Monetary and Fiscal Policy Design Issues in Low-Income Countries

Considers possible adjustments in the design of Fund-supported programs, drawing on the experience of low-income countries that have successfully addressed the most apparent domestic macroeconomic imbalances.

Abstract

Considers possible adjustments in the design of Fund-supported programs, drawing on the experience of low-income countries that have successfully addressed the most apparent domestic macroeconomic imbalances.

I. Introduction

1. Macroeconomic outcomes in low-income countries have improved markedly in recent years. Reflecting improvements in policy implementation, official financial support, and a relatively benign international environment, economic growth in the poorest countries has increased from 2½ to 3 percent in the 1980s and early 1990s to some 4 percent since the mid-1990s. These higher growth rates have been associated with lower inflation rates, healthier public finances, and higher international reserves (Table 1). While these growth outturns remain short of the rates required to achieve the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs), they nonetheless represent the best performance for low-income countries since the late 1970s.

Table 1.

Economic and Social Indicators in PRGF-eligible and Other Developing Countries

(In percent per annum, unless indicated otherwise)

article image
Source: WEO, IFS, WDI, and staff estimates.

2. Nonetheless, important questions remain regarding the appropriate focus of macroeconomic policies for the next generation of Fund-supported programs in low-income countries:

  • First, the large build-up of international reserves in recent years is indicative of possible tensions between exchange rate and monetary objectives, including inflation: how much scope is there for non-inflationary monetary growth? What is the appropriate target range for inflation in shock-prone low-income countries?

  • Second, notwithstanding the gains in other areas, progress towards external viability—a critical objective of Fund-supported programs—has been more limited, raising questions about the appropriate focus of monetary and fiscal policies.

  • Third, with macroeconomic imbalances receding, an increasing number of low-income countries face a wider range of viable policy options: should they use any fiscal space to cut excessive tax burdens, reduce high levels of domestic debt, or raise public spending to improve the provision of public services? To what extent do risks of crowding out private investment limit the scope for domestic government borrowing?

  • Fourth, with more aid and debt relief in prospect in the coming years, improving the effectiveness of public expenditures is going to be a major challenge for low-income countries.1 What steps do countries need to take to improve absorptive capacity?

3. This paper considers possible adjustments in the design of Fund-supported programs, drawing on the experience of low-income countries that have successfully addressed the most apparent domestic macroeconomic imbalances. The paper, including the discussion of stylized facts and various empirical assessments, focuses on a group of 15 mature stabilizers that had achieved positive output growth at the start of their PRGF arrangements and in which inflation and the domestic government deficit had been brought under control. An additional 5 or 6 other countries could have made this group, but the final sample was chosen with broad geographical representation in mind (Box 1) and limited to 15 to keep the analysis tractable. Importantly, the criteria used here do not include measures of external viability, which remains a serious concern in most of the countries in the sample.

Why the “Mature Stabilizer” Moniker?

There is no accepted definition of a mature stabilizer. Previous Fund documents have identified such a country as one where “political and economic institutions are in place and macroeconomic stability is reasonably well established.” The criteria developed in this paper are meant to capture those low-income countries that, after a period of protracted macroeconomic instability—manifested among other things in high levels of inflation (text figure)—have achieved some degree of internal macroeconomic balance, and a manageable fiscal position. Countries were selected on the basis of their performance on a number of macroeconomic criteria, including: (i) positive output growth; (ii) inflation less than 10 percent; and (iii) domestic financing of the budget deficit under 1 percent of GDP.1

uA01fig01

Median Inflation Rate in Mature Stabilizers

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Another label that has been used to refer to low-income countries with similar traits is “post-stabilization” countries. Gupta, et al. (2002) and Adam and Bevan (2004) referred to similar countries as post-stabilizers. The criteria used in this paper is more comprehensive. In Gupta, et al. (2002), post-stabilization countries are defined as those with deficits under 2 percent of GDP, inflation less than 10 percent during the pre-program year and projected to remain under 10 percent during the two subsequent years, and positive growth during the pre-program year. Adam and Bevan (2004) define a successful stabilization (and by extension, a post-stabilization country) as one in which inflation declines from “high levels” to rates under 15 percent for at least two years. The World Bank (2001) suggests that a primary surplus of 3 percent of GDP would qualify a country as being in a post-stabilization state.

