Global Risks, Vulnerabilities, and Policy Challenges Facing Low-Income Countries

The rapid recovery in many low-income countries (LICs) following the global crisis has been sustained in 2012. Softening commodity prices have led to moderating inflation pressures in most LICs. However, progress in rebuilding policy buffers has halted over the past two years, despite continued strong growth in LICs.

Abstract

The rapid recovery in many low-income countries (LICs) following the global crisis has been sustained in 2012. Softening commodity prices have led to moderating inflation pressures in most LICs. However, progress in rebuilding policy buffers has halted over the past two years, despite continued strong growth in LICs.

I. Background: Recent Macroeconomic Trends in LICs

The rapid recovery in many low-income countries (LICs) following the global crisis has been sustained in 2012. Softening commodity prices have led to moderating inflation pressures in most LICs. However, progress in rebuilding policy buffers has halted over the past two years, despite continued strong growth in LICs.

1. Most LICs recovered quickly from the 2008-09 global crisis and have experienced strong growth since early 2010. In 2009, solid pre-crisis macroeconomic positions facilitated a countercyclical policy response to the crisis—a first for LICs.2 In contrast to past global slowdowns, the recovery in LICs was swift and synchronized with the rest of the world, reflecting strong export demand from trading partners. While advanced economies still account for a large share of LICs’ trading partners, a number of fast-growing emerging markets (EMs) have played an increasing role in supporting growth in LICs. In addition to the usual trade channels, through which higher growth in EMs contributes to a rise in demand for LIC exports, some EMs have become major contributors to LIC growth more recently through remittances and financial linkages.3 The performance in EMs is likely to continue to support growth in LICs in 2012, in particular in Asia and the Pacific.4 Real GDP growth for the median LIC is projected at around 5 percent in 2012, repeating the 2011 performance. Over the period 2009-2010, the global environment has remained less supportive than in the pre-crisis period, and LIC growth recovery was largely driven by domestic demand, on both the consumption and investment sides. More recently, though, the role of external demand increased as investment dampened.

uA01fig01

Economic growth has been holding up relatively well, in spite of moderation in the advanced economies.

(Real per capita growth; percent, median)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

uA01fig02

Domestic demand, including investment, led the recovery in LICs’ growth.

(In percent of GDP, median)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staf f estimates.
uA01fig03

LIC economies have moved largely in synch with key trading partners.

Real GDP Growth in LICs and Their Trading Partners

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

2. The 2011 rally in commodity prices has been partially unwound but prices remain elevated, especially for food and fuel. Commodity prices started declining in the second half of 2011, reflecting the slowdown in global growth. Price decreases have been broadly similar across different commodity groups, with the exception of food and fuel. However, despite the decline, many commodity prices have remained above pre-crisis levels and are expected to stay elevated in the near term. Global food prices were broadly flat until mid-June 2012, but have since increased sharply, driven primarily by some key crops amid concerns about weather-related supply disruptions and lower buffer stocks.5 Food prices are expected to moderate by the end of 2013 but would remain elevated, given short-term supply constraints. Oil prices remain volatile, reflecting political developments in the Middle East and uncertainty regarding the global economic outlook.

uA01fig04

Commodity prices have eased som ewhat but are projected to remain elevated.

Commodity price indices (2005 = 100)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

3. Inflation has generally moderated in many LICs, partly reflecting the pass-through of lower commodity prices. Cyclical external factors that helped unwind global prices have dampened inflationary pressures, particularly the slowdown in global growth, declines in commodity prices, and depreciation of some major currencies. Consequently, inflation for the median LIC is expected to ease, from more than 7.5 percent in 2011 to about 6.3 percent in 2012 and 6.1 percent in 2013. At the same time, inflation slowed sharply in Latin America and the Caribbean and the Middle East and Europe, and inflationary pressures remained fairly subdued in small LICs,6 with median inflation projected at 4½ percent in 2012, falling to 3 percent in 2013.

uA01fig05

On average, forecast inflation in LICs in 2012 is largely unchanged from 2011 WEO...

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.
uA01fig06

...and inflationary pressures are expected to stay contained.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

4. Following the crisis, LICs continue to show significant resilience, despite slow progress in rebuilding macroeconomic policy buffers, which mostly reflects higher public investment spending. Fiscal adjustment started in 2010 as revenues rebounded along with the economic recovery, but has since halted, with the fiscal deficit of the median net oil importer remaining at around 3-3½ percent of GDP in 2011-2012—a substantial widening from about 1½ percent of GDP in pre-crisis years. It is important to note, however, that in the majority of LIC groups, the counterpart to higher revenues has been increased spending on public investment, which may bode well for future growth, while recurrent spending remained relatively stable. Public debt7 has remained broadly stable on average, reflecting previous debt relief operations in the period leading up to the global financial crisis, and prudent borrowing policies, though for a few countries debt ratios have recently reached levels seen before debt relief operations.8 On the external side, current account deficits net of foreign direct investment (FDI) (hereafter referred to as the external balance) have widened since the crisis to about 4 percent of GDP in 2012 from 1½ percent in 2007 for the median LIC, with a bigger deterioration for net oil importers. Here, again, imports were on the rise in response to increased public investment spending. Reserve coverage declined slightly to about 3.5 months of prospective imports (from 3.8 months) for the median LIC over the period 2010-2012. Overall, the situation across various country groups is uneven, with, for example, relatively high external and fiscal policy buffers in commodity-exporting LICs, and limited fiscal space in Latin America and the Caribbean. LICs in Asia and the Pacific now have more limited fiscal space and larger current account deficits than prior to the crisis. Small LICs seem to fare somewhat worse than the rest, with more limited fiscal space in the median country, higher public debt, larger current account deficits, and somewhat lower reserve coverage.

uA01fig07

LICs have been growing robustly, but macroeconomic buffers in many LICs have remained lower than before the crisis.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

II. Vulnerability Analysis

A. How Vulnerable are LICs to a Recession?

The near term risks for LICs of a shock-induced recession have been reduced since the 2009 crisis, but vulnerabilities are re-emerging in 2012 given lower macroeconomic policy buffers and additional risk factors.

5. The strong underlying growth dynamics during the recovery have reduced LICs’ near-term risk of a shock-induced recession, with improvements in fiscal indicators especially pronounced for commodity exporters. An illustrative “growth decline vulnerability index” suggests that the near-term risk of a shock-induced recession increased in the run-up to the global crisis and peaked at the end of 2009, with just over 30 percent of LICs showing a high degree of vulnerability (see Annex II for methodology, and Box 1 for a description of the various approaches used in this paper to assess LICs’ vulnerabilities). In the context of the recovery, this share of vulnerable countries declined to about 20 percent by end-2011, but started rising again in 2012, with an expected 31 percent of LICs showing increased vulnerabilities to exogenous shocks. Here, countries with weak fundamentals (top quartile of the index) face a deterioration in a few indicators of vulnerability (particularly fiscal indicators for commodity exporters and external indicators for non-commodity exporters) that would drive up the general index for end-2012.9

Assessing Vulnerabilities in LICs: Concepts and Approaches

This paper uses the various concepts and approaches defined in IMF (2011b) and IMF (2011c), to assess vulnerabilities in LICs from different angles. These include macroeconomic policy buffers, an illustrative measure of fiscal space, a growth decline vulnerability index, scenario analysis, and complementary vulnerability indicators.

