The Treatment of Indirect Taxation in Econometric Models: An Analytical Survey
Author:
Mr. Nurun N. Choudhry
Search for other papers by Mr. Nurun N. Choudhry in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Recent literature on the simulation of existing econometric models of national economies directs little attention to the incidence of indirect taxation. This “inattention” is all the more conspicuous since men of affairs are paying closer attention to the effects of changes in indirect taxation. Such changes, particularly in an era of increasingly scarce natural resources, have a significant impact on prices, employment, output, and the balance of payments. Policymakers are therefore most interested in having at their disposal realistic econometric models that incorporate the effects of changes in indirect taxation.

Abstract

Recent literature on the simulation of existing econometric models of national economies directs little attention to the incidence of indirect taxation. This “inattention” is all the more conspicuous since men of affairs are paying closer attention to the effects of changes in indirect taxation. Such changes, particularly in an era of increasingly scarce natural resources, have a significant impact on prices, employment, output, and the balance of payments. Policymakers are therefore most interested in having at their disposal realistic econometric models that incorporate the effects of changes in indirect taxation.

Recent literature on the simulation of existing econometric models of national economies directs little attention to the incidence of indirect taxation. This “inattention” is all the more conspicuous since men of affairs are paying closer attention to the effects of changes in indirect taxation. Such changes, particularly in an era of increasingly scarce natural resources, have a significant impact on prices, employment, output, and the balance of payments. Policymakers are therefore most interested in having at their disposal realistic econometric models that incorporate the effects of changes in indirect taxation.

The ability to predict the consequences of changes in indirect taxation or, for that matter, of any policy action is critically dependent upon the specification of individual behavioral responses, as well as the overall specification of the real and financial sectors of the economy, in such econometric models. Of late, a number of national econometric models have been designed; however, a comparative review of the characteristics of such models with regard to the specification of indirect taxes has not been undertaken. Such a review would be useful to both policymakers and econometricians.

This survey of econometric models focuses attention on the specification of indirect taxes in econometric models and its implications for the effects of indirect taxes on prices. Section I briefly discusses, and provides examples to illustrate, the two major problems involved in specifying indirect taxes in econometric models. The general nature of the specifications of indirect tax functions and indirect tax rates in price formation equations in the selected econometric models is discussed in Section II. In Section III, the dynamic incidence of indirect taxation is investigated with the help of price and wage dynamics as incorporated in these models. Section IV consists of a few concluding remarks.

I. Problems of Specification of Indirect Taxes

Modern incidence theory makes a basic distinction between tax incidence on the supply side (or the sources of income) and incidence on the demand side (or the uses of income). When the impact of changes in indirect taxation is estimated using econometric models that reflect this kind of distinction, there is a definite improvement in both analytical rigor and quantitative results. An application of this theory is, however, extremely difficult. First, the myriad of interacting forces affecting the supply and demand schedules in different markets are difficult to quantify. Second, even if this difficulty is overcome, the theory of tax incidence has little to say about how indirect tax rate changes can be incorporated in the behavioral responses of the market mechanism.

Overcoming the first problem is relatively easy, at least in principle. Choosing a proper framework for the effects of indirect tax rate changes on prices will essentially depend on the use for which an econometric model is designed. At one extreme is the highly aggregative Keynesian model of income determination that is often extremely important qualitatively but seldom is acceptable to either econometricians or policymakers. At the other extreme is the logically consistent, but often unmanageable, general equilibrium analysis that incorporates even minor effects in its multimarket model of the economy, and consequently generates results that are difficult to assess from the standpoint of significance or reliability. Somewhere in between these limits lies the ideal model, which is both manageable and yields meaningful results on tax incidence.

The second problem is, perhaps, the more difficult one to tackle since it involves the element of time in an important way. Modern incidence theory, which deals with static incidence, can only attempt to explain the comparative-static effects of changes in equilibrium values. Policymakers, however, are interested not only in immediate effects but also in the time profile of effects. If, for instance, a policymaker is contemplating changes in a tax system to redistribute income in a desired direction, he is interested in the tax effects on income, employment, and prices—not only the effects in the immediate period after these tax changes are established but also the tax effects on saving, investment, and economic growth in later periods.

Broadly speaking, econometricians face at least two major problems in specifying indirect taxes in econometric models in order to measure the effects of incidence and shifting: (i) the general aggregation problem and (ii) the choice of an appropriate hypothesis to use in translating indirect tax rate changes into price changes in order to account for dynamic incidence. Both of these problems will be dealt with separately in this section.

1. the aggregation problem

The aggregation of indirect taxes is linked with the general problem of aggregation of production and consumption activities. The basic aggregation problem in formulating more flexible and more general functional forms to be used in econometric models is to maintain consistency of macrobehavioral relationships with regard to the aggregation of distinct commodities, whether in production or consumption. The meaning of “consistency” can be best explained by means of two simple examples, beginning with production activity.

Consider n commodities produced in n different firms, each with its own production function and each using specialized labor, so that wage rates differ between firms. The inverse demand function for labor for the ith firm, under the profit maximization assumption, is given by

w i = p i q i ( L i ) , i = 1 , n ( 1 )

where Wi = nominal wage rate in the ith firm

Pi = producer price of the ith good

Li = labor input in the production of ith good

qi=qiLi = marginal productivity of labor.

Since the econometrician has to design a model containing only a limited number of equations, the n equations given in expression (1) have to be aggregated by means of a suitable price index P; a quantity index Q; an aggregate production function, Q(L), of the labor input index L; and a wage index W. Thus, the microequations given by (1) have to be transformed in the macrorelation

W = P Q ( L ) ( 1 )

and, depending on the desired degree of disaggregation of production activities in an econometric model, the number of macrorelations of the type (1′) should correspond to the degree of disaggregation. The consistency requirement imposes the restriction that the total wage income in the aggregate (i.e., WL) equals the sum of wage income by firms (i.e., ΣwiLi).1

In econometric applications, the aggregate macrorelation (1′) has three variables: W, P, and L. Given any two of these variables, however defined (i.e., exogenously or endogenously), the remaining variable is obtained as a solution of (1′). A great majority of the econometric models surveyed in this paper tend to determine all these variables endogenously, in order to evaluate the connection between the various sectors in the models.2

Consider the aggregation of consumption activities. For the sake of simplicity, assume that the n commodities produced are consumed by households, and that indirect taxes (τi) are levied on consumption of these commodities on an ad valorem basis. Let Cd and Cs be the aggregate demand for, and supply of, consumer goods in nominal terms so that

C d = Σ n p i ( 1 + τ i ) q i

denotes consumers’ outlays on the n commodities, and

C s = Σ n p i q i

denotes the producers’ sales receipts; hence the difference

T I = C d C s = Σ n τ i p i q i

is the yield of indirect taxes levied at rates τi. Assume that the market prices of the consumer goods can be suitably aggregated into a single price index for consumer goods (Pc). The difference between the consumer price and the producer price of the ith commodity is the per unit yield of indirect taxation on that commodity. The consistency of aggregation of prices requires that there be a relationship between the consumer goods price index (Pc) and the producer price index (P). This can be written as

P c = P ( 1 + τ ) ( 2 )

where τ is an idex of indirect tax rates (τi s). Further, since the production of qis is already indexed by Q, and if the system is in static equilibrium, the yield of indirect taxes can be expressed as

T I = τ P Q ( 3 )

That (3) indeed holds true in static equilibrium can be shown as follows: The nominal outlay on consumption can be expressed as

C d = P c Q d ( 4 )

while the nominal sales revenues of producers is given by

C s = P Q s ( 5 )

where Qd and Q8 represent the demand for, and supply of, aggregated output. In equilibrium

Q d = Q s = Q ( 6 )

Hence, the money yield of indirect taxes, which is the difference between Cd and Cs is given by (3).

Several observations about the above exposition of the nature of aggregation are in order. First, given the real demand for consumer goods (Qd), it is relatively easy—at least in principle—to aggregate indirect taxes and study the results of their incidence. Second, if an econometric model is highly aggregative, such that there is only one aggregate consumption demand (Qd), the differential impact of changes in individual indirect tax rates cannot be captured, since the aggregate index τ would behave as a general sales tax on all commodities. Clearly, if the policymaker is interested in the differential impacts of selective changes in indirect tax rates, there must be an appropriate degree of disaggregation of real consumption demands. Third, and related to the second observation above, is the issue of balanced budget incidence. In an econometric model with an aggregative consumption function, the financing of additional government expenditure by raising equivalent indirect tax revenue—for example, using sales tax A rather than sales tax B—would have the same balanced budget impact on private demand in both cases. In the real world, however, the balanced budget impact might be different in each case because of possible differences in the elasticity of consumption demand for different commodities, as well as possible differences in their supply elasticities. Fourth, in real economies, not all production is subjected to indirect taxation. The bulk of indirect taxation covers some consumer goods, while numerous other consumer goods are exempted. Accordingly, the indirect tax yield equation (3) should employ taxable commodities, rather than output Q. This could be done by some simple functional form, such as TI = a + bPQd) or TI = APQd)λ where λ is a parameter that reflects the actual base of indirect taxation. Fifth, the pure forms of equations (2) and (3) assume static equilibrium, while most econometric models incorporate dynamic elements to approximate reality. Hence, both these equations should have dynamic characteristics. Finally, in real situations, actual aggregate demand need not equal either actual production or potential output; therefore, there is an additional reason for modifying the pure form of the indirect tax yield equation (3).

A few words may be said about the general functional forms of production and consumption activities commonly employed in econometric models. In most models, the general functional forms—in particular, those used for consumption—recognize two important responses: substitution effects and income effects. Since these effects originate from microanalysis of consumer preferences, such functional forms generally embody implicit, often restrictive, assumptions regarding consumer preferences.

Most recent theoretical investigations of general functional forms point out that the conditions for perfect aggregation of producer and consumer demand models (based on microeconomic theory) are rather stringent.3 Although less restrictive theoretical functional forms have been developed, these have yet to be applied in econometric models.4 Consequently, econometric models make do with some of the more restrictive functional forms. However, this does not mean that econometric models apply ad hoc functional forms. A good many of the econometric models employ general functional forms that embody the concept of separability. This concept or idea allows commodities to be grouped in such a way that goods that interact closely (in the yielding of utility) are grouped together and treated as one commodity, while goods which are in different groups either do not interact or interact in only a general way. The degree of such grouping of commodities determines the extent of disaggregation that allows “reasonable” consistency in aggregation.5

As our interest in aggregation is primarily with regard to the incidence of indirect taxes, we should understand the implications of linear and nonlinear versions of the consumption functions (these versions include the permanent income hypothesis). Theoretical investigations of linear aggregation of consumer demand for individuals with identical tastes point out that macroresponse coefficients depend not only on the individual responses but also on the distribution of responses and incomes of consumers. This implies that linear aggregation of consumer demands do not, in general, satisfy the consistency requirement even if income distribution does not change.6 Most nonlinear aggregate consumption demand functions also do not satisfy the consistency requirement, as far as changes in income distribution are concerned. On balance, since consumers are not expected to have identical tastes and since income distribution may change in one way or another from time to time, it appears that aggregate consumer demand functions that satisfy, even approximately, the conditions for consistent aggregation do not exist.7

The preceding discussion facilitates an understanding of the problem of aggregation and its implications for the incidence of indirect taxes. For instance, if there is reason to believe that changes in certain indirect taxes may alter the consumption mix of consumers (such as increases in indirect taxes affecting consumption of luxury goods), or that there will be certain income distributional effects because of changes in the composition of output, it is likely that the existing general functional forms will bias the policy effects in such models. The extent of such bias and/or its direction is, of course, difficult to ascertain. One should at least be aware it exists and, if possible, anticipate its direction.

2. the problem of dynamic incidence

Static equilibrium analysis cannot deal with continuing effects of a given (indirect) tax policy, since most concepts of conventional economics, which hold rigorously in static general equilibrium, are not necessarily valid in a dynamic world where adjustment of prices and quantities does not take place instantaneously. In static analysis, the passing on of an indirect tax rate change to consumers alters the equilibrium price level. The chain, or the process, of price and quantity changes that involve time in an important way, however, is unknown. Also, most indirect taxes are, in the short or long run, treated as a part of business cost, and therefore passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices; but it is not known how fast this happens, or what the size of such forward shifting is during an inflationary period.