The criteria used in this exercise do not cover external debt sustainability. While external debt sustainability has been promoted under the PRGF and the HIPC Initiative, PRGF-supported programs have not aimed at ensuring full sustainability, as demonstrated in the 2004 review of program design.

On the basis of the criteria, 15 countries that also had PRGF-supported programs during the 2000-2003 period were selected, although a few more could have qualified. The exclusion of some countries was based on the expiration of PRGF eligibility (Macedonia FYR), the start of a qualifying PRGF-program period only in 2003 (Armenia, and Burkina Faso), political instability (Côte d’Ivoire), and the desirability of ensuring adequate geographical representation. The countries in the sample are: Albania, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Benin, Ethiopia, Guyana, Honduras, Kyrgyz Republic, Madagascar, Mongolia, Mozambique, Rwanda, Senegal, Tanzania, and Uganda. Data were drawn from staff reports and the World Economic Outlook (WEO) database. Given fluctuations in macroeconomic and fiscal performance, most countries did not meet all three conditions on a continuous basis. For example, of the 51 annual Fund-supported programs in these 15 countries examined between 2000 and 2003, in only 29 cases did they meet all three conditions in the pre-program year.

1/ This measure provides a proxy for the sustainability of domestic debt accumulation. As long as growth is positive, under most circumstances, such a low level of financing would result in no more than a moderate steady-state level of domestic debt as a share of GDP.

4. While the focus of this chapter is on mature stabilizers, the paper also addresses some issues that are of relevance to other PRGF-supported programs. For example, both mature stabilizers and other countries with PRGF-supported programs face the challenge of increasing their capacity to absorb foreign aid and improving the efficiency of public spending. As such, some of the analysis is applicable to low-income countries more generally.

5. The paper is structured as follows. The next section presents the stylized facts of program design in the 15 mature stabilizers during 2000-2003. Against this backdrop, Sections III and IV take up monetary and fiscal issues, respectively. Section V concludes.

II. Stylized Facts of PRGF-Supported Programs in Mature Stabilizers

6. PRGF-supported programs in the 15 countries during the 2000-2003 period have generally sought to consolidate macroeconomic stability and foster growth. By and large, growth outcomes have been in line with program targets. Reflecting favorable initial conditions, there has been limited emphasis on further disinflation. On the fiscal front, programs have sought to increase capital spending, but have not been generally successful. Developments in the external accounts have been less favorable; while external reserves have increased, current account deficits have remained too large to ensure external viability even after debt relief from the enhanced HIPC Initiative. The rest of this section discusses these stylized facts in more detail.

Growth and Inflation

7. After recovering in the late 1990s, economic growth in the mature stabilizers has been sustained at relatively high levels (Table 1 and text figure). Growth outcomes in the 15 countries have generally been close to program projections. At inception, PRGF-supported programs in the countries typically envisaged an increase in growth from around 4½ percent in the year preceding the program to 6 percent in the third program year. But growth outcomes tended to be lower, and expectations of growth increases shifted to later years in subsequent program documents (text figure and Box 2). These revised program projections (often established in the year immediately preceding the program year) are the ones with the most direct bearing on the calibration of monetary and fiscal policies. The median projection in the sampled countries one-year-out is for real GDP growth of 5½ percent per year—some 3 percent in per capita terms.2 Outcomes were only marginally (less than ½ percentage point) lower, and this difference between projections and outcome was not statistically significant.

uA01fig02

Real GDP Growth: 1980-2003 (median values; in percent) 1/

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook.1/ Dotted line excludes the 3 transition countries in the sample: Albania, Azerbaijan and Kyrgyz Republic.
uA01fig03

Projected Real GDP Growth 1/

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF Staff Reports1/ The starting point of a projection lines shows actual growth in the previous year.

