Abstract
COMPARED WITH THE TREATMENT of international trade, the analysis of international capital movements is still in a rudimentary stage of development. Over the past two decades, important advances have been made in both the theoretical and econometric studies of the trade balance, making possible a fairly rigorous statistical inquiry and quantitative projections on an individual country level and on a general equilibrium multicountry basis. Nothing comparable is as yet possible for the capital account.
COMPARED WITH THE TREATMENT of international trade, the analysis of international capital movements is still in a rudimentary stage of development. Over the past two decades, important advances have been made in both the theoretical and econometric studies of the trade balance, making possible a fairly rigorous statistical inquiry and quantitative projections on an individual country level and on a general equilibrium multicountry basis. Nothing comparable is as yet possible for the capital account.
However, recent years have seen some tangible progress in the theory and empirical analysis of short-term capital movements. Such progress reflects to some extent a fairly rich experience in coping, during the interwar period, with short-term capital movements of all kinds. However, the major influence has been the increasing attention paid, since the 1950s, to the role of short-term capital flows in the balance of payments adjustment process and to the effect of the increased capital mobility on domestic monetary and fiscal policies of industrial countries. Recent developments in monetary theory and in econometric techniques have contributed also to a more rigorous analysis of the role of short-term capital movements in the equilibrium on the foreign exchange market. Furthermore, these developments have permitted a more systematic quantitative analysis of the determinants of short-term capital movements.
Short-term capital movements play a much more important role in the domestic and international adjustment processes of industrial countries, partly because these countries have highly developed foreign exchange and short-term capital markets and partly because they allow substantially greater freedom of short-term capital transactions than is true in many less developed countries. For this reason, this survey is limited to short-term capital movements among industrial countries. Furthermore, although international capital movements infringe on a vast area of domestic and international monetary policies, such policy issues as intervention by monetary authorities in the forward exchange markets, or such problems as the analysis of the functioning and the institutional developments of the Euro-currency markets, are outside the scope of this survey.
I. Theory
1. Short-term capital movements in the international adjustment mechanism
At the turn of the century, there was already some discussion of the role of short-term capital movements in the balance of payments adjustment mechanism and of their effect on the monetary policy of countries participating in trade. This discussion proceeded within the framework of the classical price specie-flow theory and of the more modern quantity theory of money applied to an open economy. Basic to the working of the price specie-flow theory was the assumption of a rather high flexibility of prices and production costs, which enabled them to respond to movements of gold and foreign exchange; the resulting adjustments in trade flows could thereby correct an initial balance of payments disequilibrium. The essential ingredients in such a process were (a) the effect of reserve movements (whether specie or foreign exchange) on the domestic money supply and (b) the resulting adjustment between relative interest rate changes, on the one hand, and prices and reserve movements, on the other hand.1 Short-term capital movements in this system were determined essentially by international differences in yields. Flows responding to yield differentials played an important role in the classical adjustment mechanism because they were thought to economize international reserves, to provide a temporary relief to the current account adjustment process, and to facilitate the transfer of real resources that are associated with long-term capital movements.2 Nurkse called such capital movements “equilibrating” because, in his opinion, they helped to restore a temporary equilibrium in the balance of payments.3 However, under the gold exchange standard, short-term capital movements also responded to expectations of exchange rate adjustments. Such movements were defined by Nurkse as “disequilibrating” because they generated flows of gold and foreign exchange and tended to aggravate the balance of payments disequilibrium.4
The classical adjustment mechanism assumed that central banks would have a passive role; they were supposed to provide merely a clearing function between the domestic currency and desired foreign currencies or gold. In most countries, central banks were also supposed to follow the “rules of the game”; they were required to manage domestic money supply in accordance with the constraints imposed by a gold and/or foreign exchange reserve ratio as prescribed by their domestic legislation.
A major shortcoming in this rather incomplete view of the complexities in the international and domestic adjustment processes was that economies were exposed to severe fluctuations in domestic credit and employment in response to a change in the country’s international reserves. Nevertheless, the classical adjustment mechanism provided a theoretical framework integrating the monetary and real sectors of national economies into an international equilibrium system that involved in a basic way both the current and capital accounts of the balance of payments. Furthermore, because of a fair amount of downward price flexibility in the period preceding World War I and a degree of flexibility in applying reserve requirements by central banks and the banking systems in most countries, the system had functioned fairly satisfactorily.
The flaws in the classical adjustment mechanism became particularly evident during the unsettled period of the gold exchange standard in the 1920s and during the severe balance of payments crises caused by the world depression in the 1930s. The monetary authorities of the major industrial countries attempted to protect their monetary sector and their domestic credit policies from erratic shifts in gold and foreign exchange induced by the effect of these disturbances on speculative behavior and on the balance of trade. Neutralization of the effects of international reserve movements on the domestic money supply permitted a degree of insulation of the domestic economy from the vagaries of gold flows, but it also perpetuated balance of payments disequilibria and further intensified destablizing speculative pressures. Substantial speculative short-term capital movements and capital flight, which were aggravated considerably by the lack of cooperation between major countries, forced monetary authorities to undertake severe protective measures that ended in competitive devaluations, in widespread controls that severely curtailed capital movements and foreign trade, and, finally, in the almost complete breakdown of the interwar system that was based on the gold exchange standard.
These experiences with speculative capital movements made free short-term capital movement suspect as an instrument in the adjustment process during the postwar reconstruction of the international monetary system.5 As restrictions on exchange and trade transactions were lifted gradually in the 1950s, attempts were made again to integrate the short-term capital account as an operational part of the balance of payments theory.6 Such efforts were directed toward two major areas of theoretical analysis. One involved attempts to define rigorously the mechanism of short-term financial flows as an integral part of the foreign exchange market and to specify the forces that determine such flows. This survey is concerned mainly with the discussion of developments in this area. The other area of analysis involved attempts to integrate national monetary sectors into a modern theory of the balance of payments adjustment. We shall briefly examine these attempts also, to the extent that they involve the theory of short-term capital movements.
2. Short-term capital movements and the foreign exchange market
In the gold standard period, which was characterized by a remarkable stablility in exchange rates, there was little interest in analyzing the mechanism of short-term capital movements beyond an a priori assumption that they responded to interest rate differentials.7 However, unpredictable movements in exchange rates during the 1920s made it mandatory to acquire forward cover for international financial transactions. Keynes was the first to see the importance of a developed forward market under conditions of exchange rate uncertainty as (1) a facility that would eliminate exchange risk from foreign trade finance and thus stimulate trade and (2) an instrument that, to some extent, could insulate domestic interest rate policy from the vagaries of gold and speculative capital flows.8 Keynes’s interest in the forward market was basically pragmatic, and he did not enter into a more rigorous theoretical analysis of the problem.9 Others provided institutional analysis of the market, stressing mainly the role of the arbitrage activity.10 Although the role of speculators in absorbing undue fluctuations in the forward rate was sometimes recognized,11 interest focused on the destabilizing effects of forward market speculation on short-term capital movements in the system of fixed parities. Such destabilizing speculation was viewed as causing substantial differences between two countries’ interest parities and a forward discount or premium.
A more rigorous theoretical inquiry into the forces determining the working of the foreign exchange market, and into the implication of these forces for short-term capital movements, was stimulated by the post-World War II revival of limited forward exchange transactions in the early 1950s.12 Tsiang (1959–60) pioneered a rigorous theoretical system that showed how hedging, speculation, and interest arbitrage, on the one hand, and activities on the spot exchange market, on the other hand, jointly played a role in an equilibrium determining both the spot and forward rates. This integration of the spot and forward exchange markets was a key to the explanation of international short-term capital movements.
Tsiang’s treatment of hedging, speculation, and interest arbitrage as independent of one another permitted a lucid analysis of factors influencing demand and supply schedules of forward and spot exchanges. However, since most transactors who participate in these markets often perform more than one activity at the same time (in particular, trade-hedgers act as speculators as well as participants in covered interest arbitrage), some motives, such as risk that may affect all three activities, are not handled adequately.
It is useful, nevertheless, to review the forces affecting the equilibrium on the forward and spot exchange markets by using, as a starting point, Tsiang’s methodology of three separate forward market activities.
Arbitrage
Tsiang started with Keynes’s proposition, which was developed formally by Spraos (1953, pp. 87–92), that there will be a net flow of short-term capital between two countries unless the forward premium (or discount) 13 on one of the two currencies is approximately equal to the difference in relevant short-term interest rates between the two countries. Tsiang, however, clarified a statement by Keynes that available arbitrage funds are limited at any point in time 14 by specifying that a marginal opportunity cost of funds available to an arbitrageur (in terms of alternative uses of his liquid assets)15 is an increasing function of the size of his commitments in any one currency. Here a variant of a portfolio selection theory can already be found. Others have also advanced reasons for the upward slope of the opportunity-cost schedule of arbitrage funds. Stoll (1968, p. 58) considered that such a slope is caused by the relatively higher default risk on foreign assets because of “a … danger that the government concerned will freeze foreign balances.” Klopstock (1965, p. 185) and Stein (1962, pp. 26–27) pointed out that, if a need arises to sell foreign assets prior to maturity, these assets, despite being covered forward, would be less liquid than comparable domestic assets. All these interpretations imply investment behavior under conditions of risk. However, risk here does not mean the exchange risk proper—since the latter is covered on the forward market—but risk related either to lack of information about the conditions in foreign financial markets 16 or to intervention by domestic or foreign governments in the freedom of short-term capital transactions.
The existence of risk, other than the foreign exchange risk, is a major reason for the existence of a net demand for foreign exchange by arbitrageurs that is less than perfectly elastic. Other reasons are the budget constraint imposed by the total asset position of the arbitrageur and the portfolio balance constraint imposed by his existing unexpired commitments.17 The greater an arbitrageur’s risk and the higher his past commitments, the larger will be the difference between the forward premium and the interest rate differential needed to induce him to enter into new forward commitments.
For an individual arbitrageur, risk in different markets is determined by his own subjective valuation. All the other factors just mentioned are taken by the arbitrageur as either exogenous variables or parameters. However, when a market demand function is obtained by summing up functions of all individual arbitrageurs, risk represents the aggregate risk valuation on the arbitrageurs’ side of the market. Total assets become an index of arbitrageurs’ wealth, while past forward commitments acquire dynamic properties, since they not only provide a constraint on undertaking a new forward position but also generate a flow of spot foreign exchange at the moment when forward contracts mature.
Speculation
The treatment of speculation is quite a difficult problem, since the explanation of such activity is based on a still unresolved theory of expectations. Speculation on the foreign exchange market results from an open position in a foreign currency following either a spot transaction or a forward contract. It can be shown, however, that a speculative position on the spot market can be expressed without loss of generality as a combination of an open position on the forward market and a covered interest arbitrage operation.18 The most important motives influencing the behavior of an individual speculator in the forward exchange market are the difference between the expected spot rate at some future time and the current forward rate for a contract maturing at that same future time, and the speculator’s estimate of risk attached to the realization of his expectations. Tsiang followed a generally accepted theory of choice in conditions of risk and expressed the expected rate as determined uniquely by the mean rate (i.e., the most likely future rate) and by the variance of the speculator’s subjective probability distribution of expectations. The variance will reflect the speculator’s estimate of the risk that the expected rate will not prove correct. In addition, the speculator’s past forward commitments should also be taken into account.19 Tsiang correctly pointed out that the time profile of past, although not yet matured, forward contracts will considerably influence the valuation of the risk of any new forward contracts.20 The speculator’s risk reflects mainly exchange rate risk, but it also incorporates risk of government intervention in the freedom of international capital transactions.
The basic weakness of Tsiang’s treatment of speculation is that his demand function for forward exchange assumes expectations of future rates to be given exogenously.21 Thus, without a theory that would provide a basis for the formation of exchange rate expectations, Tsiang’s theoretical analysis of the forward and spot exchange markets is inoperative.