  • Macroeconomic policy buffers are indicators of the overall external and fiscal positions of an economy. Key indicators to assess buffers include the overall fiscal balance, total public debt, international reserve coverage, the external balance, and inflation. Countries with high fiscal deficits and high and/or increasing public debt stocks would generally have less flexibility to use fiscal policy when hit by a shock than countries with low deficits and debt. Likewise, countries with low current account deficits and comfortable reserve coverage may be in a better position to absorb external shocks than countries with large deficits and limited reserve cushions. Finally, countries with relatively low inflation have more scope for accommodative macroeconomic policies.

  • The illustrative fiscal space indicator is a broad concept that considers the extent to which government expenditure can be increased (or taxes cut) without jeopardizing long-run debt sustainability. While the illustrative fiscal space indicator is closely related to the overall fiscal deficit and public debt indicators, its scope is more general and takes into account long-term growth and interest rate prospects and quality of fiscal institutions. For illustrative purposes, fiscal space is defined here as the difference between the baseline primary balance and the constant primary balance that would be needed to avoid unsustainable debt over the usual time horizon for Debt Sustainability Analysis (DSAs). The debt target used is the lowest of either the 2012 baseline debt-to-GDP ratio or the debt targets defined under the Debt Sustainability Framework (DSF). Moreover, this definition of fiscal space also allows for concessional borrowing and gradual access to financial markets at commercial rates in the longer term.

  • An illustrative growth decline vulnerability index is used to measure a country’s underlying vulnerability to sudden growth declines. The latter are characterized by negative real per capita GDP growth in the event of exogenous shocks and a protracted period of growth below the pre-shock trend. The methodology takes into account historical relations between growth decline episodes and economic, fiscal, and external indicators (see Appendix II for details).

  • Scenario analysis is a tool for assessing the macroeconomic impact of global risks. In this paper, the focus is on a number of alternative risks: a sharp downturn in global growth, a protracted downturn in global growth, and global food and oil price shocks. The impact of these shocks on key macroeconomic variables allows for an assessment of the adequacy of external and fiscal buffers across countries, which are used to assess the ability of LICs to withstand shocks.

  • Under the scenario analysis, additional external financing needs are calculated as the amount needed to bring international reserve coverage (in months of next year’s imports) back to three months for those countries that had at least three months coverage prior to the shock. For countries with less than three months coverage of imports in the baseline, additional financing needs reflect the amount of the loss in reserves resulting from the shock. Additional financing needs are zero for countries where reserve coverage exceeds three months even after the shock, or if reserve coverage increased under the shock scenario.

  • Complementary vulnerability indicators are analyzed to measure additional country-specific vulnerabilities arising from geographic and domestic factors, external linkages, and macroeconomic fundamentals (see Appendix IV for details). These indicators can qualify and complement the risks and vulnerabilities identified in the growth decline vulnerability index and the scenario analysis, as they capture countries’ relative exposure to vulnerabilities and the likelihood of a shock materializing.

uA01fig08

Growth Decline Vulnerability Index

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

uA01fig09

Although strong economic growth has reduced LICs’near term risks after the global crisis of 2008-09, more LICs are showing increased vulnerabilities to a sudden shock-induced recession.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.Note: The growth decline vulnerability index is constructed by considering historical relations among economic, fiscal, and external indicators with near-term growth declines and protracted growth slowdowns in the event of exogenous shocks.

6. In addition to the standard indicators used in the growth decline vulnerability index, most LICs have country-specific vulnerabilities that can potentially increase their exposure to shocks.10 Some of the sources of vulnerability can themselves give rise to shocks and can also: (i) increase the susceptibility of being hit by a global shock, (ii) magnify the exposure to spillovers from a global shock, (iii) dampen the capacity to cope with a global shock, and/or (iv) constrain the capacity to build resilience against future global shocks. Generally, natural disasters and climate-related vulnerabilities (such as floods, drought, and earthquakes) pose additional risks to economic outcomes in most LICs, especially in Asia and the Pacific, and Latin America and the Caribbean.11 Similarly, greater integration with global markets heightens countries’ susceptibility to sudden shifts in trade prices in the majority of commodity exporters and countries in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). Meanwhile, weak governance, corruption, and political instability/insecurity12 amplify the effects and costs of global shocks (via increased risk of civil unrest and internal conflict), notably among oil exporters and fragile states. Finally, macroeconomic and financial channels can heighten sensitivity to exogenous shocks. Specifically, overvalued real effective exchange rates among small states and commodity-importers would affect these countries’ ability to cope with a shock, as would a high risk of debt distress—a concern most prevalent among fragile states and net food-importers. LICs’ direct exposure to global shocks via financial channels is limited by the relatively low degree of global financial integration, but some indirect contagion may be seen through real sector channels (a worsening of the macroeconomic environment in which parent banks operate) and global trade integration (see Box 2).

LICs’ Exposure to Global Shocks Via Financial Channels

Relatively low global financial integration shelters most LICs’ financial systems from direct exposure to worsening global financial conditions. Compared to emerging markets, cross-border financial linkages in LICs have remained low, limiting the risks and costs of available funding. The following are some supporting facts:

  • Sovereign capital market access is low, resulting in a contained impact of worsening global credit conditions (such as widening sovereign spreads relative to U.S. treasuries). Since 2006, only eight LICs have placed bonds internationally.

  • Portfolio investment liabilities (debt and equity) have remained small relative to foreign direct investment (FDI), thus limiting risks to LICs from global portfolio reallocation and re-pricing. Total portfolio liabilities only exceed 5 percent of GDP in around a fifth of LICs and are generally more in equity than debt. They originate mainly along regional lines and historical linkages.

  • Cross-border flows are generally low, thus limiting exposure to deleveraging risks. Euro area banks accounted for more than half of those claims in the majority of LICs in 2010-11 (mostly along historical linkages), with the exception of Latin America and the Caribbean economies. These claims, however, remain relatively small.

Cross-Border Claims (average 2010-11) 1/

Origin as a share of total 2/

As a share of GDP 3/

Source: BIS, and WEO.

1/ Domestically owned BIS-reporting bank’ consolidated claims on an immediate borrower basis.

2/ Country groups are based on Global Projection Model (GPM) classification.

3/ Liberia is excluded from the SSA average and median.