It may be argued that since static incidence analysis states that indirect taxes are, at least partially, passed on to consumers, a reduction in their rates ought to slow down inflation. A reduction in indirect taxation may well lower business costs, and therefore provide incentives to expand output. At the same time, it increases purchasing power, and therefore raises aggregate demand. The net result is unclear. If, however, the dynamics of inflation were such that it would eventually stop at some future date and prices would converge to a new, and higher, level, then it is possible that the new equilibrium price level would be lower than it would have been in the absence of an indirect tax reduction. It is, therefore, realistic to assume that a more satisfactory analysis of incidence of indirect taxes can be made in the context of macroeconomic theory, which attempts to integrate the dynamic elements of price and quantity adjustments.8

The dynamics of incidence of indirect taxes is, thus, an integral part of disequilibrium economics. Since much of the recent work in disequilibrium economics began because of the inadequacy of classical price dynamics in explaining movements in prices, wages, and output, a convenient approach to the problem of dynamic incidence will be to discuss it in the context of disequilibrium price and wage behavior.9

Most econometric models utilize some variants of the general theoretical structure of the markup hypothesis for their price formation equations. The basic premise of the markup hypothesis is that prices are set as a markup over “standard” or “normal” costs.10 The normal cost is a longer-run concept based on the underlying production function. Its strict use implies that temporary changes in costs arising from short-term variations in productivity are considered transient phenomena, and therefore need not be reflected in prices. The basic hypothesis can be modified so that temporary changes in costs may influence prices, though this influence need not be permanent.11 The markup over cost may also be influenced by an excess or deficiency of aggregate demand relative to supply.12

The markup hypothesis of price behavior has several advantages in application to econometric models. First, although the basic hypothesis assumes an underlying production function, its modifications incorporate both long-run and short-run features. Second, it recognizes the importance of the cost of capital, which heavily influences the optimal pricing decision in the long run. Surprisingly enough, as we shall see, most econometric models omit this variable in their price-formation equations.13 Third, and related to the issue of optimal pricing, the markup hypothesis can easily lend itself to other concepts of long-run prices—such as the target-return pricing formula of Eckstein (1964).14 Fourth, the incorporation of indirect taxes can be carried out easily in the markup hypothesis, since such taxes can be considered as part of normal costs.15 Finally, the markup hypothesis does not require competitive conditions for its validity.16 This is an important factor, especially in view of the monopolistic elements in the real world.17 Therefore, this hypothesis is suitable for a satisfactory analysis of the shifting of indirect taxes.

In the markup hypothesis, the greatest influence on prices is the wage rate, because the latter constitutes the bulk of normal costs. Hence, variations in wage rates resulting from the inflation-real output (or inflation-unemployment) tradeoff, or other causes such as increases in wages through collective bargaining, will cause price changes. Further, since price adjustments do not take place instantaneously, the speed of adjustment of prices in response to changes in their determinants must have some dynamic pattern. Consequently, the nature of the dynamic incidence of indirect taxes depends not only on the basic price behavior hypothesis but also on how the price and wage adjustment equations incorporate dynamic elements. Wage adjustments, on the other hand, are believed to explain the behavior of unemployment, in the sense that there exists some relationship between the rate of change of money wages and the level of unemployment. In fact, in most econometric models, the latter hypothesis is an essential ingredient in capturing the dynamics of disequilibria among prices, wages, employment, and output.

In order to appreciate the nature of dynamic incidence of indirect taxes, the following examples of price and wage adjustment equations may be useful.

Assume that basic price behavior is determined by markup hypothesis, so that the target, or desired, price can be written as 18

P T = λ K Q N + U L C N + τ i P 1 + τ i ( 7 )

where λ is the target rate of return on capital stock K; QN is the normal output; ULCN is standard unit labor cost; τi is the rate of indirect taxation; and P is the market price of output.19 Without loss of generality (i.e., by properly choosing output and employment levels), we may write ULCN = W, where W is the money wage rate.

Analogous to desired pricing, we assume that labor unions perceive a target or desired wage rate WT, which is a function of market price P (a proxy for the cost of living index) and current money wage W. That is,

W T = α P + β W ( 8 ) 20

If we postulate price and wage adjustments that depend on excess demand in the product and factor markets, as well as on the discrepancy between the target price and wage, respectively, we may write them as

P ˙ / P = a 1 X + a 2 ( P t P P ) + a 3 W ˙ W , a i > 0 ( 9 )

and

W ˙ / W = b 1 u + b 2 ( W t W W ) , b i > 0 ( 10 )

where X is the real excess demand for output (i.e.,X=QQNQN, Q is the real actual demand) and u=LNLLN is the unemployment rate.

Equations (9) and (10) generate the dynamics in the system, where producers attempt to obtain their price target PT, and labor its desired wage rate WT. If the desired price and wage are achieved, the dynamic system comes to rest and equilibrium is achieved (i.e., excess demand is zero so that Q = QN and the unemployment rate (u) is zero).21 This dynamic system, however, does not guarantee that the real wage offer by producers (WP)1 equals the real wage claim by labor (WP)2 when the system comes to rest. This can easily be shown by solving forWP from equations (9) and (10), by setting P˙P=0=W˙W, and utilizing equations (7) and (8). In fact, it is seen that

( W P ) 1 = 1 τ i 1 + τ i ρ ( 11 )

and

( W P ) 2 = α 1 β ( 12 )

where ρ=λKPQN is a constant in equilibrium.

Clearly, there is no reason to believe that the real wage rate equations (11) and (12) should be equal to each other. In order to achieve consistency (i.e., equality between (WP)1and(WP)2) in equilibrium, the model has to be closed by adding equations determining the demand for, and supply of, labor and output.

A few comments may be made here since a large number of econometric models utilize variants of this type of price and wage adjustment mechanism, which embodies a short-run Phillips curve relationship. First, indirect taxes can easily be incorporated into price formation behavior based on a modified markup hypothesis. The dynamic pattern of incidence, however, depends crucially on the nature of the price and wage adjustment equations.22 In this sense, without an explicit specification of dynamic elements in the price and wage adjustment equations, little can be said about the pattern of dynamic incidence on a priori grounds. Second, even if the dynamic elements are properly reflected in the price and wage adjustment equation, the dynamic incidence of indirect taxes can be biased. This is because the system may be inconsistent unless it is properly closed, so that demand and supply equations in the factor and product markets incorporate feedback from the disequilibrium behavior of prices, wages, and unemployment (see equations (11) and (12)). Third, as can be seen from the price and wage adjustment equations, the relationship between wages and unemployment can be shifted by means of changes in indirect taxes. Consequently, the equilibrium level of unemployment, if it exists, is dependent on the level of indirect taxes.23 Fourth, changes in indirect tax rates do not necessarily get passed along to consumers via increased market prices, even though producers may try to pass their increased tax burden along fully by raising their target prices. The passing along may be only partial because of possible offsetting effects on prices, which may fall because of deficient aggregate demand. Finally, in periods of rapid wage increases caused by either rising expectations or other factors not reflected in price and wage adjustment behavior, changes in indirect taxes may have an imperceptible effect on prices. This is because the wage element has a heavy influence on prices.24

The preceding discussion highlights the fact that the problem of dynamic incidence is an integral part of the problem involved in explaining the dynamic behavior of price and quantity adjustments. Further, it suggests that specification of the complexities involved in dynamic analysis is an extremely difficult task for a model builder.

II. Specification of Indirect Taxes in Selected Models

In this section, the specification of indirect taxes outlined in the preceding section is discussed with reference to the IS-LM structures (principally the IS structures) of 18 econometric models, 7 of which describe the U. S. economy. The remaining models describe the Canadian, Australian, German (Fed. Rep.), Japanese, British, Austrian, Finnish, and New Zealand economies. The 18 econometric models, of which the first 7 are models of the U. S. economy, are as follows: 25

  • 1. The Brookings Model (James S. Duesenberry, Gary Fromm, Lawrence R. Klein, and Edwin Kuh)

  • 2. The Data Resources (DRI) Model (Otto Eckstein, Edward W. Green, and associates)

  • 3. The Wharton Long-Term Annual and Industry Forecasting Model (Ross S. Preston)

  • 4. The MIT-PENN-SSRC (MPS) Model (Albert Ando, Franco Modigliani, and Robert Rasche)

  • 5. The Michigan Econometric (DHL-III) Model (Saul H. Hymans and Harold T. Shapiro)

  • 6. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) Model (Albert A. Hirsch, Maurice Liebenberg, and George R. Green)

  • 7. The Wharton Mark III Model (Michael D. McCarthy)

  • 8. The RDX2 (Bank of Canada) Model (John F. Helliwell, Harold T. Shapiro, and associates)

  • 9. The University of Toronto Quarterly (Toronto) Forecasting Model (Gregory V. Jump)

  • 10. The TRACE Mark III R (University of Toronto) Annual Econometric Model of the Canadian Economy (John A. Sawyer)

  • 11. The RBA1 (Reserve Bank of Australia) Model (W.E. Norton and J. F. Henderson)

  • 12. An Econometric Model of the Australian (H-F) Economy (C. I. Higgins and V. W. Fitzgerald)

  • 13. The Bonn Model of the German Economy (W. Krelle and G. Grisse)

  • 14. The EPA Master Model (Quarterly Model of the Japanese Economy) (Economic Research Institute, Economic Planning Agency)

  • 15 The London Business School Quarterly Econometric (LBS) Model (London Graduate School of Business Studies)

  • 16. The Austria Link Model (Macroeconometric Model for the Austrian Economy) (Bernhard Boehm and Stefan Schleicher)

  • 16. The Bank of Finland Model (On the Use of Two-Stage Least Squares with Principal Components: An Experiment with a Quarterly Model) (Juhani Hirvonen)

  • 17. The New Zealand (Reserve Bank of New Zealand) Model (R. S. Deane).

All the models attempt to capture both the cyclical and trend characteristics of the economies they purport to represent. In other words, the models reflect stock-flow relations, lag structures, and nonlinearities which cause fluctuations when subjected to shocks. The extent of capturing these fluctuations varies greatly between models because of both their structural differences and their differences in the standardization of endogenous and exogenous variables. In addition, differences in the initial conditions cause considerable variation in the performance of such models.26

Most of the econometric models, although they treat the underlying determinants of income and demand in varying degrees of aggregation, have placed less emphasis on industry production and output. The degree of disaggregation of the production sector, with the exceptions of the Brookings, the Wharton Long-Term, and the Wharton MK III models, is limited. This limitation is even more severe in most of the non-U. S. econometric models. In general, although output is primarily expenditure-determined, a majority of the models employ an aggregate production function, often of the Cobb-Douglas variety, to derive the demand for labor and capital. The latter demand, in the context of stock-adjustment theory, gives rise to investment demand in such models.

In varying degrees, the models have disaggregated the expenditure components of GNP. The extent of such disaggregation is relatively greater in the U. S. models, especially with regard to investment demand and inventory changes. The disaggregation of the fiscal sector, though quite substantial in such models as the DRI and the RDX2, is limited in most models. The financial sectors are more disparate. They range from the highly disaggregated financial sectors of the DRI, the MPS, the RDX2, and the Bonn models to the much less disaggregated financial sectors of the DHL-Ill, the BEA, the New Zealand, and the Japanese EPA models.

Despite differences in scale, purpose, and internal emphasis between the real and financial sectors, the econometric models can be seen as elaborate and complex variants of the simple Hicksian IS-LM framework. In this section, the focus is on the specification of indirect taxes in the consumption sector and on the price equations of the selected models.27

1. indirect taxes in the consumption sector

In general, these econometric models have disaggregated the consumption demand of the private sector into a few major categories. Departure from the basic division of consumption among durables, non-durables, and services is found in a majority of the models.28 At one extreme, with an aggregate consumption function, is the Bonn model; at the other extreme, the DRI and the Wharton Long-Term models have, respectively, 13 and 11 consumption demand categories. The theoretical underpinnings of real consumption demands, in all but the Bonn model,29 adhere to some form of the permanent income hypothesis—through distributed lags on real disposable income or through lagged consumption variables. While this is true for most categories of consumption demand, in some models the treatment of consumption of non-durables (and of food consumption in the DRI) employs variants of the Keynesian absolute income hypothesis. In addition, while most models consider relative price effects, a few models also consider real balance effects, interest rate effects, and the effects of the past stock of durables. Some models also consider the effects of unemployment and population.30

In Section I, it was pointed out that consistent aggregation of consumption in a general functional form does not generally account for shifts in income distribution. This is indeed true in these models. While the models disaggregate consumption demand in varying degrees, none has disaggregated disposable income, although a few models (such as the Brookings and the RDX2) have distinguished between wage and non-wage incomes. Moreover, although the underlying theory of consumption behavior is substantially the same in most models, actual specification of consumption functions differs materially. For instance, a large number of models employ a measure of permanent income that uses distributed lag weights on current and past disposable incomes, while others employ current disposable income and a lagged consumption term (sometimes even two-period lagged consumption, as in the RDX2).31 Also, inclusion of other variables (real balances, unemployment, etc.) in the consumption functions affects both the short-run and long-run marginal propensities to consume (MPCs).32 Further, although most models allow relative price effects, not all models allow the relative price effects in all individual disaggregated consumption functions.33

Several implications for the effects of changes in indirect taxes follow from the general nature of consumption functions as found in the models. First, the inclusion of aggregate disposable income in consumption functions implies that changes in indirect taxes that cause shifts in income distribution cannot properly account for differential income effects, except to the extent that such changes affect aggregate disposable income. But the models can capture the differential price effects. Second, two different indirect tax measures which cause different shifts in income distribution, but cause equivalent changes in aggregate disposable income, have the same income effects; any differential effects they may have on aggregate consumption reflect the differential effects of relative prices. Third, a change in indirect taxes will have different effects, depending on the size of MPCs, since different specifications of consumption functions, although they embody the same underlying permanent income hypothesis, may give rise to differences in the MPCs between models. Fourth, although there are considerable differences in the MPCs between different categories of consumption within each model, differential impacts of changes in indirect taxes cannot be properly accounted for because shifts in income distribution are not reflected in aggregate disposable income (although relative price effects are). Finally, in models that either ignore relative price effects (such as the Bonn model) or do not incorporate these in all the disaggregated consumption demands (many models do this), the principal indicator of the pattern of shifting and incidence of indirect taxes is the income effect (via disposable income) of changes in such taxes.