A number of efforts have been made to fill this gap and to provide some theoretical basis to link the formation process of expectations to observable variables. The major difficulty lies in the need to develop an expectations function (or a set of functions) that would explain, in the present system of pegged parities, both stabilizing and destabilizing speculative behavior and also the role of the intervention points in determining such behavior.
Among attempts to handle stabilizing speculation,22 Arndt (1968, pp. 59–61) used a concept of adaptive exchange rate expectations based on Baumol’s (1957) model of speculative behavior. Arndt assumed that a speculator’s demand for foreign exchange was a function of deviations of the current observed rate from some “expected normal” rate. He then defined this expected rate as the previous period’s expected normal rate, adjusted by a fraction of the difference between it and a current observed rate. The longer the speculator’s time horizon, the smaller would be the revision of his expectations in response to temporary fluctuations in the spot rate. This approach leads to the familiar Koyck-type distributed lag model in which the demand for foreign exchange by speculators (i.e., a speculative capital flow) is a function of the change in the exchange rate and of the speculative demand from the preceding period. The size of the coefficient of the latter variable (which is a fraction) is related directly to the length of the adjustment period.23 This theoretical approach to speculative behavior has acquired considerable currency in recent years.24
The weakness of such an approach to the formation of expectations is that it relies on a past performance of the dependent variable as the only explanatory factor. In speculation on the foreign exchange market, the past performance of the rate itself is only one among a number of variables in the minds of speculators, who try to predict the future exchange rate on the basis of a variety of indicators at hand. Furthermore, a rather rigid, exponentially decreasing path of past influences inherent in the Koyck distributed lag model is another unrealistic feature of the approach.
Other approaches relying on the band between intervention points have also been used. White (1963, pp. 487 ff.) has pointed out that in the Bretton Woods system of fixed intervention points the position of the spot rate within the band will determine expectations of the future rate. Branson (1968, Ch. 3) has used a more general form of lag distribution to approximate the stabilizing influence of the intervention points on the formation of future exchange rate expectations.
The attempts to handle destabilizing speculation in the fixed exchange rate system are much more complex and difficult. The main problem lies in the discontinuity that the existence of the band introduces into speculative behavior. A further difficulty is in the complexity of motives influencing speculative behavior under such conditions. Each country, each capital market, and each time period has specific features that are a major factor in the formation of expectations. If a country is a major participant in international trade with a low reserve position, its trade performance may be a major factor in influencing the expected exchange rate.25 In other cases, exchange rate expectations can be influenced by the dynamics of relative rates of inflation between countries,26 by substantial swings in short-term capital movements caused initially by changes in monetary policy, by an exchange rate crisis in a third country, etc. Thus, it appears that a more flexible methodology, which permits formulating a specific expectations function for a particular country or a particular period, would be more promising.
Trade-hedging
Credit arising from trade transactions contracted for future payments comprises an important proportion of short-term capital movements. In a highly competitive international capital market, traders obtain finance from the source where interest rates, after allowing for the forward premium or discount, are the lowest. Thus, by hedging (i.e., covering forward their trade credit contracts), traders behave effectively as interest arbitrageurs. In line with his methodology of separating the analysis by activity, Tsiang assumed that all traders hedge, so that all trade that is not financed by long-term credit would generate capital movements. The direction of the movements would be determined by the condition for interest arbitrage. However, such an assumption is quite unrealistic, given that traders do tend to speculate, either through leaving trade credit contracts uncovered or through leads and lags. White (1963, pp. 487–93) has shown that whenever the cost of forward cover exceeds a properly estimated risk of loss from a change in the spot rate, the trader is induced to leave uncovered a certain proportion of his trade credit. Kenen (1965, pp. 145–49) also reached the same conclusion by a microeconomic analysis of the operation of an export-import firm. Branson (1968, Ch. 2) has formalized such a view in terms of the portfolio selection theory. He has obtained the usual utility maximization condition according to which the trader will stop expanding the uncovered portion of the value of his total trade credit when the ratio of the marginal gain in utility from a further reduction of forward cover payments to the marginal loss of utility from the additional risk equals the ratio of the risk estimate to the potential gain from the operation.
Therefore, it would follow that participation in the forward exchange market by traders as hedger-speculators is determined by the size of their short-term trade contracts and by a mean-variance analysis that would balance possible exchange gains from the risks of credit transactions not covered forward against the forward cover costs of risk minimization by hedging.27 This speculation in uncovered credit transactions by traders differs from the usual activity by speculators on the forward market only in the degree of risk aversion; for traders, gains from speculation on the exchange markets are less important than trading profits. On the other hand, Learner and Stern (1970, p. 88) claim that arbitrage risk by traders will be quite small because the probability of the imposition of exchange controls on trade transactions is minimal.
Market equilibrium
The equilibrium on the forward exchange market is achieved at a forward rate at which that market is cleared. At that rate, the net supply (negative demand) of forward foreign exchange of the arbitrageurs is equal to the sum of the demand by speculators and traders.28 In Figure 1, at the forward rate 02 F, the distance AB, showing the net demand of forward exchange by speculators and traders (i.e., Ds — ST), is equal to the net supply of the arbitrageurs, FC.
It is obvious from Figure 1 that the joint determination of the forward rate and the size of the forward exchange flow are influenced by the elasticity of the arbitrage and the speculators’ demand functions along their relevant ranges. An infinitely elastic arbitrage schedule (i.e., the presumed Keynes’s interest rate parity theory) would lead to a determination of the forward rate by arbitrage alone, while the speculators’ function would determine the flow of forward exchange at that particular rate. On the other hand, if the speculators’ schedule is infinitely elastic (when there is certainty about the future exchange rate) it will determine the forward rate and the latter will be independent of the interest rate differential.29
An important point contributed by Tsiang was to clarify the essential role of arbitrageurs in creating the link between the spot and forward exchange markets. Since arbitrageurs always cover their forward commitments by reverse spot transactions, they will undertake new commitments only when the forward premium quoted on the market is at least equal to the interest rate adjusted for the difference in the marginal opportunity costs of funds.30 An individual arbitrageur observes the existing spot and forward rates, on the one hand, and the interest differential, on the other hand, and adjusts his net forward and spot position in foreign exchange accordingly.
However, as is shown by Tsiang’s analysis, in the process of achieving a full equilibrium on the exchange markets (when market behavior of arbitrageurs and speculators is considered), the forward exchange rate is an endogenous variable. This is also true for the spot rate when flexibility of the exchange rate parities (either within the band of intervention points or in the freely flexible exchange rate system) is allowed for.31 Although individual participants in the exchange rate market take both spot and forward rates as data, the equilibrium can be achieved only when through the market mechanism the mutual adjustment of forward and spot rates is such as to satisfy the conditions just outlined. In Figure 1, the equilibrium condition is satisfied at the spot rate O1R, and at the forward rate 02F, at which rates SR = CF = AB. During this adjustment process, and depending on the behavior of exogenous variables, short-term capital flows will occur. These will be reflected in the spot exchange demanded (supplied) by arbitrageurs and traders, as a consequence of their activities on the forward market.
It can be seen that the model originated by Tsiang is, in a number of important aspects, a partial equilibrium model. Changes in some of the exogenous variables, such as the expected exchange rate and interest rate differences, are most important in influencing short-term capital movements. However, these variables may, in turn, be influenced by the international readjustment of short-term capital assets. Furthermore, within this model the effect of the change in interest rates and in exchange rate expectations can be examined only by considering a shift in one of the schedules that determines the equilibrium of the model.32 Since it has been shown that these schedules are interdependent, the proper analysis of a change in one of the exogenous variables becomes even more difficult.
Tsiang’s analysis of the equilibrium in the forward and spot exchange markets was an important contribution in clarifying the relationship between forces that influence short-term capital movements. Further efforts were made to overcome the limitations of the model and, in particular, to make it operational for econometric analysis. Stein (1962) has considered a change in variables, still assumed to be exogenous, such as the interest rate in one of the two regions or an exogenous move in the spot rate. Although his analysis was institutional, it examined a dynamic process of adjustment in other variables as a result of an exogenous change in one variable. Stein differentiated between “normal” and “speculative” periods of adjustment on the basis of whether speculators expected no change or an adjustment in the exchange rate peg. In the normal period, the adjustment in both the interest rate differential and the spot rate within intervention points is such that the forward and spot rates would move in opposite directions. The comparative movement in these rates would thus affect the response of the flow of short-term capital by transferring the activity of speculators from the spot to the forward market or from the forward to the spot market. During the “speculative” period, however, an exogenous change in exchange rate expectations will tend to provoke a movement of both forward and spot rates in the same direction. Sohmen (1961, pp. 76–79; 1966, pp. 28–30), Auten (1963, pp. 13–16), and Argy and Hodjera (1973, pp. 41–43) have examined the implication of intervention points on the movement of the forward rate. Assuming no expectations of adjustment in the peg, the elasticity of supply of forward exchange will increase considerably once the upper intervention point is reached, and the elasticity of demand for forward exchange will increase once the lower intervention point is reached. In the special case where the spot rate also approaches one of the intervention points—for example, during a protracted capital outflow from a strong-currency country or a protracted inflow into a weak-currency country—the forward rate may remain at the floor or at the ceiling for a considerable period of time. This would reflect an infinitely elastic speculative demand (supply) function, and during that period the forward premium will be independent of the movements in the interest rate differential. More generally, during the period of confidence in the band, exchange rate expectations will become inelastic when the spot rate approaches the intervention points, and the movement of the forward rate will be reversed. When, on the other hand, an adjustment in the peg is expected by speculators (i.e., the exchange rate expectations become elastic in the vicinity of the intervention points), the forward rate could considerably exceed the intervention points and could be driven to a large premium or discount.
3. Stocks versus flows and the portfolio selection approach
Another aspect of the theory of short-term capital movements was related closely to attempts to empirically investigate the response of financial flows to changes in interest rates and in foreign trade. The major question was whether financial flows in general, and short-term capital movements in particular, respond to absolute interest rate differentials or whether they respond to a change in these differentials.
Early students, such as Rhomberg (1959–60, 1964), Kenen (1963), and Black (1968), followed the classical view restated by Nurkse (1934), Ohlin (1933), and Iversen (1936) 33 that an arbitrageur’s activity will generate financial flows whenever the gap between the interest rates exceeds the international differences in risk. Such a view also implied that once the monetary authorities were successful in preserving a favorable short-term interest differential they could then rely on short-term capital movements to finance a continuing deficit in the basic balance.
A coexisting view was that capital movements were influenced by a change in the international interest differentials.34 This would have meant that in an equilibrium situation stocks of domestic capital abroad and of foreign capital at home were determined by the existing interest differentials, while international flows would occur if these equilibrium differentials were disturbed. Originally, attempts were made to test the validity of the flow or stock approaches by econometric techniques. However, it was soon realized that the stock approach is consistent with the Tobin-Markowitz theory of portfolio selection. Grubel (1966, pp. 12 ff., and 1968) and Willett (1967) have suggested that applying the portfolio selection theory to international capital movements can explain the international distribution of assets and also international flows of capital. Asset distribution will depend on a given set of interest rates in different countries, reflecting the expected returns to asset holders, and on risk estimates of holding these assets in the portfolio.35 Any change in interest rates or in the degree of risk of some of these assets will generate international flows of capital, until the reallocation of capital induced by these changes results in a new international distribution of assets. As already pointed out, Tsiang’s analysis of the equilibrium in the forward and spot exchange markets has many features of the portfolio selection theory, and thus it is basically a stock approach.
