Book Reviews
Author:
Mancur Olson
Search for other papers by Mancur Olson in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Taehoon Kim
Search for other papers by Mr. Taehoon Kim in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Nancy Birdsall
Search for other papers by Nancy Birdsall in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Carol Graham
Search for other papers by Carol Graham in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Bruno S. Sergi
Search for other papers by Bruno S. Sergi in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Courtney N. Blackman
Search for other papers by Courtney N. Blackman in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Simon Cueva
Search for other papers by Mr. Simon Cueva in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Samuel P. Itam
Search for other papers by Mr. Samuel P. Itam in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Jacques Bendelac
Search for other papers by Jacques Bendelac in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mr. Oussama Kanaan
Search for other papers by Mr. Oussama Kanaan in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This paper describes the need to broaden the agenda for poverty reduction. The broadening of the agenda follows from a growing understanding that poverty is more than low income, a lack of education, and poor health. The poor are frequently powerless to influence the social and economic factors that determine their well being. The paper highlights that a broader definition of poverty requires a broader set of actions to fight it and increases the challenge of measuring poverty and comparing achievement across countries and over time.

Abstract

This paper describes the need to broaden the agenda for poverty reduction. The broadening of the agenda follows from a growing understanding that poverty is more than low income, a lack of education, and poor health. The poor are frequently powerless to influence the social and economic factors that determine their well being. The paper highlights that a broader definition of poverty requires a broader set of actions to fight it and increases the challenge of measuring poverty and comparing achievement across countries and over time.

Power and Prosperity

Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships

Mancur Olson

Basic Books, New York, 2000, xxvii + 233 pp., $28/Can$42.50 (cloth).

THE LATE Mancur Olson summed up his life’s work in this short but remarkably insightful book. He applies insights drawn from his past work to the vanishing communist world, to the transition from communism to capitalism, and to the poverty of developing countries.

Olson’s first insight is that individuals who hold power have an all-encompassing interest in the prosperity of the economy. In an apt metaphor, he describes a “stationary bandit” as better than a “roving bandit.” A roving bandit takes everything from his victims; a stationary bandit has an interest in his victims’ continuing prosperity and so takes less than 100 percent. By the same token, an unstable autocracy will loot more than a stable autocracy, because the latter has a longer horizon and thus a greater stake in future prosperity. Olson cites empirical work on developing countries that seems to support the hypothesis that long-lived autocracies perform better than short-lived ones. He devotes a fair amount of space to Joseph Stalin, one of history’s most notorious stationary bandits. Stalin seized the entire Soviet economy but offset disincentives to future wealth creation by engaging in state-led investment. Olson goes into interesting detail about Stalin’s brutally efficient system, which combined state terror with production incentives and helps the reader understand how Stalinist communism endured as long as it did.

But, Olson says, even in a stable autocracy, prosperity is not necessarily ensured for the long term because all autocrats die and create succession crises. Autocrats also have an unfortunate habit of trying to expand their revenues by preying on their neighbors. Democracies almost never go to war with each other—as has been noted many times—and are less likely to expropriate investments or break contracts. Most important, democracies that handle succession in a legal and stable manner create a stronger foundation for future prosperity. Olson points out that virtually all the richest countries are democracies with legal, stable succession processes.

Olson draws on earlier work on the logic of collective action to explain both the collapse of the Soviet Union and the difficult transition of its constituent states to market economies. His now famous insight is that centrally planned economies suffered from the same “sclerosis” as the industrial countries. That is, over time, interest groups organized and diverted resources into their own hands out of the productive economy. In the former Soviet Union, for example, state enterprise managers colluded both with their superiors and with other managers to divert resources into their own pockets. The scale of corruption became so great that the center eventually ran out of resources and the economy imploded.

