is assumed that all three loan markets are in excess demand. This implies that LSt, LSt+1, and LLt are no longer the firm’s decision variables, since they are always equal to the exogenous supplies LSt¯, LS¯t+1, and LL¯t, respectively. It follows that loan rate changes can have no effect on the firm’s composition of assets or liabilities, although these changes still have obvious effects on net profits. The authorities can alter firms’ capital requirements in this case through direct manipulation of loan supplies. The intent of the Greek monetary authorities, in particular, has been to encourage formation of fixed capital through a relative abundance of long-term credit.17

To isolate the impact of selective credit controls from that of general credit conditions, the analysis now focuses on the policy of changing the maturity composition of credit while keeping the total quantity of credit outstanding unchanged. Thus, one has

ΔLS¯t+ΔLL¯t=0,(11)

which implies that any increase in LL¯t is accompanied by an equal decrease in LSt¯. The policy is considered successful if lengthening the average maturity of credit encourages demand for KFt at the expense of KCt.

Assuming complementarity between KCt and KFt and solving for the comparative static effects of changes in LSt and LLt yields the following results:

0<dKFt/dLS¯t<dKFt/dLL¯t(12)

and

0<dKCt/dLL¯t<dKCt/dLS¯t.(13)

From equation (11) and inequalities (12) and (13) it follows that increasing LL¯t at the expense of LSt¯ will have the expected expansionary effect on KFt and the corresponding contractionary effect on KCt. The relevance of this result, however, may be limited in view of the possible effects of current policies on firms’ expectations of future loan supplies. Taking these effects into account yields

ΔKFt=(dKFt/dLL¯t)ΔLL¯t+[dKFt/dLS¯t+(dKFt/dLS¯t+1)(dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t)]ΔLS¯t(14)

and

ΔKCt=(dKCt/dLL¯t)ΔLL¯t+[dKCt/dLS¯t+(dKCt/dLS¯t+1)(dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t)]ΔLS¯t,(15)

where dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t is the sensitivity of the expected future supply of short-term loans to changes in current loan supplies. Equations (14) and (15) imply that the loan supply policy in question will be effective if and only if dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t<1. It will have no effect if dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t=1, and it will be counterproductive if dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t>1.

The effects of an increase in LLt at the expense of LSt thus depend on whether this change is expected to be transitory or permanent. A transitory change (dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t=0) will induce firms to increase their fixed capital so as to be prepared to increase productivity in the second period when the supply of short-term loans rises back to its normal level. A permanent change (dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t=1), however, provides no such incentive because total available resources are expected to remain unchanged in both periods. In the extreme case in which the supply of short-term loans is expected to fall even further in the second period (dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t>1) total available resources are expected to decline, and firms will tend to cut down on their stock of fixed capital to prepare themselves for the anticipated credit crunch.

These results have important policy implications. First, any permanent change in the maturity composition of bank credit will be completely ineffectual. Firms will substitute long-term funds for revolving short-term credit while leaving their asset composition unchanged. Second, a change in loan supply composition will be more effective the more credible it is that the change is only a temporary measure. The government thus can maximize the short-run impact of its policy by making it explicit that the change will be reversed in the near future.18 This announced intent will also help prevent the perverse possibility of any firm’s overreacting in anticipation of further tightening of short-term credit in the future. Finally, it follows that the usefulness of this specific type of selective credit policy is, at best, quite limited. The firm’s capital structure is primarily a function of technological factors that cannot be much affected by its liability composition. Redirection of the government’s efforts toward affecting the marginal productivities of the two inputs might be a more promising way to encourage formation of fixed capital.

III. A Test of the Effectiveness of Selective Credit Controls

The theoretical framework above can be used to test for the effectiveness of the Greek authorities’ policy of selectively restricting short-term credit over the period 1973–77. As pointed out in Section I, long-term loans to industry had been exempted from any such restrictions, with the aim of encouraging fixed-investment expenditure. Although this exemption generated a relatively ample supply of long-term loans during that period, private firms might have diverted these loans to any other kind of expenditure, thereby limiting the effectiveness of the policy. This section presents empirical evidence on the extent to which such diversion took place, based on the estimation of variants of equations (14) and (15).