A more rigorous application of the portfolio selection theory to the foreign exchange market was provided by Branson (1968, Ch. 2). He examined the case where traders were assumed to operate simultaneously as arbitrageurs, hedgers, and speculators.36 Branson applied a quadratic form of the expected utility function, as had been done by Tobin and Markowitz, in order to formalize the profit-maximizing behavior of such risk-averse traders. In this way he obtained a familiar equilibrium condition for interest arbitrage on spot and forward markets, derived by Spraos (1953), Tsiang (1959–60), and Sohmen (1961), but he was also able to obtain a more specific formulation of the speculative behavior.37 In analyzing the behavior of a trader as a speculator, Branson concluded that an upward shift in the expected foreign exchange rate would cause an upward shift in both forward and spot foreign exchange rates. In the process it would also generate an excess demand for foreign exchange on both spot and forward exchange markets, thus causing a short-term capital outflow. On the other hand, an increase in risk associated with given expectations of the future foreign exchange rate 38 would generate, other things being equal, a decrease in capital flows (with transactors increasing their borrowing at home) and an increase in the demand for forward cover by transactors in both countries.
However, Branson’s analysis of the effect of changes in the interest rate differential on capital movements is more ambiguous. He concluded that an increase in the foreign interest rate (generating a shift in the arbitrage schedule) would cause a decrease in the forward foreign exchange rate but that the direction of induced capital movements could not be determined. This unusual result is contradicted by the empirical work, which clearly supports the conventional view that an increase in a given country’s interest rate will have a positive effect on the short-term capital inflow.
All these results are obtained by using a quadratic utility function. When, however, Branson uses the more general form of the utility function, the effects on capital movements of both a change in the interest rate and a change in exchange rate expectations become uncertain. These theoretical findings are confirmed by Feldstein (1968, pp. 187—90), who concluded that, under these assumptions and granted multiple currencies, only an increase in risk to speculators will have an expected discouraging effect on speculative flows. In a more general criticism of the Tobin-Markowitz portfolio selection theory, Feldstein (1969) pointed out that the portfolio selection analysis can generate determinate results only if the utility functions of risk-averse investors are quadratic or if their subjective distributions of expected returns can be assumed to be normal. Thus, for any other utility function and probability distribution, a two-parameter Tobin-Markowitz analysis would be inadequate. Although Tobin (1969), one of the pioneers of the portfolio theory, appears to have conceded the validity of this view, Tsiang has recently shown that it is too restrictive. The sufficient condition, according to Tsiang (1972, pp. 355–61), for a unique solution in a portfolio selection model, which is based on a mean of expected returns and on the variance of their subjective distribution, is that the risk (i.e., variance) assumed by the investor is fairly small relative to his total wealth.39 However, when the analysis is based on such a set of more general utility functions, it is not clear what theoretical conclusion one could draw regarding the effects of changes in interest rates and exchange rate expectations on international capital movements. More work is required on this issue. As Tobin (1969) pointed out in a somewhat different context, the economic significance of “perverse” solutions should be explored. Solutions in which changes in interest differential and in exchange rate expectations cause “uphill flows” in terms of the conventional theory may be even less important than the “Giffen paradox” in the consumer demand theory.
An obvious advantage of using the portfolio selection theory in analyzing short-term capital movements is that such a theory can explain simultaneous two-way international short-term capital movements between two regions. A demand for foreign assets is viewed as a component of the total assets demand function by a given region of asset holders under conditions of risk. The supply of foreign assets is determined within a framework of the total assets demand function by asset holders abroad. This provides a theoretical basis for the separate estimation of foreign assets and foreign liabilities of a given country, since these are determined by different functions.
The original treatment, particularly in empirical studies, was to define demand and supply functions for short-term foreign assets of a representative investor on the basis of portfolio selection theory without distinguishing between arbitrage, speculative, and trade-hedging activities.40 Levin (1970), Learner and Stern (1970, and Basevi (1973) have treated each of these activities separately. However, when solved in terms of observable independent variables, the portfolio selection approach effectively evolves into the approach based on Tsiang’s original methodology.41
The rearrangement of investors’ portfolios in response to changes in exogenous variables occurs over a certain period of time. On the aggregate level, this leads to an adjustment in stocks of short-term assets among the two or more countries, which adjustment will also be completed (if not disturbed by other preceding or succeeding changes) over a period of time. Thus, a portfolio selection theory provides an explanation of adjustments in stocks in the form of a distributed lag model. However, depending on the nature of the distributed lag model used, considerable difficulty may occur in distinguishing a stock adjustment from a flow process. Hendershott (19’67a) and Learner and Stern (1970, pp. 80–81) have shown that if the adjustment process is spread evenly over a large number of periods, a statistical estimation may make a stock adjustment phenomenon appear as a continuous flow.
Another important aspect of the portfolio selection theory as applied to international capital movements, raised by Floyd (1969 a, pp. 484–90) and Willett and Forte (1969, pp. 246–52), consists in the role played by a comparative growth of total assets as variables influencing asset reallocation among countries.42 In a growing economy, a continuous flow of short-term capital may result from a difference among countries in one or more of these parameters: (a) the growth rate of each country’s total assets; (b) the absolute size of their total assets at the beginning of the period; and (c) the proportion of each country’s assets held abroad. These flows will thus occur even if the existing interest rate configuration among countries remains constant, and they can be thought of as. being induced by differences in wealth effects. Furthermore, a change in the interest rate in one of the countries will not only generate a reallocation of a stock of assets in the portfolios of each country’s investors but also cause a change in the continuous flows induced by a comparative wealth effect. This will be so because (as indicated in (c) the proportion of each country’s assets held abroad will be modified as a result of the change in international interest rate differentials. Thus, a change in the interest rate differential among growing economies generates a stock adjustment effect and a flow adjustment effect on capital movements. While the former effect is temporary and, ceteris paribus, is completed after a given period of time, the latter effect causes a smaller, but more sustained, adjustment in the flow of capital.43
The treatment of international short-term capital movements within the framework of the growing economy is a major improvement over Tsiang’s analysis, which, in this respect, was essentially static. This improvement was made possible by applying the portfolio selection theory. Also, asset diversification, on which the portfolio selection approach is based, can successfully explain simultaneous cross flows of short-term assets and liabilities among countries.
However, there are also serious weaknesses in this approach as a basis for developing a theory of a foreign exchange market in general and of short-term capital movements in particular. Some weaknesses are inherent in the portfolio selection theory itself, while others result from its application to the process of international short-term capital movements.
A. As Malinvaud (in Hahn and Brechling, 1965, p. 287) pointed out, Tobin-Markowitz’s theory is concerned with individual financial behavior. The behavior of institutional investors creates a real difficulty in defining a collective utility function that should explain behavior of an aggregative portfolio selection. Baret (in Borch and Mossin, 1968, pp. 117–18) also suggested that the portfolio behavior of a proprietor who is investing his own funds is difficult to determine, since characteristics other than a possible monetary payoff enter into his utility function. Tsiang (1972, p. 368) has further pointed out that while the two-parameter portfolio selection analysis may be adequate for risk-averse portfolio investors (since they assume relatively small risk relative to their wealth), such analysis is not appropriate to handle entrepreneurs who regularly risk a major proportion of their total wealth.
In all such cases a two-parameter, mean variance analysis is clearly inadequate. The difficulties just mentioned are particularly relevant when international short-term capital movements are concerned, since portfolio behavior of a trader is typically that of a proprietor, while speculators often risk a substantial proportion of their wealth on the foreign exchange market. Also, institutional investors and banks are important participants in the foreign exchange market’s speculative and arbitrage activities. Because of such a diversity of participants, a portfolio selection approach based on aggregate behavior, or on behavior separated by activities without regard to the nature of transactors, is not sufficiently defined. Learner and Stern (1972, pp. 176–79) advanced a proposition that portfolio selection analysis based on a somewhat more homogeneous transactor group would be more satisfactory. However, such an approach faces important difficulties because of the lack of international comparability among transactors and because many of these transactors (such as traders) do not participate directly on the foreign exchange market but through various banking or brokerage institutions.
B. The portfolio selection theory, as developed by Tobin, did not involve diversification of assets on a geographical basis but endeavored to explain the behavior of a risk-averse investor by a diversification of his assets with respect to a degree of their liquidity, that is, with respect to the assets’ maturity structure or the degree of risk. The nature of risk being what it is, it is reasonable to assume that an investor, operating on an international level, will also minimize risk by diversifying geographically. However, as pointed out by Rhomberg (1972, p. 317), an application of the portfolio selection theory limited only to one end of the maturity structure 44 violates the basic proposition of the theory. It is not possible to explain changes in short-term capital movements without considering (a) the effect of independent variables on the country’s total capital assets; and (b) the risk-induced substitution of various subportfolios along the maturity scale resulting from a change in one or more of the independent variables.
C. The treatment of international capital movements in general and short-term capital movements in particular within the framework of a growing economy is still too pedestrian.45 Still, even this simple approach faces difficulties. As has been pointed out by a number of critics of the portfolio theory (e.g., Liutner, in Hahn and Brechling (1965), pp. 18 ff., and Freimer and Gordon (1968), pp. 103 ff.), most utility functions upon which the theory is based imply a change in the degree of risk aversion associated with a change in wealth. Therefore a difference in the functional relationship between the growth of wealth and risk aversion in the two countries may generate flows, even if all other conditions indicate an equilibrium growth without international capital movements. This would mean that in such a case there would be an additional flow-adjustment effect as a result of a once-and-for-all change in the international interest rate differential. It has just been pointed out that the functional relationship between the growth of wealth and risk aversion is one of the difficult issues facing any application of the portfolio selection theory. While in a closed economy model such an issue may be considered less damaging to the theory, differences in this functional relationship between countries may generate international flows of capital whose direction cannot be determined on the basis of the present state of the portfolio selection theory.46
D. Finally, the existence of international capital markets, such as those in London and New York, should also be considered. The gross asset position of institutions forming a part of these markets reflects the growth of wealth in other countries, which are using such institutions as intermediaries in their investment policies, rather than the growth of wealth in countries in which these markets are situated. In the portfolio selection theory, as applied to international finance, gross flows are essential to explain asset diversification. However, foreign wealth-induced aggregate increases in both assets and liabilities of institutions forming such an international capital market may be consistent with unchanged or even declining domestic assets of a country to which this market belongs, although neither international interest differentials nor a risk factor has changed in any way. Thus, a considerably more complex portfolio selection model is necessary to explain the geographical distribution (and, to some extent, also a maturity distribution) of assets in a country that has a major international capital market.
Despite all these criticisms, recent applications of the portfolio selection approach to Tsiang’s theoretical framework represent a significant step forward in a development of the theory of international short-term capital movements. In particular, it has helped to resolve the controversy surrounding stocks and flows. While it led to the widespread adoption of stock adjustment models (or, more recently, of stock-flow adjustment models), it does not reject the arguments of those who insist that an arbitrageur’s activity would generate international flows of short-term capital whenever covered interest differentials between countries exceed transactions costs.
4. General equilibrium analysis of capital movements
Much of the literature discussed thus far, in both the flow and stock versions, has treated short-term capital flows in isolation and not as part of an integrated macroeconomic system. Domestic interest rates, in particular, in these approaches have been viewed as entirely exogenous. An important development has been to incorporate financial flows into a more complete macroeconomic model of an open economy. We shall briefly mention the way in which international capital movements have been accommodated in these models. This brief survey is relevant because such a model was used recently as a framework for the empirical analysis of capital movements and of their effect on monetary policy of several industrial countries.
The early model of an open economy developed by Polak used a quantity theory framework, where capital flows were treated as entirely exogenous but the money supply was allowed to respond to the balance of payments.47 The main interest of the model was to examine the relationship between changes in the credit creation of the banking system and the balance of payments. In this model, Polak has shown how an exogenous change in capital movements has an impact on the domestic money supply, which in turn influences both income and imports until equilibrium in the balance of payments is restored again.