What about the difficult transition to market economies? Olson draws an interesting contrast between the collapse of fascism (in Germany and Japan after World War II) and that of communism. When fascism collapsed, the victorious Allies swept away all the old collective interest groups and imposed constitutional democracy. In contrast, the collective interest groups of state enterprise managers did not vanish when communism collapsed. These groups have either slowed privatization or retained control of the “privatized” enterprises and continue to divert productive resources to themselves.

If there is a problem with Olson’s book, it is that his insights are somewhat contradictory. Stable, long-established democracies have a more lasting interest in future prosperity and thus promote prosperity. Long-term stability, however, leads to interest group sclerosis and is harmful to prosperity. The reader is left with some doubts about the future of the world’s stable democracies. Olson offers one ray of hope—that, as the public becomes more knowledgeable, special interest groups will lose their ability to subvert the interests of the larger society. But for his untimely death, I am sure Mancur Olson would have answered this and many other questions for those of us who have long admired his insights.

William Easterly

CLARIFICATION

In the article “Funding the IMF: The Debate in the U.S. Congress” in the September 2000 issue of Finance & Development, the accompanying box misstated the relationship between the U.S. budgetary process and IMF quota increases. A clarification follows: In the United States, the periodic quota increase exercises take place within the budgetary process, as they require appropriations by Congress.

The dollars committed by the United States under a quota increase are called by the IMF only as it needs them, in combination with contributions from other creditor countries, to extend credit to borrowing members. As and when dollars are used in transactions, the United States is credited with an equal amount in automatic drawing rights on the IMF, which it considers part of its international reserves and which earn a market-related rate of interest.

Since U.S. transfers of dollars to the IMF involve exchanges by the United States of one monetary asset for another, they do not represent net budgetary outlays, nor do they have an impact on the budget deficit and surplus.

New Markets, New Opportunities?

Economic and Social Mobility in a Changing World

Nancy Birdsall and Carol Graham (editors)

Brookings Institution Press/Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Washington, 2000, x + 331 pp., $24.95 (paper).

NANCY BIRDSALL and Carol Graham have edited a book on the economics of opportunity—the analysis of economic and political systems in which people have more social mobility and thus more access to opportunities, but where upward and downward movements are equally possible. This book looks at the process that produces social inequalities, opportunities, and political behavior, as well as the links between them. This is a topic of mounting complexity, and the editors modestly suggest that their book should be viewed as an exploration of uncharted waters.

Yet the book exceeds expectations for a number of reasons. First, it covers a well-balanced geographical distribution of countries, from Latin America to the newly democratic postcommunist societies of Eastern Europe, with the United States presented as a benchmark case. Second, the various chapters—written by distinguished economists—present rigorous case studies, innovative interpretations, and stimuli for new research.

The book opens with a discussion of the main issues and ideas on the economics of opportunity. It includes a chapter by Joseph Stiglitz, former Chief Economist at the World Bank, criticizing standard welfare economics because, in his view, social justice and the desirability of social mobility and more equal opportunities are inconsistent with this traditional theory. He does not, however, formulate any alternative.

Another section explores the existing evidence on the economics of opportunity and mobility patterns in Latin America and Eastern Europe. One finding is that education both contributes to, and is an outcome of, inequality and mobility patterns. In Latin America, especially, public spending on education was found to increase intergenerational mobility, although it does not seem to have an effect on income distribution in the short run. In Chile, the distribution of income continues to be unequal, despite market reforms, although the incomes of skilled workers have increased dramatically.

In Eastern Europe, young people, especially if they are well educated, are the primary beneficiaries of the transformation from central planning to market-oriented systems because they respond effectively to rapid change, taking advantage of new opportunities and earning higher incomes. Thus, they are the most likely group to favor reforms. The “losers” are older workers who cannot adapt to a system of intensified competition and retirees, whose pensions cannot keep up with inflation.

Without social and political support, market reforms cannot be sustained. To create the necessary consensus for reform in a country, the population must favor reforms. Policymakers should examine the link between, on the one hand, the creation of opportunities resulting from market reforms and the evidence of mobility among self-employed people and, on the other hand, the risk of inequalities and insecurity.