As a share of GDP 3/

article image

In contrast, LICs’ financial systems could face severe indirect exposure to external shocks through global trade integration and financial interconnectedness with relevant institutions in other LICs and emerging markets:

  • Higher global risk aversion adversely affects global economic activity through investment, in turn dampening trade, commodity prices, and external demand. Such a worsening of the macroeconomic environment in which banks operate will hit LICs with the most trade-integrated financial sectors, i.e. those with a more open economy and those with a significant reliance on trade and trade credit.

  • The macroeconomic situation and policy reaction in LICs will also affect the financial soundness and liquidity of banks, especially those with rapid credit growth. As the room for countercyclical policy responses is currently limited in many LICs, these countries may be unable to mitigate the impact on their economies of a global shock, including the attendant spillovers on the banking system. This in turn could create a severe feedback loop to the real economy.

  • Regional spillovers from difficulties in financially integrated banks in LICs or emerging markets can also add to stresses in otherwise less integrated LICs. Examples include the expanding Pan-African banking groups and financial and insurance sector stresses in some Caribbean countries.

B. How Exposed are LICs to Global Shocks?13

The risks to the global outlook are tilted to the downside, stemming mainly from a possible intensification of the euro area crisis, which could trigger a sharp slowdown in global growth. Last year’s VE-LIC report also looked at the possible effects of this scenario, and this section updates that analysis. A second separate global risk is a slowdown in potential growth in both advanced economies and emerging markets, leading to a protracted period of low global growth. Other downside risks—also considered separately—include supply-side price pressures in global commodity markets, and the section looks in particular at the effects of possible shocks to food and fuel prices. The impact on LICs from these shocks will be set against more limited macroeconomic buffers that render the countries less well prepared to deal with the global risks.

A sharp downturn in global growth

7. A 2 percent decline in global growth would reduce growth in the median LIC by an estimated 1.5 percent in 2013.14 This sharp downside growth scenario is based on an intensification of the euro area crisis, whereby policies fail to prevent a resolution of sovereign and banking stresses in the area. Were such a shock to occur, its effects would spill over into all regions. The scenario would lower global growth by almost 2 percentage points in 2013, relative to the World Economic Outlook (WEO) baseline15—a somewhat more severe shock than was assumed in last year’s report. The impact on LIC growth would be felt across the board in LICs, with countries in the Middle East and Europe and in Latin America and the Caribbean hit hardest, especially small states. The extent of the decline in growth is driven largely by the degree of openness and exposure of many LICs to the European Union (mainly through trade channels), since Europe is the assumed epicenter of the shock (see Appendix III for details on the methodology).

uA01fig11

A 2 percentage point decline in global growth in 2013 would shave an estimated 1.5 percent off LIC growth.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.
uA01fig12

Impact of a Global Growth Downturn on LIC Growth

(Percent, deviation in 2013 from the baseline)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

uA01fig13

A sharp downturn in global growth would severly erode fiscal and external buffers.

(Median, in percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

8. A downturn in global growth would erode fiscal and external buffers. In the baseline, the median LIC’s fiscal balance is projected to improve, and its public debt ratio to decline (see chart above). Sharply lower global growth, by triggering revenue losses in LICs, could reverse these gains.16 For the median LIC, the fiscal balance would deteriorate by 1.3 percentage points of GDP in 2013, relative to the baseline, with Latin American and Caribbean economies, including small states, seeing the strongest effects. Similarly, the balance of payments of LICs would be adversely affected through lower export receipts, negative terms of trade (TOT) for some countries, and reduced remittances and FDI inflows, causing external balances to deteriorate and reserve coverage to fall. For the median LIC, the external balance would worsen by 3½ percent of GDP, reflecting in particular weaker positions in the Middle East and Europe, as well as sub-Saharan Africa and small states.

9. With exports, remittances, and FDI all falling significantly in this scenario, additional external financing needs of around US$23 billion could emerge by the end of 2013. About half of LICs would face higher financing needs, with a significant share of total needs concentrated among a few large LICs in sub-Saharan Africa, and Asia and the Pacific. This comes against the backdrop of reduced access to traditional sources of financing, with donor financing falling recently, after a sharp increase in 2009 in response to the crisis, reflecting budgetary pressures in donor countries. In the absence of adjustment or new financing, reserve coverage in more than half of all LICs would fall below three months of imports, and 30 percent of LICs would not have any fiscal and external space to absorb the impact of the shock. In this event, the IMF would likely be called upon to provide significant financial assistance to help LICs that are affected by the shock. External and fiscal policy buffers are higher for commodity-exporting LICs, providing these countries with more scope for countercyclical policies, while fiscal space is particularly limited in small states.

Protracted global downturn scenario

10. An alternative scenario analyzes the potential vulnerabilities of LICs in the event of a protracted downturn in global growth, driven by a slowdown in potential growth in advanced economies and emerging markets.17

could lead to a sustained period of low growth, including hysteresis in unemployment, a more modest pace of technological advancement (possibly owing to high energy costs), or more cautious behavior on the part of households and firms given the damage wrought by the crisis. For emerging economies, slower advanced economy growth would imply subdued external prospects and thus a more gradual pace of catch up. Under this scenario, global growth is assumed to fall short of the baseline by 0.5 percentage points in 2013, and by an annual average 1.6 percentage points in 2014-16. Moreover, weaker global growth translates into

significantly weaker demand for commodities, as a result of which the price of oil falls by roughly 30 percent after three years, with non-oil commodity prices falling by roughly 20 percent, relative to the baseline (see Appendix III for details on methodology).

uA01fig14

For advanced economies, a number of factors

LICs could experience significant and prolonged growth moderation under the prolonged downturn scenario.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Source: WEO , and IMF staff estimates.

11. Under such a scenario, absent any policy response, macroeconomic buffers in all LICs would progressively weaken as the permanent output loss accumulates over time.

All countries could experience protracted lower growth, as the demand for their exports, FDI inflows, and remittances would stay below trend, especially driven by spillovers from emerging markets. The cumulative output loss over the period 2013-16 in the median LIC would be 4.4 percentage points, with output losses ranging from 2.3 to 8.5 points. As a result, macroeconomic buffers would weaken more slowly than in the sharp shock scenario, but could get progressively more depleted over time. Without a policy response, the illustrative fiscal space indicator would continue to deteriorate in the majority of LICs, and LICs would accumulate significant public debt—a marked reversal of the gradual improvement in debt ratios projected in the baseline.

uA01fig15

Government Debt

(In percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

uA01fig16

Fiscal Balance

(In percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

uA01fig17

Deterioration in Overall Balance and Public Debt Stock Under no Policy Reaction

(In percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

12. A protracted downturn in global growth would also erode external balances . For the median LIC, the external balance would worsen by 0.3 and 2.4 percent of GDP in 2013 and 2014, respectively, with the hit broadly similar across LICs. The cumulative worsening in the external balance over the period 2013-16 in the median LIC would be 5.9 percentage points of GDP—a substantial deterioration.

uA01fig18

Protracted global downturn could lead to significant deterioration in external balances, in particular, in Latin America and the Caribbean.