Implicit in the use of equations (14) and (15) is the assumption of excess demand for loans, according to the analysis of Section II. This assumption is crucial for purposes of estimation because it allows the treatment of loan supplies as exogenous to the firm’s investment decision. There is good reason to believe that, during the sample period (1973–77), loans were indeed in excess demand. The figures in Table 3 imply negative or near-zero real interest rates throughout that period, rates that are likely to have contributed to such excess demand. Further evidence to this effect is provided by the banks’ persistent tendency to exceed the authorities’ credit ceilings.19

The obvious difficulty in estimating equations (14) and (15) directly is the inability to measure the extent to which firms’ expectations of future loan supplies are affected by current policies. One practical alternative is to assume that, in normal times, firms view current changes in loan supplies as temporary deviations from trend, with no implications for any systematic change in future loan supplies. In terms of the theoretical model, dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t equals zero in such periods, and the coefficients of ΔLSt¯ and ΔLL¯t can be estimated directly. In times of announced, deliberate government measures to change the mix of ΔLSt¯ and ΔLL¯t however, firms may reasonably be assumed to expect that this change may persist for some time. This assumption may render dLS¯t+1/dLS¯t positive and may exert a systematic impact on the coefficients of ΔLSt¯. If ΔLL¯t=ΔLS¯t, then the estimated coefficients of both loan supply variables may move in a way that tends to neutralize the government policy. The test of the effectiveness of selective credit controls is thus reduced to a test of the stability of firm’s investment equations (14) and (15).

The methodology of the test is as follows. Separate investment equations were estimated for fixed and working capital over the entire sample period (1973–77) in an effort to determine firms’ average patterns of financing. If firms kept these patterns constant at all times and if inequalities (12) and (13) held, then the credit policy in question would be effective. If firms shifted their patterns of financing in response to credit policy, however, they would tend to render the policy ineffective.20 To determine the extent to which such shifts have taken place, the two investment functions were re-estimated, allowing separate coefficients over the tight short-term credit period 1973–74 and over the more normal period 1976–77. The estimated coefficients over the two subperiods were then compared, and stability tests were run to determine whether policy-induced changes in firms’ patterns of financing tended to weaken significantly the impact of the credit policy in question.21

More specifically, equations (14) and (15) were adapted to allow for the possibility of internal financing by including a profit variable on the right-hand side. The data were obtained from the balance sheets of all Greek industrial corporations with capital of over 500,000 drachmas and were aggregated into 20 industry groups (Federation of Greek Industries, various issues). In each equation all variables were normalized by the appropriate capital stock in order to minimize any problems of heteroscedasticity. The data were pooled over the years 1973, 1974, 1976, and 1977; separate equations were estimated for investment in fixed capital (IFit) and investment in circulating capital (ICit), with 80 observations.22 These procedures yielded

IFit/KFit1=0.071(2.406)+0.496(2.921)Pit/KFit1+0.273(3.713)ΔLSit/KFit1+0.686(5.062)ΔLLit/KFit1(16)
R2=.548DW=2.072Fstatistic=30.706
ICit/KCit1=0.042(1.672)+0.325(2.913)Pit/KCit1+0.566(6.944)ΔLSit/KCit1+0.511(5.325)ΔLLit/KCit1(17)
R2=.780DW=2.036Fstatistic=89.745

where

article image

and

ICit=KCitKCit1(18)
IFit=KFitKFit1(19)
ΔLLit=LLitLLit1(20)
ΔLSit=LSitLSit1,(21)

and the numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.

All of the estimated slope coefficients turned out to be positive and statistically significant—suggesting that profits, short-term loans, and long-term loans were all important sources of funds for both types of investment. Moreover, the coefficient of long-term loans was larger in the IFt equation (16) and smaller in the ICt equation (17) relative to the respective coefficients of short-term loans.23 This finding is consistent with the results of the theoretical model (inequalities (12) and (13)) but does not necessarily imply that shifting the maturity structure of loans would be an effective selective credit policy. The coefficients in equations (16) and (17) might themselves be endogenous and might change systematically in response to any policy change that was expected to be lasting. The endogeneity of firms’ patterns of financing was already discussed in the context of equations (14) and (15) of the theoretical model.