Isabel Sawhill of the Brookings Institution writes about the U.S. economy, in which income distribution has changed very little over time and large inequalities exist. She notes, however, that people appear to cope well because the large inequalities are associated with abundant opportunities. This assertion has never been fully proved, however, and, indeed, there is evidence that opportunities in the United States are no greater than in many other western countries. As people acquire more education, more opportunities become available to them, although in the United States, family background and income patterns also matter, influencing how long an individual goes to school and who goes to college. An effective elementary and secondary education can also expand an individual’s opportunities.

All told, the book presents an excellent analysis of the growing interest in social mobility and suggests areas of research for future examination. The editors have done a good job in distinguishing between the economics of opportunity and the politics of public perception and in looking at those countries in which social mobility partially applies or is beginning to emerge. This book fills a gap in the economic literature and should prove useful to economists, sociologists, and policymakers. At the same time, the experiences of transition countries and of their newly market-based economies might be promising areas for continued research.

Bruno S. Sergi

Credits

Cover photo: World Bank.

Illustrations: contents page and pages 2,18, and 38: Michael Gibbs; page 30: Massoud Etemadi.

Photographs: contents page, authors, and books: IMF Graphics Photo Unit; page 46, courtesy of British Petroleum Exploration Colombia (BPXC).

Central Banking in Theory and Practice

A Small State Perspective

Courtney N. Blackman

Caribbean Center for Monetary Studies, St. Augustine, Trinidad, Trinidad and Tobago, 1998, xx + 303 pp., $25 (paper).

THIS COLLECTION of 15 essays has the unmistakable style of an experienced central banker, which Courtney N. Blackman is, having served three terms as founding governor of the Central Bank of Barbados. Central banks were conceived as apolitical institutions characterized by operational autonomy and a highly educated staff, a tradition of excellence and integrity that involves cordial but frank relations with government political entities, and a role in helping to educate the general public about economics.

The book emphasizes the imperfect market conditions in which central banks operate in small economies, with narrow money and capital markets in which a small number of participants represent a sizable share of the market. This explains the important role of moral suasion in the relationship between a country’s central bank and its financial institutions and justifies the central bank’s use of direct intervention in the conduct of monetary and exchange rate policies, including through reserve requirements, interest rate floors, and exchange restrictions.

The reader will discern Blackman’s marked aversion for currency devaluation—recommended, together with fiscal adjustments, at different times for a number of the Caribbean economies by the international financial institutions—and his preference for currency pegs (to the U.S. dollar). The author believes that the exchange rate instability that characterizes small, open economies has a rapid and sizable impact on domestic prices, undermining the public’s confidence in the currency and affecting the credibility of the central bank.

He therefore emphasizes throughout the essays the need for a prudent fiscal stance, wage restraint, and limits on the central banks’ money-creation powers. Failure to adhere to this approach is reflected in many aspects of Caribbean economic history—the fiscal expansion in Guyana and Jamaica in the mid-1970s, episodes of fiscal strain in Barbados through the 1980s (for example, the pre-electoral increase in fiscal expenditures in 1981 and the sizable tax reductions in 1986), and the collapse of the CARICOM (Caribbean Common Market) multilateral clearing facility as a result of the excessive indebtedness of Guyana, whose severe external imbalances were associated with ambitious public spending.

In Blackman’s view, a Caribbean central bank should consider not only the peculiarities of small developing countries—including their development needs and narrow financial markets—but also the prevailing environment, in which the central bank authorities will be perceived as part of the political arena. In practice, central banks in the Caribbean region have enjoyed diverse levels of autonomy, the Eastern Caribbean Central Bank (ECCB) with its quasi-currency board arrangement being perhaps the most independent. In this context, besides some other reforms in central banks (like lengthening the directors’ terms in office, making them responsible to the parliaments rather than to the ministries of finance, and introducing legal limits on their financing of the governments), Blackman supports the creation of a Caribbean monetary union with a common currency and free capital movements. Within this union, monetary policy would be managed by a Caribbean federal reserve system with pooled reserves—a larger version of the ECCB. The checks and balances system that would result from the participation of several governments in the decisionmaking process and the need to reach consensus would, in Blackman’s opinion, ensure that the system used its money creation powers with skill and restraint.