Consistency in the aggregation of indirect taxation is also important, since the effects of rate changes are felt not only by the real sector; such rate changes produce feedback between the real and financial sectors via the government budget constraint and other macroaggregates, which are common to both of these sectors.34 We now examine the indirect tax functions in the models.

The fact that indirect taxation covers not only most of consumption but also other components of gross national product (GNP) is reflected in most models. Except for three U.S. models (Wharton MK III, DHL-Ill, BEA) and three non-U.S. models (Bonn, EPA, Austria Link) where aggregate indirect tax yields are simply related to either gross domestic product or national income, the fiscal sector of most models disaggregates indirect taxes into consumption taxes and other categories (tariffs, state and local taxes), and attempts to specify the tax functions in terms of the relevant bases, rates, and other variables that affect their yields.35

In most models, the stress on indirect taxation has been on consumption. In general, there are two types of functional forms preferred by most models, (1) TI = A(τC)λ or (2) TI = a + b Σ τiCi. The Brookings, MPS, BEA, and Finland models have the form (1) for individual categories of consumption, while most others have the form (2) or variants of it in which a broader definition of tax base that includes more than consumption is employed.36 The RDX2 is the only model which employs the most consistent aggregation of indirect tax yield, in that it has TIi=τiCiandTI=ΣTIi..37 For import taxes and other import fees and surcharges, most models relate their yields to taxable imports/total imports and GDP. In some models, either or both of these tax yields are treated exogenously.38 It may be pointed out that, to the extent such indirect taxes are treated exogenously, the model cannot properly reflect the feedback between the real and financial sectors via the government budget constraint.39 Also, the relevant indirect tax rates that are a suitable average index of effective rates over the class or category of goods in question are treated as fiscal policy instruments in a number of models. For consistency of aggregation, these rates must enter into price equations as, indeed, they do in some models.40

The preceding discussion should suffice to highlight the nature of aggregation and its implications for the effects of indirect taxes in the selected econometric models, in particular, the probable importance of shifts in income distribution that may be caused by rate changes in the long run. Regarding the aggregation of indirect tax yields, this aspect of the problem is taken care of, in a limited sense, in most models. We now proceed to examine the incorporation of indirect taxes in price equations.

2. indirect taxes in price equations

There is considerable divergence in the manner of incorporating indirect tax rates in the models. The divergence between models arises mainly for three reasons: (i) differences in the level of aggregation of prices, (ii) differences in the mode of specifying the price formation equations, and (iii) differences in incorporating indirect tax rates, as well as defining such rates, in the price equations. It is beyond the scope of this paper to discuss in detail the differences in the price formation equations between models.41 However, a general overview of this topic is attempted in the ensuing discussion.

In the models, the price equations determine both an aggregate price index and a number of price indices for goods and services, commensurate with the level of disaggregation of the real sector.42 Although the models utilize some variants of the markup hypothesis, they differ in their approach to incorporation of the hypothesis in price equations.43 Most models have employed either of the following two basic approaches: (i) the one-stage price determination approach, in which the prices of the goods and services are individually based on the markup hypothesis, and (ii) the two-stage price determination approach, in which some basic sectoral prices (such as the commonly employed price deflator for gross nonfarm business product) are determined by the markup hypothesis in the first stage. In the second stage, these basic prices are utilized as explanatory variables, among other relevant explanatory variables, to determine the deflators for final demand for goods and services. A few models combine these two basic approaches, in that deflators for some components of GDP (especially the consumer price index) are determined separately, while deflators for other components of GDP are determined by the two-stage approach.

The one-stage approach is utilized by seven non-U.S. models only, viz., the RDX2, RBA1, H-F, Bonn,44 EPA, Austria Link, and New Zealand models. Those employing a mix of the two basic approaches are the MPS, Toronto, and LBS models. The remaining models employ the two-stage approach to price determination. Irrespective of the approach of price determination, the consistency criterion for price aggregation, as discussed in general terms in Section I, has been met by all the models. For instance, the aggregate consumer price index Pc is obtained by taking the weighted average of the price deflators for various categories of consumption.45

It is difficult to ascertain the intrinsic superiority of either one of these approaches to price determination. It could be argued that the one-stage approach to price determination might be preferable, since it relates each price directly to its determinants; this is because unit labor cost is one of the principal determinants of prices and, since this variable is an aggregate index of interindustry unit labor costs, one-stage price determination might be more sensitive to changes in wages and productivity. On the other hand, it could be argued that price deflators for the components of GDP are, themselves, convenient aggregate indices of industry prices weighted by the fraction of industry outputs that go into a unit of final demand. Consequently, it might be preferable to determine the industry or sectoral prices first, which, in turn, could be utilized to explain the deflators of components of GDP. In other words, the two-stage approach to price determination might be more logical.46

The case for the intrinsic superiority of the one-stage approach to price determination appears to be weak, in view of the logic of the two-stage approach. This is also reflected in the models, since a majority of them utilize the two-stage approach. In these models, although there are substantial differences in two-stage price formation, unit labor costs and demand pressures through capacity utilization are the main determinants of sectoral prices. Sometimes, changes in labor productivity and other cyclical factors also enter into these price equations. In the second stage, the price equations for components of GDP utilize sectoral prices as important determinants of their behavior.

The most interesting cases of two-stage price determination are found in the Brookings and Wharton Long-Term models. In these two models, in the first stage the sectoral or industry value-added prices are determined by the markup hypothesis. In the second stage, these prices are converted into consistent final demand price indices using the price-output conversion technique that utilizes an input-output framework. The only difference between the Brookings model and the Wharton Long-Term model is that the former employs a static Leontief input-output table, while the latter bases its input-output table on variable coefficients obtained from sectoral constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production functions.47

With the exception of the EPA, the Finland, and the New Zealand models, indirect tax rates are incorporated in the price equations of all the above-mentioned models. As distinct from the level of price aggregation, which corresponds to the level of aggregation of the real sector, the level of aggregation of indirect tax rates follows neither the level of aggregation of indirect tax yield functions nor that of prices. As a result, in most models the components of final demand, such as imports (which are subjected to indirect taxation and for which there are customs receipt functions), do not often have the corresponding indirect tax rates specified in their price equations. Also, in models such as the Wharton MK III, some of the categories of consumption demand, such as services or “other nondurables,” do not incorporate indirect tax rates in their respective price equations. On the other hand, with the exception of a few models such as the Toronto model, import tariffs generally do not enter into the price equations of consumption categories.

In general, indirect taxes enter into the price equations of various categories of consumption, either as average rates in the GDP deflator or as commodity-group average rates. The typical form of the aggregate indirect tax rate, hereinafter called the A-type specification, is

P y = P x X + T 1 X = P x + i ( 13 )

where Py is the implicit GDP deflator, Px is the GDP deflator at factor cost, τ = TI/X is the aggregate average indirect tax rate, and X is the GDP at constant base-year prices.

The commodity-group average indirect tax rate specification, hereinafter called the B-type specification, has two alternative forms:

P i m ( t ) = λ i m ( t , T ) U L C ( t ) + γ i m ( t , T * ) τ i ( t ) + ω i m ( t ) ( 14 )
o r P i f ( t ) = P i m ( t ) l + τ i ( t ) = λ i f ( t , T ) U L C ( t ) + γ i f ( t , T * ) τ i ( t ) + ω i f ( t ) ( 14 )

where Pim and Pif are the ith sectoral market price and factor price, respectively. The symbolsλi and represent T and T*-period lag structures on unit labor cost ULC and indirect tax rate τi, respectively. Other factors influencing prices, including lagged prices, are denoted by wim and wif. A variant of the B-type, which uses lagged prices as explanatory variables, has the form

P i ( t ) = λ i ( t , T ) U L C ( t ) + l i ( t , T * ) τ i ( t ) P i ( t 1 ) + w i ( t ) ( 14 " )

where Pi could be either the market price or factor price, in which case Pi=Pif=Pim1+τi,λi is a T-period lag structure, while li is a T*-period lag structure associated with the product variable τi (t) Pi(t - 1). The variable ωi is as before, but excludes lagged prices.

The models which have the exact A-type specification of indirect taxes in price equations are the BEA, TRACE, and Austria Link models. The MPS model has a variant of the A-type equation, in that the implicit deflator for gross nonfarm business product, Pxbnf is defined as

P X B N F = ( 1 λ ) P X B 1 τ + 100 λ ,

where PXB is the price deflator of gross nonfarm business product determined by the markup hypothesis, λ is the proportion of household product to gross nonfarm business product, and τ is the indirect tax rate defined as the ratio of indirect tax receipts to gross nonfarm business product.48 With the exception of the EPA, Finland, and New Zealand models, the models under consideration have the B-type specification of indirect taxes, mostly the B(14) type, irrespective of whether they have one-stage or two-stage price formation equations.49

The Toronto model, however, is an interesting case. It has variants of both A- and B(14)-type specifications. The private GDP deflator is a variant of the A type, but is based on the markup hypothesis, which also incorporates the unit price of imports, while consumer prices are based on the B(14) type, with both import prices plus tariffs and lagged values of private GDP deflators added to the markup hypothesis. While the Brookings,50 Wharton Long-Term, and DRI models belong to the B(14)-type specification, the Wharton MK III is a particularly interesting case of B(14)-type specification. It first determines the manufacturing price by the markup hypothesis, and then utilizes this price in the price equations for various consumptions, along with commodity group indirect tax rates (defined as the tax yield over the commodity group divided by the value of the group consumption). In the DHL-III model, only changes in excise tax rates are specified in B(14)-type price equations for gross nonfarm business product. Later, this price variable is utilized in a double-logarithmic price equation for consumption goods. The only model with both B(14’)- and B(14”)-type specifications of indirect taxes in price equations is the RDX2 model.51

A few comments should be made about these specifications of indirect taxes, as well as the definition of such rates generally employed by the models. First, despite differences in the incorporation of indirect taxes, the incidence and shifting of such taxes in the models are, ceteris paribus, in the same direction as would be expected from the static theory of incidence.52 In both A-type and B-type (and their variants, as in the MPS and other models) specifications, a change in the indirect tax rate influences prices in the same direction. The only difference between these two types of specification is that a change in τ is fully passed on to the general price level in an A-type specification, while it is partially passed on for a corresponding change in τ in the B-type specification. In addition, to the extent that other prices of GNP components are functions of Py (as, indeed, they are in the MPS, BEA, TRACE, and Austria Link models), there is relatively more quantity adjustment than price adjustment in models of the A type, especially if Py is lagged in the other price equations, compared with models of the B type.

Second, in all the A-type models the response of Px, the price deflator for gross nonfarm business product, to a change in τ is mainly through quantity adjustments. If this response is a weak one, the burden of adjustment falls mostly on the gross farm product deflator, which is determined residually in such models. In contrast, in the B(14)-type models prices respond to changes in the value of τ, both through quantity and other price adjustments. In other words, the relative price effects are well taken care of in the B(14)-type models.53 Third, in a large number of models, of either the A type or the B type, the definition of τi is

τ i = T i B a s e

where Ti is the indirect tax yield of the ith category. Base could be GDP or other relevant bases—consumption of durables, nondurables, and the like. Since both Ti and Base are endogenous variables in such models, the indirect tax rate so defined is also endogenous and is not a policy instrument. (This, of course, is important.) Thus, even though there need not be any discretionary indirect tax measures, there can be variation in τi because of nonproportional variations in Ti and Base.54 As a result, endogenous variations in τi can cause changes in prices in such models.55

The synoptic discussion of the models thus far suffices to highlight the nature of aggregation of the consumption sector and the incorporation of indirect taxes in the various models’ price equations. Despite differences between models in their internal emphasis on the aggregation and specification of indirect taxes, the incorporation of such taxes in most models appears to have the basic ingredients of the static incidence theory. With this perspective, it is worth investigating how the dynamics of price-wage movements in the models affect the dynamic pattern of incidence of such taxes.

III. Price-Wage Dynamics and Indirect Taxes in Models

The interconnections of indirect taxation with price and wage dynamics has already been discussed in Section I. Other things being equal, changes in indirect taxation initially tend to alter prices, which, in turn, set into motion interacting forces between prices and wages. The dynamics of such interacting forces determine price-wage movements over time. In this section, the nature of dynamic incidence in econometric models is investigated in the context of price-wage dynamics in the models.