Later models based on the Keynesian open economy framework were used in analyzing macroeconomic policies oriented toward the simultaneous maintenance of domestic full employment and balance of payments equilibrium.48 Flow models developed by Mundell (1964), Johnson (1966), Argy (1969, pp. 267–78), Helliwell (1969 b), Baguley,49 Courbis (1971), Basevi (1973), and others assumed capital movements to be endogenous, being sensitive to relative interest rates, but either the money supply or interest rates were taken to be exogenous variables. International capital movements played an important role in this analysis because the degree to which a country’s capital flows were sensitive to interest rates was one of the key elements in determining a feasible policy mix for the internal-external balance.
Taking interest rates as exogenous variables in these models implied that, while the domestic interest rate was allowed to influence capital movements, capital movements themselves did not influence interest rates. An implicit assumption was that monetary authorities adopt sterilization policies so as to counteract the effect of balance of payments developments on the domestic money supply or interest rates. Other flow models by Argy (1969, pp. 279 ff.), Swoboda (1972), and Aghevli and Borts (1973) used a Keynesian framework but treated the money supply as endogenous; they assumed that the monetary authorities either did not use sterilization policies or adopted a partial sterilization.
The appropriateness and relevance of these alternative Keynesian models are quite dependent on the extent or degree of sterilization by monetary authorities. Some attempts at econometric analysis of sterilization by Argy and Kouri (1972) suggest that in fact there may be only partial sterilization, but, as the authors show, the issues are complicated and not easily amenable to empirical testing. More important, the feasibilty of sterilization depends largely on the degree of capital market integration. The more financially integrated an economy, the larger the reserve volatility that is associated with a given dose of monetary independence. At the limit, where capital mobility is perfect, the domestic interest rate, and hence the domestic money supply, is completely at the mercy of developments in allied foreign markets.
At this point a distinction should be made between a “short-term” and a “long-term” equilibrium condition in these macro-models. Short-term equilibrium can be interpreted as an “impact effect” of the change in an independent variable in which behavioral relations in the model are satisfied but the balance of payments is not necessarily in equilibrium; the actual surplus or deficit caused by such a change in an independent variable is equal to the ex ante surplus or deficit. Long-term, or “full,” equilibrium implies that the adjustment process in the model has worked itself out in such a way as to eliminate any payments imbalance. The analysis of a majority of the models just discussed is limited to a short-term equilibrium. Since these are flow models, in which a one-time change in the interest rate generates a continuous flow of capital, a long-term equilibrium would imply that the interest rate reverts to its original level.50 Argy (1969), Polak and Argy (1971), and Swoboda (1972) have explored the long-term equilibrium condition by examining implications of monetary and fiscal policies on income and international reserves, given the long-run constraint that the balance of payments must be restored to equilibrium.
A further development consisted in the use of a portfolio balance approach within a macroeconomic framework. Basically, it meant adding to the usual Keynesian open economy model an additional behavioral equation defining the equilibrium in the asset market51 and including wealth as an explanatory variable in the expenditure, money, and asset demand functions. The portfolio approach permitted a treatment of capital movements as a stock adjustment phenomenon in the model. As indicated in Section 3, under such conditions the effect of a one-time change in the interest rate is seen as a transitory phenomenon causing a once-and-for-all change in a country’s reserves but generating no continuous effect on the balance of payments.
Early, simplified, portfolio balance models of an open economy assumed either perfect immobility or perfect mobility of capital. A model by McKinnon (in Mundell and Swoboda, 1969) is based on complete international immobility of capital and does not concern us here. On the other hand, models by McKinnon and Oates (1966), Oates (1966), Levin (1970), and Whitman (1970) assume perfect capital mobility by considering that asset holdings by the private sector consist of both domestic and foreign bonds, which are treated as perfect substitutes. In these models, money supply is determined exogenously, implying that the monetary authorities sterilize the effect of disequilibrium in the balance of payments. Consequently, the equilibrium in this kind of model is satisfied when a surplus or deficit on the current account is offset by a deficit or surplus in the asset market.52
All these portfolio models consider the case of a single small country that is unable to influence variables in the rest of the world, such as foreign interest rates and the asset position abroad. When one considers the portfolio balance in the rest of the world, a long-term stationary equilibrium in models based on Oates’s framework is inconsistent with continuing capital movements. Formal two-country macro-models taking up this problem are developed by Floyd (1969a, b and 1972) and Allen (1973). In both models, a neutralization of the effect of capital movements on domestic money supply is assumed, but while Allen assumes a single type of asset in both countries and thus perfect capital mobility, Floyd considers the case of imperfect capital mobility with different interest rates in the two countries. Floyd’s Keynesian model is addressed to a comparative static analysis of effects of changes in the money stock and output in one country on international capital movements and the balance of payments. Allen’s model exhibits dynamic properties that enable her to distinguish between a short-run market equilibrium, when all markets are cleared, and a long-run portfolio equilibrium reached gradually through a sequence of short-run equilibria, when the additional condition of unchanged desired holdings of assets by participants is also met. On the basis of her model, Allen reaches an interesting conclusion that a change in one country’s liquidity preference or in money supply will have no long-run effect on the balance of payments. The distribution of assets between countries achieved during this process depends on which country had a temporary balance of payments surplus; the surplus country will gain wealth. Finally, whether these disturbances in the liquidity preference or money supply are expansionary or contractionary in both countries will depend on their relative wealth effects on the demand for assets.
A distinctive feature of a model by Kouri and Porter (1972a, b) is that, on the one hand, it treats the money supply as endogenous but, on the other hand, it treats the real sector as exogenous to the model. By specifying demand and supply functions for money and domestic and foreign bonds, Kouri and Porter are able to solve the model for changes in the domestic interest rate and net capital flows as a function of the same set of exogenous variables. In particular, the capital flow equation that they obtain enables them to directly estimate the effect of changes in domestic monetary policy on capital movements, under the assumption that the monetary authorities do not sterilize the effects of payment imbalances. Girton and Henderson (1973) have also developed a two-country financial portfolio model; however, the advantage of the Kouri-Porter approach is in the ability to use their reduced forms for quantitative analysis.
However, the macroeconomic portfolio balance approach has a number of unresolved problems. It is still limited to a one-country or a two-country analysis. In a multicountry approach the complexity of a disturbance-induced adjustment in asset holdings of various countries, which is consistent with the additional constraint of a portfolio balance in all countries, is still to be examined. Moreover, there is still no satisfactory treatment of the problem of growth of wealth at home and abroad, although recent monetary models by Johnson (1972), which relate growth of the overall balance of payments to growth in income, domestic credit, and international reserves, provide a basis for further analysis. Finally, the proper treatment of short-term capital movements requires integrating into a portfolio balance the macro-model forces that determine equilibrium on the forward exchange market.53 Future developments in the analysis of short-term capital movements will no doubt attempt to fill the gap in these areas.
II. Empirical Analysis
Attempts to subject various hypotheses about the determinants of short-term capital movements to statistical tests are quite recent. Initially, these tests were limited to capital flows of the United States and Canada. Only since the beginning of the 1970s has econometric analysis been applied to the capital account of some developed countries outside North America. However, the methodology has not advanced beyond the estimation of either short-term capital flows of a single country or bilateral flows between two industrial countries. Finally, several attempts were made to estimate capital flow equations as a part of large econometric models of the Canadian and U. S. economies.
This part is divided into two sections: (1) a survey of the major methodological approaches that are structured within Tsiang’s theoretical framework; and (2) a description of the more recent attempts to reformulate econometric analysis within the framework of the portfolio selection theory and to apply this analysis to capital movements of a number of industrial countries.
1. Early attempts and the “conventional” approach
The complexities of the forces influencing short-term capital movements are such that the first attempts at empirical analysis were necessarily limited. In his structural model of the Canadian economy and of its foreign exchange market, Rhomberg (1959–60, p. 450, and 1964, pp. 9–12) estimated Canadian short-term capital movements with the U. S.-Canadian interest differential, the forward premium, and the change in the Canadian floating rate as independent variables. Studies by Bell (1962) and Kenen (1963) consisted of simple or multiple regressions that used a selected number of independent variables. The use of a stock model by Bell and of a flow model by Rhomberg and Kenen was also on an ad hoc basis, since no theoretical reasons were provided. While Bell found little evidence that either movements of short-term U. S. claims on foreigners and of U. S. short-term liabilities to foreigners or their components were very sensitive to changes in international interest rate differentials (1962, pp. 440–47), he found a close log-linear relationship between U. S. claims outstanding and exports (1962, pp. 428–29 and 462). Kenen (1963, pp. 155–59 and passim), on the other hand, found a significant, but rather weak, relation between the various components of U. S. short-term capital flows and the levels of covered interest rate differentials; but he found no significant relation between exports and the component flows generally associated with export finance. Neither of the two studies found a significant relationship between short-term capital movements and uncovered interest rate differentials.54 The more complex analysis by Rhomberg suggested that short-term capital movements played a stabilizing role in the Canadian foreign exchange market. They appeared to have offset large swings in Canada’s basic balance without subjecting the exchange rate to substantial fluctuations.
Powrie (1964) also tested a flow version of Canadian short-term capital movements during the floating exchange rate period (1953–61). He used, in the same equation, both covered and uncovered interest differentials as regressors. He also tried to allow for speculation on exchange rate fluctuations by using as regressors the differences between the current and the future, as well as the current and the past, exchange rates. The explanatory power of his regression equations was not good.
The main difficulties in all these studies were as follows: (a) the lack of a rigorous theoretical framework relating short-term capital movements and the independent variables used in the equations tested;55 (b) the use of disaggregated short-term capital flows by Kenen and Bell without taking into account the substitution effects between various subflows; (c) a bias introduced by using interest differentials covered forward as independent variables; and (d) multi-collinearity among the independent variables in the equations.
More rigorous approaches
By the mid-1960s it had been recognized (Stein, 1965 a, pp. 42–45; Heckerman, 1967, pp. 555–56; Laffer, 1967, p. 58; Stoll, 1968, pp. 49 ff.) that the use of a covered interest rate differential as an explanatory variable for short-term capital movements (whether expressed in the form of stocks or of flows) results in biased and inconsistent estimates. This is caused by the fact that the disturbance that affects short-term capital movements also affects the forward cover, so that there exists a substantial simultaneous relationship between the independent and dependent variables in the regression equation.
Stein attempted to construct a testable model that would, on the one hand, provide a theoretical framework for an empirical analysis of short-term capital movements and, on the other hand, permit a separation of the effects of the speculative activity from the effects of international interest rate changes. He attempted to explain the determinants of the speculative activity in order to avoid using the covered interest differential as an independent variable in the regression equation. The regression equation used was a linearized reduced form of a simplified equilibrium system for the spot and forward exchange markets based on Tsiang’s approach. However, Stein thought that he could use as an estimate of speculation the residual between the actual and computed values obtained by regressing the pound sterling forward premium on the U. S.-U. K. interest differential.56 Both the theoretical model57 and the econometric methodology were questioned. Heckerman (1967) showed that Stein’s “proxy” for speculation was derived in a way that was inconsistent on econometric grounds. Since the equations defining the demand and supply functions for spot dollars and the net demand function for forward dollars include a lagged adjustment variable, the error terms are serially correlated in the reduced form regression equation. This, of course, leads to biased and inconsistent estimates of the determinants of short-term capital movements. Stein used his structural equation, which basically expressed short-term capital movements as a function of the interest rate differential and of the residual as a proxy for speculation, to empirically test the validity of a stock and a pure flow model in the analysis of short-term capital movements. Despite the fact that he favored the flow model, his quantitative results were such that no distinction could be made between the two models.58
A more rigorous application of Tsiang’s theoretical model for estimating short-term capital movements between the United States and Canada was attempted by Black (1968). He carefully specified a structural system for the spot and forward exchange markets and developed a system of two testable regression equations with short-term capital movements and the change in the forward exchange rate as dependent variables. Black eliminated the problem of endogenicity of the spot and forward exchange rates in the regression equation by using the two-stage least-squares estimation. He further introduced the use of a distributed lag function of the observed foreign exchange rates as an estimate of the expected exchange rate, a key variable in defining speculative activity.