Overall, this book provides helpful insights on the practices of small developing economies and explores, from their perspective, a number of challenging arguments. It should be noted, however, that the central banks in the Caribbean region have evolved considerably since these essays were completed. They have progressively reduced, and in some cases eliminated, reliance on direct policy instruments, such as reserve requirements, interest rate and credit controls, and exchange restrictions, as they develop domestic or regional money markets, depend more on indirect instruments, and become more integrated with international capital markets. Similarly, the strengthening of the regulatory and supervisory frameworks for the financial sector—especially in the wake of problems in the early to mid-1990s—has made most central banks in the region considerably more independent in the way they conduct monetary policy. But in one important area Blackman’s counsel is still particularly apt: it is important to provide appropriate fiscal policy support for monetary policy.

Simon Cueva and Samuel Itam

CORRECTION

In the article “Estonia Moves Toward EU Accession” in the September 2000 issue, there was an error in Table 2, “Foreign direct investment in Central and Eastern European countries.” The denomination for Column 2, which listed “Cumulative inflows per capita, 1989–98,” should have been “dollars,” not “million dollars.”

L’économie palestinienne

De la dépendance à l’autonomie

Jacques Bendelac

L’Harmattan, Paris, 1999,157 pp., FF 90 (paper).

A NUMBER of recent publications on the economy of the West Bank and Gaza, including some produced by international organizations and quasi-official think tanks, have tended to gloss over important economic issues related to the peace accords between the Palestine Liberation Organization (PLO) and Israel, perhaps because of an excessive preoccupation with the political sensitivities involved. As a result, recent coverage of thorny topics—such as the economic consequences of the Israeli occupation or of corruption in the Palestinian government—has been largely journalistic and often lacked analytical rigor. This book by Jacques Bendelac is one of the few notable exceptions to this trend. It presents a refreshingly candid and bold yet balanced analysis of the evolution of the Palestinian economy from its beginnings to the present.

In the first part of the book, Bendelac examines the factors that constrained the development of the Palestinian economy during the Israeli occupation and that, over time, distorted its pattern of external trade, skewed its private investment away from growth-generating areas, and weakened its agricultural and industrial sectors. One important constraint to growth was the absence of a level playing field in trade between Israel and the West Bank and Gaza. Unlike Israeli exports to the occupied territories, Palestinian exports of agricultural and industrial goods to Israel were severely restricted. Private activities were also constrained by a nontransparent legal and regulatory environment, inadequate public investment in infrastructure, and the virtual absence of a banking system until the early 1980s. As a result, growth in the West Bank and Gaza was sustained largely by the earnings of Palestinian workers in Israel (mostly from low-skill employment); the development of modern farming and industry was suppressed; and private investment remained concentrated in residential construction.

Bendelac examines next the economic opportunities offered by the peace accords, in particular the trade and development strategy envisaged by the 1994 Protocol on Economic Relations. This strategy had the potential to expand and reorient the West Bank and Gaza’s productive base toward agricultural and industrial exports and gradually reduce its dependence on the export of labor. The improved trade environment was expected to induce a boom in private investment and create lucrative domestic outlets for a large stock of savings that had previously been deposited abroad.

In the remainder of the book, Bendelac discusses the disappointing performance of the Palestinian economy following the peace accords, which he largely attributes to recurrent border closures and, to a lesser extent, to government interference in private activities. At the same time, he highlights some improvements in fiscal transparency by the Palestinian Authority since 1996, which he credits in part to pressures and assistance from donors and the IMF.