Targets and Projections in IMF-supported Programs

The projections for the original program may not be the most relevant ones for the entire program period. Program projections are updated regularly—in principle at each half-yearly program review.

Macroeconomic policies and outcomes are likely affected by the Fund-supported policy programs presented in both staff reports issued during the year concerned (year “t”), as well as by the last one presented in the previous year (“t-1”). The projections contained in the latter report may be the most relevant ones for shaping the budget, and affecting end-year policy outcomes regarding broad money and inflation—given the time lags in the transmission of monetary policy, often estimated at about 6 to 12 months. On the other hand, the current year projections underpin the program’s quantitative conditionality regarding fiscal balances and the central bank balance sheet, which should have an impact on policy-making during the year.

Projection horizon differs across countries and variables. While program documents generally include projections for inflation and GDP for the next two or three years, the projection period for broad money is often shorter, and reserve money and central bank NDA and NFA projections often do not extend beyond one year (i.e., “t+1”).

8. These growth targets and outcomes are high by historic standards, but for most countries fall short of the levels considered necessary to achieve the MDGs. Until the second half of the 1990s, real growth in the mature stabilizer sample was quite anemic, averaging 3 percent or lower. And while real GDP growth has picked-up since the mid-1990s they remain short of the 7 percent or so growth rates that are considered necessary to meet the MDG target of halving poverty by 2015. Why, then, don’t the authorities generally target higher growth rates? Some clearly do—for example, a fifth (10) of the PRGF-supported program episodes under consideration (50) target growth rates of 7 percent or more. Elsewhere, the modest growth objectives likely reflect estimates of potential growth, and the caution exhibited in program growth targets does not seem to be out of order.3

9. On the inflation front, the overall focus of PRGF-supported programs has been gradual further disinflation:

  • At the inception of a new PRGF-supported program, inflation was generally projected to decline to less than 4 percent over the three-year program period from more than 6 percent in the year before the start of the program, as shown in Table 2.4 The end-year projections across the programs ranged from 2 to 6 percent. Average and median projected inflation were close, reflecting the scarcity of large outliers in this sample limited to countries that already had largely disinflated. However, as with growth projections, the inflation targets that matter most for program design purposes, and around which monetary and fiscal policies are calibrated, are the ones set shortly before and during program episodes under consideration. During the arrangement period, these inflation targets tend to be adjusted upwards by about 1 percentage point—to around 6 percent—to take into account somewhat higher inflation outturns (Table 3).5 The magnitude of this revision is related to inflation overruns in the previous year.

  • Based on this revised metric—inflation as targeted in the year before—the approximately 50 program episodes under consideration, projected inflation of 5 percent and outturns have been relatively close.6 Significant deviations between targets and outcomes are few and far between. In those instances when inflation was above 10 percent in the year before the program, a gradual reduction of inflation was envisaged. In the 11 such cases, the median inflation was targeted to decelerate from 14½ percent in the year preceding the program episode to 9 percent in the first program year.

  • Overall, then, inflation did recede during these PRGF-supported programs, albeit somewhat less than projected. On average, CPI inflation moderated from more than 9 percent in the year before the start of the program to less than 5 percent three years later—about one percentage point above the original program target.7

Table 2.

Inflation Targets in Original PRGF-supported Programs 1/

(In percent)

article image
Source: IMF Staff Reports and World Economic Outlook database.

Originating programs are those reported in the staff report requesting a new arrangement under the PRGF, and for Azerbaijan, also the 2001 program augmentation.

Table 3:

Inflation Targets in Consecutive Program Updates 1/

(In percent)

article image
Source: IMF Staff Reports and World Economic Outlook database.