To test for any such systematic effects of the selective tightening of short-term credit in 1973–74, equations (16) and (17) were re-estimated on the pooled data with the two dummy variables D7374 and D7677 incorporated in the equations. D7374 equals unity for observations in the years 1973 and 1974 and equals zero for observations in 1976 and 1977. Similarly, D7677 is equal to zero for observations in 1973 and 1974 and to unity for all other observations. The results were as follows:

IFit/KFit1=0.028(0.734)D7677+0.134(2.843)D7374+0.852(3.270)PitD7677/KFit1+0.163(0.688)PitD7374/KFit1+0.197(1.896)ΔLSitD7677/KFit1+0.300(2.528)ΔLSitD7374/KFit1+0.796(4.294)ΔLLitD7674/KFit1+0.565(2.851)ΔLLitD7374/KFit1(22)
R2=.574DW=2.175Fstatistic=76.429
ICit/KCit1=0.122(3.409)D7677+0.35(1.197)D7374+0.178(1.125)PitD7677/KCit1+0.225(1.771)PitD7374/KCit1+0.362(3.821)ΔLSitD7677/KCit1+0.791(7.009)ΔLSitD7374/KCit1+0.227(1.725)ΔLLitD7677/KCit1+0.493(4.185)ΔLLitD7374/KCit1.(23)
R2=.846DW=2.296Fstatistic=147.09

The results reveal substantial differences between the estimated coefficients for each subperiod. The profit coefficient in the IFit equation was much lower in 1973–74 than in 1976–77. The reverse relationship held for the profit coefficients in the ICit equation. This finding would seem to suggest that in 1973–74, when the supply of short-term credit was tight, firms shifted internal funds from IF to IC. The external funds coefficients still satisfied inequalities (12) and (13), but the difference between the coefficients of short-term and long-term credit in the IFit equation shrank in 1973–74 to almost half its size in 1976–77. In the ICit equation, both external funds coefficients in 1973–74 were more than twice their size in 1976–77. This evidence is consistent with a systematic effort on the part of firms to change their patterns of financing in favor of IC in order to mitigate the impact of the government’s 1973–74 selective credit policy.24

When the stability of the coefficients of equations (16) and (17) was tested more formally, the null hypothesis of no structural change between 1973–74 and 1976–77 could not be rejected for IF, but it could be rejected at the 1 percent level of significance for IC. The null hypothesis of no structural change was also tested for each coefficient separately, and it could be rejected for only half of the coefficients. The results are summarized in Table 6.

Table 6.

Tests for Changes in Regression Coefficients in Tight-Money Period (1973–74)

article image

In sum, even though some of the results are not statistically significant, there is enough evidence that selective credit policies have a systematic effect on the structural coefficients of the equations to warrant cautious use of such policies. Even if inequalities (12) and (13) are found on average to be valid, the endogeneity of patterns of financing does not allow one to make inferences about the impact of selective credit policies strictly on the basis of these relationships.

IV. Conclusions

This paper has focused on how the profit-maximizing behavior of firms can limit the effectiveness of selective credit policies, even when the authorities exercise direct control over interest rates and credit supplies. If, as a result of this type of control, loan markets are in disequilibrium, the impact of loan rate and loan supply policies will depend on the state of the loan market. Changes in loan rates will be the more appropriate policy tool when there is excess supply of loans, whereas changes in loan supply will be more effective under excess demand.

When loans are in excess demand, a policy of lengthening the average maturity of credit will be most successful in stimulating formation of fixed capital when that policy is explicitly temporary. The effects of any change in the maturity composition of credit that is perceived to be permanent will be completely neutralized as firms change their patterns of financing. These results give support to Silber’s assertion (1973, p. 339) that “selective credit policies have their greatest potential usefulness within a cyclical context rather than secularly.”