I would have liked to see a final chapter with policy recommendations less constrained by the straitjacket of the 1994 protocol. Bendelac could have taken a more critical approach to the trade regime envisaged by the protocol, in particular, its failure to directly address important obstacles to external trade. These include, notably, the limited flexibility Palestinians have to determine their import policies and tariff structures, as well as their lack of control over borders and outlets to external markets, including seaports and airports. Other issues that are neglected include the establishment of equitable water rights and a system of fair property settlement for land, as well as the impact on productivity growth of the return of highly skilled diaspora Palestinians.

Overall, Bendelac’s presentation of the key impediments to the development of the Palestinian economy is clear, persuasive, and dispassionate. He apportions the responsibility for the dismal economic performance to both the Israeli and the Palestinian authorities. The former get the lion’s share of the blame, given the damage done during three decades of occupation and by the intermittent border closures, while the latter’s track record, although relatively short (barely six years), is exposed for inadequate fiscal discipline and weak governance. Despite a few deficiencies in the forward-looking policy areas—I would have liked to see a more comprehensive and novel discussion of the economic issues being addressed in the permanent status negotiations—Bendelac’s book is an important and timely contribution to the longstanding debate on the future of the Palestinian economy.

Oussama Kanaan

want to know more about the IMF?

www.imf.org

INDEX: 2000—Volume 37

ARTICLES

Masood Ahmed and Hugh Bredenkamp, Supporting Poverty Reduction in Low-Income Developing Countries: The International Community’s Response, December

Eduardo Aninat, Chile in the 1990s: Embracing Development Opportunities, March

Leszek Balcerowicz, Poland’s Transformation, September

Tomás J.T. Baliño and Angel Ubide, The New World of Banking, June

Andrew Berg and Eduardo Borensztein, The Dollarization Debate, March

James M. Boughton, Michel Camdessus at the IMF: A Retrospective, March

Leonardo Cardemil, Juan Carlos Di Tata, and Florencia Frantischek, Central America: Adjustment and Reforms in the 1990s, March

Paul Cashin and Catherine Pattillo, The Duration of Terms of Trade Shocks in Sub-Saharan Africa, June

Enzo Croce and Mohsin S. Khan, Monetary Regimes and Inflation Targeting, September

Uri Dadush, Dipak Dasgupta, and Dilip Ratha, The Role of Short-Term Debt in Recent Crises, December

Raj Desai and Itzhak Goldberg, Stakeholders, Governance, and the Russian Enterprise Dilemma, June

Mohamed A. El-Erian, Where Are Emerging Markets Headed? June

Robert A. Feldman and C. Maxwell Watson, Central Europe: From Transition to EU Membership, September

Stanley Fischer and Ratna Sahay, Economies in Transition: Taking Stock, September

Arminio Fraga, Monetary Policy During the Transition to a Floating Exchange Rate: Brazil’s Recent Experience, March

Sanjeev Gupta, Brian Hammond, Richard Leete, and Eric Swanson, Progress Toward the International Development Goals, December

Emine Gürgen, Central Asia: Achievements and Prospects, September

José Angel Gurría, Mexico: Recent Developments, Structural Reforms, and Future Challenges, March

Sean Hagan, Promoting Orderly and Effective Insolvency Procedures, March

Oleh Havrylyshyn and John Odling-Smee, Political Economy of Stalled Reforms, September

Ernesto Hernández-Catá, Raising Growth and Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa: What Can Be Done? December

Paul Hilbers, Russell Krueger, and Marina Moretti, New Tools for Assessing Financial System Soundness, September

Christopher Jarvis, The Rise and Fall of Albania’s Pyramid Schemes, March

Oussama Kanaan, Tanzania’s Experience with Trade Liberalization, June

Cem Karacadag and Michael W. Taylor, Toward a New Global Banking Standard: The Basel Committee’s Proposals, December