The year the projections are for is t. The projections as of year t-1 and t-2 are those from the last staff reports in the previous year and the year before that, respectively. The projection as of t(SR1) is from the first staff report in year t, and the one at t(SR2) is from the final staff report in that year. In case only one staff report was issued in year t, the last two observations coincide.

Fiscal developments

10. PRGF-supported programs in the sampled countries have sought to keep the overall budget deficit broadly unchanged (at 4½ percent of GDP), with modest increases in spending targeted to be offset by an increase in revenues (Table 4). Specifically:

  • On average, public expenditure was targeted to increase by some ¾ percentage point of GDP per year, with most of the increase targeted for higher capital outlays consistent with the growth orientation of PRGF-supported programs. In general, countries with higher initial spending (in relation to GDP) targeted smaller increases (or larger declines) in expenditure (Figure 1).8 Current spending and the wage bill, in contrast, were targeted to remain broadly unchanged.

  • This increase in expenditures was expected to be offset by an improvement in tax revenues and grants of the same order of magnitude.

  • Deficits (relative to GDP) were programmed on average to be unchanged. Relatively few programs targeted a significant increase in domestic financing—even when the level of domestic debt was low—with an average increase in domestic financing by 0.2 percent of GDP.

  • Finally, the broad stability in the targeted fiscal balance contrasts with the lower fiscal deficit and domestic financing typically envisaged in other PRGF programs where internal macroeconomic stability remained a concern. For example, in a sample of 18 countries with PRGF-supported programs for such countries over the same period, the overall deficit was targeted to decline by some 1½ percent of GDP.

Table 4.

Fiscal Targets and Performance in Mature Stabilizers

(unweighted averages in percent of GDP)

article image
Sources: National authorities and Fund staff estimates.

Total expenditure and net lending includes spending items that are not classified as current or capital.

Data on foreign-financed capital spending are not available for Bangladesh, Honduras, and Guyana.

Other fiscal transactions include repayment of arrears and float.

Data on project loans are not available for Bangladesh and Honduras.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Expenditure Targets in PRGF Programs, 2000–2003

(in percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Sources: IMF staff reports and staff estimates.

11. Fiscal deficits in PRGF-supported programs have, however, been smaller than envisaged, owing to shortfalls in capital spending. The mature stabilizers did not raise capital outlays as a share of GDP, mainly because of shortfalls in foreign project implementation. These shortfalls were partially offset by higher-than-programmed current spending, including for wages. The composition of spending has also shifted towards social and poverty-reducing spending as sought under the PRSP approach (see Box 3). Revenue collection as a share of GDP was broadly in line with program projections. As a result, the fiscal deficit was about ½ percent of GDP smaller than envisaged. These averages mask a great deal of variation in targets. For instance, several PRGF-supported programs have accommodated large increases in the fiscal deficit to accommodate higher external financing—for example, Guyana (2000), Mozambique (2000), Rwanda (2000), and Tanzania (2002).

Social and Poverty-Reducing Spending 1/

Programs in the mature stabilizer sample have achieved significant increases in poverty-reducing spending. The average PRGF-supported program achieved an increase of about 1 percent of GDP (2¾ percent of total spending) in these outlays per year. Average annual spending on poverty-reducing programs increased by more than 2 percent of GDP in Ethiopia, Guyana, and Mozambique, and by more than 1 percent of GDP in Tanzania and Uganda. Honduras was the only country in the sample where the ratio decreased while there was practically no increase in Benin and Madagascar. Over the 1999-2002 period, these outlays in the sampled countries rose by over 3 percent of GDP. Social spending (outlays on education and health care) has also risen. The average social spending to GDP ratio increased in all countries in the sample except Azerbaijan and Kyrgyz Republic.1 Thus, the mature stabilizers have achieved a modicum of success in making their budgets more pro-poor, despite difficulties in raising total government spending to the extent programmed. While it is possible that changes in classification may account for part of these increases, they have nonetheless been accompanied by improvements in social indicators for which data are available.