Black also formalized a stock and a flow model of short-term capital movements and used the regression analysis to test the validity of these two alternative concepts. Although he favored the flow concept, his “hybrid” model, combining a stock and a flow concept, yielded the best empirical results; this should have indicated that the time adjustment process was more complex than the one expressed by either a pure stock or a pure flow model. The explanatory power of Black’s regression analysis was not very high, probably as a result, in part, of using a simple exchange rate expectations function. Black found a significant, but quite low, interest sensitivity in U. S.-Canadian short-term capital movements. In a somewhat simpler regression analysis of short-term capital movements between the same two countries, based on a more general structural model of the capital accounts, Caves and Reuber (1971, pp. 70–87) obtained somewhat better results. They sided with a flow concept and used forward exchange rate as an exogenous variable.
The exchange between Stein and his critics and Black’s efforts contributed greatly toward clarifying many of the issues that face one who attempts to empirically estimate the determinants of short-term capital movements in a way that is consistent with a theoretical framework. Insofar as the structure of the model is concerned, it became obvious that any choice between stock and flow approaches on the basis of the empirical evidence alone was a fruitless exercise; such a selection can be meaningful only if it is consistent with a clearly formulated theoretical hypothesis. It also became obvious that quantitative estimates of speculative activity cannot be made unless a satisfactory function explaining exchange rate expectations can be introduced into the econometric model. Finally, it became more and more apparent that the adjustment process either in exchange rate expectations or in the short-term capital flows may be spread over a period of time. Thus, some form of lagged adjustment of dependent variables to changes in independent variables should have been considered.
Estimating effects of speculation
Since the late 1960s, several attempts have been made to provide a more rigorous explanation of the effect of speculation on short-term capital movements. In particular, a number of ways have been tried to formulate an estimating equation capable of explaining the exchange rate expectations that are the key instrumental variable in expressing speculative activity. Stoll (1968) and Arndt (1968) drew on the Koyck-Nerlove concept of adaptive expectations in expressing the expected exchange rate as a geometrically declining weighted average of past spot rate. It is well known, however, that when the Koyck distributed lag model is used to express a lag adjustment process, the estimates are subject to serious serial correlation in the disturbances and are beset with problems of specification that are likely to lead to inconsistent estimates.59 Furthermore, if serial correlation is positive, which it is most often, a substantive upward bias may be introduced into the estimated average lag.60 Arndt used the “three pass least squares” method as an alternative procedure to eliminate the problem of serial correlation. However, this procedure resulted in an even longer period of adjustment (Arndt, 1968, p. 63, and Table 1). Also, the length of the lag based on either of the two methods of estimation was not robust and changed substantially when the regression coefficient of the term in question was changed within the limit of one standard error.61
Econometric models using the geometric lag structure to express the process of formation of exchange rate expectations were criticized as inappropriate in the system of fixed parities, with a band within which the spot exchange rate tends to fluctuate in something of a sinusoid fashion. Branson (1968, pp. 43–66) approximated such a formation of expectations by a second-order difference equation of observed exchange rates, on which equation he imposed conditions reflecting dampened oscillatory movements. He used this model, in a study of U. S. financial capital flows, for estimating expected exchange rates of Canada and of several European countries. However, his estimated coefficients of the regression equations did not generally satisfy stability conditions for dampened oscillatory movements.62 Kesselman (1971) also tried to describe oscillatory movements of the exchange rate within the band by a so-called dual expectation model. He combined an adaptive expectation equation along the lines of a Koyck-Nerlove approach with an extrapolative expectation equation showing a movement away from some “normal” exchange rate.63 However, Kesselman’s complex structural equation was underdetermined, so that he could obtain only a range of solutions by considering one coefficient as a variable parameter and by calculating other coefficients over a range of values of that variable parameter. Furthermore, the regression result exhibited a high degree of positive serial correlation of residuals, strongly suggesting that one or more important variables had been omitted.64
More recently, in a study of Germany’s capital movements, Kouri and Porter (1972b) advanced a hypothesis that the determination of the forward rate is dominated by speculative activity and that speculators’ exchange rate expectations are determined basically by the relative inflationary processes at home and abroad. In their study, they proceeded to explain the forward premium on the deutsche mark in terms of the ratio of the cumulative rates of inflation in Germany and in the United States. The regression analysis yielded reasonably good results. However, a closer examination of residuals suggests that the correlation coefficient was dominated by the substantial speculative pressures between late 1967 and 1970, while during the earlier period of the series tested (i.e., the first quarter of 1963 to the third quarter of 1967) the fit does not appear to be very good. Thus, the hypothesis by Kouri and Porter appears to be a quite useful approach in explaining longer-term speculative forces during the period of protracted destabilizing speculation and should be tested for other industrial countries. However, during periods of confidence in the parity, exchange rate fluctuations are dominated by the intervention points of the band, and also in such conditions arbitrage activity cannot be ignored as a determinant of the forward rate. Finally, the Kouri-Porter hypothesis cannot explain sudden, large, international shifts in short-term assets generated by intensive speculative crises.
Black (1972, and 1973, pp. 22–27) used a more flexible approach in analyzing the effect of speculative stocks on short-term capital movements within a floating exchange rate system. He reformulated Muth’s (1961) analysis of rational price expectations in order to construct a nonstochastic model of exchange rate expectations. This model enabled him to specify behavioral relations for different kinds of disturbance and to associate these with different time paths of exchange rate movements. Completely foreseen disturbances are distinguished by exchange rate changes originating ahead of the event, reaching a peak at the time of the event, and afterward returning progressively toward the original level. In unforeseen disturbances there is a sudden large exchange rate adjustment at the time of the event and then a slow adjustment toward the original level, while in partially foreseen disturbances a sudden change may occur some time ahead of the event. Black approximated the effect of these disturbances on exchange rates and capital movements by a series of exponential dummy variables of an appropriate form. Using his model for an econometric analysis of short-term capital movements between Great Britain and the United States in the latter half of the 1930s, Black has obtained results that are consistent with his expectations hypotheses and that suggest that the forward market has played an important role in determining equilibrium in the foreign exchange market.
It can be seen from all this that empirical studies of the possible determinants of speculation have not yet produced very encouraging results. Many problems raised by these efforts—in particular, the problem of the adjustment process involved—have provided thought for further theoretical analysis. However, despite progress achieved by Black (1973), the problem of explaining the formation of exchange rate expectations still remains basically unresolved. Without such an explanation, no satisfactory testable hypothesis can be advanced that could handle speculative behavior, especially the behavior within the system of pegged exchange parities. This difficulty is compounded by the fact that any empirical analysis of short-term capital movements in recent years should be able to properly incorporate both stabilizing and destabilizing speculation.
2. Tests of the portfolio selection approach
Short-term capital movements of the United States
The application of the theory of portfolio selection to international capital movements provided a much more satisfactory framework for economic analysis than did the earlier “conventional” approach. However, adapting this theoretical framework to econometric analysis involved resolving a number of serious methodological and statistical difficulties, so that the progress was relatively slow. Thus, although Branson pioneered in developing the theory of portfolio selection in this area, his initial empirical investigation of U.S. financial flows (1968, Chs. 4 and 6) represented essentially a transition from the conventional approach to the portfolio selection approach. His selection of a stock adjustment structural model in relating independent variables to short-term foreign assets and short-term liabilities abroad was consistent with the portfolio selection theory, as was his testing of gross rather than net financial flows as dependent variables. On the other hand, the lack of wealth as an explanatory variable in his model, and no clear concept of risk, reflected conventional lines of analysis.
Branson’s attempt to use a polynomial lag model to estimate the stock adjustment process in financial variables is of methodological interest. This method avoided problems of serial correlation and of possible inconsistency in estimates associated with the Koyck-Nerlove distributed lag technique,65 as well as the awkwardness of a geometrically declining lag profile. However, the unusually flexible lag structure of the polynomial lag model, and the Almond technique of selecting a lag with the best fit, generates a lag adjustment process that is practically tailor-made for each series tested. The resulting lag profile is not based on any a priori hypothesis of what the adjustment process to that particular financial variable should look like. Furthermore, since the application of the polynomial lag technique for any one of the independent variables in the regression equation uses up a considerable number of degrees of freedom, extensive use of such techniques in Branson’s econometric work raises the question of the appropriate level of significance for his coefficients.66
Branson’s selection for the final regression equation of various industrial countries’ interest rates and of instrumental variables standing for expected exchange rates appears arbitrary, since this selection was based on a trial-and-error technique. His method of truncating the lag adjustment process in order to select only those current or lagged variables that, based on his statistical exploration, appear to exert significant influence can also be questioned. Nevertheless, the results of his econometric estimation are interesting and suggestive.
Branson has estimated that an increase in the interest rate differential of 1 per cent in favor of the United States generates an inflow of short-term capital of $0.8–0.9 billion over the six-month period, which considerably exceeded all earlier estimates. However, he also uncovered an asymmetry in the sensitivity of short-term flows to changes in the U. S. interest rate compared with foreign rates. When tested separately as independent variables, the U. S. rate had a substantially smaller explanatory power than did most foreign rates. Branson suggested that rates in foreign national money markets adjust rapidly to changes in the U.S. rates, while, on the other hand, foreign monetary authorities could intervene in their domestic money markets without making an impact on the U. S. interest rate.67
A regression analysis, more consistent with the portfolio selection theory, was developed by Lee (1969), Bryant and Hendershott (1970, 1972), Branson and Hill (1971 b), Branson and Willett (1972), and Miller and Whitman (1972). All these studies involved estimation of U.S. short-term capital movements, except that Bryant and Hendershott limited their analysis to bilateral flows between the United States and Japan.68 The improvement on Branson’s (1968) approach consisted in the introduction of wealth as a constraint and as a scale variable in the regression equations. This method permitted a more rigorous estimation of the effect of interest rate changes on the adjustment in the stock of foreign assets held. Furthermore, it permitted estimating the effect of interest rate changes on the continuous flow of short-term capital induced by a growth of wealth at home and abroad.
In most cases the method used consisted of a separate estimation of a stock adjustment and a flow adjustment process.69 Miller and Whitman, Branson and Willett (1972), and Bryant and Hendershott estimated the determinants of U. S. short-term holdings of foreign assets only, using as a wealth variable several variants of total U. S. short-term assets.70 Only Branson and Hill (1971 b) estimated all three major categories of U. S. short-term capital flows (i.e., foreign assets, liabilities to foreigners, and errors and omissions) by using as a proxy for foreign wealth variables a sum of the value of gross national product (GNP) of the six major industrial countries other than the United States.71 The regression analysis by Miller and Whitman and by Bryant and Hendershott shows a greater degree of consistency with their theoretical framework than is true with others.72 However, even these writers could not avoid using some ad hoc proxies for those variables in their theoretical framework that were unobservable or empirically untractable. Branson and his collaborators have shown more flexibility by taking into account institutional conditions in the U. S. money market, but their methodology suffers from the trial-and-error approach to selecting variables for the regression analysis.
Neither of these investigations was successful in handling the difficult problem of estimating risk. While Miller and Whitman attempted to use a proxy for the degree of risk attached to U. S. domestic assets, arbitrageurs’ and exchange rate risks were altogether left out of the estimating equations. Bryant and Hendershott showed considerable ingenuity in estimating the effect of capital restrictions on lending to Japan by U. S. banks. They went beyond the usual way of using dummy variables for such a purpose and constructed variables that reflected a differential restrictive impact of the U. S. voluntary foreign credit restraint program, of the increase in creditworthiness of Japanese borrowers, and of relaxations in Japanese capital restrictions.