Daniel Kaufmann, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobatón, Governance Matters: From Measurement to Action, June

Anne Y. Kester, Improving the Framework for Reporting on International Reserves, June

Mahmood Hasan Khan, Rural Poverty in Developing Countries, December

Robert Klitgaard, Subverting Corruption, June

János Kornai, Making the Transition to Private Ownership, September

Mary Locke, Funding the IMF: The Debate in the U.S. Congress, September

Claudio M. Loser and Martine Guerguil, The Long Road to Financial Stability, March

Prakash Loungani, Comrades or Competitors? Trade Links Between China and Other East Asian Economies, June

Nora Lustig and Omar Arias, Poverty Reduction, March

Nora Lustig and Nicholas Stern, Broadening the Agenda for Poverty Reduction: Opportunity, Empowerment, Security, December

Catherine L. Mann, Is the U.S. Current Account Deficit Sustainable? March

Kathryn McPhail, How Oil, Gas, and Mining Projects Can Contribute to Development, December

Deepa Narayan, Poverty Is Powerlessness and Voicelessness, December

Andrei Nesterenko, The Modernization Challenge Facing President Putin, September

Roger Nord, Central and Eastern Europe and the New Financial Architecture, September

Saleh M. Nsouli, Capacity Building in Africa: The Role of International Financial Institutions, December

Jeremy Pope and Frank Vogl, Making Anticorruption Agencies More Effective, June

Barry H. Potter and Jack Diamond, Building Treasury Systems, September

Pedro Pou, Argentina’s Structural Reforms of the 1990s, March

Robert Powell, Debt Relief for Poor Countries, December

Robert Rennhack, Banking Supervision, March

Einars Repše, Latvia: Focus on Country Development, September

Caroline M. Robb, How the Poor Can Have a Voice in Government Policy, December

Dani Rodrik, Growth Versus Poverty Reduction: A Hollow Debate, December

Hans Dieter Seibel, Agricultural Development Banks: Close Them or Reform Them? June

Torsten Sløk, Can Monetary Policy Be Effective During Transition? Lessons from Mongolia, September

Rüdiger Soltwedel, Dirk Dohse, and Christiane Krieger-Boden, European Labor Markets and EMU: Challenges Ahead, June

Janet Stotsky, Esther Suss, and Stephen Tokarick, Trade Liberalization in the Caribbean, June

Rachel van Elkan, Czech Republic: Recent Developments and Current Outlook, September

Willy H. Verheye, Food Production or Food Aid? An African Challenge, December

René Weber and Günther Taube, Estonia Moves Toward EU Accession, September

BOOK REVIEWS

Jacques Bendelac, L’économie palestinienne: De la dépendance à l’autonomie, December

Jagdish Bhagwati, A Stream of Windows: Unsettling Reflections on Trade, Immigration, and Democracy, June

Nancy Birdsall and Carol Graham (editors), New Markets, New Opportunities? Economic and Social Mobility in a Changing World December

Courtney N. Blackman, Central Banking in Theory and Practice: A Small State Perspective, December

Edward Chancellor, Devil Take the Hindmost: A History of Financial Speculation, March

Diane Coyle, The Weightless World: Strategies for Managing the Digital Economy, March

Dana Frank, Buy American: The Untold Story of Economic Nationalism, June

Thomas L. Friedman, The Lexus and the Olive Tree, March

Norman K. Humphreys, Historical Dictionary of the International Monetary Fund, Second Edition, March

Henry Kaufman, On Money and Markets: A Wall Street Memoir, September

Derek Leebaert (editor), The Future of the Electronic Marketplace, March

Mancur Olson, Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships, December

Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom, June

Andrei Shleifer and Daniel Treisman, Without a Map: Political Tactics and Economic Reform in Russia, September

Muhammad Yunus, Banker to the Poor: Micro-Lending and the Battle Against World Poverty, March

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Finance & Development, December 2000
Author:
International Monetary Fund. External Relations Dept.