Abstract
This paper identifies and analyzes some of the potential costs and benefits that are likely to be associated with the implementation of wage indexation in an industrial economy. The term “wage indexation” means here an explicit provision, either legislative (mandatory) or voluntary, that automatically links changes in money wages to changes in some general price index (for example, the consumer price index).
This paper identifies and analyzes some of the potential costs and benefits that are likely to be associated with the implementation of wage indexation in an industrial economy. The term “wage indexation” means here an explicit provision, either legislative (mandatory) or voluntary, that automatically links changes in money wages to changes in some general price index (for example, the consumer price index).
Although the idea of indexing wages and/or financial instruments has a long history in economics,1 it has been primarily during periods of high and prolonged inflation that indexation has captured the attention of policymakers as well as economists. Since most countries have experienced rates of inflation in the 1970s well above those of the 1950s and 1960s, it is not surprising that indexation has once again been proposed as a viable policy option.
In brief, the traditional, and perhaps strongest, argument for indexation is that it will make “living with inflation” less costly. More specifically, the proponents of indexation argue that the costs and inequities usually associated with inflation (such as the redistribution of income and wealth and the misallocation of resources) relate almost exclusively to unanticipated inflation,2 and they believe that with proper indexation of labor, product, and financial contracts inflation need not produce any significant social welfare costs.3 More recently, some economists, most notably Milton Friedman (1974), have also tried to dispel the belief that indexation must lead to a higher rate of inflation. In fact, it is Friedman’s position that indexation might even serve to reduce the rate of inflation indirectly by (1) reducing the incentive (from an inflation tax) that governments otherwise might have to pursue inflationary policies, (2) reducing the time lag between aggregate demand reductions and aggregate price changes, and (3) reducing the employment losses associated with aggregate demand reductions (see Section II). Finally, the case for indexation has received a boost (perhaps unjustifiably) from the indexation experiences of a few countries—especially Brazil, where it has been possible to reduce the rate of inflation substantially without any retardation in the rate of economic growth.4
The paper is necessarily limited in scope. First, it deals exclusively with wage indexation, without any attempt to consider the implications of indexing either financial instruments or income taxes.5 Second, while some reference is made to wage indexation policies adopted in the past, no attempt is made to provide a detailed and comprehensive review of such policies.6 Third, while the technical details of wage indexation have obvious practical importance (such as, which wages and salaries are to be indexed, what price index is to be used, how often cost of living compensation is to be made), only limited attention is given to these details, except for their implications for labor market behavior. Finally, the analysis has been restricted to only a few representative wage indexation schemes.
Section I is directed at one of the more controversial questions in the wage indexation debate—namely, is the implementation of wage indexation likely to be inflationary? To provide a framework for analyzing this question, a simple model of wage-price behavior in the absence of indexation is introduced and then the channels by which wage indexation can influence the rate of wage inflation are discussed. In Section II, other potential labor market effects of wage indexation are considered, including its possible effects on the variability of real wage changes over time, on the time duration of labor contracts, on aggregate strike activity, and on the functional distribution of income. Section III deals briefly with the probable effect of wage indexation on the efficacy of exchange rate policy. The principal conclusions are given at the end of Sections I, II, and III, and in Section IV.
I. Is Wage Indexation Inflationary?
A major point of contention between those who favor and those who oppose wage indexation revolves around the question of whether the implementation of wage indexation is likely to be inflationary. There are three possibilities: wage indexation is inflationary, wage indexation is anti-inflationary, and wage indexation is neutral with respect to the rate of inflation.7 Unfortunately, there is no simple and clear-cut answer to this question, and dramatically different conclusions can be obtained by simply altering a few key assumptions.
As a starting point, it is useful to rephrase the inflation question as follows: Is the rate of wage (or price) inflation likely to be higher with wage indexation than in the absence of wage indexation, other things being held equal? Actually, only by addressing the inflation question in this form can one hope to identify, in either a theoretical or empirical way, the independent effect of wage indexation on the rate of inflation. This is because wage indexation is but one of many determinants of the rate of inflation and therefore, unless these other determinants of inflation are held constant, one will not be able to ascribe any change in wage behavior (after indexation) to wage indexation itself.8
Clearly, then, the key to determining the inflationary impact, if any, of wage indexation lies in determining the behavior of money wages (and prices) in the absence of indexation. Once this is known, each of the channels by which wage indexation might affect the rate of inflation can be examined. This strategy will be followed in this section.
a simple wage-price model
In order to describe the process of aggregate wage and price determination in the absence of indexation, let us consider a variant of a general wage-price model recently proposed by Tobin (1972a). The model used here has two features that are helpful for the subsequent analysis: (1) as it is representative of much of the recent and on-going empirical work on aggregate wage and price determination, estimates of most of the key parameters are available; and (2) it contains most of the channels or mechanisms by which wage indexation might conceivably affect the rate of inflation.
The model contains four equations—a wage adjustment equation, a price adjustment equation, an equation for price expectations, and an equation for normal capacity utilization, as presented below:
In the above model, W is the money wage rate (or average hourly earnings), P is the price level, Pe is the expected price level, U is the unemployment rate,
The wage adjustment equation (1) is a form of the well-known Phillips curve. The rate of change of money wages is related, inter alia, to the unemployment rate and to the rate of change of the unemployment rate, where these two variables are proxies for the level and rate of change of excess demand in the labor market (see Lipsey, 1960). The percentage change in expected prices enters equation (1) to allow wage bargains to be struck in real rather than in nominal terms, while the trend rate of growth of labor productivity is intended to capture the equilibrium path of money wages over time (when there is no excess demand for labor).9
The price adjustment equation (2) relates the rate of price change to the rate of change of variable costs and to the level of excess demand in the product market, where the proxy for this latter variable is the deviation of capacity utilization from its normal value. Equation (3) expresses the expected rate of inflation as a weighted average of past actual rates of inflation, and equation (4) uses an equivalent, weighted average formula to express the normal (or expected) capacity utilization rate.
For the subsequent analysis of wage indexation, a few important characteristics of the above wage-price model should be noted. First, the presence of
Note that in both equations (5) and (6) the coefficient on the unemployment rate will be infinite if (a1b1) = 1; hence, there would be no long-run trade-off between the rate of wage (or price) inflation and the unemployment rate. In fact, the model implies in more general terms that there will not be a stable, long-run equilibrium rate of wage (or price) inflation if (a1b1) = 1, for in such a case, the denominator in both equations (5) and (6) would be zero.11 Finally, note that a comparison of equations (1) and (2) with equations (5) and (6) reveals that the long-run effect of a change in each of the exogenous variables on the rate of wage (or price) inflation will be greater than the short-run effect by the factor 1/(1 – a1b1). Thus, for example, if a1 and b1 were each equal to 0.75, the long-run effect on the inflation rate of (say) an increase in import prices would be about 2.3 times greater than the short-run effect.
the impact of wage indexation on inflation
Given the above wage-price model, it can now be seen how wage indexation might be expected to affect the rate of inflation. In general terms, wage indexation can affect the rate of inflation in any of the three following ways: (1) by altering the values of any of the explanatory variables in equations (1) through (4); (2) by altering the values of any of the coefficients in these same four equations; or (3) by introducing a new, or replacing an existing, explanatory variable in equations (1) through (4). Fortunately, many of these possible effects of wage indexation on inflation can probably be safely ignored here (on a priori grounds), since they are likely to be of negligible importance. For example, it seems doubtful that wage indexation would have any direct effect on the rate of change of either import prices or capital goods prices, or on the productivity of labor. In fact, the wage indexation literature suggests that it would be most fruitful to concentrate on the probable impact of wage indexation on (1) the money wage response to actual price changes (that is, on the a1 coefficient), (2) the role of price expectations in the wage determination process, and (3) the relationship between aggregate demand changes and price changes, including the time lags in this relationship.
the money wage response to price changes
The first and most obvious channel by which wage indexation might affect the rate of inflation is through its effect on the money wage response to price changes. As illustrated by equations (1) and (3), when there is no wage indexation, money wages will respond to expected price changes, so that the money wage response to actual price changes will depend on two parameters—the response of money wages to expected price changes (ai) and the response of expected price changes to actual price changes (Σαi). Unfortunately, since price expectations are generally not observable, all that can be observed from empirical data is the money wage response to actual price changes (a1Σαi) and not the two individual components of that relationship. Therefore, in the first part of this section, it is assumed that actual price changes equal expected price changes (that
Obviously, the extent to which wage indexation affects the money wage response to price changes depends in large part on the form or type of wage indexation under consideration. Contrary to popular opinion, wage indexation as applied in practice has seldom provided for full wage compensation for all price changes. As such, the discussion below deals with the inflationary implications of several alternative forms of wage indexation.12
Full wage indexation
As a starting point, let us consider what can be regarded as a polar case of wage indexation. Suppose that a base year (call it year t) is selected for both the money wage index W and the aggregate price index P and that from year t on, it is mandated that W change by 1 per cent for every 1 per cent change in P. Further, assume that all other determinants of
Given these assumptions, it is clear that wage indexation will be inflationary, in both the short and long run, if the wage response to price changes with full indexation is greater than the wage response to price changes in the absence of indexation.14 Equivalently, since a1 with indexation is by assumption equal to unity, the required condition for an inflationary impact is that a1 without indexation must be less than unity. The only unknown parameter is therefore the wage response to price changes in the absence of indexation.