Because of substantial differences in methodology, a comparative analysis of regression results obtained by these studies would not serve a useful purpose. However, on one point all studies appear consistent. In all studies, U. S. domestic and foreign interest rates are entered separately in regression equations, and the results indicate higher responsiveness of capital movements to changes in foreign interest rates than to changes in the U. S. rate. These results are consistent with Branson’s (1968) suggestion that a change in the U. S. short-term interest rate is followed rapidly by adjustments in foreign interest rates, while foreign rates are freer to change without repercussions on the U. S. money market. Therefore, the estimated sensitivity of short-term capital movements to changes in U. S. short-term rates appears to be biased downward.
Capital movements of other industrial countries
Econometric analysis of capital movements of countries other than the United States and Canada is quite a recent phenomenon. The major stumbling block had been a lack of adequate data for the capital account. Up to now there have been studies of short-term capital movements for only three countries—the United Kingdom (Hodjera, 1971), Germany (Willms, 1971; Porter, 1972; Kouri and Porter, 1972 a, b; and Kouri, 1973), and, quite recently, France (Bourginat and others, 1973). The degree of financial integration for several European countries was studied indirectly by Argy and Hodjera (1973), who used a reduced form regression equation of the forward exchange market in which data on short-term capital movement were not necessary.73 Total capital movements, which include both short-term and long-term capital, were examined for several industrial countries by Branson and Hill (1971 b) and Kouri and Porter (1972 a, b).
The approaches were based on an incomplete form of the portfolio selection theory, since—because of the lack of data—no wealth variable could be included. Also, net capital flows were used in all cases as dependent variables. Furthermore, with the exception of Hodjera and of Kouri and Porter (1972 b), no attempt was made to include variables to represent exchange risk. The studies can be separated broadly into two categories: those assuming interest rates to be exogenous variables and those treating these rates as endogenous.
In analyzing U.K. short-term capital movements, Hodjera (1971) examined total short-term capital movement and its three major components. He found the U. K./Euro-dollar interest rate differential significant in influencing capital movements, particularly when net transactions in non-sterling area currencies are concerned. He also found that a lagged trade balance operates as a sensitive index of speculators’ confidence in the parity of the pound and could be used as a variable for speculation during the period covering crises in the U. K. balance of payments between November 1964 and November 1967. In using the interest rate differential covered forward, he also found that in the period 1963–67, which was dominated by destabilizing speculation, use of the forward cover, which is an endogenous variable in the equation, introduces a large upward bias in the estimate of interest sensitivity of short-term capital flows.
Branson and Hill (1971 a, b) applied methods of analysis developed in earlier Branson studies of the U. S. financial capital account to six other major countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Because of the lack of data on capital movements in some of these countries, the authors had to use as capital flow series the balance of payment residuals between the official settlement position and the current account balance. Despite these difficulties, the results for Germany, Japan, and Italy were encouraging. The explanatory power of the regression equations for these countries is relatively high.74 While in Germany and Japan assorted short-term and long-term domestic interest rates and foreign interest rates were significant explanatory variables, in Italy the most significant variables were the gap between potential and real GNP, and the Euro-dollar rate. In many aspects the study by Branson and Hill is pioneering, since it is the first attempt to estimate the determinants of the capital movements of major industrial countries in such a way as to achieve analytic comparability. However, before substantial progress can be achieved in this area, the question of the quality of data for capital flows and their components and for major domestic explanatory variables—including variables for differing institutional conditions—must be resolved.
Kouri and Porter (1972 a, b) 75 have developed an interesting method for empirical analysis of capital movements that was based on a model with domestic interest rates as endogenous variables. They were thus able to avoid the problem of biased estimates that are caused by a simultaneous relationship between capital movements and interest rates. Such a simultaneous relationship occurs when interest rates are treated as exogenously determined 76 and the monetary authorities are not sterilizing the effect of capital movements on domestic liquidity. The underlying model is based on the portfolio selection approach, but, as in all earlier models for countries other than the United States, the regression equations do not include wealth as a constraint and as a scale variable.
Kouri and Porter used a reduced form of their model and a limiting case of perfect capital mobility to obtain a regression equation for capital movements, in which changes in the Euro-dollar rate, in the domestic component of the monetary base (which is adjusted for the reserve requirements), and in domestic income, as well as in the level of the trade balance, are taken as independent variables.77 The hypothesis is that the change in base money is used as an exogenous policy instrument by the monetary authorities but may be offset by induced capital movements. If the coefficient of the change in the domestic base money component is equal to unity, this component is perfectly offset by capital flows; if it is equal to zero, there is no offsetting, that is, the effect of capital movements on the money supply is completely sterilized by the authorities. An offset coefficient close to unity also implies a high degree of integration between the domestic and foreign capital markets. Financial integration that is so nearly perfect means that monetary authorities are powerless in their attempts to sterilize the effect of international capital movements on domestic money supply.
The regression equation is tested for four industrial countries. The results appear to be encouraging. It is interesting that the change in income (as an index of a change in the transactions demand for money) is significant in all cases tested. The “offset coefficient” for Germany is 0.7–0.8; it is about 0.6 for the Netherlands, 0.5 for Australia, and 0.4 for Italy. It appears that German monetary policy was not very effective during the 1960s, as it was largely offset by induced capital movements. On the other hand, in the other three countries there was apparently more scope for a partial neutralization of the liquidity effects of capital movements.
On closer examination, the regression results for Germany, Australia, and, to some extent, Italy appear to have been dominated by periods of substantial destabilizing speculation in the closing years of the 1960s. This is probably caused by an important simultaneous relationship exhibited in the regression equation between capital movements as a dependent variable and domestic money supply as an independent variable. Such a simultaneous relationship is expected to generate a substantial bias in the coefficients and in the level of significance when periods with large speculative flows are included in the series used. Also, lack of significance of any foreign interest rate in the regression equations for the Netherlands, Italy, and Australia is surprising. Nevertheless, Kouri and Porter have initiated an important econometric approach based on a general equilibrium analysis, which, on the one hand, avoids the bias occurring in models that assume interest rates to be exogenous and, on the other hand, facilitates statistical analysis by expressing the (often unavailable) appropriate domestic interest rate in terms of other monetary variables.
III. Conclusions
The theory of international short-term capital movements has experienced significant progress over the past 20 years. The integration of the spot and forward exchange markets within Tsiang’s framework permitted a more rigorous explanation of the forces influencing short-term capital movements. The application of the theory of portfolio selection to international finance settled the stock-flow controversy, led to the development of theoretically more satisfactory stock adjustment models, and permitted the treatment of financial flows within the framework of a growing economy. A parallel development of macroeconomic models of an open economy allowed an analysis of capital movements within a general equilibrium framework and led to a more complete explanation of causal links between short-term capital flows and domestic monetary policies. However, although progress has been made in integrating some of these approaches into a unified framework, a number of serious problems have remained unresolved.
1. The formation of exchange rate expectations still needs to be explained before the forward exchange market can be incorporated into a theory of short-term capital movements. Furthermore, the problem of integrating the forward exchange market into portfolio selection models is still far from resolved. This is particularly so if the aim of the analysis is to facilitate econometric estimation in term of observable variables.
2. The problem of dynamic adjustments in models describing short-term capital movements is as yet barely outlined. These adjustments involve two separate issues, (a) The analysis of capital movements between growing economies is probably more germane to long-term portfolio investment. However, the inclusion of savings and investment functions into an open economy’s interest determination process that would be consistent with some concept of equilibrium growth, as well as with international reallocation of assets, must be resolved if portfolio balance models are to be useful in analyzing international capital movements. (b) The process of adjustment of capital flows, as a dependent variable, to changes in one or more independent variables is more germane to the dynamics of short-term capital movements. Although some results have been achieved in the analysis of the distributed lags on the microeconomic level and in a closed economy, little is known about the appropriate lagged adjustment process when variables influencing international short-term capital movements are concerned.
3. Finally, the most difficult problem still to be faced in formulating a theory of short-term capital movements is the development of a framework covering more than one or two countries. The portfolio balance behavior should be mutually consistent in all countries covered. In a multicountry framework, simultaneous determination of variables hitherto assumed to be exogenous, such as the “foreign” interest rate, should also be attempted. Although the tremendous difficulties of such a task should not be underestimated, only in this way can a truly general equilibrium analysis of capital flows be achieved.
The econometric analysis of short-term capital movements has also progressed in recent years. A better specification of structural relationships underlying the regression analysis of U.S. capital movements has resulted in considerably improved estimates of the effects of changes in some key financial variables, such as interest rates. The use of this improved methodology has provided the basis for a systematic comparative study of determinants of short-term capital movements in a number of other industrial countries. Econometric estimation based on general equilibrium macro-models, with the domestic interest rate treated as an endogenous variable, was a further step in this direction.
However, the progress in empirical work in recent years has been rather lopsided. One reason for this has been the inadequacy of data on financial variables in most countries. Another reason has been an increasing discrepancy between the rapid advance in econometric techniques and the rather slow development in the specification of a structural framework upon which the regression analysis of short-term capital movements is based. Often, methods from other areas of quantitative analysis are applied to international financial flows with rather dubious results. Instead of attempting to use new, powerful econometric tools in the analysis, perhaps the more modest goal of developing a carefully defined structural framework is currently appropriate. A useful development along these lines has consisted of estimating techniques that take careful account of various institutional rigidities, such as controls of capital movements or other forms of intervention in the foreign exchange market mechanism. Also, specifying a theoretically consistent framework based on independent variables for which data are readily available can be much more fruitful than applying advanced techniques to an ad hoc framework.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Aghevli, B.B., and G.H. Borts, “The Stability and Equilibrium of the Balance of Payments Under a Fixed Exchange Rate,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 3 (1973), pp. 1–20.
Aliber, Robert Z., “Exchange Risk, Yield Curves, and the Pattern of Capital Flows,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXIV (1969), pp. 361–70.
Allen, Polly Reynolds, “A Portfolio Approach to International Capital Flows,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 3 (1973), pp. 135–60.
Almon, Shirley, “The Distributed Lag Between Capital Appropriations and Expenditures,” Econometrica, Vol. 33 (1965), pp. 178–96.
Angeli, James W., The Theory of International Prices: History, Criticism and Restatement (Harvard University Press, 1926).
Antier, Daniel, “Mouvements internationaux de capitaux à court terme,” Statis-tiques et Etudes Financières, No. 12 (1973), pp. 25–55.
Argy, Victor, “Monetary Variables and the Balance of Payments,” Staff Papers, Vol. XVI (1969), pp. 267–88.
Argy, Victor, “Monetary Policy and Internal and External Balance,” Staff Papers, Vol. XVIII (1971), pp. 508–27.
Argy, Victor, and Zoran Hodjera, “Financial Integration and Interest Rate Linkages in the Industrial Countries, 1958–71,” Staff Papers, Vol. XX (1973), pp. 1–77.
Argy, Victor, and Pentti J.K. Kouri, “Sterilization Policies and the Volatility in International Reserves,” presented at the Conference on National Monetary Policies and the International System, Racine, Wisconsin, July 1972.
Argy, Victor, and Michael G. Porter, “The Forward Exchange Market and the Effects of Domestic and External Disturbances Under Alternative Exchange Rate Systems,” Staff Papers, Vol. XIX (1972), pp. 503–32.
Arndt, Sven W., “International Short Term Capital Movements: A Distributed Lag Model of Speculation in Foreign Exchange,” Econometrica, Vol. 36 (1968), pp. 59–70.
Auten, John H., “Forward Exchange Rates and Interest-Rate Differentials,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XVIII (1963), pp. 11–19.
Baguley, Robert W., “International Capital Flows and Canadian Monetary and Fiscal Policies, 1951–1962” (unpublished doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, 1969).
Basevi, Giorgio, “A Model for the Analysis of Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Markets,” Chapter 7 in International Trade and Money, ed. by Michael B. Connolly and Alexander K. Swoboda (London, 1973), pp. 107–26.
Baumol, William J., “Speculation, Profitability, and Stability,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XXXIX (1957), pp. 263–71.