The essence of price-wage dynamics, as found in most models, can be obtained by recasting equations (9) and (10) of Section 1.2 in a more familiar form. Assuming that an econometric model is properly closed, so that there is feedback between excess aggregate demand and unemployment (as is true of most models), these two equations, with slight modifications, can be combined into a semireduced form that yields the general Phillips curve equation.56

f ( Δ P P , Δ W W , u , π ) = 0 ( 15 )

where π denotes expected price inflation.

Since equation (15) is derived from a set of linear relations, it can be written as

Δ W W = α 0 + α 1 Δ P P + α 2 u + α 3 π ( 16 )

where the αi s are appropriate parameters such as α1 > 0, α2 < 0, and α3 > 0. Further, if we assume that price expectations are formed on the basis of past rates of actual inflation, we may write 57

π = Σ i = 1 T * α 3 i ( Δ P P ) i , α 3 i 0 f o r a l l i .

Equation (16) can now be put in a form found in most models,

Δ W W = α 0 + α 1 ( t , T * ) Δ P ( t ) P + α 2 u ( 17 )

where α1 (t, T*) is a T*-period lag structure on the rate of actual price change.

None of the models have defined a target price or a target wage equation, as was done in the basic analytical framework in Section 1.2. However, the use in most models of lag structures in price equations suggests that an implicit partial adjustment of actual prices to desired prices is assumed.58 Further, the use of an explicit lag structure in price equations eliminates the need for price adjustment equations. This, indeed, appears to have been the practice in most models. The Phillips curve form (17), as derived from the basic analytical framework, suggests that, even though target prices and wages, as well as inflationary expectations, are not explicit in the models, the incorporation of lag structures in a Phillips curve implies their existence via some partial adjustment mechanism (see footnote 58).

The transmission of the effects of indirect taxation in econometric models may be looked at in terms of their IS-LM structures and the Phillips curve equation. Broadly, we may trace the effect of a change in the indirect tax rate τi. An increase in τi, other things being equal, causes a rise in the market prices of consumer goods. The rise in consumer prices reduces disposable income and, therefore, reduces consumption and aggregate demand. The reduction in aggregate demand leads to a buildup of inventories, and eventually to cutbacks in investment and production. The simultaneous rise in consumer prices tends to push actual wages up. The wage push can, however, be dampened, offset, or even negated by an increase in unemployment owing to production cutbacks. A priori, the movement in actual wages will be determined by the relative, but offsetting, impacts of price changes and rising unemployment (i.e., the size of αi and αi in equation (16) or (17)). It is quite possible that an increase in τi may cause no rise in money wages if the existing level of unemployment is sufficiently high, even though the coefficient of the unemployment variable, as opposed to that of the price change variable, may be relatively smaller (in an absolute sense) in the Phillips curve equation.

At any rate, it is not clear, a priori, that an increase in the indirect tax rate will sustain the initial rise in prices, even when producers try to pass it on fully to consumers. Also, the effects of a change in indirect taxation work by means of the feedback between the real and monetary sectors. An increase in τi, other things being equal, initially tends to reduce the budget deficit, which, in turn, tends to push up interest rates. Rising interest rates cause business to invest less, and this aggravates the downward pressure on aggregate demand even more; feedback will be felt on output, prices, and wages as before. It is likely, however, that the eventual decline in output and aggregate demand will wipe out the initial reduction in the budget deficit, so that the upward shift in the LM curve will be relatively less than the downward shift of the IS curve. This implies that the feedback from the monetary sector counters, to some extent, the depressing effect of an increase in indirect taxation.

The dynamics of the incidence of indirect taxes in these models, in the context of a Phillips curve equation, may now be considered. Recall that the EPA, Finland, and New Zealand models do not incorporate indirect taxes in their price equations—in particular, the consumer price equations—although they do specify indirect tax functions. Of these three, the New Zealand model does not have a Phillips curve equation. As a result, the incidence of indirect taxes in these models is captured only to the extent that changes in such taxes have feedback from the monetary sector to the real sector via the government budget constraint.59 The Phillips curve equation is also absent in two other models—the LBS and the Austria Link.60 The dynamic feedback in these two models is, therefore, improperly specified despite the use of lag structures incorporating indirect tax rates in their price equations. The remaining models have Phillips curve equations, which are reproduced in Table 1.

Table 1.

The Phillips Curve in Models

article image
article image
article image

As Table 1 shows, only a few models have employed variables other than those found in the Phillips curve equation (17). The Brookings model has employed a “rate of change of corporate profits before taxes” variable in its Phillips curve equation, while the MPS model has incorporated “a proportion of cash flow after taxes” variable. The EPA model, on the other hand, uses “corporate savings as a proportion of national income” in its equation. With the exception of the RBA1, Bonn, and Finland models, none of the models under discussion employs labor productivity or its rate of change in the respective Phillips curve equations.61 The only other models employing different variables are the Toronto and the H-F models. In the Toronto model, the use of employer and employee contribution rates for unemployment insurance, and another contribution rate for the Canada Pension Plan, in the Phillips curve equation act as added restraints on the downward movement of wage rates if these rates are increased in times of high unemployment. The more interesting case is the Australian H-F model, in which changes in award wage rates are first determined by the decisions of the National Wage Decision Board and Metal Trade Wage Decision Board.62 The changes in award wage rates are used in the Phillips curve equation to influence the movements of actual wage rates.

The price change variable in the Phillips curve equations of these models is the change in the consumer price index, which is a weighted average index of various categories of consumption. Most of the models, as discussed in Section II, incorporate commodity group indirect taxes in their respective consumer price deflators. A few models, however, employ an aggregate average indirect tax rate. The effects of a change in indirect tax rates in either of these two types of models are transmitted via the change in the consumer price index in the Phillips curve equation. The only difference is that models with an aggregative average indirect tax rate cannot compare the differential impacts of changes in individual commodity group indirect tax rates.

Table 1 reveals several interesting facts. First, although there is variety in the length of the lag structures associated with the unemployment variable in these equations, their modal length appears to be between two and four quarters in most models. The exceptions at the upper end are the RDX2 and RBA1 models that employ lag structures of 7 and 10 quarters, respectively, on their unemployment rates. Second, there is greater variety in the lag structure of the price variable in these equations. A number of models have lag structures or first differences extending as long as 12 quarters. Third, a majority of the models employ nonlinear Phillips curve equations, since the unemployment variable appears in reciprocal form.63 Fourth, a majority of the models capture the cyclical effects of changes in the unemployment rate by taking the harmonic mean difference between average unemployment rates for two periods. Fifth, the Brookings and the Wharton MK III models employ smoothed-out average unemployment rates in their Phillips curve equations.

It is, indeed, difficult to ascertain the pattern of incidence of indirect taxes without knowledge of the dynamic multipliers. However, a priori, it appears that, on the basis of differences in the lag structures between models, and between the price change and unemployment variables in the Phillips curve equations within these models, the effects of changes in indirect taxes are felt for a longer period through the price change variables than through the unemployment variables (see Table 1, where the price variables have longer lags than the unemployment variables). Also, the coefficients associated with the price change variables appear, in general, to be relatively larger than those of the unemployment variables.64

Interestingly enough, the coefficients of both price change and unemployment variables vary widely between models. Among the U. S. models, the estimates of the coefficients of price change variables range from 0.20 in the MPS model to 0.77 in the BEA model. The same estimates for the non-U. S. models range from 0.24, for the first four-quarter price change in the Toronto model, to 0.99, for the first one-quarter price change in the TRACE model. Similarly, estimates of the coefficients of unemployment variables show a wide divergence between U. S. and non-U. S. models.

Other things being equal, since the coefficients associated with the price change variable are significantly larger than those associated with the unemployment variable in all the Phillips curve equations presented in Table 1, it is expected that the positive effect of an increase in indirect taxes would outweigh the negative effect of a rise in unemployment. Therefore, while prices rise, wage rates may also rise with declining employment and output in these models.65

Except for the Brookings and the LBS models, it has not been possible to obtain the dynamic multipliers of changes in indirect tax rates. The dynamic incidence multipliers for these two models are presented in Tables 2 and 3.

Table 2.

Dynamic Multipliers for an Excise Tax Cut in the Brookings Model1

(1954 prices)

article image
Source: Based on Fromm and Taubman (1968), pp. 66-64.

The simulation of changes in excess tax rates from mid-1960 through 1972 are based on excise tax reductions enacted by the U. S. Congress in July 1965. The solution started with the equivalent 1960: III reduction of $2.7 billion in excise taxes.

Table 3.

DYNAMIC MULTIPLIERS FOR A PURCHASE TAX CUT IN THE LBS MODEL1

(1972 prices)

article image
Source: Ball and others (1975), p. 200.

The solution of a sustained reduction in the purchase tax of £100 million per quarter started with the initial conditions of the first quarter of 1972.

Before discussing these dynamic incidence multipliers, a few points need to be made. First, as mentioned above, the Brookings model employs the markup hypothesis to determine the value-added prices that are utilized in an input-output framework to determine price deflators for GDP components. Fromm and Taubman (1968), in carrying out simulation exercises with an excise tax cut, employed the following mode of incorporating ad valorem excise taxes in price equations:

P v i = ( 1 + τ i ) P v i * ( 18 )

where Pvi* is the value-added price based on the markup hypothesis and Pvi is the value-added price after the imposition of ad valorem tax rate τi. As it stands, equation (18) implies a 100 per cent passing along of the tax to consumers. In order to incorporate a different pass-along hypothesis, Fromm and Taubman assume that if firms retain, say, m per cent when τi is cut to τi final demand prices fall from Pi to Pi so that

P ¯ i = 1 m ( τ i τ ¯ i 1 + τ i ) ( 19 )

Second, in the LBS model, on the other hand, the purchase tax τ is incorporated in the price for consumer durables as

P c d = 0.0581 + 2.0757 ( 1 4 Σ 0 3 U L C i ) + 0.0838 τ 0.0045 T i m e + Σ 1 3 α i D u m m y i
α i = 0.0054 , 0.0004 , 0.0012.

In other words, in the LBS model, changes in indirect tax rates are partially passed on to consumers. Third, while the Brookings model has well-specified sectoral Phillips curve equations, the LBS model has none. Finally, the Brookings model has an implicit government budget constraint that assumes all deficits to be money financed; the LBS model has neither an explicit nor an implicit government budget constraint. It has been shown elsewhere66 that fiscal policy effects in the Brookings model are reinforced by the monetary repercussions, so that the effect of an ad valorem-excise tax cut would be expected to be more pronounced in the Brookings model than in the LBS model. On the other hand, it is expected that the absence of a government budget constraint in the LBS model would bias the effects of a cut in the purchase tax.67

The dynamic incidence multipliers, shown in Tables 2 and 3, exhibit several interesting features. First, the dynamic multipliers for GDP and consumption in the Brookings model are greater in magnitude than the corresponding dynamic multipliers in the LBS model.68 Second, the indirect tax cut multipliers for consumption are smaller than those for GDP in the Brookings model, while it is the other way round in the LBS model.69 Third, although the indirect tax cut multipliers for GDP and consumption increase up to the end of eight quarters in both models, they begin to decline in the LBS model thereafter.70 Fourth, an examination of the Brookings model’s dynamic multipliers in Table 2 reveals that the effect of fully passing indirect taxes along to consumers is greater than the effect of partially passing them along (as seen in a comparison of multipliers for 100 per cent and 80 per cent pass-along hypotheses). However, the difference between the effects of passing along 80 per cent and 50 per cent of indirect taxes is relatively smaller than the difference between 100 per cent and 80 percent pass-along hypotheses. Fifth, in both models, cuts in indirect taxes substantially reduce the unemployment rate.71 Sixth, prices fall initially in both models, but economic expansion eventually pushes them back toward their initial levels. In the LBS model, the aggregate price level falls initially following a tax cut, but is pushed back to its original level by the end of eight quarters; however, economic expansion continues to exert upward pressure on prices.

The pattern of dynamic incidence, as shown in Tables 2 and 3, cannot be taken as the general pattern among models. The simulation periods in both the Brookings and LBS models were too short to permit this. Moreover, both these models have disparate IS-LM structures, as well as disparate wage-price dynamics. In fact, there is no Phillips curve equation in the LBS model. Also, the LBS model has lags of no more than five quarters in other structural equations, whereas the Brookings model has approximately eight-quarter lags in some of its structural equations other than the Phillips curve equation.