Average Annual Improvement in Selected Social Indicators 2/

(percent change, positive indicating improvement)

article image
Source: World Development Indicators database, World Bank.
uA01fig04

Average Annual Increase in Social and Poverty-Reducing Spending Realized in the Mature Stabilizers

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

1 Sample comprises 42 programs for social spending and 40 programs for poverty-reducing spending. Social spending is defined as education and health care expenditures.2 In many countries, budgetary data do not cover all public spending in social and poverty-reducing sectors. Non-public spending in these sectors could also be significant in some countries.1/ Average annual improvement refers to the annual change between 1999 and the latest available year, usually 2001. Positive growth rates correspond to improved outcomes.

External viability

12. Progress towards external viability among the mature stabilizers has been limited. On the positive front, international reserves have increased significantly in the 15 countries from less than 3 to around 5 months of import cover since the mid-1990s, increasing the scope for absorbing the impact of shocks (Figure 3, top panel). This improvement, in part, reflected an increase in aid inflows (including debt relief) as well as a recovery in export growth (Figure 3, lower panel). Current account deficits have been lowered relative to program targets (by about 1¼ percentage points of GDP, text table).

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Revenue Targets in PRGF Programs, 2000–2003

(in percent of GDP)

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Sources: IMF staff reports and staff estimates.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

External Development Indicators in the Mature Stabilizers

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, country documents and staff estimates.

These lower-than-projected current account deficits and close adherence to fiscal deficit targets implies a lower-than-projected investment-savings imbalance by the private sector.9 Nonetheless, these current account deficits (net of FDI) have been too high to stabilize the stock of NPV of debt—including after HIPC initiative debt relief (Figure 4). In particular:

  • In 8 countries (those below the horizontal axis), the current account deficits during 2000-03 were too high to stabilize the external debt stock. All of these countries are HIPCs. And while they are accumulating debt from moderate levels reflecting the debt relief that has been provided to them,10 these findings nonetheless suggest that external debt build-up will resume anew unless steps are taken to curb borrowing and/or move to grant financing.11

  • The other 7 countries (including Honduras, which benefited from HIPC debt relief) have sustained current account deficits that would allow them to stabilize or even reduce their external debt stocks—though in the case of Mongolia and Kyrgyz Republic—from a very high level.

Target vs Outcomes in the Mature Stabilizer Sample

article image
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Actual and Debt Stabilizing Current Account Balances 1/

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database.1/ Debt figures include actual or expected completion point debt relief for HIPCs. Triangles show the values for non-HIPCs.

13. External viability has not received adequate attention in PRGF program design, although the findings are somewhat more encouraging for this sample group than for the broader sample of PRGF countries (IMF 2004a). One reason is that conditionality in Fund-supported programs seldom limited either the overall fiscal balance or external borrowing on concessional terms. Out of the 38 PRGF arrangements in place at end-March 2003, only 12 arrangements had conditionality to limit either the overall or primary fiscal balance and no arrangement had direct limits on concessional borrowing. Of course, poor use of concessional resources is one reason that low-income countries have built-up unsustainable debt burdens in the past.

14. More recently, the incorporation of debt sustainability assessments (DSAs) in the Fund’s operational work on low-income countries should allow PRGF-supported programs to focus more explicitly on debt sustainability considerations. While this will not fully resolve the tension between increasing poverty reducing expenditures and making progress towards external viability, it will help clarify the longer-term implications of near-term fiscal decisions. Importantly, these assessments, which look at the issue of debt sustainability from many angles, will help signal to donors the need for grant financing when there is a higher likelihood of debt distress.