2014 Current Account Deficit (incl. FDI) (Median, in percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

13. Such imbalances could not be financed indefinitely. Additional cumulative financing needs could be as large as US$26 billion by the end of 2014, reaching about US$83 billion by end-2016.18 This comes against the backdrop of falling growth in donor financing, as noted above. Since aid flows have depended historically on the size and duration of a shock in donor countries, a protracted decline in growth may result in further reductions in aid envelopes.19 This implies that countries would typically need to undertake medium-term adjustment in the face of such a shock. The IMF would also likely be called upon to provide significant financial assistance to help LICs that are affected by the crisis. (See Section III for a further discussion).

Commodity price shocks

Last year’s report looked at the possible effects of generalized increases in global commodity prices. This section looks instead at particular shocks to food and fuel prices, stemming from assumed supply-side shocks. Such supply disruptions to two vital commodities affecting LICs could aggravate the effects of either of the global demand shocks considered above, if they were to coincide.

14. Given the dependence of many LICs on food imports, a third downside scenario analyzes their potential vulnerabilities to a sharp increase in global food prices. The

scenario assumes that food prices would increase by 27 percent in 2012 and 36 percent in 2013, relative to the baseline, driven primarily by global supply shocks. (The current WEO baseline scenario projects a decline in food prices of 1 percent in 2012 and 3 percent in 2013, compared to 2011.)

uA01fig19

The scenario assumes higher food prices, across the board.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.Note: Global food prices are assumed to increase by 27% in 2012, 36% in 2013, relative to the baseline across all food commodities.

15. A fourth downside scenario assumes a sharp surge in oil prices driven by a supply disruption from geopolitical uncertainty in the Middle East. Under such a scenario, oil prices would increase by 50 percent in 2012 and 40 percent in 2013, relative to the baseline projections.

16. Global spikes in food prices expose LICs to inflationary pressures that could undermine price stability and increase poverty. Under a global food price shock, assuming that the pass-through from global to domestic prices follows historical patterns and that, as in the past, only mild countervailing monetary policy action is undertaken, inflation could more than double, to a median of around 14 percent in 2013 from the current projection of about 6 percent. This reflects the high share of food in LICs’ Consumer Price Index (CPI) baskets. The impact on growth is likely to be muted, with a marginal increase in the risk of recession in LICs, but the global food price shock would also lead to weaker fiscal positions in the median LIC (worsening by about 0.3 percentage points), with noticeable effects across all regions.

uA01fig20

Under the higher global food price scenario, inflation in LICs could more than double relative to the baseline projection.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.Note: Scenario simulated impact based on an increase in global food prices by 27 and 36 percent in 2012 and 2013, respectively, compared to baseline.

17. The inflationary impact of an oil price shock would be considerably smaller than that of a food price shock, partly reflecting incomplete pass through to domestic fuel prices given price controls. Under the oil price shock scenario, inflation in the median LIC could increase to 8.7 percent, with the largest effect on LICs in the Middle East and Europe. The impact is more muted compared to a food price shock due to a smaller share of fuel prices in the CPI basket of LIC consumers. Conversely, the impact on the fiscal balance in the median LIC would be more pronounced under an oil shock (with a deterioration of about 0.6 percentage points), given low domestic substitutability of oil imports, pervasive price controls and support, as well as a traditionally large presence of state-owned enterprises in energy sectors in LICs.20

18. An additional 14 million people in LICs could be pushed into poverty by 2013 under a food price shock scenario, compared to 7 million people under the oil shock.21

Without taking into account policies to mitigate the impact on the poor,22 the median poverty rate is estimated to increase by 1.3 percentage points by 2013, under the food prices shock. In contrast, under an oil price shock scenario, the median poverty rate would increase by 0.3 percentage points in the same year.

A sharp increase in global food prices could leave an additional 14 million people in poverty in 2013

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.
uA01fig22

... while a sharp increase in global oil prices could push an additional 7 million in poverty.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

19. The external impact of a food price shock would differ significantly across LICs depending on their trade structure, but the large majority would be adversely affected, with additional financing needs reaching US$6 billion by the end of 2013. Net food importers would be most hit due to increased spending pressures and worsening terms of trade, while net food exporters (about 13 countries) will experience a positive terms of trade shock, with improving current account balances. On balance, the 2013 median external balance could widen to 3½ percent of GDP compared to 3 percent under the baseline. The external balance in the median net food importer would worsen by about 0.7 percentage points, while that in net food exporters would improve by about 0.8 percentage points. Almost all regions would be adversely affected, with the largest impact seen in the Middle East and Europe as well as sub-Saharan Africa. The scenario would also cause reserve coverage in the median LIC to decline to 3.3 months of imports in 2013, with LICs in the two worst-hit regions requiring 75 percent of the financing needs.

uA01fig23

A food price shock’s impact on LICs’ external and fiscal balances is not uniform across the regions.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

20. By comparison, the oil scenario’s impact on external balances would be relatively large with additional financing needs that could reach US$21 billion in 2013.

The external deficit in the median LIC could worsen to 5 percent of GDP (from 3 percent in the baseline), with LICs in Latin America and the Caribbean most affected. Oil exporters would of course benefit from the shock, with the median external surplus in these countries reaching more than 3 percent of GDP (from about 1 percent in the baseline). Reserve coverage for the median LIC would fall to 2.6 months of imports, while rising in oil exporting LICs to 6.7 months. LICs in Asia and the Pacific and sub-Saharan African economies would account for the bulk of the additional financing need.

uA01fig24

An oil price shock would lead to a sharp deterioration in fiscal and external balances in the median LIC across all regitions.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Sources: WEO, and IMF staff estimates.

C. Conclusions from the Vulnerability Analysis

21. LICs remain vulnerable to global risks, and a sharp slowdown in global growth would significantly raise the near-term recession risk for many countries. The illustrative growth decline vulnerability index would increase significantly in the event of a sharp downturn in global growth in 2013 (a decline in global growth by about 2 percentage points). The number of LICs at high risk of going into recession would roughly double, with over 40 percent of LICs showing increased vulnerabilities to further exogenous shocks (substantially higher than the levels experienced at the height of the global crisis). The majority of countries would experience a pronounced worsening in external sector indicators vis-í-vis the baseline, and non-commodity exporters would suffer from worsened fiscal vulnerabilities (a reversal compared to the projected improvement in the baseline).

uA01fig25

LICs’ near-term vulnerability to a shock induced recession would increase sharply in the case of a sharp global downturn.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

22. Macroeconomic buffers are much lower than prior to the 2008-09 global economic crisis and remain insufficient to address the risks facing many LICs, although vulnerabilities vary significantly across countries. In the current environment, with fiscal and external room for maneuver reduced after the global crisis, the ability to absorb the impact of global shocks would be limited:

  • Under a food price shock, a third of LICs would have not have any fiscal and external buffers to absorb the shock, while nearly 20 percent would have room to absorb the impact in full.

