Abstract
The Web edition of the IMF Survey is updated several times a week, and contains a wealth of articles about topical policy and economic issues in the news. Access the latest IMF research, read interviews, and listen to podcasts given by top IMF economists on important issues in the global economy. www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/home.aspx
Over the past two decades, central banks have steadily become more powerful. Until the late 1980s, only the U.S. Federal Reserve, the German Bundesbank, and the Swiss National Bank were legally independent. With the surge in global inflation in the 1970s and 1980s, many central banks were given a clear mandate to tackle the problem. But low inflation does not guarantee financial stability, and now central banks face an additional challenge: preventing booms and busts in economic activity caused by large swings in asset prices. In a new Working Paper, Garry J. Schinasi, Advisor in the IMF’s International Capital Markets Department, takes a closer look at the evolving role of central banks in the quest for financial stability. He spoke with Christine Ebrahim-zadeh of the IMF Survey about his paper, which draws on the experiences of Europe, Japan, and the United States.
IMF Survey: Why are you looking at this issue now?
IMF Survey: What do we mean by financial stability? Is it more than the absence of crises?
For at least three reasons, financial stability should be seen as occurring along a continuum. Financial systems are dynamic, first of all. What might constitute stability at one point in time might be more or less stable at some other time, depending on other dynamic aspects of the economic system, such as technological, political, and social developments. Second, financial stability is consistent with various combinations of the soundness of financial institutions, the condition of the financial markets, and the effectiveness of the various components of the financial infrastructure. And, finally, financial stability depends on participants’ confidence in the financial system and related infrastructure, such as the legal system.
IMF Survey: What are the implications, then, of looking at financial stability as a continuum?
• single institution or market problems not likely to have systemwide consequences for either the banking or financial system;
• problems that involve several relatively important institutions engaged in market activities with some nontrivial probability of spillovers and contagion to a subset of institutions and markets; and
• problems likely to spread to significant numbers and types of financial institutions and across usually unrelated markets for managing liquidity needs, such as forward, interbank, and even equity markets.
Each category requires different diagnostic tools and policy responses, ranging from doing nothing, intensifying supervision or surveillance of a specific institution or market, to injecting liquidity into the markets to dissipate strains, and intervening in particular institutions.
IMF Survey: Do central banks have a natural role in ensuring financial stability?
The second natural role for the central bank is to ensure the smooth functioning of the national payment system to avoid systemic risk. Traditionally, systemic risk has been viewed as the possibility that problems at one bank would spill over to others and lead to bottlenecks in payments, which could threaten the pace of economic activity. The payment system, being the core of the economy and the financial market, has been the subject of much discussion, policy, and reform. Through the efforts of the Group of 10, there now exist real-time gross payments settlement systems that try to prevent a failure at one institution from cascading through the payment system.
The third natural role is related to a central bank’s responsibility for monetary stability. The banking system is the vehicle through which monetary policy affects, in the first instance, the real economy. To the extent that the banking system is experiencing distress, it will be more difficult for the central bank to provide whatever liquidity it thinks is necessary to achieve its monetary objectives. For this reason alone, central banks have a natural interest in sound financial institutions and stable financial markets and in being in a position to influence corrective actions.
There is another explicit link between monetary stability and financial stability. When financial instability occurs, trust and confidence break down. When this happens, there is usually a rush to obtain liquidity—the most liquid asset being fiat money. This means that bank credit and the money supply begin to contract. If this process is allowed to continue, there is the potential for a sharp contraction in monetary aggregates—including bank money—that could ultimately lead to a decline in economic activity.
IMF Survey: What authority or tools does a central bank need to execute this role effectively?
The European Central Bank (ECB) is a case in point. This newly created central bank, which is supranational, manages the one currency of 12 countries. In many ways, the German Bundesbank was the model for the ECB, both in statute and in practice. The Bundesbank, as it existed prior to the creation of the euro zone, could be characterized as a central bank based on a narrow concept of central banking. It had a single objective—the stability of the deutsche mark, which, in domestic terms, meant price stability. In practice, the Bundesbank was a de facto bank supervisor as well, even though there was a separate Federal Supervisory Office. The Bundesbank was responsible for collecting all of the information required for good banking supervision, and it provided that information to the Federal Supervisory Office, which legally was the supervisor. The Bundesbank had a very direct and central role in banking supervision.
By contrast, the ECB’s mandate is to ensure price stability. It has a small role in ensuring financial stability, and this role is effectively confined to ensuring the smooth functioning of the TARGET payment system (the settlement system for the euro) and not the financial system per se. Most of the authority for banking supervision is delegated to the 12 national European central banks. The U.S. Federal Reserve, on the other hand, is a broadly conceived central bank with several mandates, including the responsibility to regulate and supervise key sectors of the financial markets, both domestic and international. The U.K. system is somewhere in between. The Bank of England plays the role of lender of last resort in ensuring financial stability, but it no longer has a mandate for banking supervision.
IMF Survey: How far have central banks actually gone in safeguarding financial stability?
The second example is the U.S. Federal Reserve’s involvement, in 1998, in coordinating a private rescue of Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM), a $4 billion hedge fund on the brink of failure. There appear to be two main reasons why the Federal Reserve coordinated the private rescue and reduced interest rates (in three separate moves totaling 75 basis points) simultaneously. One was for financial stability; certainly, although the fund was relatively small by U.S. standards, there was tremendous turbulence in the deepest and most liquid markets in the world. The other reason is that there was a real threat to future monetary stability in that if risk taking were not restored to at least a normal level, even small, thriving businesses would not have been able to receive the credit they needed to conduct their day-to-day business. This would have been a threat to monetary stability.
A third example is the Hong Kong Monetary Authority’s intervention in support of the equity markets during the Asian crisis in 1997. One possible reason for the intervention was to establish financial stability in the face of attacks on currencies, sometimes through the equity markets. The second reason was for monetary stability. The Hong Kong economy was likely to be subject to a widespread systemic problem if the equity market collapsed.
IMF Survey: Can any further steps be taken to make central banks more effective?
Copies of IMF Working Paper No. 03/121, “Responsibility of Central Banks for Stability in Financial Markets,” by Garry J. Schinasi, are available for $15.00 each from IMF Publication Services. Please see below for ordering details. The full text is also available on the IMF’s website (http://www.imf.org).