Beach, W. Edwards, British International Gold Movements and Banking Policy, 1818–1913 (Harvard University Press, 1935).
Bell, Philip W., The Sterling Area in the Postwar World: Internal Mechanism and Cohesion, 1946–1952 (Oxford, 1956).
Bell, Philip W., “Private Capital Movements and the U.S. Balance-of-Payments Position,” Factors Affecting the United States Balance of Payments (compilation of studies prepared for the Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments of the Joint Economic Committee, 87th Congress, 2nd Session, Washington, 1962), pp. 395–481.
Black, J., and A. E. De Jasay, “Speculation and the Rate of Interest,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. XXIV (February 1957), pp. 95–110.
Black, Stanley W., “Theory and Policy Analysis of Short-term Movements in the Balance of Payments,” Yale Economic Essays, Vol. 8 (Spring 1968), pp. 5–78.
Black, Stanley W., “An Econometric Study of Euro-Dollar Borrowing by New York Banks and the Rate of Interest on Euro-Dollars,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXVI (1971), pp. 83–88.
Black, Stanley W., “The Use of Rational Expectations in Models of Speculation,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. LIV (1972), pp. 161–65.
Black, Stanley W., International Money Markets and Flexible Exchange Rates, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 32 (Princeton University Press, 1973).
Bloomfield, Arthur Irving, Speculative and Flight. Movements of Capital in Postwar International Finance, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 3 (Princeton University Press, 1954).
Bloomfield, Arthur Irving, Monetary Policy Under the International Gold Standard: 1880–1914 (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1959).
Borch, Karl, and Jan Mossin (eds.), Risk and Uncertainty: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association (New York, 1968).
Bourginat, Henri, Marché des changes et crises des monnaies (Paris, 1972).
Bourginat, Henri, Y. Marquet, and G. Nancy, Effets tendanciels des mouvements de capitaux a court terme, Unversité de Bordeaux I (June 1973).
Brainard, William C, and James Tobin, “Pitfalls in Financial Model Building,” American Economic Association, Papers and Proceedings of the Eightieth Annual Meeting (The American Economic Review, Vol. LVIII, May 1968), pp. 99–122.
Branson, William H., Financial Capital Flows in the U.S. Balance of Payments (Amsterdam, 1968).
Branson, William H., “The Minimum Covered Interest Differential Needed for International Arbitrage Activity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77 (November/December 1969), pp. 1028–35.
Branson, William H., “Monetary Policy and the New View of International Capital Movements,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 2 (1970), pp. 235–62.
Branson, William H., and Raymond D. Hill, Jr. (1971a), “Capital Movements Among Major OECD Countries: Some Preliminary Results,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXVI (1971), pp. 269–86.
Branson, William H., and Raymond D. Hill, Jr. (1971b), “Capital Movements in the OECD Area: An Econometric Analysis,” OECD Economic Outlook: Occasional Studies (Paris, December 1971).
Branson, William H., and Thomas D. Willett, “Policy Toward Short-Term Capital Movements: Some Implications of the Portfolio Approach,” in International Mobility and Movement of Capital, ed. by Fritz Machlup, Walter S. Salant, and Lorie Tarshis, National Bureau for Economic Research (Columbia University Press, 1972), pp. 287–310.
Brown, Jr., William Adams, The International Gold Standard Reinterpreted, 1914–1934, National Bureau of Economic Research (New York, 1940).
Bryant, Ralph C, and Patrie H. Hendershott, Financial Capital Flows in the Balance of Payments of the United States: An Exploratory Empirical Study, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 25 (Princeton University Press, 1970).
Bryant, Ralph C, and Patrie H. “Empirical Analysis of Capital Flows: Some Consequences of Alternative Specifications,” in International Mobility and Movement of Capital, ed. by Fritz Machlup, Walter S. Salant, and Lorie Tarshis, National Bureau for Economic Research (Columbia University Press, 1972), pp. 207–40.
Canterbery, E. Ray, Foreign Exchange, Capital Flows, and Monetary Policy, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 15 (Princeton University Press, 1965).
Canterbery, E. Ray, “A Dynamic Theory of Foreign Exchange,” The National Banking Review, Vol. 4 (1967), pp. 397–413.
Canterbery, E. Ray, “Exchange Rates, Capital Flows and Monetary Policy,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LIX (June 1969), pp. 426–32.
Canterbery, E. Ray, “A Theory of Foreign Exchange Speculation under Alternative Systems,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 79 (May/June 1971), pp. 407–36.
Cassel, Gustav, The Downfall of the Gold Standard (Oxford, 1936).
Caves, Richard E., and Grant L. Reuber, Capital Transfers and Economic Policy: Canada, 1951–1962 (Harvard University Press, 1971).
Chouraqui, Jean Claude, La Speculation et la politique de défense des monnaies (Presses universitaires de France, 1972).
Cohen, Benjamin J., “A Survey of Capital Movements and Findings Regarding Their Interest Sensitivity,” The United States Balance of Payments, Hearings Before the Joint Economic Committee (88th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, July 8 and 9, 1963), Part I, pp. 198–208.
Connolly, Michael B., and Alexander K. Swoboda (eds.), International Trade and Money (London, 1973).
Cooper, Richard N., “Macroeconomic Policy Adjustment in Interdependent Economies,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. LXXXIII (1969), pp. 1–24.
Coulbois, Paul (ed.), Le Change à terme : technique, théorie, politique, Centre d’Economie Bancaire Internationale, Université de Paris I (April 1972).
Courbis, Raymond, “Marché international des capitaux et politiques monétaires nationales,” Economie Appliquée, Vol. XXIV (1971), pp. 379–411.
Day, Alan Charles Lynn, Outline of Monetary Economics (Oxford, 1957).
Dernburg, Thomas F., “Exchange Rates and Co-ordinated Stabilization Policy,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. III (1970), pp. 1–13.
Dockès, Pierre, “Spéculation stabilisante ou déstabilisante?” Economies et Sociétés, Vol. IV (1970), pp. 831–54.
Einzig, Paul, “Some Theoretical Aspects of Forward Exchanges,” The Economic Journal, Vol. XLVI (1936), pp. 462–70.
Einzig, Paul, The Theory of Forward Exchange (London, 1937).
Einzig, Paul, A Dynamic Theory of Forward Exchange (London, 1961).
Fama, Eugene F., “Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Some Clarifying Comments,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXIII (1968), pp. 29–40.
Feldstein, Martin S., “Uncertainty and Forward Exchange Speculation,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. L (1968), pp. 182–92.
Feldstein, Martin S., “Mean-Variance Analysis in the Theory of Liquidity Preference and Portfolio Selection,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. XXXVI (January 1969), pp. 5–12.
Fleming, J. Marcus, “Domestic Financial Policies Under Fixed and Under Floating Exchange Rates,” Staff Papers, Vol. IX (1962), pp. 369–80.
Floyd, John E. (1969a), “International Capital Movements and Monetary Equilibrium,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LIX (September 1969), pp. 472–92.
Floyd, John E. (1969b), “Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a World of Capital Mobility,”. The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. XXXVI (October 1969), pp. 503–17.
Floyd, John E. “Portfolio Equilibrium and the Theory of Capital Movements,” in International Mobility and Movement of Capital, ed. by Fritz Machlup, Walter S. Salant, and Lorie Tarshis, National Bureau of Economic Research (New York, 1972), pp. 91–124.
Freimer, Marshall, and Myron J. Gordon, “Investment Behavior with Utility a Concave Function of Wealth,” in Risk and Uncertainty: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association, ed. by Karl Borch and Jan Mossin (New York, 1968), pp. 94–109.
Frevert, Peter, “A Theoretical Model of the Forward Exchange: Part I,” International Economic Review, Vol. 8 (1967), pp. 153–67; “Part II,” Vol. 8 (1967), pp. 307–26.
Girton, Lance, and Dale Henderson, “A Two Country Model of Financial Capital Movements as Stock Adjustments with Emphasis on the Effects of Central Bank Policy,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Discussion Paper No. 24 (Washington, 1973).
Glahe, Fred R., An Empirical Study of the Foreign-Exchange Market: Test of a Theory, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 20 (Princeton University Press, 1967).
Goldstein, Henry N., “The Implications of Triangular Arbitrage for Forward Exchange Policy,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XIX (1964), pp. 544–51.
Griliches, Zvi, “Distributed Lags: A Survey,” Econometrica, Vol. 35 (1967), pp. 16–49.
Grubel, Herbert G., “A Neglected Aspect of Forward Exchange Theory and Policy,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XVIII (1963), pp. 537–48.
Grubel, Herbert G., Forward Exchange, Speculation and the International Flow of Capital (Stanford University Press, 1966).
Grubel, Herbert G., “Internationally Diversified Portfolios: Welfare Gains and Capital Flows,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LVIII (December 1968), pp. 1299–1314.
Hahn, F.H., and F.P.R. Brechling (eds.), The Theory of Interest Rates: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association (London, 1965).
Hawtrey, R.G., The Gold Standard in Theory and Practice (London, 1927).
Hawtrey, R.G., Currency and Credit (London, Fourth Edition, 1950).
Heckerman, Donald G., “International Short-Term Capital Movements: Comment II,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LVII (June 1967), pp. 551–56.
Helliwell, John F. (1969a), “A Structural Model of the Foreign Exchange Market,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. II (1969), pp. 90–105.
Helliwell, John F. (1969b), “Monetary and Fiscal Policies for an Open Economy,” Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, Vol. 21 (1969), pp. 35–55.
Helliwell, John F. Lawrence H. Officer, Harold T. Shapiro, and Ian A. Stewart, The Structure of RDX1, Bank of Canada, Staff Research Studies, No. 3 (Ottawa, July 1969).
Hendershott, Patrie H. (1967a), “International Short-Term Capital Movements: Comment IV,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LVII (June 1967), pp. 560–63.
Hendershott, Patrie H. (1967b), “The Structure of International Interest Rates: The U.S. Treasury Bill Rate and the Eurodollar Deposit Rate,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXII (1967), pp. 455–65.
Hodjera, Zoran, “Short-Term Capital Movements of the United Kingdom, 1963–1967,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 79 (July/August 1971), pp. 739–75.
Hodjera, Zoran, “Recent Analysis of Short-Term Capital Movements and the Problem of Controls” (paper prepared for the Conference on Capital Movements and Their Control, Geneva, June 1973).
Iversen, Carl, Aspects of the Theory of International Capital Movements (Copenhagen, 1936).
Jasay, A.E. (1958a), “Bank Rate or Forward Exchange Policy,” Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, Quarterly Review (March 1958), pp. 56–73.
Jasay, A.E. (1958b), “Forward Exchange: The Case For Intervention,” Lloyds Bank Review (October 1958), pp. 35–45.
Jasay, A.E. and John Spraos, “Exchange Policy in the Forward Market,” The Banker (London), April 1958, pp. 225–35.
Johnson, Harry G., “Towards a General Theory of the Balance of Payments,” Chapter VI in his International Trade and Economic Growth: Studies in Pure Theory (Harvard University Press, 1961), pp. 153–68; also reprinted in Readings in International Economics, ed. by Richard E. Caves and Harry G. Johnson (Homewood, Illinois, 1968), pp. 374–88.
Johnson, Harry G., “Some Aspects of the Theory of Economic Policy in a World of Capital Mobility,” in Essays in Honor of Marco Fanno: Vol. II, Investigations in Economic Theory and Methodology, ed. by Tullio Bagiotti (Padua, 1966), pp. 345–59.
Johnson, Harry G., “The Monetary Approach to Balance-of-Payments Theory,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. VII (1972), pp. 1555–72; also reprinted in International Trade and Money, ed. by Michael B. Connolly and Alexander K. Swoboda (London, 1973).
Kenen, Peter B., British Monetary Policy and the Balance of Payments, 1951–1957 (Harvard University Press, 1960).