Upon first thought it would appear that there should be no problem in identifying the a1 parameter (without indexation), given that there exists a voluminous econometric literature on aggregate wage determination and given that almost all of these estimated equations contain estimates of the money wage response to price (cost of living) changes.15 Upon further reflection, however, it becomes apparent that the empirical wage studies may not provide the required information for two reasons. First, since the parameter of interest is the wage response to price changes in the absence of indexation, it is clear that estimates of a1 taken from equations fitted over time periods in which there was indexation (for at least some years) will be inappropriate here because the estimated wage response to price changes will reflect in part the influence of wage indexation. This means that, ideally, one should exclude from the sample countries in which there have been national wage indexation policies in effect for much of the postwar period and countries in which a significant proportion of private labor contracts contained cost of living escalator clauses.16 In the first category, one should probably include Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Israel, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, and Switzerland, among others. Canada, the United Kingdom, and the United States would probably fall in the second category.17 However, if these countries are excluded from consideration, very few countries with estimated wage equations are left from which to obtain information on the a1 coefficient. In other words, there will not be an adequate number of observations for the period without indexation to permit a reliable comparison of wage behavior, in periods with and without indexation.
Second, the problem arises as to which time period to use in examining the wage response to price changes, because the empirical literature suggests that the a1 parameter is quite unstable over time (see Cargill and Meyer, 1974; Goldstein, 1972 and 1974; and Gordon, 1971a). Thus, quite different conclusions could be reached about the size of the a1 parameter and also about the inflationary impact of indexation, depending on the time period selected.
Despite the above-mentioned caveats, some limited information on the wage response to price changes in the absence of indexation might be gleaned from estimates of the ax parameter for countries without pervasive indexation. Estimates are presented for the United States, the United Kingdom, Canada, Japan, and the Federal Republic of Germany in Table 1.
Econometric Estimates of the Money Wage Response to Price Changes
In the vast majority of the studies listed, the estimate of a1 refers to the estimated coefficient on
Q = quarterly data, SA = semiannual data, and A = annual data.
Econometric Estimates of the Money Wage Response to Price Changes
In the vast majority of the studies listed, the estimate of a1 refers to the estimated coefficient on
Q = quarterly data, SA = semiannual data, and A = annual data.
Econometric Estimates of the Money Wage Response to Price Changes
In the vast majority of the studies listed, the estimate of a1 refers to the estimated coefficient on
Q = quarterly data, SA = semiannual data, and A = annual data.
An examination of the estimates of a1 in Table 1 suggests that: (1) the vast majority of the estimates of a1 are less than unity, which implies, ceteris paribus, that full wage indexation is likely to be inflationary; (2) the estimates of a1 show considerable variation within each country, suggesting either that this parameter is quite unstable over time or that estimates of a1 are quite sensitive to relatively minor differences in the specification of the aggregate wage equation; and (3) for those countries in which there are quite a few estimates of a1 the estimates for the more recent time period (including the post-1968 period) are closer to unity than those for earlier periods. In fact, estimates of the aggregate wage equation for the 1965–74 period would probably yield estimates of a1 that are not significantly different from unity.18 If this were correct, it would mean that implementation of full wage indexation in 1975 would produce little, if any, inflationary impact in most countries, at least in the short run.
Partial wage indexation
A second form of wage indexation is one where percentage changes in money wages and prices are automatically linked together but where the a1 parameter is set below unity. For example, most wage contracts in Italy have provided for an 0.6 per cent wage increase for every 1 per cent change in the cost of living index (see Vega, 1973, and Ulman and Flanagan, 1971). Quite obviously, if a1 with indexation is less than unity, it is less likely that wage indexation would be inflationary. In fact, it would appear from Table 1 that if wage indexation provided for an a1 parameter of (say) 0.5, wage indexation could well be anti-inflationary in many countries. On the other hand, workers are apt to be dissatisfied with an indexation formula that provides only partial compensation for cost of living increases, unless the other determinants of money wages lead to an increase in real wages.
Threshold wage indexation
Another variant of wage indexation is what might be called threshold indexation. Under threshold indexation, money wages are adjusted for price changes only when the price change reaches some threshold (minimum) rate. For example, a possible formula might be that workers receive full cost of living adjustment when the consumer price index has increased by 2 per cent or more over the past year;19 if the price change is less than 2 per cent, no cost of living adjustment is made—that is, a1 = 1 for
Threshold indexation will be inflationary, ceteris paribus, if the a1 parameter is higher than it is in the absence of indexation. Unfortunately, the existing empirical evidence on the money wage response to small versus large price changes in the absence of indexation is very limited. What evidence exists, however, suggests that a1 will be larger when inflation is high than when it is low (see Hamermesh, 1970; Eckstein and Brinner, 1972; and Sumner, 1972). In other words, wage bargains seem to be struck more in real terms when price changes are large than when they are small. If this hypothesis is true, then threshold indexation may not be inflationary and might even be anti-inflationary. This conclusion would follow, for example, if the a1 parameter for
One probable reason for the popularity of threshold indexation is that it insulates wage determination, and hence the wage-price spiral, from small exogenous price changes, some of which may be temporary and reversible. As such, cost of living adjustments will not have to be made as frequently as under full indexation.
The primary difficulty with threshold indexation is where to set the threshold. If the inflation threshold is set too low, threshold indexation will not offer much of an advantage over full indexation.20 If the threshold is set too high, workers are apt to be dissatisfied, at least over the long run, because they will not be receiving adequate cost of living protection.
Before concluding the discussion of the effect of indexation on the wage response to price changes, it is important to note that the preceding analysis has rested on the assumption that indexation affects the a1 parameter but leaves unaffected all other determinants of wage changes. Some proponents of wage indexation, however, have based their case that wage indexation will not be inflationary on a directly contrasting assumption—namely, that by granting workers full protection against increases in the cost of living, the inflationary impact of the other determinants of
the role of price expectations in wage determination
As suggested by wage equation (1), one of the determinants of the rate of wage inflation in the absence of wage indexation is the expected rate of inflation. With indexation, the role of expectations about the inflation rate would presumably be greatly reduced.21 In fact, one of the supposed advantages of indexation is that it will remove the uncertainty associated with future changes in prices and therefore that labor, product, and financial contracts can then be negotiated exclusively with respect to “real” variables.22 This in effect means that with full wage indexation, wage equation (1) can be rewritten with the actual rate of inflation
The above discussion suggests that, given some value for a1 full wage indexation will be inflationary, anti-inflationary, or inflation-neutral, ceteris paribus, as the actual inflation rate exceeds, falls short of, or equals the expected inflation rate, respectively. Some of the proponents of wage indexation claim that full wage indexation will be anti-inflationary because, in the absence of indexation, workers overestimate the future rate of inflation and then succeed in embodying these erroneous inflation forecasts in their wage contracts. The opponents of wage indexation take the precisely opposite position that workers usually under estimate the actual future inflation rate, so that the implementation of wage indexation would be inflationary. Finally, the prevailing view among neoclassical economists is that while in the short run workers may underestimate or overestimate the inflation rate, in the long run their expectations will be correct (in the long run,
Unfortunately, economic theory does not offer very much guidance about the formulation of price expectations. As illustrated by equation (3), economists have in general assumed that people form their price expectations as some weighted average of past actual rates of inflation. Empirical work on price expectations has been very limited, however (in large part due to the lack of good survey data on price expectations), with the result that it is not really known whether workers (or employers) have underestimated or overestimated future rates of inflation.24 Thus, the effects of wage indexation on inflation by means of the substitution of actual for expected rates of inflation remains essentially an open question. It might be noted, nevertheless, that if workers consistently overestimated the future rate of inflation and if they were powerful enough to obtain compensation for these price forecasts in their wage contracts, then they would have little to gain from indexation. Since much of the pressure for indexation has come from labor groups, one might therefore conjecture either that workers feel they have in the past underestimated the actual rate of inflation or that workers value the “insurance” that indexation provides against inflation even if it leaves unaffected their average increase in real wages.