The empirical results suggest that the short-term credit ceilings implemented in Greece in 1973–74 may have exerted a systematic influence on firms’ behavior, which may have tended to neutralize the selective credit controls in question. Disregard of such policy-induced changes in behavior may lead to erroneous conclusions about the effectiveness of policy. Selective controls on short-term credit may fail to encourage formation of fixed capital even if the impact of long-term credit on fixed investment is stronger, on average, than that of short-term credit. This latter condition is necessary, but not sufficient, for policy effectiveness. Only if these effects are strong enough to be unaffected by the imposition of credit controls can one be sure that the controls will be effective.

Several questions that may be worth investigating through future research have not been addressed in this paper. The theoretical model of the firm’s investment decision can be extended into a multiperiod framework that would allow for variations of the firm’s equity capital over time through the retention of profits. Each period’s profits would then enter not only into the firm’s objective function but also into the financing constraint of the following period. This formulation would allow a formal investigation of the effects of selective credit controls on firms’ dividend policies and of the way in which these effects influence the outcome of the controls in question.

Uncertainty about future credit conditions is another important variable that might be incorporated in the model. Changes in the expected variability of these conditions may have systematic effects on the investment decisions of firms. For example, if a firm is uncertain about the amount of short-term credit that will be available in the future, it may tend to underinvest in fixed capital for fear of incurring losses if a credit squeeze forces it to restrict its working capital and to underutilize its fixed capital. Risk can be introduced in the model by allowing the firm’s objective function to depend on expected profits, as well as on the expected variability of such profits, and by letting the interest rate and the supply of future short-term credit be random variables.

The empirical tests can also be strengthened by using a more disaggregated and more carefully selected data sample. It would be useful to distinguish between external and domestic borrowing because the former is more likely to be beyond the authorities’ control. It would also be desirable to restrict the sample to those particular firms that were actually unable to obtain all the credit they demanded. This restriction would ensure the exogeneity of loan supplies, which is a necessary condition for the estimates to be unbiased. The simultaneity problem may be somewhat more serious for the profit variable, which (according to the theoretical model) is not only a constraint on, but also the outcome of, financing and investment decisions. This problem may be alleviated with the use of an instrumental-variables technique of estimation or with the construction of a better measure for the firm’s cash-flow constraint. Finally, it would be most fruitful to use data from other countries that have had experience with selective credit controls to assess the effectiveness of these policies. The results of this paper suggest that stability tests should be an integral part of any such endeavor.

REFERENCES

  • Barth, J.R., J.J. Cordes, and A.M.J. Yezer, “Financial Institution Regulations, Redlining, and Mortgage Markets,” in Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, The Regulation of Financial Institutions, Conference Series No. 21 (Boston, 1980), pp. 10113.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bitros, George C., “The Fungibility Factor in Credit and the Question of the Efficacy of Selective Controls,” Oxford Economic Papers (London), Vol. 33, (November 1981), pp. 45977.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eisner, Robert, “Fiscal and Monetary Policy Reconsidered,” American Economic Review (Nashville, Tennessee), Vol. 59 (December 1969), pp. 897905.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Federation of Greek Industries, The State of Greek Industry (Athens, various issues).

  • Greece, Bank of Greece, Monthly Statistical Bulletin (Athens), various issues.

  • Greece, Bank of Greece, Report of the Governor (Athens, 1984 and various issues).

  • Halikias, Demetrios I., Money and Credit in a Developing Economy: The Greek Case (New York: New York University Press, 1978).