Even though most models have not simulated the effects of changes in indirect taxes, such simulations would not be of much use in a number of models that have endogenous indirect tax rates in their price equations. In fact, half the models discussed in this paper either do not incorporate indirect tax rates in their price equations (the EPA, Finland, and New Zealand models) or else incorporate them endogenously (the MPS, BEA, Wharton MK III, TRACE, Bonn, and Austria Link models). Of these nine models, the indirect tax functions in the Wharton MK III, TRACE, and Bonn models do not incorporate indirect tax rates exogenously, although they could be easily modified to do so.72 The other six models, however, incorporate indirect tax rates as policy instruments in their respective tax functions. The remaining nine models treat indirect tax rates as policy instruments in price equations, although they are not always incorporated in the indirect tax functions.73

The EPA, Finland, and New Zealand models can simulate the effects of a change in indirect tax rates, since these rates are exogenous in their tax functions, even though their price equations do not incorporate them. In these models, an increase in indirect tax rates initially raises the indirect tax yield, which, in turn, reduces the budget deficit. The reduction in the budget deficit causes a reduction in the money supply to the extent that the amount of high-powered money declines. This causes an upward movement in the interest rate, which, in turn, tends to depress the level of investment (and, consequently, aggregate demand and, eventually, disposable income). At the same time, to the extent that unit labor costs and other determinants of price behavior change following a cutback in production, prices will also change in the same direction. In this way, these models respond to a change in indirect tax rates and can simulate the incidence effects.

As for the other six models that incorporate indirect tax rates as endogenous variables in their price equations, but employ statutory or other kinds of indirect tax rates as policy instruments in their tax functions, the response of these models to a change in indirect tax rates is quite similar to that of the above three models. The only difference in the latter six models is that the increase in prices may be more than it would have been if indirect tax rates were exogenous in the price equations.74 In these six models, the increase in prices will reduce real disposable income, and hence consumption. At the same time, since investment is adversely affected (through the repercussions of budget deficits on the financial sector), this would lead to a further decline in aggregate demand and, in turn, cause output to decline. The decline in output may increase unit labor cost if wages do not fall sufficiently and/or labor productivity does not rise enough so that prices rise more than they would have if indirect tax rates were exogenous in the price equations.75

What, in general, can be said about the incidence of indirect taxation in these models, even though the simulated dynamic multipliers (except for the Brookings and the LBS models) are not available? First, despite wide variety in the IS-LM structures and the methods of aggregation of indirect taxation in these models, the crucial element turns out to be the variety of treatment of indirect taxes in the price equations. Clearly, failure to incorporate indirect tax rates in the price equations results in, at best, improper incidence effects. On the other hand, when models such as the MPS, BEA, and Wharton MK III treat indirect tax rates endogenously in their price equations, they bias the incidence effects and may even cause irregularities in price movements. Second, although other models treat indirect tax rates exogenously in their price equations, a few of them do not incorporate these rates in their indirect tax functions. These latter models also bias the incidence effects of indirect taxation, since such models cannot properly reflect the interaction between the real and financial sectors because of bias in the indirect tax yield that affects the budget deficit or surplus (although the extent of this bias may be limited). Third, the simulated multipliers for the Brookings and the LBS models cannot be regarded as representative of other models, especially since the incidence effects on consumption differ so markedly between these two models. However, the simulation of incidence in the Brookings and LBS models indicate that the dynamic incidence of indirect taxation is likely to produce the effects predicted by static incidence theory, although the time path and size of the dynamic multipliers may vary among models. Finally, models (such as the Brookings, DRI, RDX2, and Toronto) that treat indirect taxes exogenously in their price equations should be considered better specified in this regard than models that fail to do so.

IV. General Conclusions

The following impressions emerge from this survey of the treatment of indirect taxation in econometric models: First, most econometric models are aggregative in their treatment of the consumption sector. Also, little effort has been made to capture the effects of periodic shifts in income distribution. As a result, the differential impact of indirect taxation is limited in such models.

Second, the substitution effects of price changes are comparable in magnitude to income effects, despite wide variations between models. This suggests that indirect tax measures, to the extent that they affect prices, have an important effect on aggregate demand.

Third, the disaggregation of indirect taxes in terms of their yields has been insufficient relative to the level of disaggregation of the consumption demands in most models. Consequently, the discretionary indirect tax measures are unsatisfactory.

Fourth, disaggregation of indirect tax rates in the price equations has been insufficient relative to the disaggregation of the consumption sector and its corresponding prices. Hence, few models can capture differential impacts of indirect taxation on broad commodity groups.

Fifth, the endogenous treatment of indirect tax rates in some models is a gross error, which not only assigns an improper role to this fiscal instrument but also causes unnecessary bias in the simulation results of such models. This is an important conclusion.

Sixth, the models reveal a wide variety of lag structures, not only between but also within models. Also, the Phillips curve equations have differences in lag structures between the price change variables and the unemployment rates. As a result, it is expected that the time path of incidence of indirect taxation will differ between models. This greatly affects the apparent efficiency of fiscal policy.

Seventh, in periods of rapid wage increases caused either by rising inflationary expectations or other factors not reflected in price-wage adjustment behavior, changes in indirect taxes may have negligible effects on prices. This is because the wage element has a very heavy influence on prices in most models.

Finally, since endogenous inflationary expectations can be represented by lag structures on actual price changes in the price-wage adjustment equations, most models have implicitly incorporated some form of inflationary expectations in their Phillips curve equations.

Three important lessons follow from the above impressions. First, econometricians should not be casual in their treatment of taxes, direct and indirect, in econometric models designed to study stabilization policies. The aggregation of the consumption sector, with its corresponding prices, must include appropriate aggregation of indirect tax rates, as well as indirect tax yield functions. Second, the form for price behavior should be made explicit, and the appropriate lag structures should be employed in wage-price dynamics to reflect feedback between aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Third, and most important, indirect tax rates must be treated exogenously in price equations, in order to properly trace the effects of discretionary indirect tax measures.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

  • Anderson, Leonall C., and Keith M. Carlson,An Econometric Analysis of the Relation of Monetary Variables to the Behavior of Prices and Unemployment,in The Econometrics of Price Determination Conference, ed. by Otto Eckstein (Washington, 1972), pp. 16683. (Hereinafter this book is referred to as The Econometrics of Price Determination.)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ando, Albert,Equations in the MIT-PENN-SSRC Econometric Model of the United States” (mimeographed, University of Pennsylvania, January 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ando, Albert, and others,On the Role of Expectations of Price and Technological Change in an Investment Function,International Economic Review, Vol. 15 (June 1974), pp. 384414.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arrow, Kenneth J. (1959), “Toward a Theory of Price Adjustment,in The Allocation of Economic Resources, ed. by Moses Abramowitz (Stanford University Press, 1959), pp. 4151.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arrow, Kenneth J. (1971), “The Firm in General Equilibrium Theory,in The Corporate Economy, ed. by Robin Morris and Adrian Wood (London, 1971), pp. 68110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bahl, Roy W., and Kenneth L. Shellhammer,Evaluating the State Business Tax Structure: An Application of Input-Output Analysis,National Tax Journal, Vol. 22 (June 1969), pp. 20316.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Roy J., and Martyn Duffy,Price Formation in European Countries,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 34768.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Roy J., and others,Preliminary Simulations with the London Business School Macro-economic Model,in Modelling the Economy, ed. by G. A. Renton (London, 1975), pp. 181212.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barro, R. J.,A Theory of Monopolistic Price Adjustment,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 39 (January 1972), pp. 1726.

  • Barro, R. J., and H. I. Grossman, A General Disequilibrium Model of Income and Employment,American Economic Review, Vol. 61 (March 1971), pp. 8293.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barten, A. P.,Consumer Demand Functions under Conditions of Almost Additive Preferences,Econometrica, Vol. 32 (January-April 1964), pp. 138.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barten, A. P., and S. J. Turnovsky,Some Aspects of the Aggregation Problem for Composite Demand Equations,International Economic Review, Vol. 7 (September 1966), pp. 23159.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barten, A. P., and others,A Note on a Class of Utility and Production Functions Yielding Everywhere Differentiate Demand Functions,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 36 (January 1969), pp. 10911.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benassy, Jean-Pascal (1975), “Neo-Keynesian Disequilibrium Theory in a Monetary Economy,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 42 (October 1975), pp. 50323.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benassy, Jean-Pascal (1976), “The Disequilibrium Approach to Monopolistic Price Setting and General Monopolistic Equilibrium,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 43 (February 1976), pp. 6981.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergson, A.,Real Income, Expenditure Proportionality, and Frisch’s ‘New Methods of Measuring Marginal Utility,’Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 4 (October 1936), pp. 3352.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berndt, E. R., and L. R. Christensen,The Internal Structure of Functional Relationships: Separability, Substitutions, and Aggregation,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 40 (July 1973), pp. 40310.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Betancourt, Roger R.,The Estimation of Price Elasticities from Cross-Section Data under Additive Preferences,International Economic Review, Vol. 12 (June 1971), pp. 28392.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bischoff, Charles W.,The Effect of Alternative Lag Distributions,in Tax Incentives and Capital Spending, ed. by Gary Fromm (The Brookings Institution, Washington, 1971), pp. 61130.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bodkin, Ronald G. (1969), “Real Wages and Cyclical Variations in Employment: A Reconsideration,Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 2 (August 1969), pp. 35374.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bodkin, Ronald G. (1972), “Wage and Price Formation in Selected Canadian Econometric Models,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 36985.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boehm, Bernhard, and Stefan Schleicher, Model Austria Link: Macro Econometric Model for the Austrian Economy, Institute for Advanced Studies (Vienna, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brechling, Frank,The Trade-Off Between Inflation and Unemployment,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76 (July/August 1968), pp. 71237.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brock, W. A.,On Models of Expectations that Arise from Maximizing Behavior of Economic Agents Over Time,Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 5 (December 1972), pp. 34876.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brown, A., and A. Deaton,Surveys in Applied Economics: Models of Consumer Behaviour,Economic Journal, Vol. 82 (December 1972), pp. 1145236.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brown, M., and D. M. Heien,The S-branch Utility Tree: A Generalization of the Linear Expenditure System,State University of New York at Buffalo Economics Department, Discussion Paper No. 18 (mimeographed, 1968).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Byron, R. P.,A Simple Method for Estimating Demand Systems under Separable Utility Assumptions,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 37 (April 1970), pp. 26174.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carlson, J.A., and M. Parkin,Inflation Expectations,Economica, Vol. 42 (May 1975), pp. 12338.

  • Chamberlin, Edward H., The Theory of Monopolistic Competition (Harvard University Press, 1933).

  • Chipman, John S., and others, eds., Preferences, Utility and Demand (New York, 1971).

  • Choudhry, Nurun N. (1976 a), “Integration of Fiscal and Monetary Sectors in Econometric Models: A Survey of Theoretical Issues and Empirical Findings,Staff Papers, Vol. 23 (July 1976), pp. 395440.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choudhry, Nurun N. (1976 b), “Indirect Taxation in Econometric Models: A Schematic Presentation” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, December 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christ, Carl F. (1968), “A Simple Macroeconomic Model with a Government Budget Restraint,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76 (January/February 1968), pp. 5367.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christ, Carl F. (1972), “Discussion of Papers in Session III,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 32532.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christ, Carl F. (1975), “Judging the Performance of Econometric Models of the U.S. Economy,International Economic Review, Vol. 16 (February 1975), pp. 5474.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christenson, C. L.,Variations in the Inflationary Force of Bargaining,American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings of the Sixty-Sixth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (hereinafter referred to as American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings), Vol. 44 (May 1954), pp. 34762.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clower, Robert W. (1965), “The Keynesian Counterrevolution: A Theoretical Appraisal,in The Theory of Interest Rates, ed. by F. H. Hahn and F. P. R. Brechling (London, 1965), pp. 10325.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clower, Robert W. (1967), “A Reconsideration of the Microfoundations of Monetary Theory,Western Economic Journal, Vol. 6 (December 1967), pp. 18.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cramer, J. S.,A Dynamic Approach to the Theory of Consumer Demand,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 24 (February 1957), pp. 7386.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deane, Roderick S., The Reserve Bank’s Model of the New Zealand Economy, Reserve Bank of New Zealand (Wellington, 1974).

  • de Menil, George and Jared J. Enzler,Prices and Wages in the FR-MIT-PENN Econometric Model,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 277308.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dhrymes, P. J.,On a Class of Utility and Production Functions Yielding Everywhere Differentiable Demand Functions,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34 (October 1967), pp. 399408.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dixit, A. K.,On the Optimum Structure of Commodity Taxes,American Economic Review, Vol. 60 (June 1970), pp. 295301.

  • Due, John F. (1953), “Toward a General Theory of Sales Tax Incidence,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 67 (May 1953), pp. 25366.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Due, John F. (1963), “Sales Taxation and the Consumer,American Economic Review, Vol. 53 (December 1963), pp. 107884.

  • Duesenberry, James S., and others, The Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States (Chicago, 1965).

  • Eckstein, Otto,A Theory of the Wage-Price Process in Modern Industry,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 31 (October 1964), pp. 26786.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eckstein, Otto, and David Wyss,Industry Price Equations,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 13365.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eckstein, Otto, and others, “The Data Resources Model: Uses, Structure, and Analysis of the U.S. Economy,International Economic Review, Vol. 15 (October 1974), pp. 595615.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Economic Planning Agency [Japan], Economic Research Institute, EPA Master Model (Quarterly Model, M-111) (mimeographed, Tokyo, 1973).