A further factor to consider on the question of wage indexation and price expectations is the potential impact of the announcement of indexation on expectations. Some writers (see the references in Bhatia, 1974) have argued that the adoption of wage indexation will be regarded by the public as a clear signal that the government has abandoned its battle against inflation and has instead opted for “living” with inflation. For example, Day (1964, p. 2) has stated that indexing implies “a deliberate acceptance of inflation by the monetary authorities … and it is a clear admission of the expectation of defeat.” Similarly, Collier (1969) has stated that it is disastrous for the government to admit that inflation is inevitable, as this reinforces the price rise. In brief, what these writers are implying is that indexation will increase the public’s price expectations, and this in turn will ultimately increase the actual rate of inflation.25
In evaluating the above argument, it is necessary to distinguish between economy-wide indexation (where all financial, labor, and product contracts are indexed) and partial indexation (where only some assets or labor contracts are indexed). If everything except currency in circulation is indexed on the actual rate of inflation, then an increase in the expected rate of inflation should be of little consequence, since only actual inflation rates matter. On the other hand, if (say) only wage contracts are indexed, then the adoption of wage indexation could lead to an increase in the expected rate of inflation and this in turn would affect the actual rate of inflation in those markets that are not indexed. The basic question, however, of whether in fact the announcement of indexation would actually increase the expected rate of inflation is again an open one, because price expectations are generally not observable. In particular, the relationship between government policy decisions and price expectations is an almost completely unresearched area. Thus, an agnostic position on this issue seems unavoidable.
aggregate demand changes, price changes, and time lags
Recently, Friedman (1974) and Laidler (1974) have proposed yet another mechanism by which indexation can affect the rate of inflation—or, more accurately, how indexation can improve the government’s ability to deal with inflation. It is their position that past attempts to use aggregate demand policy to control inflation have been largely unsuccessful due to the long time lag between decreases in aggregate demand and decreases in the rate of inflation. More specifically, Friedman claims that when aggregate demand falls in an unanticipated manner, producers respond by first reducing output and/or accumulating inventories, next by reducing employment, and only finally by lowering prices. Similarly, laid-off workers first wait to be recalled to their former jobs, next seek new jobs elsewhere, and only finally moderate their money wage demands. He estimates that the total time delay between a change in monetary growth (demand policy) and a change in the rate of inflation is about two years in both the United Kingdom and the United States. During the interim period, it is common for both unemployment and the rate of inflation to be high, with the result that public pressure leads to a reversal of aggregate demand policy and, hence, to little if any reduction in the rate of inflation. Under this situation, it is the unwillingness of the public to accept the temporary side effects of anti-inflationary policy that prevents the government from reducing inflation.
With indexation, Friedman and Laidler argue that the time delay between aggregate demand changes and price changes will be reduced—that is, the time lags in equations (1) and (2) will be shortened.26 The time lag is presumed to be reduced because with indexation it will no longer be necessary to reduce price expectations in order to reduce the future actual rate of inflation and because indexation will make it easier for the public to recognize changes in the actual rate of inflation. A capsule statement of this position is given by Laidler (1974, p. 541):
Without escalator clauses, deficient demand leads to unemployment; this decreases the inflation rate which in turn decreases inflationary expectations so that future wage and price inflation rates are also cut. Each step in the process takes time, but the use of escalator clauses “short circuits” the expectation adaption stage and hence speeds up the whole process.
A second related argument for indexation is that full wage indexation will make it easier politically for the government to reduce inflation because it will reduce the employment and output losses associated with aggregate demand reductions. This point has been most fully developed by Morley (1974) within the context of a simple one-sector model of the economy where all prices are rising (or falling) at the same rate. Morley uses this model to contrast the effects of anti-inflationary, demand-reducing policy under full wage indexation with those in the absence of indexation. First, consider the case without indexation and assume that the government attempts to reduce the inflation rate by adopting a restrictive demand policy in a period in which past actual inflation rates have been high. Morley argues that when aggregate demand is reduced and prices fall, the expected inflation rate will for a time exceed the actual inflation rate. Workers will therefore be demanding, and obtaining, salary increases which turn out afterward to be too high. Consequently, businessmen will have to lay off workers because their selling prices will not be high enough to meet the salary demands of workers—that is, the money wage will exceed the value of labor’s marginal product. Thus, the level of unemployment will rise and the equilibrium level of employment will be restored only when workers revise their expectations so that the equilibrium level of real wages is restored. By analogy, antirecessionary, aggregate demand-increasing policy will be associated with a temporary increase in the level of employment above the equilibrium level.
Now consider the case with full wage indexation. Under indexation, workers will not need to build any inflation forecasts into their wage demands because any real wage losses which they experience due to inflation will be fully restored to them through cost of living adjustment. Therefore, Morley argues, it will not be possible for workers to overestimate the future rate of inflation and to demand an excessive money wage, which is what causes the employment losses under stabilization policy. Rather, with indexation, it is argued that a fall in the actual rate of inflation induced by restrictive demand policy will be automatically matched by a fall in the rate of increase of money wages. Thus, it is claimed that indexation will permit the authorities to move the economy from a higher to a lower rate of inflation without causing unemployment to rise above its equilibrium level because under indexation the real wage will not deviate from its equilibrium level.
Critical evaluation of both the Friedman-Laidler and Morley hypotheses is severely hampered by the lack of empirical studies comparing wage-price flexibility and employment behavior under indexation with that in the absence of indexation.27 Without such empirical evidence, it is difficult to know whether the adjustment of prices and money wages to aggregate demand changes would occur as smoothly and as rapidly under indexation as these authors suggest. Further, both the Friedman-Laidler and Morley arguments have been framed within the context of simple models which embody some rather restrictive assumptions. For example, Friedman implicitly assumes that with indexation producers will be more inclined to reduce their selling prices in response to a decline in demand because such a price decline will lead to a compensating decline in money wages, thereby leaving unaffected the real wage. Such an argument, however, makes no distinction between output price, which is the relevant price variable for the producer’s employment decision, and the consumer price index, which is the relevant price variable for the worker’s employment and wage-bargaining decisions. More specifically, since a single employer’s price change is likely to have a negligible influence on the cost of living, he cannot be certain that his price cuts will be matched by a fall in the money wages of his employees. In fact, given the existence of imported products, indirect taxes, rents, and so on in the cost of living (and given that the producer has no control over the prices of these items), it is questionable whether a decline in the price of (say) all manufactured goods would be associated with a corresponding decline in either the cost of living index or the index of money wage rates. In short, even under full wage indexation, producers cannot be certain about their real wage costs.
Similarly, Morley’s analysis of employment behavior in the absence of indexation rests on the assumption that producers will lay off workers whenever the money wage exceeds the value of labor’s marginal product. As such, it gives no role or influence to the fixed transaction costs associated with hiring, training, and firing workers—all of which drive a wedge between the money wage and the value of labor’s marginal product—and which transform labor into a quasi-fixed factor of production in the short run (see Oi, 1962). Finally, neither Friedman nor Laidler pays much attention to the issue of time lags in the payment of compensation for cost of living changes under indexation—a technical detail, but one which will have an important effect on how fast money wages adjust to price changes and, hence, to aggregate demand changes. In sum, while both the Friedman-Laidler and Morley arguments for indexation have considerable intuitive appeal, many questions remain to be answered before one can be confident about indexation’s positive effect on the government’s ability to deal with inflation.
summarizing the effect of wage indexation on inflation
One of the dominant conclusions that emerges from the preceding analysis is that it is not possible to draw any meaningful conclusions about the effect of wage indexation on inflation without specifying explicitly both what type of wage indexation is being considered and what is being assumed about wage behavior in the absence of wage indexation. Further, even when this is done, very few definitive conclusions can be drawn because existing empirical wage studies are generally not suitable for inferring either what would have happened in the absence of indexation or what would happen if wage indexation were to be introduced.