  • Hamburger, Michael J., and Burton Zwick, “Installment Credit Controls, Consumer Expenditures and the Allocation of Real Resources,” Journal of Finance (New York), Vol. 32 (December 1977), pp. 155769.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hodgman, Donald R., “Selective Credit Controls in Western Europe,” study prepared for the Trustees of the Banking Research Fund (Chicago: Association of Reserve City Bankers, 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaffee, D., “Housing Finance and Mortgage Policy,” in Government Credit Allocation: Where Do We Go From Here?, ed. by Karl Brunner (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies, 1975), pp. 93122.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Omotunde E.G., “Direct Credit Controls in a Development Context: The Case of African Countries,” in Government Credit Allocation: Where Do We Go From Here?, ed. by Karl Brunner (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies, 1975), pp. 15180.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kane, Edward J., “Good Intentions and Unintended Evil: The Case Against Selective Credit Allocation,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking (Columbus, Ohio), Vol. 9 (February 1977), pp. 5569.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kapur, Basant K., “Alternative Stabilization Policies for Less-Developed Economies,” Journal of Political Economy (Chicago), Vol. 84 (August 1976), pp. 77795.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kearl, J., K. Rosen, and C. Swan, “Relationships Between the Mortgage Instruments, the Demand for Housing, and Mortgage Credit: A Review of Empirical Studies,” in New Mortgage Designs for Stable Housing in an Inflationary Environment, ed. by Franco Modigliani and Donald R. Lessard, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series No. 14 (Boston, 1975), pp. 93109.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lucas, Robert E., Jr., “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,” in The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, ed. by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 1 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1976; New York: Elsevier, 1976), pp. 1946.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., Money and Capital in Economic Development (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1973).

  • Mayer, T., “Credit Allocation: A Critical View,” in Government Credit Allocation: Where Do We Go From Here?, ed. by Karl Brunner (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies, 1975), pp. 3992.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Modigliani, Franco, and R. Sutch, “Innovations in Interest Rate Policy,” American Economic Review (Nashville, Tennessee), Vol. 56, (May 1966), pp. 17897.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Molho, Lazaros E., Monetary Policy and Selective Credit Controls in Greece (doctoral dissertation; New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Molho, Lazaros E., “The Determinants of Commercial Bank Loan Supply in Greece: An Empirical Investigation,” Greek Economic Review (Athens), Vol. 5 (April 1983), pp. 6588.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Molho, Lazaros E., “Loan Rates as a Selective Credit Control,” Journal of Banking and Finance (Amsterdam), Vol. 8 (March 1984), pp. 7998.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Morley, Samuel A., “Inflation and Stagnation in Brazil,” Economic Development and Cultural Change (Chicago), Vol. 19 (January 1971), pp. 184203.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Economic Surveys: Greece (Paris, various issues).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Financial Statistics (Paris, various issues).

  • Psilos, Diomedes D., Capital Market in Greece, Research Monograph 9 (Athens: Center of Economic Research, 1964).

  • Silber, William L., “Selective Credit Policies: A Survey,” Quarterly Review, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro (Rome), No. 26 (December 1973), pp. 32853.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smith, P.F., “A Review of the Theoretical and Administrative History of Consumer Credit Controls,” in Studies in Selective Credit Policies, ed. by Ira Kaminow and James M. O’Brien (Philadelphia: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 1975), pp. 12344.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wood, J.H., “Some Effects of Bank Credit Restrictions on the Short-Term Behavior of Large Firms,” in Studies in Selective Credit Policies, ed. by Ira Kaminow and James M. O’Brien (Philadelphia: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 1975), pp. 14770.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

Mr. Molho, an economist in the Central Banking Department, is a graduate of Yale University.

1

For descriptions of the various types of policies implemented in different parts of the world, see Johnson (1975) on African countries; Hodgman (1976) on Western European countries; and Jaffee (1975), Smith (1975), and Barth, Cordes, and Yezer (1980) on the United States.

2

Costs, efficiency, and equity are other related issues that will not be addressed in this paper. For discussions on these issues, see Silber (1973) and Mayer (1975).

3

For some illustrations on the long-run effects of selective credit controls in the United States, see Kane (1977).

4

For a detailed description of the Greek financial sector, see Halikias (1978).

5

Currently, these bills are held mostly by commercial banks in partial fulfillment of the banks’ compulsory investment requirements; the treasury bills are not negotiable and cannot be discounted by the Bank of Greece. Steps were recently taken, however, to initiate the direct sale of treasury bills to individuals and private enterprises. To this end, the Bank of Greece intends to take measures to develop a secondary market and plans to sell treasury bills in small denominations (Greece, Bank of Greece, Report of the Governor, Summary (1984, p. 28)).