  • Similarly, under a fuel price shock, a third of LICs would not have any room to absorb the shock, while just above 10 percent would be able to fully cushion the impact.

  • Under a sharp decline in global growth, as with the other shocks, a third of LICs would be fully exposed (i.e., would not have any fiscal and external buffers to absorb the shock), while about one in ten would have room to absorb the impact in full.

    uA01fig26

    Macroeconomic policy buffers of many LICs have not yet been sufficiently rebuilt to insulate against potential shocks.

    Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

    1 Based on simulated impact on fiscal space and international reserve coverage of the global risk scenario of a sharp growth slowdown.

  • Looking specifically at currency unions,23 the Central African Economic and Monetary Community (CEMAC) has adequate external buffers to accommodate the impact of a sharp decline in global growth and both commodity price shocks. Reserves at the Bank of the Central African States (BEAC) would remain above three months of imports, as in the baseline. In fact, with a number of large oil exporters in the CEMAC, reserve coverage increases significantly under an oil price shock. The West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU) has adequate external buffers to accommodate the impact of both commodity price shocks. A sharp decline in global growth could push reserves at the Central Bank of Western African States (BCEAO) just below three months of imports. However, neither the BEAC nor the BCEAO would have adequate reserves to absorb, even partially, the impact of a protracted decline in global growth. Conversely, the East Caribbean Currency Union (ECCU) would not be able to cushion the impact of any of the shocks considered, given that reserve coverage at the Central Bank (ECCB) is currently below three months of imports and would be further reduced under all scenarios, with the largest impact seen under the oil shock (see Appendix III for details on methodology).

23. A protracted global downturn would raise recession risks further in LICs. The illustrative growth decline vulnerability index would increase significantly in both 2013 and 2014 and ease only slightly thereafter. Fiscal vulnerabilities for all LICs would increase sharply owing to permanent output losses. Similarly, weaker commodity prices would amplify the impact on commodity exporters and would lead to a marked and persistent increase in external vulnerabilities.24

uA01fig27

A prolonged global downturn would lead to very high and persistent increases in LICs vulnerability to a shock-induced recession.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

III. Macroeconomic Policy Challenges in the Face of Global Risks

Despite the unfavorable global environment, and so long as their growth remains buoyant, LICs should take the opportunity to gradually rebuild their policy buffers, without unduly compromising other development needs. Should risks materialize, LICs would have to manage the short-run consequences of the shocks, taking into account longer term objectives. In the event of a sharp global downturn, the scope for fiscal stimulus would be more limited than in 2009 for most LICs, given weaker fiscal buffers and constrained aid envelopes. In the face of a protracted slowdown in global growth, further realignment of fiscal, monetary, and exchange rate policies may be necessary, as neither buffers nor external financing would likely be adequate to deal with the crisis. LICs also remain highly vulnerable to global commodity price shocks. The impact on poverty from a food price shock will be significant, with implications for social and priority fiscal spending, while an oil price shock would incur large fiscal costs and generate large additional financing needs.

sharp global growth decline

24. In the event of a sharp global downturn, support for growth would be warranted, where feasible, subject to maintaining medium-term fiscal and external sustainability.

Scope for fiscal stimulus would be more limited than in 2009 for most LICs given weaker fiscal buffers and constrained external aid envelopes. Countries with sufficient fiscal room should maintain spending levels, depending on the prevailing cyclical conditions, to avoid aggravating the negative economic and social effects of the shock. With donor countries facing severe budget constraints, LICs may find it difficult to finance larger deficits and some adjustment may be inevitable, alongside greater reliance on domestic financing.25 On monetary policy, since LICs did not fully exploit the scope for monetary easing during the 2009 global crisis, more active monetary easing may be appropriate in countries with moderate inflation to mitigate the impact of the shock. The effectiveness of monetary policy would vary among LICs, however, depending on the transmission mechanism, the functioning of financial markets, and the credibility of central banks. For a few LICs where inflationary pressures have recently spiked, a more conservative monetary policy response may still be appropriate.26

Protracted global downturn scenario

Fiscal Policy

25. Limited fiscal buffers and the permanent nature of the protracted growth shock imply that most LICs would need to pursue some degree of fiscal consolidation over the next 3-5 years. Primary fiscal deficits, which increased significantly during the global crisis, would remain elevated because of the growth slowdown. Instead of converging toward sustainable levels, these deficits would remain close to 2 percent of GDP after the shock.

26. However, fiscal space varies substantially across LICs, affecting the magnitude of the required fiscal adjustment.27 For example, the median LIC in Latin America and the Caribbean would need a surplus in their primary balance to achieve medium-term debt sustainability, while the median LIC in Asia and the Pacific would have room for a small deficit.28 The magnitude and timing of the adjustment would also vary depending on initial public debt ratios and other factors.

Primary Balance Under Fiscal Consolidation

(Median in percent of GDP)

article image
uA01fig28

Primary Balance Consolidation to Achieve Long-term Debt Targets 1/

(In percentage points of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

1/ Calculated as the difference between the constant primary balance required to achieve debt targets by 2030 and the primary balances after the PGGS shock assuming no policy reaction.

27. Long-term consolidation would also be needed in resource rich countries. While these countries were running primary surpluses prior to the global crisis, their primary balances are now negative. This indicates that they would also need to rebuild their buffers to manage challenges arising from volatility and exhaustibility of natural resources. Once resource revenues are exhausted, the non-resource primary balance for these countries would converge to the primary balance. Unless these countries have sufficient financial savings, they would need to undertake large fiscal adjustment in the future.29

uA01fig29

Primary Balance of Resource-Rich LICs

(In percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

1/ Revenues from the natural resource are only displayed for 2012.2/ Assumes fiscal consolidation takes place in 2013.

28. Another key issue is the appropriate pace and composition of the adjustment. The composition of the adjustment should strike a balance between revenue mobilization and expenditure measures, taking into account their impact on the economy. In general, a combination of revenue and expenditure measures is more appropriate in LICs for achieving a durable fiscal adjustment than relying exclusively on either type of measures.30 LICs have relatively low tax-to-GDP ratios and would need to strengthen their tax administration and avoid, reverse, or resist extending ad hoc tax reductions or exemptions that undermine the revenue base (such as lowering taxes on petroleum products in the face of rising international prices and providing preferential treatment to particular types of investment). There is also scope for improving the effectiveness of the value-added tax (VAT), where applicable. These measures would help limit the burden of adjustment falling excessively on the expenditure side and protect high priority expenditures (e.g., infrastructure and social sector spending). Moreover, making budgetary spending more growth-friendly, for example, by reallocating spending from untargeted subsidies to productivity-enhancing investments, and replacing them with well-targeted transfers that protect the poor would not only improve the quality of adjustment, but also support domestic demand.