Despite the large degree of uncertainty surrounding the inflationary implications of wage indexation, the analysis presented in this section suggests the following tentative conclusions:
(1) Full wage indexation is more likely to be inflationary if implemented during a period of low inflation (say, the 1960s) than during a period of high inflation (say, the 1970s) because the wage response to price changes in the absence of indexation is apt to be closer to unity when inflation is high than when it is low.
(2) Both partial wage indexation (a1 < 1) and threshold wage indexation (a1 = 1 only when
(3) A wage-price spiral will result from changes in any exogenous determinant of wage (or price) inflation whether indexation is present or not. However, the size of the wage-price spiral (which depends in large part on the coefficients a1 and b1) may well be affected by the implementation of wage indexation. Further, threshold wage indexation may help to insulate wage determination from small, temporary price changes.
(4) In cases where workers have erroneously high expectations about the future inflation rate and where workers and labor unions are powerful enough to embody these expectations in their wage contracts, the implementation of wage indexation, ceteris paribus, may well prove to be anti-inflationary by substituting actual inflation rates for expected inflation rates. Of course, where employers hold the balance of power and have erroneously low expectations about the future inflation rate, the above conclusion will be reversed.
(5) In firms and/or industries where producers are price-setters rather than price-takers, wage indexation may improve the government’s ability to deal with inflation by reducing the time lag between aggregate demand changes and price changes. However, even under full wage indexation, producers will not have complete assurance that their price cuts will be matched by a corresponding decline in money wages.
(6) When the government attempts to reduce inflation by implementing restrictive aggregate demand policy, full wage indexation may decrease, ceteris paribus, the rise in unemployment by preventing workers from seeking money wage increases (based on expected rates of inflation) that turn out later to be too high. The slower workers are to adapt their price expectations to the actual rate of inflation, the more likely this is to occur.
II. Other Labor Market Effects of Wage Indexation
Clearly, the case for or against wage indexation does not rest exclusively on whether or not wage indexation is likely to be inflationary. In fact, some observers would argue that the inflation issue is not an important one because the social welfare consequences of a high (perfectly) anticipated rate of inflation will not be any different than those for a low anticipated rate of inflation—that is, the adverse welfare consequences of inflation are attributable to unanticipated relative price changes. In this section attention is focused on a number of other labor market implications of wage indexation, some of which are only tangentially related to the inflation issue.
the variability of real wages over time
Although workers, employers, and government policymakers are no doubt primarily concerned with the mean rate of increase of real wages over time, they may also have an interest in the variability of real wage changes. Taking a cue from portfolio theory, one might surmise that at any given mean rate of change of real wages, all three groups would prefer a lower variance in the rate of change of wages if for no other reason than that a highly variable rate of change (of real wages) will make it more difficult to plan long-term consumption, production, and stabilization decisions. The question then arises as to what effect, if any, wage indexation is likely to have on the variability of real wages over time.
It may be recalled from Section I that in the absence of indexation it will be necessary for workers and employers to base their wage bargains on the expected rate of inflation over the contract period. In some cases (perhaps most) the inflation forecasts of one or both parties will be erroneous—with the result that the aggrieved party (workers when
Let us consider a concrete example. Assume first that a one-year wage contract is signed which provides for a 10 per cent increase in money wages. Assume further that labor and management have agreed to this wage bargain on the assumption that prices will increase by 5 per cent over this one-year period so that, in effect, 50 per cent of the wage bargain represents real factors (say, increased productivity) and 50 per cent represents monetary factors. Now assume that the actual inflation rate proves to be 10 per cent. If inflation expectations and projected productivity do not change, and if labor can obtain full correction for its past forecast error, the next wage bargain will provide for a 15 per cent increase in money wages (where the 15 per cent equals 5 per cent for productivity, 5 per cent for expected inflation, and 5 per cent for inflation correction). This time assume that the actual inflation rate proves to be 3 per cent. If the same assumptions are retained (with the exception that management is now the recipient of the inflation correction), the third money wage bargain will be for 8 per cent. Finally, assume that the actual inflation rate in the third period is 5 per cent. Calculating the increase in real wages for each period, it can be seen by inspection that the three increases will be zero, 12 percent, and 3 per cent—a mean rate of increase in real wages of 5 per cent over the three-year period. It might also be noted that one could generate the same time path of money and real wage changes by dropping the inflation correction factor and by replacing the assumption
Now repeat the same exercise, assuming full wage indexation—that is, assume that the money wage bargain in each period equals 5 per cent for projected productivity plus the actual rate of inflation over the period. In this case, the increase in real wages will obviously be 5 per cent in each period, so that the mean rate of increase over the three-year period will be identical to that without indexation. The variance of real wage changes will, however, be much smaller than in the case without indexation; in the above example, this variance under full indexation would be zero.
While the preceding exercise is admittedly a stylized one based on rather restrictive assumptions, it illustrates that full wage indexation is likely to lead to greater stability of real wages over time. As such, full wage indexation is also likely to lead to less variability of employment over time, since in classical employment theory the demand for employment is a negative function of the real wage. It should be noted, however, that so long as the expected real wage equals the actual real wage in the long run, the level of employment will be the same with full indexation as without it, other things being held equal.
To the extent that the variability of real wages is reduced by indexation, the mean rate of increase of real (and money) wages may in turn also be affected, although the outcome in this case is difficult to predict since it depends, inter alia, on the characteristics of the utility functions of workers and employers (about which only very limited indirect information is available). For illustrative purposes, assume that the utility of workers varies positively with the real wage and negatively with the variance of real wages, and also assume that the corresponding utility function for employers varies negatively with the real wage but positively with the variance of real wages (that is, assume that workers are risk averters and employers are risk lovers). In such a case, if the variance of real wages falls, the mean level of real wages (or its rate of increase) should fall as well so as to keep the utility of both parties unchanged. In other words, workers will be willing and, just as importantly, will be required to accept a lower real wage to pay for the insurance that indexation provides against variability of real wages. On the other hand, under the seemingly more plausible assumption that employers are also risk averters, both parties will be “better off” when the variance of real wages is reduced; hence, no change in the mean level of real wages should be forthcoming. In the cases where either (but not both) workers or employers are risk neutral, the results appear to be indeterminate if no additional assumptions are made about the properties of the two utility functions. Unfortunately, there have been no attempts (to the author’s knowledge) to test empirically the relationship between changes in aggregate money (or real) wages and the variability of wages so that the practical importance of the above issue remains unanswered.29
the duration of labor contracts
As mentioned previously, one of the presumed advantages of indexation is that it removes the uncertainty associated with future changes in the price level. In other words, when there is no indexation, workers and employers will be assuming a risk when they enter into labor contracts denominated in nominal terms. Further, under the assumption that it will be more difficult to forecast prices accurately in period t + 1 than in period t, this risk will be greater the longer the contract period is. Thus, in situations where inflation rates are high and variable and where workers and employers are risk averters, one would expect labor contracts to be of relatively short duration (probably less than one year).