6

The authorities set ceilings on the loan rates charged by banks. As a result, real loan rates have been negative for some loan categories in recent years (see Table 3).

7

For a detailed description of the Greek capital market, see Psilos (1964).

8

Beginning in 1984, two of the specialized credit institutions made considerable progress in attracting private deposits and in reducing their dependence on central bank funds. Also in 1984, the central bank abandoned its practice of regulating credit allocation by these institutions, with the aim of decentralizing the formulation of banks’ portfolio policies. Currently, the central bank sets ceilings on its financing of these institutions as well as on their total credit, leaving the allocation of credit to the institutions’ discretion (Greece, Bank of Greece, Report of the Governor, Summary (1984, pp. 26–27)).

9

The commercial banks and the specialized credit institutions have traditionally made little use of foreign loans as a source of funds. For both types of institutions, deposits in foreign exchange—mainly by Greek seamen, emigrants, and shipping companies—constitute the bulk of foreign liabilities. As of November 1984, nondeposit foreign liabilities as a percentage of total liabilities amounted to 2.6 percent for commercial banks and 3.7 percent for specialized credit institutions.

10

The rediscount rate of the Bank of Greece, which applies to commercial bank borrowing from the central bank, is not used to influence money market rates because most interest rates are fixed independently by the Bank of Greece. Through most of the 1970s, monetary growth was high enough for commercial banks to meet their obligations with their own funds, without having to resort to the central bank. Thus the rediscount rate has been important mainly as an indicator of trends in monetary policy.

11

According to Halikias (1978, pp. 225–26), “In many cases, the banks, instead of acting in accordance with the stated aims of the credit policy, are actually cooperating with their clients in finding ways to evade credit regulations. In fact, the banks have shown great ingenuity in this respect.”

12

Bitros (1981, p. 464) has pointed out that, even if all types of loans bear the same nominal rate of return, systematic differences in risk characteristics may still make banks favor the kinds of lending that the authorities wish to discourage. Halikias (1978, pp. 229–39) has also discussed and evaluated this loan rate policy, underlining its possible perverse results, and the same issues have been treated more formally by Molho (1983, 1984).

13

Halikias has presented evidence that Greek manufacturing enterprises channel a high proportion of their borrowed funds to trading companies by selling them their products on credit. He concluded that “under conditions of essentially free bank financing of the manufacturing industry, combined with restrictions on lending to trade, bank financing of the latter sector could not be prevented. It merely became indirect. In fact, Greek industrial enterprises were converted into financiers of trade” (Halikias (1978, p. 212)). The monetary authorities have been aware of these developments. According to the Report of the Governor of the Bank of Greece (1975, p. 15), “To a significant extent, the working capital requirements of industrial and commercial enterprises were met by credit leakages out of commercial bank lending not subject to a ceiling. This is evident from the fact that the growth rate of commercial bank lending in this category was very high (61 percent) last year, without being justified either by developments in economic activity or by the increasing cost of inputs. Credit leakages grew especially after the elimination of credit ceilings for funds intended to finance industrial exports and handicrafts.”

14

To simplify the analysis, the model distinguishes between total short-term and total long-term debt without any breakdown of domestic and external funds. The possibility of external finance, however, would only strengthen the model’s results with respect to the effectiveness of selective credit controls. If, in addition to substituting between domestic short-term and domestic long-term funds, firms could also substitute between domestic and external funds, the effectiveness of controls on the domestic banking system would be further weakened. Substitutions between external short-term and external long-term funds, however, would probably be less likely to occur. The bulk of external borrowing by Greek manufacturing firms consists of short-term suppliers’ credits; only a few large firms borrow directly from foreign banks (Halikias (1978, pp. 150–52)).