29. The pace of adjustment would need to take into consideration a country’s available fiscal space and growth prospects (i.e., its cyclical position). In particular:

  • In countries with a strong cyclical position, more frontloaded adjustment would be feasible, especially in cases where fiscal space is more limited. This would have the advantage of reducing the size of the overall required adjustment over time and limit the need for additional financing. Countries with more fiscal space could follow a slower pace of adjustment, provided that this is consistent with short-term macroeconomic stability (i.e., low inflation and sustainable current account deficits).

  • In countries with a weak cyclical position, a more gradual adjustment would be desirable, as frontloading the adjustment would compound the negative growth impact and result in an even weaker fiscal position. However, a gradual adjustment may not be feasible in countries with no available fiscal space. In such cases, official financing would help smooth out the required adjustment over time.

Monetary and exchange rate policies

30. The burden of adjustment on fiscal policy can also be shared by some adjustment in monetary policy, on the external side, and in private sector behavior:

• The vast majority of LICs would have sufficient policy space to reduce interest rates in the event of a protracted global growth decline. Substantial easing of commodity prices accompanied by the protracted fall in output and widening excess capacity would bring headline inflation down and create scope for an accommodative monetary policy in most LICs. In a few countries with currently high inflation rates, the shock would help accelerate the disinflation process.

• Some external adjustment can also be undertaken, especially in countries with overvalued exchange rates, to help mitigate the impact of a protracted global downturn on domestic economies and preserve foreign exchange reserves. For commodity exporters without hard pegs, a persistent drop in commodity prices under a protracted global downturn would call for an exchange rate adjustment. Absent such a policy adjustment, median reserve coverage for commodity exporters would decline from 4 months of imports in 2011 to about 1¼ months by 2016. Countries with fixed exchange rate regimes and high initial level of reserves could afford to smooth the required adjustment to avoid unduly depressing output at the height of the shock.

uA01fig30

Reserve Coverage

(Inmonths of next year’s imports)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

• Given the protracted nature of the shock, some adjustment in private sector behavior will also help partially offset the impact of lower external demand. The realization of lower domestic economic growth for a sustained period of time would come gradually. In that context, private sector economic agents may gradually adjust their imports to be consistent with the new, lower economic growth path (as well as new relative prices). As a result, the deterioration in the external balance under the protracted lower growth scenario would be lower at the tail end of the period compared to the initial period, resulting in a smaller reduction in reserve coverage.

structural policies

31. The global risks highlight the importance of stoking domestic engines of growth in LICs that can, over time, substitute for lost global demand and reduce the impact of external shocks. These alternative drivers of economic activity would need to be nurtured through a range of structural reforms. Such reforms could include measures to deepen the financial sector and develop domestic debt markets, coupled with strengthened supervisory frameworks,31 as well as better-targeted investments in infrastructure to increase productivity and living standards by addressing bottlenecks, supported by measures to improve the business climate.32 The positive impact of reforms on growth and economic resilience could be amplified if they were pursued on a region-wide basis, given positive cross-country spillovers.

Commodity price shocks

32. Under the global food and fuel price shock scenarios, the appropriate monetary policy response would depend on initial conditions such as inflationary pressures and levels of foreign exchange reserves. For LICs with weak external buffers or high initial inflation,33 some degree of policy tightening may be needed, supported by exchange rate flexibility where appropriate. For countries with fixed exchange rate regimes, tighter monetary policies may be required to avoid excessive losses in reserves. Countries should avoid imposing restrictions on food exports or administrative measures to control domestic food prices, even if temporary, as these would exacerbate supply disruptions and price increases. Members of monetary unions may not face immediate and intensified pressures for a shock-induced external adjustment even at relatively low levels of reserves, given the availability of regional reserve buffers and regional safety nets such as common pools of foreign exchange liquidity. Nevertheless, individual countries would need to tighten policies if macroeconomic imbalances lead to high inflation and widening current account deficits, or if global food and fuel price increases do not abate.

uA01fig31

Pass-through from spikes in global food prices increases sharply with the share of food items in the CPI basket.

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

33. While headline inflation in LICs may be strongly affected by global food price increases, given the large share of food in the CPI basket, policies need to focus on preventing generalized price pressures.34 Accommodating first-round effects from global food price shocks would increase headline inflation and, as a result, lead to real exchange rate appreciation. When possible, monetary policy should target underlying rather than headline inflation, as this would help stabilize both output and inflation volatility, and head-off second-round price effects. Significant differences across LICs (reflecting aggregate demand and structural factors) imply a relatively wide range of longer-run pass-through effects from spikes in global food prices. The pass-through to inflation is more significant for very open small and dollarized LICs (mostly net food importers), exerting pressures on reserves and the exchange rate.

34. To mitigate the impact of high food and fuel prices and the resulting inflationary pressures on the poor, social safety nets need to be made more effective. Where fiscal space exists, countries should put in place temporary fiscal measures, such as a reduction in food taxes, to help mitigate the impact of higher food prices on the poor. Longer lasting measures should include scaling up effectively targeted social safety nets, drawing on external financing and support where available.

Appendix I. List of Low-Income Countries (LICs)

The group of LICs analyzed in this work is formed by the 70 PRGT-eligible countries for which data were available,1 which include, by region:

Sub-Saharan Africa:

Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Democratic Republic of Congo, Republic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Eritrea, Ethiopia, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mozambique, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, São Tomé and Príncipe, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, and Zambia.

Middle East and Europe:

Armenia, Djibouti, Georgia, Kyrgyz Republic, Mauritania, Moldova, Sudan, Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, and Republic of Yemen.

Asia and the Pacific:

Afghanistan, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Cambodia, Kiribati, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Maldives, Mongolia, Myanmar, Nepal, Papua New Guinea, Samoa, Solomon Islands, Timor-Leste, Tonga, Vanuatu, and Vietnam.

Latin America and Caribbean:

Bolivia, Dominica, Grenada, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Nicaragua, St. Lucia, and St. Vincent and the Grenadines.

Country Groups:

LICs are grouped according to the following criteria:

  • Exchange rate regimes (based on the data from the Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions);

  • Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA) rating (based on the guidance for the IMF/WB Debt Sustainability Framework);

  • Net oil exporter/importer (based on WEO data);

  • Net food exporter/importer (based on data from the United Nations’ Commodity Trade Statistics);

  • Small states (based on population size of less than 1.5 million people as of end-2010); and

  • HIPC eligible (based on status-of-implementation report of the HIPC and MDRI Initiative and SPR-DP HIPC database.