With the introduction of full wage indexation, one can expect the time duration of most labor contracts to increase because both workers and employers will be protected against unforeseen price changes.30 For example, it has been reported that if it were not for the semiannual cost of living adjustment in most wage contracts, labor unions in Denmark would insist on one-year contracts rather than the two-year or three-year contracts commonly found in practice (see Ulman and Flanagan, 1971, pp. 125–26). To the extent that indexation increases the length of contracts, it is likely to generate some cost savings for employers and workers since wages will not have to be renegotiated as frequently as in the absence of indexation.
aggregate strike activity and industrial peace
Another important factor to consider in assessing the case for or against wage indexation is its probable impact on aggregate strike activity in the economy. Even a casual reading of the literature on industrial strike activity suggests a number of channels by which indexation might be expected to affect the number and duration of strikes in an economy. For the purposes of this paper, it will suffice to mention three such channels. First, although econometric modeling of aggregate strike activity is still in its infancy, there seems to be growing support for the hypothesis that strike frequency (and duration) varies inversely with both the rate of change of real wages (over, say, the preceding two-year period) and the unemployment rate.31 Thus, ceteris paribus, if indexation leads to a larger increase in real wages, it should in turn lead to lower strike activity. Second, to the extent that indexation leads to a lengthening of the duration of labor contracts, it should, ceteris paribus, reduce the number of strikes because, at least in countries where labor contracts are legally binding on both parties, strikes can occur only when existing contracts expire. If the number of strikes occurring in a given year (5) is thought of as being equal to the number of labor contracts negotiated in that year (NL) times the probability that a negotiation will end in a strike (Ps)—that is, S = NL · Ps—then indexation can reduce S by reducing NL. Third, and finally, if it is assumed that some strikes occur because labor and management cannot agree on the expected future rate of inflation, then indexation, by eliminating the need for such inflation forecasts, can remove one potential area of disagreement from the negotiations and hence, ceteris paribus, can reduce the number of strikes.
The above analysis suggests that even if wage indexation leads to a larger increase in both money and real wages than would occur in the absence of indexation, the indexation-induced increase in real wages may produce some offsetting benefit to employers in the form of more favorable and more stable labor relations. Laidler (1974), for example, has recently put forward the view that the increasing tendency for U.S. labor contracts to include cost of living escalator clauses has surely contributed to the lack of industrial strife that has accompanied accelerating inflation in the United States. In a similar vein, Wallich (1971) has suggested that “no strike pledges” might be obtained from employees whose labor contracts provide for full cost of living protection. It should be noted, however, that until there is greater certainty about the effect of wage indexation on the rate of change of money (and real) wages, it cannot be predicted with very much confidence what effect wage indexation will have on aggregate strike activity.
the functional distribution of income
Up to this point, the discussion has centered primarily on the probable impact of wage indexation on the rate of change of the price of labor services—that is, on the rate of change of money (or real) wages. Even if, however, it could be unambiguously demonstrated that wage indexation would lead to a larger increase in the rate of change of money wages, it would not necessarily follow that labor’s share in industry (or national) income would increase. This is because increases in money wages lead, ceteris paribus, to decreases in employment and because labor’s share in national income reflects both the price of labor services and the quantity of labor employed.32 More specifically, given some increase in money wages, labor’s share in income will rise, fall, or remain constant as the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital is less than, greater than, or equal to unity, respectively. Further, following Hicks (1963), the elasticity of employment with respect to money wages (the elasticity of the derived demand for labor) will be greater as the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital and the price elasticity of demand for the final product become greater. Also, in cases where the price elasticity of demand exceeds the elasticity of substitution, the elasticity of the derived demand for labor will be larger as labor’s share becomes larger.33
The above discussion suggests that, in order to predict the likely effect of wage indexation on the functional distribution of income between labor and capital, it will be necessary to know the size of the elasticity of substitution, as well as the effect of wage indexation per se on the rate of change of money wages. Unfortunately, despite a voluminous econometric literature on the subject (see the review of the empirical evidence in Nerlove, 1967), there seems to be no agreement on whether this elasticity is greater than, less than, or equal to unity.34 Early direct estimates of the elasticity of substitution by Arrow and others (1961) suggested a value less than unity for most of the 24 countries in their sample, but these estimates have subsequently been challenged. Further, it is extremely doubtful that the effect of past wage indexation policies on the change in labor’s share could be identified by comparing changes in labor’s share between countries with and without indexation because indexation is sure to be only one of the many factors responsible for such changes (and probably a relatively unimportant factor). Thus, while it is by now well documented (for example, see Kravis, 1968, and Heidensohn, 1969) that labor’s share in national income has been steadily rising in most countries for at least the past three to four decades, there is as yet no evidence that wage indexation, where applied, has contributed to such a change.35
In sum if, as sometimes assumed, wage indexation leads to a larger increase in money wages than would occur in the absence of indexation, and if the elasticity of substitution is less than unity, labor’s share in national income will increase as a result of the implementation of indexation. At present, however, neither of these two assumptions can be accepted with a great deal of confidence. What is more predictable is that if wage indexation induces a faster growth in real wages without affecting the productivity of labor, it will also induce, ceteris paribus, some decrease in employment.
other labor market effects of indexation
The analysis presented in this section suggests the following tentative conclusions about the effects of wage indexation on the labor market:
(1) Full wage indexation is likely to lead to greater stability of real wage movements over time; as such, wage indexation should also lead, ceteris paribus, to greater stability of employment over time and, hence, to a reduction in the fixed hiring, training, and lay-off costs associated with changes in employment.
(2) To the extent that wage indexation eliminates the need to forecast future inflation rates and to the extent that these forecasts in the absence of indexation are often incorrect, wage indexation may well lead to a more efficient allocation of labor resources in the economy by reducing the number of erroneous labor force and employment decisions based on incorrect perceptions of relative prices.
(3) Full wage indexation is quite likely to lead to a lengthening of the duration of labor contracts and in turn to some cost savings for both employers and workers, since the costs associated with frequent wage renegotiations will be diminished.
(4) Wage indexation may well lead to a decrease in aggregate strike activity in the economy if it leads either to an increase in real wages or to a lengthening of the duration of labor contracts, or to a reduction in those strikes caused by divergent views of management and labor on the expected rate of inflation.
(5) If wage indexation leads to an increase in money wages, it will lead to a decrease in employment, ceteris paribus; however, the probable effect of wage indexation on labor’s share in national income is not clear, since there is at present considerable uncertainty about the size of the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital in most countries.
III. Wage Indexation and Exchange Rate Policy
A further point to consider in appraising the case for or against wage indexation is how wage indexation is likely to affect the government’s ability to pursue and to attain its domestic and international policy targets; that is, how is wage indexation likely to affect the efficacy of exchange rate and stabilization policies?36 Since the effect of wage indexation on anti-inflationary stabilization policy has already been discussed in Section I (the Friedman-Laidler and Morley hypotheses), attention is turned in this section toward the likely effect of wage indexation on the efficacy of exchange rate policy. Further, since much of the discussion in the literature has been addressed to the impact of wage indexation on the effectiveness of a devaluation, this issue is emphasized below.
wage indexation and devaluation
As is well known, one of the traditional arguments for devaluation is that it is a viable method of reducing the real wage (thereby improving the economy’s international competitive position) in countries where money wages are inflexible downward. In other words, it is argued that workers will accept a reduction in their real standard of living that is induced by devaluation which they would not accept in the form of a forced reduction of domestic money wages. This argument, however, rests on the implicit assumption that the money wage response to price changes (the coefficient a1 is less than unity (see Goldstein, 1974). Therefore, it is sometimes concluded that full wage indexation will prevent devaluation from having a positive effect on the trade balance, since under such a policy a1 will be equal to unity.
In evaluating the impact of wage indexation on the efficacy of devaluation policy, it is necessary to consider the following factors. First, to the extent that the a1 coefficient is close to unity in the absence of wage indexation, full wage indexation will have very little effect on the efficacy of a devaluation—that is, devaluation will not bring about much, if any, reduction in the real wage in either case. Second, for the cases of partial or threshold wage indexation—which are the most popular in practice—the a1 coefficient with indexation might be less than that in the absence of indexation; in such cases, devaluation might be more effective with indexation than without it. For example, with threshold indexation it will be possible to obtain a reduction in the real wage from devaluation as long as the devaluation does not push price changes up to or beyond the threshold point.37 Third, it may be possible to reduce the wage response to a devaluation with indexation if the price index used in the indexation formula does not contain imported (finished) goods—for example, by linking wages to the gross national product deflator rather than to the consumer or retail price index. However, if imported goods represent a significant proportion of consumption and investment expenditures, workers are apt to become dissatisfied with a wage determination formula that permits the international purchasing power of their income to fall over time. Finally, it may be recalled that in the absence of indexation, wage changes will be based, inter alia, on the expected rate of inflation. If the expected rate of inflation, in turn, is a positive function not only of present and past actual rates of inflation but also of the devaluation itself, then indexation may reduce, ceteris paribus, money wage changes by substituting the actual rate of inflation for the higher expected rate of inflation. Once again, however, it is unfortunately not really possible to evaluate this effect because very little is known about the impact of government policy decisions on the formation of price expectations.