Kenen, Peter B., “Short-Term Capital Movements and the U.S. Balance of Payments,” The United States Balance of Payments, Hearings Before the Joint Economic Committee (88th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, July 8 and 9, 1963), Part I, pp. 153–91.
Kenen, Peter B., “Trade, Speculation, and the Forward Exchange Rate,” in Trade, Growth, and the Balance of Payments: Essays in Honor of Gottfried Haberler (Chicago, 1965), pp. 143–69.
Kesselman, Johnathan, “The Role of Speculation in Forward-Rate Determination: The Canadian Flexible Dollar 1953–1960,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. IV (1971), pp. 279–98.
Keynes, John Maynard, Monetary Reform (New York, 1924).
Keynes, John Maynard “The Future of the Foreign Exchanges,” Lloyds Bank Limited Monthly Review (October 1935), pp. 527–35.
Kindleberger, Charles Poor, International Short-Term Capital Movements (Columbia University Press, 1937).
Klopstock, Fred H., “The International Money Market: Structure, Scope and Instruments,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XX (1965), pp. 182–208.
Komiya, Ryutaro, “Economic Growth and the Balance of Payments: A Monetary Approach,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77 (January/February 1969), pp. 35–48.
Kouri, Pentti J.K. , The Hypothesis of Offsetting Capital Flows: A Case of Germany” (paper presented at the Fourth Konstanz Seminar on Monetary Theory and Monetary Policy, Konstanz, Germany, June 1973).
Kouri, Pentti J.K. and Michael G. Porter (1972 a), “International Capital Flows and Portfolio Equilibrium” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, September 19, 1972). (This article is scheduled for publication in Journal of Political Economy, May/June 1974.)
Kouri, Pentti J.K. and Michael G. Porter (1972b), “Interest Rates, Capital Flows, and Exchange Rate Expectations” (unpublished, International Monetary Fund, October 24, 1972).
Koyck, L.M., Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis (Amsterdam, 1954).
Laffer, Arthur B., “International Short-Term Capital Movements: Comment III,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LVII (June 1967), pp. 556–60.
Larre, René, “Mouvements de capitaux à court terme et changements de parités,” Economie Appliquée, Vol. XXIII (1970), pp. 505–33.
League of Nations (Ragnar Nurkse), International Currency Experience: Lessons of the Inter-War Period (Geneva, 1944).
Leamer, Edward E., and Robert M. Stern, Quantitative International Economics (Boston, 1970).
Leamer, Edward E., and Robert M. Stern, “Problems in the Theory and Empirical Estimation of Interantional Capital Movements,” in International Mobility and Movement of Capital, ed. by Fritz Machlup, Walter S. Salant, and Lorie Tarshis, National Bureau for Economic Research (Columbia University Press, 1972), pp. 171–206.
Lee, C.H., “A Stock-Adjustment Analysis of Capital Movements: The United States-Canadian Case,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 77 (Part I, July/August 1969), pp. 512–23.
Lee, C.H., “The Balance of Trade, Interest Rates, and Capital Movements,” Kyklos, Vol. XXIII (1970), pp. 65–74.
Levin, Jay H., Forward Exchange and Internal-External Equilibrium, Michigan International Business Studies, No. 12 (University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, 1970).
Markowitz, Harry Max, Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments (New York, 1959).
McKinnon, Ronald I., “Portfolio Balance and International Payments Adjustment,” in Monetary Problems of the International Economy, ed. by Robert A. Mundell and Alexander K. Swoboda (University of Chicago Press, 1968), pp. 199–234.
McKinnon, Ronald I., and Wallace E. Oates, The Implications of International Economic Integration for Monetary, Fiscal, and Exchange-Rate Policy, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 16 (Princeton University Press, 1966).
Meade, J.E., The Balance of Payments, The Theory of International Economic Policy, Vol. I (Oxford University Press, 1951).
Miller, Norman C, and Marina v. N. Whitman, “A Mean-Variance Analysis of United States Long-Term Portfolio Foreign Investment,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. LXXXIV (1970), pp. 175–96.
Miller, Norman C, and Marina v. N. Whitman, “The Outflow of Short-Term Funds from the United States: Adjustments of Stocks and Flows,” in International Mobility and Movement of Capital, ed. by Fritz Machlup, Walter S. Salant, and Lorie Tarshis, National Bureau for Economic Research (Columbia University Press, 1972), pp. 253–86.
Moore, Basil J., An Introduction to the Theory of Finance (New York, 1968).
Mundell, Robert A., “The Monetary Dynamics of International Adjustment under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. LXXIV (1960), pp. 227–57.
Mundell, Robert A., “The International Disequilibrium System,” Kyklos, Vol. XIV (1961), pp. 153–72.
Mundell, Robert A., “The Appropriate Use of Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Internal and External Stability,” Staff Papers, Vol. IX (1962), pp. 70–79.
Mundell, Robert A., “Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates,” The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, Vol. 29 (1963), pp. 475–85.
Mundell, Robert A., “A Reply: Capital Mobility and Size,” The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, Vol. 30 (1964), pp. 421–31.
Mundell, Robert A., “International Disequilibrium and the Adjustment Process,” Chapter 13 in Capital Movements and Economic Development: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association, ed. by John H. Adler and Paul W. Kuznets (London, 1967), pp. 441–71.
Mundell, Robert A., and Alexander K. Swoboda (eds.), Monetary Problems of the International Economy (University of Chicago Press, 1969).
Munier, Bertrand, “Capitaux flottants : une interprétation en terms de théorie des jeux,” Economie Appliquée, Vol. XXIII (1970), pp. 535–69.
Muth, John F., “Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements,” Econometrica, Vol. 29 (1961), pp. 315–35.
Nancy, Gilles, “Une Approche économétrique de la variation des termes de paiement : Le cas de la France,” Economie Appliquée, Vol. XXV (1972), pp. 207–45.
Nerlove, Marc, Distributed Lags and Demand Analysis for Agricultural and Other Commodities, Department of Agriculture, Agriculture Handbook No. 41 (Washington, June 1958).
Nerlove, Marc, “Lags in Economic Behavior,” Econometrica, Vol. 40 (1972), pp. 221–52.
Niehans, Jürg, “Monetary and Fiscal Policies in Open Economies under Fixed Exchange Rates: An Optimizing Approach,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76 (Part II, July/August 1968), pp. 893–920.
Nurkse, Ragnar, “Ursachen und Wirkungen der Kapitalbewegungen,” Zeitschrift fuer Nationaloekonomie, Vol. V (1934), pp. 78–96; translated in Equilibrium and Growth in the World Economy: Economic Essays by Ragnar Nurkse, ed. by Gottfried Haberler and Robert M. Stern (Harvard University Press, 1961), pp. 1–21.
Nurkse, Ragnar, “Domestic and International Equilibrium,” Chapter XXI in The New Economics: Keynes” Influence on Theory and Public Policy, ed. by Seymour E. Harris (New York, 1947), pp. 264–92.
Oates, Wallace E., “Budget Balance and Equilibrium Income: A Comment on the Efficacy of Fiscal and Monetary Policy in an Open Economy,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XXI (1966), pp. 489–98.
Officer, Lawrence H., and Thomas D. Willett, “The Covered-Arbitrage Schedule: A Critical Survey of Recent Developments,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. II (1970), pp. 247–57.
Ohlin, Bertil, Interregional and International Trade (Harvard University Press, 1933).
Ott, David J., and Attiat F. Ott, “Budget Balance and Equilibrium Income,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XX (1965), pp. 71–77.
Pelletier, Robert, “Mouvements internationaux de capitaux à vue et à très court terme,” Conseil Economique et Social, Section des Finances (Paris, December 1970).
Pippenger, John, “Spot Rates, Forward Rates, and Interest-Rate Differentials,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. IV (1972), pp. 375–83.
Polak, J.J., “Monetary Analysis of Income Formation and Payments Problems,” Staff Papers, Vol. VI (1957–58), pp. 1–50.
Polak, J.J., and Victor Argy, “Credit Policy and the Balance of Payments,” Staff Papers, Vol. XVIII (1971), pp. 1–24.
Polak, J.J., and Lorette Boissonneault, “Monetary Analysis of Income and Imports and Its Statistical Application,” Staff Papers, Vol. VII (1959–60), pp. 349–415.
Porter, Michael G., “A Theoretical and Empirical Framework for Analyzing the Term Structure of Exchange Rate Expectations,” Staff Papers, Vol. XVIII (1971), pp. 613–45.
Porter, Michael G., “Capital Flows as an Offset to Monetary Policy: The German Case,” Staff Papers, Vol. XIX (1972), pp. 395–424.
Powrie, T.L., “Short-Term Capital Movements and the Flexible Canadian Exchange Rate, 1953–1961,” The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, Vol. 30 (1964), pp. 76–94.
Prachowny, Martin Frederick Jacob, A Structural Model of the U.S. Balance of Payments(Amsterdam, 1969).
Rhomberg, Rudolf R., “Canada’s Foreign Exchange Market: A Quarterly Model,” Staff Papers, Vol. VII (1959–60), pp. 439–56.
Rhomberg, Rudolf R., “A Model of the Canadian Economy under Fixed and Fluctuating Exchange Rates,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXXII (February 1964), pp. 1–31.
Rhomberg, Rudolf R., “Comments,” in International Mobility and Movement of Capital, ed. by Fritz Machlup, Walter S. Salant, and Lorie Tarshis, National Bureau for Economic Research (Columbia University Press, 1972), pp. 314–22.
Salant, William A., “Interest Arbitrage and the Forward Exchange Market: A Comment,” The National Banking Review, Vol. 3 (December 1965), pp. 245–48.
Samuelson, Paul A., “General Proof That Diversification Pays,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 2 (1967), pp. 1–13.
Samuelson, Paul A., “The Fundamental Approximation Theorem of Portfolio Analysis in Terms of Means, Variances, and Higher Moments,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. XXXVII (October 1970), pp. 537–42.
Scammell, William McConnell, International Monetary Policy (London, 1957).
Sharpe, William F., “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium Under Conditions of Risk,” The Journal of Finance, Vol. XIX (1964), pp. 425–42.
Sohmen, Egon, Flexible Exchange Rates: Theory and Controversy (University of Chicago Press, 1961).
Sohmen, Egon, The Theory of Forward Exchange, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 17 (Princeton University Press, 1966).
Southard, Frank A., Foreign Exchange Practice and Policy (New York, 1940).
Spraos, John, “The Theory of Forward Exchange and Recent Practice,” The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. XXI (1953), pp. 87–117.
Spraos, John, “Speculation, Arbitrage and Sterling,” The Economic Journal, Vol. LXIX (1959), pp. 1–21.
Stein, Jerome L., The Nature and Efficiency of the Foreign Exchange Market, Essays in International Finance, No. 40 (Princeton University Press, October 1962).
Stein, Jerome L., (1965 a), “International Short-Term Capital Movements,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LV (March 1965), pp. 40–66.
Stein, Jerome L., (1965 b), “The Forward Rate and the Interest Parity,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. XXXII (April 1965), pp. 113–26.
Stein, Jerome L., “Short-Term Capital Movements; A Reply,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LVII (June 1967), pp. 565–70.
Stein, Jerome L., and Edward Tower, “The Short-Run Stability of the Foreign Exchange Market,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XLIX (1967), pp. 173–85.
Stoll, Hans R., “A Note on Exchange Rate Changes and Capital Flows,” The American Economic Review, Vol. LVII (September 1967), pp. 894–97.
Stoll, Hans R., “An Empirical Study of the Forward Exchange Market Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rate Systems,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. I (1968), pp. 55–78.
Swoboda, Alexander K., “Equilibrium, Quasi-Equilibrium, and Macroeconomic Policy Under Fixed Exchange Rates,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. LXXXVI (1972), pp. 162–71.
Taussig, F.W., International Trade (New York, 1927).
Tinbergen, Jan, On the Theory of Economic Policy (Amsterdam, 1952).
Tobin,