Appendix II. Methodology for the Growth Decline Vulnerability Index

This appendix briefly describes refinements in the methodology for developing the Growth Decline Vulnerability Index (GDVI).1 The index aims to capture LICs’ underlying vulnerabilities to sharp growth declines when hit by large exogenous shocks. The GDVI relates the likelihood of a sharp growth decline occurring in the event of a large exogenous shock to various economic and structural vulnerability variables. 2

1. Selection of vulnerability indicators: For the 2012 VE-LIC exercise, the GDVI has been refined to include more variables than that constructed for the 2011 exercise, and with different weights. Variables found effective in explaining growth crises, following a shock, are grouped into three clusters: overall economy and institutions, external sector, and fiscal sector. Compared to the 2011 VE-LIC exercise, sectoral weights have been rebalanced based on probit regressions and the following additional variables have been included in the analysis to improve the fit of the model by capturing additional dimensions of vulnerability (see charts and Table 1 below):

Table 1

Non-Parametric Signaling Approach: Performance of Indicators and Model Fit

article image

The va riables are lagged one peri od, except real GDP growth, growth in trading pa rtners, and change i n export prices.

The thresholds are achieved by minimizing type I and type II errors.

Threshold for the overall index is derived by minimizing the asymmetri cally wei ghted l oss function giving more weight to type I error.

Missed crises plus false alarms as percent of total observations.

i. Capturing differentials in structural and institutional aspects: The country-specific sample average of real GDP per capita growth is used as a proxy for a combination of cross-country differences in some underlying structural and institutional conditions. The long-run historical performance of income per capita can capture shock amplifiers that are not already in the index,3 such as relative diversification of trade and production, a broader measure of inequality, and the broader impact of weaker institutions.

ii. Controlling for the size of exogenous external shocks: In constructing the GDVI, large shock episodes are identified from country-specific distributions.4 The implication is that the size of the shocks in the tail of the country-specific distributions can differ substantially across countries. To take account of countries experiencing larger “tail shocks” (thereby suffering from more severe growth declines when shocks materialize), two additional variables were added: growth in trading partners weighted by lagged exports to GDP, and the lagged change in export prices weighted by lagged exports to GDP. The impact of external demand scaled by the country-specific exposure is pronounced, while large downward swings in commodity prices would have a marked effect especially on commodity-exporters. Conversely, a very favorable external environment may shield a country with weak policies and institutions from growth crises, possibly hiding its existing vulnerabilities during good times.

iii. Capturing balance of payments pressures: The exchange market pressure index was found to be significant as a potential “shock amplifier” in the GDVI model. This variable is a composite index comprised of depreciation of official exchange rates, the change in the stock of international reserves (in months of imports of goods and services), and the black market premium.

2. Methodology: The approach, which is also used in the Vulnerability Exercise for Emerging Markets (VEE), examines a range of individual indicators to identify variables and thresholds that separate crisis from non-crisis cases. For each of the individual indicators, the approach involves searching for a split that minimizes the combined percentages of missed crisis (Type I error) and false alarms (Type II error). Thresholds that yield the best split are used to map indicator values into zero-one scores. These indicators are then aggregated into sectoral indices using weights that depend on the individual indicator’s ability to discriminate between crisis and non-crisis cases. The overall vulnerability index, which ranges from zero (low vulnerability) to one (high vulnerability), is a summary measure of underlying vulnerabilities to a growth decline.5 The charts and table below compare the results using the modified index with those based on last year’s model. Increased granularity in the index allows for more differentiation in medium to low vulnerability cases, likely reflecting additional dimensions captured by the new variables.

uA01fig32

Growth Decline Vulnerability Index

(observed differences reflect changes in the model not in data)

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

Appendix III. Methodology of Scenario Analysis

This Appendix describes the refinements undertaken to strengthen the quality of the vulnerability analysis in the VE-LIC framework and the methodology used for scenario analysis.1 The framework is extended to construct multiyear modeling, which, unlike the V-shapedgrowth shock examined in the 2011 exercise, analyzes the dynamic response of macroeconomic variables to a protracted growth decline scenario, taking into account the cumulative (multiyear) effects of the shock.

1. The 2012 VE-LIC exercise extends the framework used in 2011 from a single year shock impact analysis to a multiyear one. In addition to analyzing the impact of a sharp decline in global growth (V-shaped shock) on LIC growth and macroeconomic indicators in the year of the shock, the 2012 exercise models dynamic adjustment across macroeconomic indicators to examine LICs’ exposure to multiyear downside scenarios. The downside scenarios includes an analysis of a protracted decline in global growth throughout the period 2012-2016 driven by renewed escalation of the euro area crisis, as well as studying the impact of a sharp increase in food prices, based on the Fall 2012 WEO scenarios and data.2 Regardless of the nature of the shock, the 2012 VE-LIC framework assesses the first round impact of tail risk scenarios on LICs’ economic growth, external balances, and fiscal balances as follows:

  • To assess the impact on LICs’ economic growth, as with the 2011 VE-LIC, two channels of transmission are taken into account: (i) external demand (partner country growth) and (ii) terms of trade.3 On the first channel, partners’ growth was calculated using weighted averages of trading partners’ GDP growth, based on DOTS 2008 bilateral trade flows. In the regression analysis, partners’ growth was interacted with the degree of trade openness (expressed as the ratio of exports and imports to GDP) to control for its impact on the size and magnitude of spillovers effects across LICs. A dummy for commodity-exporters is also interacted to test for different elasticities for commodity versus non-commodity exporters. However, unlike the 2011 exercise, where only the elasticity with respect to BRICs was applied to commodity exporters, the elasticity with respect to all trading partners was applied, scaled by openness. On the second channel, the regression analysis finds that the elasticity of growth to changes in terms of trade is statistically significant only for the most open economies (i.e., countries in the top quartile in trade openness).

  • To more fully assess the impact on exports and imports, the analysis includes dynamic effects in the behavior of a country’s trade volumes to reflect the adjustment of the economy to the permanent external shock.4 The methodology includes: (i) estimating dynamic panel export and import equations using a panel error correction model that allows for adjustment of export/import volumes with respect to long-run fundamentals (relative export prices and external demand); (ii) estimating elasticities of exports and imports with respect to demand and relative prices; and (iii) estimating export and import equations for different types of commodities (food, metals and ores, fuel, and non-fuel products), using the pooled-mean group (PMG) estimator,5 to capture the heterogeneity of the composition of LICs’ exports and imports. Data are drawn from the Baci database for 1995-2010.6

  • To more fully assess the impact on remittances, the methodology used in the 2011 VE-LIC exercise7 was extended by introducing dynamic effects that enable an adjustment in remittances in the years following the crisis. In addition, unlike the 2011 exercise, the bilateral country remittances’ shares are no longer fixed shares, but are time-variant, taking into account changes in income in source countries/regions.

  • Similarly, the impact on foreign direct investment (FDI), takes into account dynamic effects in the years following the crisis. In addition, the effect of changes in the real interest rate in source countries or regions are included in the analysis

    (a product of the elasticity of FDI flows with respect to interest rates and the weighted average of the change in real interest rates).8 As in the case of remittances, bilateral country FDI shares is time-variant taking into account changes in income in source countries/regions.