15

Morley (1971), McKinnon (1973), and Kapur (1976) have all argued that working capital may be an important factor of production in countries with less developed capital markets. The function of the distinction between fixed and working capital in these studies is to highlight the contractionary effects of disinflationary policies on output that are due to the linkage between bank financing and working capital (see, for example, Kapur (1976, p. 778)).

16

In a free market setting, arbitrage in the markets for securities of different maturities may be expected to bring short-term, long-term, and expected future short-term rates in line with one another. Arbitrage possibilities are in general much more limited in the loan market; in the particular case that the government sets loan rates, the term structure of interest rates will reflect the authorities’ goals rather than the market’s expectations.

17

The spirit of this policy is similar to that of “Operation Twist,” which was tried in the United States in the early 1960s, in an effort to stimulate investment spending without any deleterious balance of payments effects. The major differences between the two policies have to do with the method of implementation, which is ultimately a function of the institutional setting. Thus, instead of open market operations (which are impractical in the absence of well-developed capital markets), the Greek authorities used direct controls over the maturity composition of bank credit. For empirical evidence on the effects of Operation Twist, see Modigliani and Sutch (1966).

18

Note that these results differ from those of Wood (1975) in an important way. Wood found that the effectiveness of credit controls is stronger when firms are caught by surprise. In the model presented here, there are no surprises in the first period because firms determine their asset structure with full information on current loan supplies. Future loan supplies, however, can only be forecast, and this is why the important distinction is between transitory and permanent credit policies. In the second period there are obvious real effects of surprise changes in loan supplies, but these effects are not of interest because the fixed-capital stock is determined in the beginning of the first period. Finally, in this model explicitly transitory measures are more effective than permanent ones. This finding is the opposite of results on the relative effects of temporary and permanent tax increases on aggregate demand (for example, in Eisner (1969)).

19

For example, the target rates of growth for commercial bank credit were 18 and 20 percent for 1976 and 1977, respectively, compared with actual rates of growth of 32 and 25 percent.

20

For a more general and rigorous discussion of how optimizing agents may take actions that offset fully anticipated government policies, see Lucas (1976).

21

The tests in this section can be viewed as an extension of the work of Bitros (1981). In that work, estimation of expenditure equations on data from 153 Greek manufacturing firms provided evidence that the supplies of short- and long-term bank funds were endogenous variables from the firms’ point of view. From this evidence it was inferred that government efforts to redirect loan supplies were ineffective. In this paper, attention was confined to a period for which there is evidence that loans were in excess demand and, therefore, exogenous to firms’ decisions, and it was shown that, even then, redirection of loan supplies may have been ineffective because firms tended to neutralize the government policy by shifting their patterns of financing. These results strengthen Bitros’s findings by highlighting the possibility of endogeneity of the structural parameters of firms’ expenditure functions in the presence of credit rationing.

22

Observations for 1975 were excluded from the sample for two reasons. First, the investment climate was especially bad in that deep-recession year. This may account for the fact that, when the equations were estimated separately for each year, the coefficients for 1975 were outliers and exerted a disproportionate influence on the coefficients of the pooled regressions. Second, monetary tightening was eased in 1975, but the selective credit policy was completely abandoned only in 1976. Comparing 1973–74 with the later period may thus provide a sharper test if 1975 is excluded. Inclusion of 1975, however, would not alter the results in any significant way. Results of estimation over the whole 1973–77 period and for different specifications are presented in Molho (1980).

23

The hypothesis of equality of the short-term and long-term loan coefficients cannot be rejected for the ICt equation, but it can be rejected at the 5 percent level of significance in the IFt equation. The results differ substantially from those in Bitros (1981), not only because the samples in the two studies are different, but also because of major differences in specification. Bitros (1981) disaggregated KCt into inventories and accounts receivable, and liabilities into short- and long-term bank loans, nonbank long-term loans, and trade credit. He also included several explanatory variables in addition to financial flows.

24

Data limitations have not allowed the disaggregation of firms’ liabilities into domestic and foreign loans. In view of the above results, it seems likely that firms might also seek to adjust their mix of foreign liabilities in response to selective credit policies, thereby placing an additional limitation on the effectiveness of these policies.