In sum, it does not necessarily follow that wage indexation will make devaluation a completely ineffective or even a less effective policy instrument. Further, even if indexation did have an adverse effect on the efficacy of devaluation policy, it could always be temporarily suspended so that devaluation could have its intended relative price effects. For example, cost of living escalator clauses in wage contracts were suspended for a one-year period in Denmark after the 1967 devaluation so as to increase the effectiveness of that devaluation (see Vega, 1973).
IV. Conclusions
In this paper an attempt has been made to provide an eclectic review and analysis of some of the important issues associated with wage indexation. One of the dominant’ conclusions is that few meaningful generalizations can be made about the probable effects of wage indexation because these effects will vary with the type of wage indexation under study (full indexation, partial indexation, threshold indexation, and so on) and with the assumptions made about the behavior of the labor market in the absence of indexation. Further, although a voluminous econometric literature exists on aggregate wage, price, and employment determination, this empirical literature is of only limited use for analyzing the effects of wage indexation because the empirical studies were not really designed for estimating the separate effect of wage indexation on these variables.
Despite the considerable uncertainty that surrounds most of the expected costs and benefits associated with the implementation of wage indexation, it was found that certain tentative conclusions could be drawn on a number of important issues. More specifically, as regards the inflationary impact of wage indexation, it has been argued: (1) that full wage indexation is likely to be more inflationary if implemented during a period of low or moderate inflation than during a period of high and prolonged inflation; (2) that partial and threshold indexation are likely, ceteris paribus, to be less inflationary than full wage indexation; (3) that a wage-price spiral will exist with or without indexation but that the size of this spiral (which depends in large part upon the coefficients ax and bx) may be affected by wage indexation; (4) that threshold indexation may help to insulate wage determination from small, temporary price changes but that this protection is not likely to be of much practical concern unless indexation is introduced when past inflation rates have been low; (5) that wage indexation may help to moderate inflation (by substituting actual for expected inflation rates) when workers have erroneously high expectations about the future inflation rate and when they are powerful enough to embody these expectations in wage contracts; and (6) that wage indexation may lead to an increased effectiveness for anti-inflationary stabilization policy, both by reducing the time lag between aggregate demand changes and price changes and by temporarily reducing the employment losses induced by aggregate demand reductions; however, neither of these latter effects can at present be forecast with much confidence.
Turning to some other labor market effects of wage indexation, it was suggested that wage indexation may well lead to: (1) less variability of real wages over time and thus to more stability in employment; (2) a lengthening of the time duration of labor contracts; (3) a decrease in aggregate strike activity (if wage indexation is associated with an increase in real wages or a decrease in the frequency of wage negotiations, or a decrease in those strikes caused by conflicting views over the future rate of inflation); and (4) to an increase in labor’s share in national income (if indexation induces an increase in money wages and if the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital is less than unity). As with the inflation issue, however, none of these effects can be forecast with great confidence, especially as regards the effect of wage indexation on aggregate strike activity and on labor’s share.
Finally, while it has often been argued that full wage indexation will eliminate or drastically reduce the positive impact of a devaluation on the trade balance, it was argued that this conclusion need not be true. In fact, the efficacy of devaluation will probably be seriously reduced by wage indexation only when the money wage response to price changes with indexation is higher than that without indexation. Further, in cases where price expectations themselves are a positive function of devaluation, wage indexation may help to reduce the total change in money wages that is induced by devaluation.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Arrow, Kenneth J., Hollis B. Chenery, Bagicha S. Minhas, and Robert M. Solow, “Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 43 (August 1961), pp. 225–50.
Artus, Jacques R., “The 1967 Devaluation of the Pound Sterling,” Staff Papers, Vol. 22 (November 1975), pp. 595–640.
Ashenfelter, Orley, and George E. Johnson, “Bargaining Theory, Trade Unions, and Industrial Strike Activity,” American Economic Review, Vol. 59 (March 1969), pp. 35–49.
Ashenfelter, Orley, and John H. Pencavel, “Wage Changes and the Frequency of Wage Settlements,” Economica, Vol. 42 (May 1975), pp. 162–70.
Bach, G. L., and Albert Ando, “The Redistributional Effects of Inflation,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39 (February 1957), pp. 1–13.
Bach, G. L., and James B. Stephenson, “Inflation and the Redistribution of Wealth,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 56 (February 1974), pp. 1–13.
Bernstein, E. M., “Wage-Price Links in a Prolonged Inflation,” Staff Papers, Vol. 6 (November 1958), pp. 323–68.
Bernstein, E. M., “Indexing Money Payments in a Large and Prolonged Inflation,” in Essays on Inflation and Indexation (American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, 1974), pp. 71–86.
Bhatia, Kul B., “Index-Linking of Financial Contracts: A Survey of the State-of-the-Arts” (unpublished, International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, June 1974).
Black, S. W., and H. H. Kelejian, “A Macro Model of the U. S. Labor Market,” Econometrica, Vol. 38 (September 1970), pp. 712–41.
Bodkin, Ronald G., Elizabeth P. Bond, Grant L. Reuber, and T. Russell Robinson, Price Stability and High Employment: The Options for Canadian Economic Policy (Economic Council of Canada, Ottawa, 1967).
Boelaert, Remi, “Unemployment-Inflation Trade-Offs in EEC Countries,” Welt-wirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 109, No. 3 (1973), pp. 418–51.
Braun, Anne Romanis, “Indexation of Wages and Salaries in Developed Economies” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, July 30, 1975; forthcoming in Staff Papers, March 1976).
Brown, Murray, “Introduction,” in The Theory and Empirical Analysis of Production, edited by Murray Brown (National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1967).
Budd, Edward C, and David F. Seiders, “The Impact of Inflation on the Distribution of Income and Wealth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 61 (May 1971), pp. 128–38.
Cargill, Thomas F., and Robert A. Meyer, “Wages, Prices and Unemployment: Distributed Lag Estimates,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 69 (March 1974), pp. 98–107.
Choudhry, Nanda K., Yehuda Kotowitz, John A. Sawyer, and John W. L. Winder, TRACE, 1969—An Econometric Model of the Canadian Economy, Institute for the Quantitative Analysis of Social and Economic Policy (University of Toronto Press, 1969).
Collier, Robert P., Purchasing Power Bonds and Other Escalated Contracts (Taipei, 1969).
Day, Alan, “A New Stake in the Country?,” Westminster Bank Review (February 1964), pp. 2–11.
De Menil, George, and Jared J. Enzler, “Prices and Wages in the FR-MIT-Penn Econometric Model,” in The Econometrics of Price Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein (Washington, 1972), pp. 277–308.
Dernburg, Thomas F., “The Macroeconomic Implications of Wage Retaliation Against Higher Taxation,” Staff Papers, Vol. 21 (November 1974), pp. 758–88.
Dernburg, Thomas F., “Inflation Indexing of the Personal Income Tax: The Case from the Perspective of Stabilization Policy” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, February 14, 1975).
Eckstein, Otto, and Roger Brinner, “The Inflation Process in the United States,” a study prepared for the use of the Joint Economic Committee, 92nd Congress, 2nd Session (Washington, 1972).
Fishlow, Albert, “Indexing Brazilian Style: Inflation Without Tears?,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1 (1974), pp. 261–82.
Flanagan, Robert J., “The U. S. Phillips Curve and International Unemployment Rate Differentials,” American Economic Review, Vol. 63 (March 1973), pp. 114–31.
Friedman, Milton, “Monetary Correction,” in Essays on Inflation and Indexation” (American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, 1974), pp. 25–61.
Giersch, Herbert, “Index Clauses and the Fight Against Inflation,” in Essays on Inflation and Indexation (American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, 1974), pp. 1–23.
Goldstein, Morris, “The Trade-Off Between Inflation and Unemployment: A Survey of the Econometric Evidence of Selected Countries,” Staff Papers, Vol. 19 (November 1972), pp. 647–95.
Goldstein, Morris, “The Effect of Exchange Rate Changes on Wages and Prices in the United Kingdom: An Empirical Study,” Staff Papers, Vol. 21 (November 1974), pp. 694–731.