  • Farrell, Michael J. (1952), “Irreversible Demand Functions,Econometrica, Vol. 20 (April 1952), pp. 17186.

  • Farrell, Michael J. (1953-54), “Some Aggregation Problems in Demand Analysis,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 21(3), (1953-54), pp. 193203.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feige, E. L.,Expectations and Adjustments in the Monetary Sector,in American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 57 (May 1967), pp. 46273.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Friedman, Milton,The Quantity Theory of Money—A Restatement,in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, ed. by Milton Friedman (University of Chicago Press, 1956), pp. 321.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frisch, Ragnar (1936), “Annual Survey of General Economic Theory: The Problem of Index Numbers,Econometrica, Vol. 4 (January 1936), pp. 138.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frisch, Ragnar (1954), “Linear Expenditure Functions,Econometrica, Vol. 22 (October 1954), pp. 505510.

  • Frisch, Ragnar (1959), “A Complete Scheme for Computing all Direct and Cross Demand Elasticities in a Model with Many Sectors,Econometrica, Vol. 27 (April 1959), pp. 17796.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fromm, Gary, ed., Tax Incentives and Capital Spending (The Brookings Institution, Washington, 1971).

  • Fromm, Gary, and Paul Taubman, Policy Simulation with an Econometric Model (The Brookings Institution, Washington, 1968).

  • Fromm, Gary, and Lawrence R. Klein,A Comparison of Eleven Econometric Models of the United States,American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 63 (May 1973), pp. 38593.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Geary, R. C.,A Note on ‘A Constant Utility Index of the Cost of Living,’Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 18 (1950), pp. 6566.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gibson, William E.,Interest Rates and Inflationary Expectations: New Evidence,American Economic Review, Vol. 62 (December 1972), pp. 85465.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberger, A. S. (1967), “Functional Form and Utility: A Review of Consumer Demand Theory,Social Systems Research Institute, University of Wisconsin, Systems Formulation, Methodology, and Policy Workshop Paper No. 6703 (mimeographed, 1967).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberger, A. S. (1969), “Directly Additive Utility and Constant Marginal Budget Shares,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 36 (April 1969), pp. 25154.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldman, S. M., and H. Uzawa,A Note on Separability in Demand Analysis,Econometrica, Vol. 32 (July 1964), pp. 38798.

  • Gordon, R. J.,The Recent Acceleration of Inflation and Its Lessons for the Future,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity :1 (1970), pp. 841.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorman, William M. (1953), “Community Preference Fields,Econometrica, Vol. 21 (January 1953), pp. 6380.

  • Gorman, William M. (1959 a), “Separable Utility and Aggregation,Econometrica, Vol. 27 (July 1959), pp. 46981.

  • Gorman, William M. (1959 b), “The Empirical Implications of a Utility Tree: A Further Comment,Econometrica, Vol. 27 (July 1959), p. 489.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorman, William M. (1961), “On a Class of Preference Fields,Metroeconomica, Vol. 13 (August 1961), pp. 5356.

  • Gorman, William M. (1963), “Additive Logarithmic Preferences: A Further Note,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 30 (February 1963), pp. 5662.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorman, William M. (1965), “Production Functions in which the Elasticities of Substitution Stand in Fixed Proportions to Each Other,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 32 (July 1965), pp. 21724.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorman, William M. (1968), “Conditions for Additive Separability,Econometrica, Vol. 36 (July-October 1968), pp. 605609.

  • Grandmont, Jean-Michel, and Guy Laroque,On Temporary Keynesian Equilibria,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 43 (February 1976), pp. 5367.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Green, Harold A. J. (1961), “Direct Additivity and Consumers’ Behaviour,Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 13 (June 1961), pp. 13236.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Green, Harold A. J. (1964), Aggregation in Economic Analysis (Princeton University Press, 1964).

  • Green, J. R.,Pre-existing Contracts and Temporary General Equilibrium,Harvard University, Department of Economics (unpublished, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grossman, H. I. (1972 a), “A Choice-Theoretic Model of an Income Investment Accelerator,American Economic Review, Vol. 62 (September 1972), pp. 63041.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grossman, H. I. (1972 b), “Money, Interest and Prices in Market Disequilibrium,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 79 (September-October 1972), pp. 94361.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hall, Robert E.,Consumption Versus Income Taxes: Implications for Economic Growth,in National Tax Association, Proceedings of the Sixty-First Annual Conference on Taxation (1969), pp. 12545.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanoch, G.,Production and Demand Models with Direct or Indirect Implicit Additivity,Econometrica, Vol. 43 (May 1975), pp. 395419.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansen, Bent, A Study in the Theory of Inflation (London, 1951).

  • Harberger, Arnold C.,Taxation, Resource Allocation and Welfare,in The Role of Direct and Indirect Taxes in the Federal Revenue System, A Conference Report of the National Bureau of Economic Research and the Brookings Institution (Princeton University Press, 1964), pp. 2570.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helliwell, John F., and others, The Structure of RDX2, Bank of Canada, Staff Research Studies, No. 7, Parts 1 and 2 (Ottawa, 1971).

  • Hicks, John R. (1946), Value and Capital (Oxford, Second Edition, 1946).

  • Hicks, John R. (1956), A Revision of Demand Theory (Oxford, 1956).

  • Hicks, John R. (1963), The Theory of Wages (London, Second Edition, 1963).

  • Higgins, C. I., and V. W. Fitzgerald, An Econometric Model of the Australian Economy, Commonwealth Treasury and Bureau of Census and Statistics (mimeographed, Canberra, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hirvonen, Juhani, On the Use of Two Stage Least Squares with Principal Components, Bank of Finland (Helsinki, 1975).

  • Hirsch, Albert A.,Price Simulations with the OBE Econometric Model,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 23776.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hirsch, Albert A., and others, The BEA Quarterly Econometric Model, Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Staff Paper No. 22 (Washington, January 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hirsch, Werner Z.,A Survey of Price Elasticities,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 19 (1951), pp. 5058.

  • Houthakker, Hendrik S. (1960 a), “The Influence of Prices and Incomes on Household Expenditures,Bulletin of the International Institute of Statistics, Vol. 37 (1960).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Houthakker, Hendrik S. (1960 b), “Additive Preference,Econometrica, Vol. 28 (January 1960), pp. 24457.

  • Houthakker, Hendrik S. (1961), “The Present State of Consumption Theory: A Survey Article, Econometrica, Vol. 29 (October 1961), pp. 70440.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Houthakker, Hendrik S. (1965), “New Evidence on Demand Elasticities,Econometrica, Vol. 33 (April 1965), pp. 27788.

  • Hymans, Saul H. (1972), “Prices and Price Behavior in Three U.S. Econometric Models,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 30924.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hymans, Saul H. (1974), “The Inflation-Unemployment Trade-Off: Theory and Experience,in Readings in Money, National Income, and Stabilization Policy, ed. by W. L. Smith and R. L. Tiegen (Homewood, Illinois, Third Edition, 1974), pp. 16074.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hymans, Saul H., and Harold Shapiro (1970), The DHL-III Quarterly Model of the U.S. Economy, Research Seminar in Quantitative Economics (University of Michigan, 1970).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hymans, Saul H., and Harold Shapiro (undated), The Equations of the Michigan Quarterly Econometric Model (mimeographed, University of Michigan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Iwai, K., (1972), “Towards Keynesian Microdynamics of Price, Wage, Sales and Employment,Center for Research for Management Science Working Paper (University of California, Berkeley, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Iwai, K., (1973), “The Firm in Uncertain Markets and Its Price, Wage and Employment Adjustments,Center for Research for Management Science Working Paper (University of California, Berkeley, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jorgenson, Dale W. (1963), “Capital Theory and Investment Behavior,American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 53 (May 1963), pp. 24759.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jorgenson, Dale W. (1965), “Anticipations and Investment Behavior,in The Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States, ed. by James S. Duesenberry and others (1965), pp 3592.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jump, Gregory V., The University of Toronto Quarterly Econometric Forecasting Model: A Description of its Real Sector, Institute for Policy Analysis (University of Toronto, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York, 1936).

  • Klein, Lawrence R., and H. Rubin,A Constant-Utility Index of the Cost of Living,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 15(2), (1947-48), pp. 8487.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krauss, Melvyn,Differential Tax Incidence: Large Versus Small Tax Changes,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 80 (January/February 1972), pp. 19398.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krelle, Wilhelm, and G. Grisse, The Bonn Model of the German Economy (Version 8), Discussion Paper No. 61 (Bonn University, 1974).

  • Lau, L. J.,Duality and the Structure of Utility Functions,Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 1 (December 1969), pp. 37496.

  • Legler, John B., and James A. Papke,Optimizing State Business Taxation: An Application of Differential Impact Analysis,National Tax Journal, Vol. 18 (September 1965), pp. 24046.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leijonhufvud, Axel (1968), On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes (Oxford University Press, 1968).

  • Leijonhufvud, Axel (1973), “Effective Demand Failures,Swedish Journal of Economics, Vol. 75 (March 1973), pp. 2748.

  • Leontief, Wassily W. (1936), “Composite Commodities and the Problem of Index Numbers,Econometrica, Vol. 4 (January 1936), pp. 3959.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leontief, Wassily W. (1947), “Introduction to a Theory of the Internal Structure of Functional Relationships,Econometrica, Vol. 15 (October 1947), pp. 36173.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • London Graduate School of Business Studies, The London Business School Quarterly Model of the United Kingdom Economy (mimeographed, London, May 1974).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lucas, Robert E., Jr., and Leonard A. Rapping,Price Expectations and the Phillips Curve,American Economic Review, Vol. 59 (June 1969), pp. 34250.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mattei, Aurelio,A Complete System of Dynamic Demand Functions,European Economic Review, Vol. 2 (Spring 1971), pp. 25176.

  • McCarthy, Michael D., The Wharton Quarterly Econometric Forecasting Model Mark III, Studies in Quantitative Economics, No. 6, University of Pennsylvania, Wharton School of Finance and Commerce (Philadelphia, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., Money and Capital in Economic Development (The Brookings Institution, Washington, 1973).

  • McLure, Charles E., Jr. (1970), “Tax Incidence, Macroeconomic Policy, and Absolute Prices,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84 (May 1970), pp. 25467.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McLure, Charles E., Jr. (1973), “Economic Effects of Taxing Value Added,in Broad-Based Taxes: New Options and Sources, ed. by Richard A. Musgrave (Johns Hopkins University Press, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mieszkowski, Peter,Tax Incidence Theory: The Effects of Taxes on the Distribution of Income,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 7 (December 1969), pp. 110324.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Modigliani, Franco,The Monetary Mechanism and Its Interaction with Real Phenomena,Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 45 (February 1963), pp. 79107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Modigliani, Franco, and Richard Brumberg (1954 a), “Utility Analysis and the Aggregate Consumption Function: An Attempt at Integration,” (mimeographed, 1954).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Modigliani, Franco, and Richard Brumberg (1954 b), “Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross Section Data,in Post Keynesian Economics, ed. by Kenneth Kurihara (Rutgers University Press, 1954), pp. 388436.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moffat, William R.,Taxes in the Price Equation: Textiles and Rubber,Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 52 (August 1970), pp. 25361.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moore, Geoffrey H.,Objectives for Price and Wage Statistics at the Bureau of Labor Statistics,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 38692.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Muellbauer, John,Aggregation, Income Distribution and Consumer Demand,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 42 (October 1975), pp. 52543.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Musgrave, Richard A., The Theory of Public Finance (New York, 1959).

  • Nerlove, Marc L., Distributed Lags and Demand Analysis, Agricultural Handbook No. 141, U.S. Department of Agriculture (Washington, 1958).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nordhaus, William D.,Recent Developments in Price Dynamics,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972), pp. 1649.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Norton, W. E., and J. F. Henderson, A Model of the Australian Economy: A Further Report, Reserve Bank of Australia, Occasional Paper No. 3G (Sydney, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Parks, R. W.,Systems of Demand Equations: An Empirical Comparison of Alternative Functional Forms,Econometrica, Vol. 37 (October 1969), pp. 62950.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Patinkin, Don,Involuntary Unemployment and Keynesian Supply Function,Economic Journal, Vol. 59 (September 1949), pp. 36083.

  • Pearce, Ivor F. (1961 a), “An Exact Method of Consumer Demand Analysis,Econometrica, Vol. 29 (October 1961), pp. 499516.

  • Pearce, Ivor F. (1961 b), “A Method of Consumer Demand Analysis Illustrated,Economica, Vol. 28 (November 1961), pp. 37194.

  • Pearce, Ivor F. (1964), A Contribution to Demand Analysis (Oxford, 1964).