  • Fiscal indicators in a protracted growth slowdown scenario: The analysis of the fiscal impact of a protracted global growth decline scenario comprises three approaches: (a) the impact of a passive policy scenario; (b) modeling of a benchmark policy response based on an illustrative fiscal space; and (c) the analysis of the increase in LIC financing needs as a result of the shock.

a. Passive policies: The impact on revenues is estimated as a weighted average of revenues from general economic activity, assumed to be affected by GDP growth, and also by the impact from natural resources when relevant, as affected by the corresponding commodity price index (calculated based on export shares). Primary expenditures are assumed to remain at the baseline level in nominal terms. As a result, spending as a percent of GDP changes only to the extent GDP (the denominator) is affected by the global growth slowdown. It is also assumed that LICs gradually access financial markets at commercial (as opposed to concessional) interest rates over time, while also gradually overcoming financial repression that allow systematically negative real interest rates that are observed in the sample period. This methodology results in more conservative (less negative) discounting than under baseline WEO projections, based on the assumption that the discount factor under a protracted growth downturn scenario should be higher than the baseline given: (i) lower GDP growth rates; (ii) higher interest rates (based on an increase in sovereign spreads as weakened fiscal positions worsens creditworthiness); and (iii) an increase in share of market financing at commercial interest rates as other concessional sources of financing decline.

uA01fig33

Effective discount factor implicit in WEO debt and primary balance data for LICs

Citation: Policy Papers 2012, 089; 10.5089/9781498339766.007.A001

The discount factor is (r - g) / (1 + g), solved for from the debt accumulation identity D(t) = [1+(r-g)/( 1+g)] D(t-1) - PB(t).

b. Policy reaction: Given the permanent nature of the protracted growth decline shock, the analysis of the fiscal policy stance focuses on (i) the magnitude of structural fiscal consolidation that might be necessary to remain fiscally sustainable in the long term; and (ii) the timing of the consolidation over a transition period over which the shock unravels.

• The magnitude of the consolidation is assessed according to the constant primary balance consistent with long-term public debt sustainability targets, which are assumed to be reached by 2030. The long-term debt targets are set at the CPIA upper-threshold if the pre-shock debt stock (at end 2012) is above the CPIA upper threshold; or the end-2012 level if the pre-shock debt stock (at end 2012) is above the CPIA upper threshold. These assumptions are set so as to allow countries to gradually rebuild their fiscal buffers over the long-term. For countries with high initial levels of public debt, the calculations would result in the minimum need for consolidation, given the use of a debt sustainability upper-threshold. For countries with lower debt ratios than the CPIA thresholds, the calculations take into account the need to rebuild buffers to the levels prevailing before the global growth and commodity shocks in 2009, to the extent these have been used, or to the pre-shock level.

• The timing of the policy response includes two calculations, which are meant to represent the extremes of a fiscal policy reaction spectrum: Early response, where it is assumed that countries adjust their primary balances in full in 2013. This assumes that policymakers realize that the onset is permanent, knowing its depth and duration with certainty and that they have full policy flexibility to deliver the necessary measures. Delayed response, where it is assumed that no policy reaction takes place through the protracted downturn period (2013-2016), and governments continue with their baseline expenditure plans in nominal terms while allowing automatic stabilizers to act. As a result, deficit and debt accumulation proceed as under no policy response until the end of 2016. The policy reaction would then take place starting in 2017. Realistically, the actual policy reaction can be expected to take place at some intermediate point within the two bounds above, as policy makers react gradually and partially, and the policy response builds over time through the shock period 2013-2016 -as the shock reveals itself and policymakers are assumed to identify and implement their plans.

The primary balances corresponding to the two extreme bounds of the timing of the policy response are calculated by setting the appropriate initial levels and year of public debt. In the case of “early response,” the end-2012 debt stock is used. In the case of “delayed response,” the end-2016 debt stock under no policy response is used instead. The change in the primary balance required to achieve the debt targets is finally calculated as the difference between the baseline primary balance in 2013 after LICs are hit by the shock, and the primary balances under early and delayed consolidation, respectively. The primary balances used in the calculation of public debt dynamics through 2013-2016 are as follows: (a) for the case of “early adjustment” the constant primary balances that achieve long-term debt targets when fiscal consolidation takes place in 2013; and (b) for the case of “delayed adjustment” the primary balances under no policy response until end-2016 (as in this case it is assumed that fiscal consolidation takes place starting in 2017, as explained above).

For simplicity, the same framework is applied for resource rich countries, though in these cases a more complex assessment focusing on net wealth would be warranted (see Macroeconomic Policy Frameworks for Resource Rich Countries, IMF, 2012b).

c. Impact on financing needs: The increase in the financing needs under a protracted growth downturn scenario are obtained as the difference between the annual increase in public debt under the scenario (separately for both policy reaction bounds explained above), and the increase in public debt under baseline projections. For the purposes of the calculation of financing needs of all LIC countries as a group, only those countries with positive financing needs are included in the total LICs amount.

2. The following tables depict the main assumptions used in the global risk scenarios under the 2012 VE-LIC exercise, as provided by the IMF Research Department and consistent with the most recent WEO:

GDP Growth Projections under the Sharp Growth Downturn Scenario

article image

Includes: China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia, Phillipines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.

Includes: Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Colombia, and Peru.

Includes: Argentina, Australia, Bulgaria, Canada, Denmark, Israel, New Zealand, Norway, Russia, South Africa, Sweden, Switzerland,Turkey, United Kingdom, Venezuela, and Bolivia.

GDP Growth Projections under the Protracted Growth Decline Scenario

article image

Includes: China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia, Phillipines, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China, and Thailand.

Includes: Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Colombia, and Peru.

Includes: Argentina, Australia, Bulgaria, Canada, Denmark, Israel, New Zealand, Norway, Russia, South Africa, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom, Venezuela, and Bolivia.

Appendix IV. Methodology for the Vulnerability Indicators

This appendix reports the definitions, thresholds, and data sources used for the vulnerability indicators discussed in Section II.A. Aiming at measuring LICs’ relative idiosyncratic exposure to specific shocks, they can qualify and complement the growth decline vulnerability index and the scenario analysis.

Table 1.

Vulnerability Indicators - Definitions, Thresholds and Data Sources

article image

Countries are excluded if data coverage is less than a third of the specified time period.

Natural disasters include droughts, earthquakes, epidemic, extreme temperature, flood, insect infestation, mass movement (wet and dry), storm, volcano, and wildfire.

There is no common definition of NPLs used here. Instead, data are collected from country desks reflecting each country’s specific circumstances.

Table 2.

Vulnerability Indicators - Share of Countries in the Low Risk (L), Medium Risk (M) and High Risk (H) Category

article image
Note: See Appendix VI for definitions, thresholds and sources.

Appendix V. selected Economic Indicators

article image
article image