Gordon, Robert J., (1971a) “Inflation in Recession and Recovery,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1 (1971), pp. 105–66.
Gordon, Robert J., (1971b) “Steady Anticipated Inflation: Mirage or Oasis?,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2 (1971), pp. 499–510.
Guenther, Jack D., “The Role of Indexing in Brazil’s Economic Policies” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, November 18, 1974).
Hamermesh, Daniel S., “Wage Bargains, Threshold Effects, and the Phillips Curve,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84 (August 1970), pp. 501–17.
Heidensohn, K., “Labour’s Share in National Income—A Constant?,” Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 37 (December 1969), pp. 295–321.
Heien, Dale, and Joel Popkin, “Price Determination and Cost-of-Living Measures in a Disaggregated Model of the U. S. Economy,” in The Econometrics of Price Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein (Washington, 1972), pp. 184–201.
Helliwell, John E., Lawrence H. Officer, Harold T. Shapiro, and Ian A. Stewart, The Structure of RDXI, Bank of Canada Research Study No. 3 (July 1969).
Hicks, John Richard, The Theory of Wages (London, second edition, 1963).
Hines, A. G., “Trade Unions and Wage Inflation in the United Kingdom, 1893-1961,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 31 (October 1964), pp. 221–52.
Hirsch, Albert A., “Price Simulations with the OBE Econometric Model,” in The Econometrics of Price Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein (Washington, 1972), pp. 237–76.
Hymans, Saul H., and Harold T. Shapiro, The DHL-III Quarterly Econometric Model of the U. S. Economy (University of Michigan, 1970).
Kafka, Alexandre, “Indexing for Inflation in Brazil,” in Essays on Inflation and Indexation (American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, 1974), pp. 87–98.
Kaliski, S. F., “The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in Canada,” International Economic Review, Vol. 5 (January 1964), pp. 1–33.
Kessel, Reuben A., and A. A. Alchian, “Effects of Inflation,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 70 (December 1962), pp. 521–37.
Knöbl, Adalbert, “Price Expectations and Actual Price Behavior in Germany,” Staff Papers, Vol. 21 (March 1974), pp. 83–100.
Kravis, Irving B., “Income Distribution: Functional Share,” International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, Vol. 7 (1968), pp. 132–45.
Kuh, E., “A Productivity Theory of Wage Levels—An Alternative to the Phillips Curve,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34 (October 1967), pp. 333–60.
Laidler, David, “The 1974 Report of the President’s Council of Economic Advisers: The Control of Inflation and the Future of the International Monetary System,” American Economic Review, Vol. 64 (September 1974), pp. 535–43.
Lipsey, Richard G., “The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1862-1957: A Further Analysis,” Economica, Vol. 27 (February 1960), pp. 1–31.
Lipsey, Richard G., and J. M. Parkin, “Incomes Policy: A Re-Appraisal,” Economica, Vol. 37 (May 1970), pp. 115–38.
Morley, Samuel A., “Indexing and the Fight Against Inflation” (unpublished, University of Wisconsin, 1974).
Nerlove, Marc Leon, “Recent Empirical Studies of the CES and Related Production Functions,” in The Theory and Empirical Analysis of Production, edited by Murray Brown (National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1967), pp. 55–122.
Nordhaus, William D., (1972a) “Recent Development in Price Dynamics,” in The Econometrics of Price Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein (Washington, 1972), pp. 16–49.
Nordhaus, William D., (1972b) “The Worldwide Wage Explosion,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2 (1972), pp. 431–65.
Okun, Arthur M., “The Mirage of Steady Inflation,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2 (1971), pp. 485–98.
Oi, Walter Y., “On Measuring the Impact of Wage-Price Controls: A Critical Appraisal,” Industrial Relations Section, Working Paper No. 45, Princeton University (February 1974).
Oi, Walter Y., “Labor as a Quasi-Fixed Factor,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 70 (December 1962), pp. 538–55.
Page, S. A. B., and Sandra Trollope, “An International Survey of Indexing and Its Effects,” National Institute Economic Review, No. 70 (November 1974), pp. 46–60.
Pencavel, John H., “An Investigation into Industrial Strike Activity in Britain,” Economica, Vol. 37 (August 1970), pp. 239–56.
Perna, Nicholas, “Cost of Living Escalator Clauses in Collective Bargaining Contracts,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Research Paper No. 7334 (December 1973).
Perry, George L., “Changing Labor Markets and Inflation,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 3 (1970), pp. 411–48.
Rees, Albert, The Economics of Work and Pay (New York, 1973).
Rowley, J. C. R., and D. A. Wilton, “Quarterly Models of Wage Determination: Some New Efficient Estimates,” American Economic Review, Vol. 63 (June 1973), pp. 380–89.
Schultze, Charles L., and Joseph L. Tryon, “Prices and Wages,” in The Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States, edited by James S. Duesenberry and others (Chicago, 1965), pp. 281–333.
Simler, N. J., and A. Tella, “Labor Reserves and the Phillips Curve,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50 (February 1968), pp. 32–49.
Smith, David C, “Incomes Policy,” in Britain’s Economic Prospects, edited by Richard E. Caves and associates (Washington, 1968), pp. 104–44.
Spitäller, Erich, “Semi-Annual Wage Equations for the Manufacturing Sectors in Six Major Industrial Countries, 1957(1)-72(2)” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, March 14, 1975).
Sumner, Michael T., “Aggregate Demand, Price Expectations, and the Phillips Curve,” in Incomes Policy and Inflation, edited by Michael Parkin and Michael T. Sumner (Manchester University Press, Manchester, England, 1972).
Tobin, James, (1972a) “The Wage-Price Mechanism: Overview of the Conference,” in The Econometrics of Price Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein (Washington, 1972), pp. 5–15.
Tobin, James, (1972b) “Inflation and Unemployment,” American Economic Review, Vol. 62 (March 1972), pp. 2–18.
Toyoda, Toshihisa, “Price Expectations and the Short-Run and Long-Run Phillips Curves in Japan, 1956-68,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54 (August 1972), pp. 267–74.
Turnovsky, Stephen J., “The Expectations Hypothesis and the Aggregate Wage Equation: Some Empirical Evidence for Canada,” Economica, Vol. 39 (February 1972), pp. 1–17.
Turnovsky, Stephen J., and Michael L. Wachter, “A Test of the ‘Expectations Hypothesis’ Using Directly Observed Wage and Price Expectations,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54 (February 1972), pp. 47–54.
Ulman, Lloyd, and Robert J. Flanagan, Wage Restraint: A Study of Incomes Policies in Western Europe (Berkeley, California, 1971).
Vanderkamp, John, “Economic Activity and Strikes in Canada,” Industrial Relations, Vol. 9 (February 1970), pp. 215–30.
Wallich, H., Newsweek (January 25, 1971), p. 76.
White, William H., “The Anti-Inflationary Advantages from Indexation of Financial Contracts” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund).
Zaidi, M. A., “The Determinants of Money Wage Rate Changes and Unemployment—Inflation ‘Trade-Offs in Canada,” International Economic Review, Vol. 10 (June 1969), pp. 207–19.
Zoeteweij, Bert, “The Adjustment of Wages to Changes in the Cost of Living,” International Labour Review, Vol. 66 (August 1952), pp. 89–112.
Mr. Goldstein, an economist in the Special Studies Division of the Research Department, is a graduate of Rutgers University and of New York University. He was formerly a Research Fellow in Economics at The Brookings Institution.
Proposals for indexing apparently date back to at least the year 1707; see Friedman (1974) for a good description of the historical development of the “tabular standard.”
For analyses of the redistributional and resource allocation effects of unanticipated inflation, see Bach and Ando (1957), Budd and Seiders (1971), Kessel and Alchian (1972), and Bach and Stephenson (1974).
Economic theory suggests that the only social cost stemming from perfectly anticipated inflation is the wasteful use of resources to economize holdings of currency and other noninterest-bearing means of payment. See Tobin (1972b, p. 15) for an analysis of the likely social cost of perfectly anticipated inflation in the United States.
While there is no doubt that the inflation rate in Brazil fell substantially during the period of indexation (from about 100 per cent in 1964 to about 16 per cent in 1972), there is some controversy as to whether and how wage indexation affected this decline. For analyses of the Brazilian experience, see Fishlow (1974), Guenther (1974), and Kafka (1974).