  • Phillips, A. W.,The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957,Economica, Vol. 25 (November 1958), pp. 28399.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pitchford, John, and Stephen J. Turnovsky,Income Distribution and Taxes in an Inflationary Context,Economica, Vol. 42 (August 1975), pp. 27282.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pollak, R. A. (1971 a), “Conditional Demand Functions and the Implications of Direct Separability,Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 37 (April 1971), pp. 42333.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pollak, R. A. (1971 b), “Additive Utility Functions and Linear Engel Curves,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 38 (October 1971), pp. 40114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pollak, R. A. (1972), “Generalized Separability,Econometrica, Vol. 40 (May 1972), pp. 43153.

  • Powell, Alan,A Complete System of Consumer Demand Equations for the Australian Economy Fitted by a Model of Additive Preferences,Econometrica, Vol. 34 (July 1966), pp. 66175.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Prest, Alan R.,Observations on Dynamic Incidence,Economic Journal, Vol. 73 (September 1963), pp. 53546.

  • Preston, Ross S. (1972), The Wharton Annual and Industry Forecasting Model, University of Pennsylvania, Wharton School of Finance and Commerce (Philadelphia, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Preston, Ross S. (1975), “The Wharton Long-Term Model: Input/Output Within the Context of a Macro Forecasting Model, International Economic Review, Vol. 16 (February 1975), pp. 319.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reder, Melvin W.,Wage Structure and Structural Unemployment,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 31 (October 1964), pp. 30922.

  • Robinson, Joan, The Economics of Imperfect Competition (London, 1933).

  • Sawyer, John A., TRACE MK IIIR: An Annual Econometric Model of the Canadian Economy, Institute for the Quantitative Analysis of Social and Economic Policy (University of Toronto, 1974).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schultze, C. L., and Joseph L. Tryon,Prices and Wages,in The Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States, ed. by James S. Duesen-berry and others (Chicago, 1965), pp. 281333.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shackle, George L. S., Expectation in Economics (Cambridge University Press, 1949).

  • Solow, Robert M., Price Expectations and the Behavior of the Price Level (Manchester University Press, 1969).

  • Solow, Robert M., and J. E. Stiglitz,Output, Employment and Wages in the Short Run,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 82 (November 1968), pp. 53760.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stiglitz, J. E.,The Structure of Indirect Taxation and Economic Efficiency,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 1 (April 1972).

  • Stigum, B.,Competitive Equilibria Under Uncertainty,in Allocation Under Certainty: Equilibrium and Optimality, ed. by Jacques H. Dreze, proceedings from a workshop sponsored by the International Economic Association held in Bergen, Norway (1971), (New York, 1974).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stone, Richard, and D. A. Rowe,The Durability of Consumers’ Durable Goods,Econometrica, Vol. 28 (April 1960), pp. 40716.

  • Strotz, Robert H. (1957), “The Empirical Implications of a Utility Tree,Econometrica, Vol. 25 (April 1957), pp. 26980.

  • Strotz, Robert H. (1959), “The Utility Tree: A Correction and Further Appraisal,Econometrica, Vol. 27 (July 1959), pp. 48289.

  • Theil, H., Linear Aggregation of Economic Relations (Amsterdam, 1965).

  • Tobin, James (1972 a), “The Wage-Price Mechanism: Overview of the Conference,in The Econometrics of Price Determination (Washington, 1972) pp. 515.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tobin, James (1972 b), “Inflation and Unemployment,American Economic Review, Vol. 62 (March 1972), pp. 118.

  • Triffin, Robert, Monopolistic Competition and General Equilibrium Theory (Harvard University Press, 1941).

  • Turnovsky, S. J.,On the Role of Inflationary Expectations in a Short-Run Macroeconomic Model,Economic Journal, Vol. 84 (June 1974), pp. 31737.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

Mr. Choudhry, economist in the Fiscal Analysis Division of the Fiscal Affairs Department, holds degrees in statistics and economics from the University of Dacca (Bangladesh) and the University of California at Berkeley.

1

Notice that the “consistency” restriction requires that the quantity and price indices be based on different methods of indexation (i.e., if one is a Laspeyres index, then the other has to be a Paasche index).

2

If indirect taxes are levied, then appropriate adjustment has to be made on the price variable P, since the producer price will differ from the market price because of the imposition of such a tax.

3

In a recent article Muellbauer (1975, p. 540) has shown that if consistency is defined in a way which is useful, given identical tastes across consumers but changing income distribution, the minimum conditions necessary for the existence of consistent aggregation of consumer demands are:

  • (i) a systematic variation in the proportion of expenditure on the ith good for each consumer unit with income;

  • (ii) the absence of money illusion;

  • (iii) the independence of the proportion of expenditure between any two pairs of goods; and

  • (iv) no consumer unit must have income below a certain minimum level.

Most of the known aggregate consumer demand functions violate one or more of these conditions.

4

See Muellbauer (1975) and Hanoch (1975) on the general functional forms. Also on the implications of various types of assumption, see Leontief (1947); Gorman (1959 a); Harold A. J. Green (1961); Goldman and Uzawa (1964); Lau (1969); Pollack (1971 a and b, 1972); Berndt and Christensen (1973); and Hanoch (1975).

5

The separability assumption is less stringent than the Leontief-Hicks composite commodity theorem, which states that commodities whose relative prices do not change may be treated as single commodities for the purposes of maintaining consistency in aggregation. The works of Gorman (1959 b) and Strotz (1957) on utility trees have shown that, as long as utility (or production) functions are strongly (i.e., additively) separable into groups, each of which is homogeneous, then this assumption ensures that, no matter what happens to prices and incomes, the expenditures on each good within the group remain in the same proportions.

6
Pearce (1964, p. 120) has shown that a sufficient condition for the existence of an aggregate consumption function is that, given an income distribution with identical tastes for every consumer, the demand for ith good has the form
xi=αiy2+βiy
where αi and βi are constants and y is income. The above form is also closely allied to the log-linear form
xi=αiyβi

Notice that if αi = 0 in the first case and βi = 1 in the second, then the demand for the ith good is a straight line through the origin—that is, unitary income elasticity.

7

See Brown and Deaton (1972), p. 1170.

8

See the works of Clower (1965) and Leijonhufvud (1973) on the concepts and tools permitting the study of economies at disequilibrium prices.

9

For a sample of the different directions of theories of disequilibrium price and wage behavior, see, for example, the works of Patinkin (1949), Hansen (1951), Modigliani (1963), Clower (1965), Solow and Stiglitz (1968), Barro and Grossman (1971), Arrow (1971), Iwai (1972), J. R. Green (1972), Leijonhufvud (1973), and Stigum (1971).

10

The theoretical foundation of the markup hypothesis appears to reject the view of the firm as a price taker, as it incorporates elements of monopolistic price setting. Recently, Arrow (1971) advocated an approach to price determination with firms behaving monopolistically, and stressed the relation between monopolistic and out-of-equilibrium behavior.

11

To the extent that changes in wages are considered permanent, these can enter into normal costs.

12

For a lucid discussion on the determinants of prices, see Schultze and Tryon (1965), pp. 284-91.

13

Some econometric models utilize a time trend as a proxy for this variable.

14

A common rationalization of target-return pricing or other markup pricing decisions is that they provide practical guidelines in an uncertain world. In general, the optimal price rule does not coincide with the target-return pricing rule except under competitive conditions. See Nordhaus (1972), pp. 30-31.

15

One may argue that a full cost markup price could include any profit tax, so that such taxes can be included in normal costs. If a price equation is derived from a neoclassical model, such taxes are irrelevant. On the other hand, the markup hypothesis, which looks much like the neoclassical price equation, may incorporate such taxes as a part of normal costs.

16

On this point, see Nordhaus (1972), pp. 30-31.

17

There is a long history of monopolistic price setting in economic literature (see Chamberlin (1933), Robinson (1933), and Triffin (1941)) where quantity adjustments also play an important role. In this sense, the markup hypothesis can also account for the effects of quantity adjustments insofar as they affect both the long-run and short-run determinants of price behavior.

18

One could introduce other elements of normal costs in the target price equation, such as standard raw material costs.

19

Notice that the market price P includes the indirect tax rate. For a similar treatment of price and wage behavior, see Pitchford and Turnovsky (1975).

20

Notice that the parameters α and β need not be constants in the “desired” wage determination equation. The parameter α may be a function of the expected rate of inflation or similar concepts, while the parameter β can be a function of the labor unions’ bargaining power. Alternatively, β can be taken as exogenous to reflect the many factors which enter into the wage bargaining process.

21

Notice that equation (10) has a short-run Phillips curve trade-off. For simplicity, equilibrium in this system yields a zero rate of unemployment. This could easily be modified to some constant rate of natural unemployment.

22

The price adjustment equation need not be cast in a differential form of equation type (9) to exhibit dynamic behavior. In fact, the basic price equation (7) can be made dynamic by incorporating a suitable lag structure. Most models have the latter type of dynamic behavior of price adjustments.

23

The stylized price and wage adjustment equations (equations (7)-(10)) embody the expectation hypothesis of the natural rate of unemployment. In a well-specified system, the equilibrium condition of equations (9) and (10) implies that actual unemployment is equal to the natural rate of unemployment since W˙W=0 and WT = W in equilibrium. The most common criticism of the standard Phillips curve analysis is its lack of treatment of expected wages and prices. According to the critics, if expectations are fulfilled, the supply and demand for labor return to their equilibrium position—the natural rate of unemployment. The fact that the above stylized system gives rise to a natural rate of unemployment when expectations are fulfilled does not prove that the Phillips curve tradeoff is nonexistent. Indeed, even in the stylized system, there is a short-run tradeoff between wages and unemployment.

The real issue in the controversy about the existence of the Phillips curve is the persistence of unemployment despite upward movements in wages and prices. While this controversy continues, it is clear that acceptance of the validity of the natural rate hypothesis implies that its proponents have a very simple dynamic structure of price and wage adjustments in mind. If the price and wage adjustment equations (9) and (10) had elaborate lag structures, it is possible that such a system might not be stable in equilibrium, if an equilibrium existed.

24

In such a situation, the full pass-along or partial pass-along hypotheses concerning indirect taxes are not particularly relevant, as long as the system is in motion. Besides, to the extent that the basic markup hypothesis of price formation is valid, indirect taxes are always passed along, at least partially.

25

There are considerable differences in scale, purpose, and internal emphasis between models. The degree of disaggregation of the real and financial sectors varies greatly from one model to another, particularly for the financial sector. The largest real sector is that of the Data Resources model, while the largest financial sector is that of the Bonn model. Also, differences in internal emphasis arise because of the character of technical and definitional equations, as well as the number of identities in these models.

27

For more details on the specification of real sectors with emphasis on indirect taxation in these models, see Choudhry (1976 b).

28

Classification of these three categories of consumption demands are found in (1) the BEA, (2) the Canadian Toronto, (3) the Australian RBA1, (4) the Austria Link, (5) the Japanese EPA, and (6) the New Zealand models. Two category classifications between durables and “all other” are found in (1) the MPS, (2) the Canadian TRACE, and (3) the LBS models. Models with four categories of consumption, with automobiles separated from durables, are (1) the Brookings, (2) the Wharton MK III, (3) the Canadian RDX2, and (4) the Finland models. Those with five categories of consumption, including automobile and housing services (separated from services category), are (1) the DHL-Ill model and (2) the H-F model of the Australian economy.

29

In the Bonn model, aggregate nominal consumption is defined as a simple function of five quarters’ (including the current quarter) nominal disposable income. Real consumption is then obtained by deflating nominal consumption with the gross domestic product (GDP) deflator.

30

Less than half the models consider the effects of real balances, the stock of durables, and unemployment on consumption of durables. Also, some models employ the first difference of real disposable income as an explanatory variable in their consumption function.

31

Differences in the specification of consumption functions in models are summarized in Choudhry (1976 b).

32

To see the wide variations in the short-run aggregate MPC in some of the models, the following may be of interest: for instance, the short-run MPCs of the Brookings, the MPS, and the BEA models are 0.51, 0.11, and 0.49, respectively. The short-run MPCs for the RDX2, the RBA1, the H-F, the Bonn, the EPA, and the Austria Link models are 0.06, 0.63, 0.07, 0.92, 0.10, and 0.67, respectively. Interestingly enough, the long-run MPCs for the MPS and the RDX2 are approximately equal to 0.67. The Toronto model, on the other hand, has aggregate values of 0.39 for the short-run MPC and 0.82 for the long-run MPC.

33

It may be noted that there are significant differences in the relative price effects within and between models. For instance, in the Brookings model, the relative price effects on consumption of automobiles, other durables, nondurables, and services (in comparable units) are −8.33, −10.62, −15.76, and −6.01, respectively, while the same effects for the RBA1, although it does not have a services category, (in comparable units) are −2.57, −1.02, and −14.33, respectively. The BEA model has a relative price effect, for automobiles only, of −26.8, while the MPS has a relative price effect for all durables (including automobiles) of −65.51. Surprisingly, the Austria Link model exhibits magnitudes of relative price effects for durables (−11.89) and nondurables (−16.48) that are similar to those of the Brookings model.

34

For a discussion of the importance of the government budget constraint in econometric models, see Choudhry (1976 a).

35

Some models, such as the Brookings, employ lagged bases to reflect institutional delays in the collection of indirect tax yields. Because of the aggregative nature of taxable commodities, the relevant bases in the models are the various categories of consumption, investment (to the extent investment is subjected to indirect taxation in the models), and imports. Export taxes have not been treated in any of the models, although some of the countries represented by the models do have selective export taxes.

36

One of the few models to employ specific indirect taxes is the BEA model, which relates the excise tax yield function to real GDP as

Texcise = a.teY

where te = average index of specific rates

Y = real GDP.

37

Although the RDX2 is most consistent in this regard, the New Zealand model has the most realistic specification of four categories of indirect tax functions, in that it utilizes lagged bases in all four categories.

38

The MPS model treats customs receipts exogenously, while the BEA model treats “other indirect taxes” exogenously. The TRACE model, on the other hand, treats customs receipts as TcustomstcM, where M is taxable imports.

39

Unfortunately, the channel of feedback is very weak since most models have at best an implicit government budget constraint. For a discussion of the existence of implicit government budget constraint, see Choudhry (1976 a), pp. 414-17.

40

The MPS model is an interesting exception. It has defined ti as the average indirect tax rate for the ith category of consumption but does not use this rate in the price equation.

41

For a summary of the differences in specifying the price equations and the differences in incorporating indirect tax rates in these equations see Choudhry (1976 b).

42

The Bonn model is an exception. The only relevant price in the model is the GDP deflator, which is determined by unit labor cost, interest on borrowed capital, and an index for the degree of monopoly.

43

The only exception is the Finland model, in which the price block is based on a four-sector input-output framework that is outside the model. The coefficients of the input-output matrix are the relevant weights of the production of the four sectors that are assumed to go into each final demand component of GDP. The price deflators for the components of GDP are then determined using these sectoral prices. Since the input-output matrix is outside the model, the price deflators for GDP components are effectively exogenous to the model.

44

The one-stage approach for the Bonn model is trivial, since it only determines the GDP deflator.

45

The LBS model is the only exception. It disaggregates consumption into two categories—durables and nondurables. The aggregate consumer price index and the price index of durables are behaviorally determined. The price index of nondurables is then determined consistently as a residual.

46

The principal motivation for the logic of two-stage price determination is to distinguish differences in unit labor costs between manufacturing and non-manufacturing production.

Let Y - Xm + Xnm be the real GDP

where Xm = manufacturing output

and Xnm = nonmanufacturing output.

Employing the similarity between the markup hypothesis and marginal labor productivity, in the context of a Cobb-Douglas production function for manufacturing, we have
XmLm=αXmLm=WmPXm

so that

PXm=1αWmLmXm=1αULCm, since

WmLm = total wage payment in manufacturing. Similarly, for nonmanufacturing production, we have
PXnm=1βWnmLnmXnm=1βULCnm

Notice that in consumption and investment both Xm and Xnm are used; hence, we can relate the second stage price formation for the ith and jth categories of consumption and investment, respectively, as

Pci = Pci(PXm, Pxnm)

P1 = PIi, PXnm, Pxnm)

to account for the share of both manufacturing and nonmanufacturing output, and their different prices, in the deflators for components of GDP.

47

The author considers the price-output conversion technique of transforming sectoral prices to final demand prices to be one of the most elegant and theoretically sound methods of treating indirect taxes in econometric models. Unfortunately, this technique is extremely sophisticated and data-intensive. For a digression on the basic analytics of price-output conversion technique, see Choudhry (1976 b).

48

Presently, the implication of this definition of r will be discussed in the text.

49

Models with one-stage price information having the B(14)-type specification of indirect taxes are the Australian RBA1 and the H-F models.

50

The original Brookings model did not specify indirect tax rates in the price equations. Fromm and Taubman (1968), however, studied the changes in price structure due to changes in excise tax rates by modifying the industry value-added prices on the basis of the B(14)-type specification.

51
In the RDX2 model, the price of private motor vehicles has a form slightly different from the B(14”) type. Instead of the product term n(t)Pi (t-1), this equation has only the Pi (t-1) term, that is,
Pf(t)motor=P(t)motor1+τmotor=λi(t,T)ULC(t)+li(t,T*)Pmotor(t1)+wi(t)

An implication of this variant of B(14”) type is that, since the price is purged of indirect taxes, any change in the rate τmotor under simulation will produce a corresponding change in the price Pmotor to the purchaser. In other words, indirect taxes are fully passed on to consumers. However, since the coefficients of li are negative, from the next period after the tax rate has been changed, Pmotor will begin to decline. The pattern of decline depends on the weights of the coefficients li distributed over the T* period, which is 11 quarters long.

52

The ceteris paribus assumption is quite restrictive here, especially when the price and wage dynamics in the models are explored in some detail in the next section.

53

In fact, in the BEA and TRACE models, which are of the A type, relative prices do not exist in the consumption categories. A change in the consumer price index caused by a change in τ affects consumption through real disposable income. The other two A-type models, the MPS and the Austria Link, have relative price effects in their consumption functions. In these models, the response of the relative prices to a change in τ is very weak, since the prices, both in the numerator and the denominator, are functions of Py; even though each price responds to such a change in τ, the relative effects are considerably weakened.

54

The EPA model specifies domestic indirect tax yield and customs receipts as Tdomestic = tid GDP and Tdomestic = tcM, respectively. But it does not incorporate the rates tid or tc in the price equations.

55

Interestingly enough, the MPS model employs an index of the federal excise tax rate in its indirect tax function, but employs an endogenous τ in its price equation.

B(14)-type models which employ an exogenous τ are the Brookings (as modified by Fromm and Taubman (1968)), the DRI, the DHL-Ill, the RDX2, the Toronto, the RBA1, the H-F, and the LBS. See Choudhry (1976 b).

56
The Phillips curve equation (15) incorporating expected price inflation can be obtained from equations (9) and (10) of Section 1.2. The equations for target prices and target wages (equations (7) and (8)) in Section 1.2 can be modified to incorporate inflationary expectations as follows:
PT=k0λKQn+k1ULCn+k2ULC+τiP1+τi+k3π,ki>0,foralli

and WT = β0 + β1w + β2 π, βi > 0, i = 0,1, 2.

Notice that both producers and labor unions (and nonunionized labor as well) can revise their target prices and wages in the light of their particular perceptions of the expected rate of inflation. For simplicity, we have considered only one expected rate of inflation it for these two sets of economic agents. Further, if we assume that unemployment u is negatively related to excess aggregate demand x, that is,

u=h(x), h’ < 0

and
P=P1(1+ΔPP)andw=w1(1+ΔWW)

then we can substitute these relations in equations (9) and (10) in Section 1.2 to arrive at equation (17) in the text.

57

See Tobin (1972 a) on this form of price expectation.

58

This can be shown as follows:

Let Pt and Pt* be the actual and desired prices. The partial one-period adjustment of actual price to desired price is given by
PtPt1=λ(PtPt*)(A)
If Pt-1 = λ(ULCt, Vt), where ULC is unit labor cost and V is a vector of other relevant variables, then
Pt=Pt11λλ1λf(ULCt,Vt)(B)
Clearly, if ULC and V have lag structures λ(t, T) and γ(t, T*) respectively, we can express equation (B) as
Pt=α0+λ*(t,T)ULC(t)+γ*(t,T*)Vt+(1/1λ)Pt1(C)

The price equation (C) is commonly used in most models (see Section II.2).

59

The EPA, Finland, and New Zealand models are, however, capable of simulating the effect of changes in indirect taxes by positing such rate changes in their respective prices.

60

The Austria Link model determines the current wage rate as a linear function of the lagged wage rate W and the current consumer price index Pc. Thus, although it does not have a Phillips curve, it can trace the dynamic incidence of indirect taxes on output, employment, and prices because of the presence of Pc in the wage rate equation. The LBS model, on the other hand, measures “true” unemployment by an indirect method. First, the degree of utilization of employed labor is determined. The true unemployment is then determined by adding the amount of nonutilized employed labor (translated into an equivalent number of unemployed persons) to the actual number of unemployed persons. Hence, to the extent changes in indirect taxes affect the amount of nonutilized employed labor from the demand side, it does capture incidence of such taxes on unemployment.

61

The BEA model employs a cyclical variable—average weekly hours for production workers in manufacturing—that may be looked at as a proxy for a labor productivity variable.

62

These wage decisions guarantee minimum wage rates and their adjustments throughout the economy as a whole.

63
The nonlinearity of the Phillips curve equation, as seen in Table 1, can be fully reconciled with the basic analytical framework by rewriting equation (10) as follows:
ΔWW=γ0*1u+γ1(WTWW),γ0*>0,γ1>0.

Further, one could postulate a lag structure on the 1/u variable in order to obtain the general form of the Phillips curve equation found in these models.

64
The coefficients of the price change variables should be carefully interpreted in view of inflationary expectations. As mentioned earlier, if inflationary expectations are formed on the basis of past and current rates of inflation, then the lag structure on the price change variable could also reflect such expectations. Although most models do not explicitly incorporate inflationary expectations in their real sectors, a few do contain the actual rate of price change in some of their consumption demand categories. In fact, the Brookings, DRI, MPS, H-F, and EPA models all contain some form of inflationary expectations in some of their consumption functions. Except for the MPS model, the other three models incorporate either
π=αΔPcPcorπ=Σi=01or2αi(ΔPcPc)i
as an explanatory variable in some of their consumption functions. The MPS model has inflationary expectations of the form
π=Σi=111αi(ΔPcPc)i

in the durable consumption category.

65

In fact, simulation results for some of these models show that, following a fiscal stimulus, prices initially decline before they begin to rise in later periods. See de Menil and Enzler (1972), Hymans (1972), and Christ (1972). Also, in the context of recent experience with rising prices accompanied by rising unemployment and falling output in most developed countries, these coefficients in the Phillips curve equations appear to be reasonable, at least insofar as the direction of movement is concerned.

66

On the implication of this government budget constraint in the Brookings model, see Choudhry (1976 a).

67

This bias owing to the absence of a government budget constraint is likely to underestimate the effects of a cut in a purchase tax on GDP. Other things being equal, a cut in a purchase tax increases the budget deficit and at the same time raises aggregate demand, and induces an increase in the demand for money as well. However, to the extent that the increase in the budget deficit is money financed, the increase in the money supply cannot be accounted for in the model. As a consequence of this deficiency in the model, interest rates will rise. Thus, the initial increase in aggregate demand would be partly offset by the rise in interest rates.

68

This difference might arise because of the absence of a government budget constraint in the LBS model.

69

In the Brookings model, indirect tax cuts interact through the whole system via the input-output framework. Hence, it is likely that other components of aggregate demand are affected in the same fashion as consumption. On the other hand, in the LBS model the higher magnitude of consumption multipliers, relative to those of GDP, may reflect the fact that feedback is not strong between and within the real and financial sectors.

70

It is likely that the tax cut multipliers will decline over time, mainly because (i) lag structures have declining weights, and (ii) the “crowding out effects” of fiscal actions will take place. On the latter point, see Choudhry (1976 a).

71

Surprisingly, it has relatively more effect on unemployment than on prices. This suggests that the income effects are greater than the price effects in the LBS model.

72

Insofar as changes in statutory indirect tax rates can be appropriately reflected by the endogenous indirect tax rates in models, the effects of such discretionary changes can be traced reasonably well. This is the case in the TRACE model.

73

The Toronto and LBS models do not incorporate such rates in the tax functions, although they treat indirect taxes as policy instruments in the price equations.

74
In these models, the price equation is of the form
Pi=f(ULC,TIiGDP,0)

where ULC = unit labor cost, τi = τi=TIiGDP is the endogenous indirect tax rate, and 0 is

vector of other variables. Other things being equal, an increase in TIi following an increase in the statutory indirect tax rate raises n and, hence, Pi.

75

It is interesting to compare the price simulations of the MPS, BEA, and DHL-Ill models. The first two models treat indirect tax rates endogenously, while the third treats them exogenously. Hymans (1972), in simulating the price-wage behavior in these three models, concludes that the FMP (an earlier version of the MPS model) price equation is a winner on all counts, while the OBE (an earlier version of the BEA model) price equation significantly underestimates the relatively low rates of (actual) inflation and overestimates the relatively high rates of (actual) inflation. The DHL-Ill model produces no evidence of any bias, although it leaves substantially more unexplained variation than either the FMP or OBE models.

While we do not know how Hymans carried out the simulations, Christ (1972), in comparing the same three models, states that “no model was uniformly better in price simulation than the others” (p. 328). We learn from Christ that he employed only the wage-price subblock of these models. Christ goes on to conclude that “the submodel simulations, on the whole, were better than the full model simulations (as is to be expected, because a submodel simulation uses the observed data for certain lagged endogenous variables that a full model simulation has to calculate for itself)” (p. 328).

  • Collapse
  • Expand