For treatments of the effects of indexing financial instruments, see Bhatia (1974) and White (1974). An analysis of the effects of indexation of the personal income tax can be found in Dernburg (1975).
Rather detailed descriptions of the indexation policies adopted in various countries can be found in Bernstein (1958), Giersch (1974), Vega (1973), Braun (1975), and Zoeteweij (1952).
One can always argue (as does Friedman, 1974, p. 44) that wage indexation cannot be inflationary (or deflationary) because escalator clauses go into effect only as the result of a previous price increase. This line of reasoning, however, seems to ignore the important fact that the wage response to (past) price changes will in part determine the size of the wage-price spiral. Thus, while wage indexation may not be the original cause of inflation, it can be an important factor in the inflation transmission process.
The fact that it is so difficult to hold other things equal is probably the primary reason why there has been so little empirical work on the effects of indexation. For example, Page and Trollope (1974, p. 51) have written: “To determine the effect that indexation has had in practice, in the limited and incomplete forms in which it has been used, is impossible in any rigorous way because it was rarely introduced as the only change in policy.”
More specifically, in equilibrium, the time path of nominal wages should be determined by the time path of the value of labor’s marginal product (see Kuh, 1967). Note that for expositional convenience γ has been defined in real rather than in nominal terms in equation (1), although economic theory suggests that the latter formulation is the correct one. For the purposes of this study however, the exclusion of output prices from equation (1), given the presence of consumer prices (P) in the equation, should not have any serious consequences for the subsequent analysis.
If
However, so long as
Since econometric estimates of b1 at least those for the United States, suggest that b1 ≃ 1, the size of the a1 coefficient takes on crucial importance for the stability of the wage-price system (see Tobin, 1972a). It should be noted, however, that past econometric estimates of b1 may well be biased upward because most price equations have omitted capital prices (R) and because it is probable that
This paper deals only with wage indexation schemes that provide for percentage changes in W when there are percentage changes in P. In some cases, however, wage indexation has operated by providing for a lump sum increase in W for every percentage change in P (for example, workers might receive a $50 increase for every 1 per cent increase in the cost of living). For the most part, lump sum indexation has been used as a means of narrowing wage differentials over time between higher-paid and lower-paid workers, since the lump sum payment represents a larger percentage increase in W for lower-paid than for higher-paid workers.
Note that if price changes were the sole determinant of
The above conclusion will hold only for positive price changes. When negative price changes are considered, the necessary condition for wage indexation to be inflationary, ceteris paribus, is that the a1 coefficient with indexation must be less than that in the absence of indexation. While not all wage indexation formulas provide for symmetric indexation, the analysis in this paper (for reasons of length) deals only with positive price changes
Once again, the reader is reminded that one can identify the a1 parameter from the empirical literature only by making some specific a priori assumption about the relationship between actual and expected price changes.
In countries where wage indexation has been present for some periods but not for others, one might try to obtain an estimate of a1 for the years without indexation. However, in many cases there may not be enough observations for these years to obtain a reliable estimate of a1. Further, it is at least possible that in cases where indexation has at times been made mandatory that wage behavior in the period without indexation will be affected by the threat (or expectation) of future indexation. For example, employers may voluntarily and without written agreement provide for an a1 coefficient close to unity to forestall formal indexation. Similarly, in industries without formal indexation, employers may provide for a unitary a1 coefficient on a temporary basis to forestall formal indexation. In both cases, the period without indexation or “policy-off” industries will not make for a good control group because they will be affected by the policy (for a good discussion of this general problem, see Oi, 1974).
At present, about 60 per cent of all employees in manufacturing industries in the United States are covered by escalator clauses (see Giersch, 1974, p. 19, and Perna, 1973). Escalator clauses apparently now cover about 20 per cent of all wage and salary workers in the United Kingdom (see Braun, 1975). No corresponding estimate could be found for Canada.
This presumption is based on the fact that most estimated wage equations (known to the author) that include the 1968–72 period in the sample suggest estimates of a1 not much below unity, and on the assumption that inclusion of the observations for 1973 and 1974 would move the a1 coefficient even closer to unity.
Obviously, even when a1 = 1, there will always be some people who are not receiving “full” cost of living protection because the price index does not accurately reflect their consumption pattern. This problem, however, is ignored in this study.
In the present period in which inflation rates are in excess of 5 per cent a year, threshold indexation will in effect be equivalent to full indexation; thus, unless the threshold rate is set very high, threshold indexation is not likely to offer any anti-inflationary benefits in the current period.
While wage indexation has typically involved indexing money wages on past actual price changes, it should be mentioned that some countries (for example, Brazil and the Netherlands) have experimented with wage indexation schemes that link wages to expected or forecasted inflation rates over the contract period (ex ante indexation). In some cases, money wages are adjusted if the forecast turns out to be incorrect, while no correction is made in other cases. As an example of the latter, it has been argued that the decline in real wages in Brazil during the 1966–67 period was largely attributable to the consistent underestimates of the inflation rate made by the Government during that period (see Guenther, 1974, p. 5).
As Morley (1974, p. 3) has argued, “… the economy with full COL adjustment would operate just like the neoclassical economy of macroeconomic theory, in which employment and output are determined by productivity and willingness to work, and in which the money supply only determines the price level with no feedback into the real workings of the economy.”
Although reference to equation (3) implies that the expected rate of inflation is some function of past actual rates of inflation,
For three notable attempts to use survey data on price expectations in the aggregate wage equation or in the aggregate price equation (for the United States, Canada, and the Federal Republic of Germany, respectively), see Turnovsky and Wachter (1972), Turnovsky (1972), and Knöbl (1974).
It should be noted that both Day and Collier were writing during a period of low or moderate inflation, at least by today’s standards. Also, see Okun (1971, p. 492) for a view of the “announcement effect” of indexation that is supportive of Day and Collier.
For example, Friedman argues that with indexation producers will be more inclined to cut prices in response to a fall in demand because of the assurance that price cuts will reduce their wage costs.
In principle, such an empirical study could be done for any country that has had alternating periods of indexation and nonindexation. In practice, however, it is likely to be very difficult to separate empirically the influence of indexation from that of other factors affecting time lags in the wage-price-employment determination process.
For a real world example of this inflation correction factor at work, see Friedman’s (1974, p. 34) discussion of the 1967 wage contract between General Motors and the United Automobile Workers Union.
There has, however, been some empirical work on the relationship between the mean rate of price inflation and its variability which suggests that the two are positively correlated (see Okun, 1971; and Gordon, 1971b).
See Ashenfelter and Johnson (1969) for the United States, Pencavel (1970) for the United Kingdom, and Vanderkamp (1970) for Canada.
The conclusion that an increase in the money wage leads to a decrease in employment (demand) depends on the assumptions that output price, other input prices, and the level of output are all held constant—that is, on the assumptions usually made in drawing a factor demand curve. However, if the government increases demand to prevent employment from falling, then money wages and employment might well rise together. In other words, the analysis in this section traces only the first-round effects of a money wage increase, holding all other factors constant.
For the case where the supply elasticity of capital is infinite, the elasticity of the derived demand for labor (λ) can be written as
For a similar agnostic conclusion on the value of the elasticity of substitution, see Brown (1967).
It should be noted that there exists some controversy in the literature as to how labor’s share should be measured, given the steady growth of government in national income (labor’s share in government output being unity by definition) and the steady decline in self-employment. Nevertheless, even when adjustment is made for these factors, labor’s share still shows an increase over time in most countries (for example, see Kravis, 1968; and Rees, 1973, pp. 215–16).
It should be noted that if money wages are fully indexed on a price index that includes indirect taxes, indexation will, in effect, make wage earners exempt from sales and excise taxes (see Bernstein, 1974), and therefore will reduce the efficacy of tax policy. Here again, however, care must be taken to compare the outcome under indexation with the outcome in the absence of indexation. In this latter regard, there is tentative evidence that money wage changes in the absence of indexation vary positively with increases in direct and indirect taxes (see Gordon, 1971a, and Dernburg, 1974, on this point).
Clearly, if devaluation is instituted when the domestic inflation rate is already high, threshold indexation will not be of much use because the threshold will in all likelihood be exceeded.