15. In sum, the mature stabilizers have done relatively well, with markedly higher growth, lower inflation, higher international reserves, but continuing concerns about external viability. An important question, however, is whether the recent pick-up growth can be sustained or, better still, improved upon. Since 1995, private investment, arguably the most telling predictor of future growth performance, has edged-up in the countries in the sample (see text figure). With the exception of Tanzania and Uganda, where it has been broadly flat, private investment in 2000-03 was marginally higher than in the late 1990s. But this improvement is modest, and leaves investment ratios low relative to other regions.

uA01fig05

Ratio of Private Investment to GDP (median values; in percent) 1/

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

1/ Dotted line excludes the 3 transition countries in the sample: Albania, Azerbaijan, and Kyrgyz Republic.

III. Monetary Policy Issues in PRGF-Supported Programs

16. As noted above, maintaining inflation in the low single digits is an important feature of PRGF-supported programs in the mature stabilizers. In general, programs sought to keep inflation in the 4-6 percent range. The next two sections consider the appropriateness of these targets and the monetary policy framework in which these targets have been pursued. A third section considers the nexus between private sector credit growth, fiscal policy, and economic activity.

A. Inflation and Economic Growth

17. The desirability of single-digit inflation targets has been questioned. The 15 countries in the sample have kept inflation at relatively low levels for a sustained period. But critics have argued that such inflation has required high real interest rates and constrained potential seigniorage income. And, indeed, while unanimity exists in the economic literature on the costs of very high inflation, consensus is lacking on the appropriate inflation range for low-income countries.12 More generally, the scope for monetary policy to impede growth far exceeds its ability to create it: high inflation—above, for example, 40 percent—is certainly inimical to growth, but keeping inflation low will not by itself induce a growth boom. Against this backdrop, this section considers the appropriate inflation range for low-income countries.

18. While high inflation is harmful to economic growth, the gains from continued moderate inflation on growth are ambiguous, reflecting the multitude of transmission channels.13,14 As inflation accelerates, a negative effect on growth is likely given the associated increase in inflation uncertainty, clouding price signals, limiting both the quantity and quality of investments. On the other hand, some inflation could enhance real wage flexibility, or help avoid liquidity trap problems. In case of price-stickiness, a low inflation target could render an economy vulnerable to prolonged downturns in case of adverse supply shocks (see below). Empirical analysis aimed at untangling these effects is hindered by the possibility of reverse causality—from growth to inflation, and the endogeneity of both variables. For example, high inflation may signal poor institutions and policies more generally, and be associated with lower growth as a result.15

19. Notwithstanding this complexity, considerable empirical support exists for policies that aim at keeping inflation between, say, 5 and 10 percent. The existence of a negative relationship between inflation and growth at higher rates of inflation is empirically well supported. By contrast, identifying the growth effects of moving from, say, 20 percent inflation to 5 percent, has been challenging. According to Bruno and Easterly (1998), only for generally short-lived periods of high inflation, can significant adverse growth effects be found, after which growth tends to return to its long-run path—classic money neutrality. However, several other studies indicate this may understate the adverse growth effects of moderate inflation.

  • Examinations of prolonged episodes of accelerated growth show that the onset of such periods is typically associated with lower inflation and that, moreover, the upfront improvement in macroeconomic indicators is more generalized for longer episodes of growth acceleration than for shorter ones.16

  • Quantifying the association between inflation and growth requires careful attention to the nonlinearities in the relationship between inflation and growth. This relation appears to be convex: a given increase in inflation is associated with a larger negative growth effect, the lower the initial inflation. But at low rates, higher inflation may have no effect on growth or its effect may even be positive. Since Fischer (1993), several authors have tried to identify and locate such a “kink” in the relation between inflation and economic growth—associated with a maximum growth rate. Empirical studies using panels of countries have located this “kink” in the inflation-growth nexus at a level of inflation somewhere between 3 percent and 40 percent, with a majority suggesting a level in the 5-10 percent range (see Table 5). Notably, however, most of these studies have not focused on the “kink” in low-income countries as opposed to broader country groupings, and none of the studies covers the period since 2000.

Table 5.

Empirical Studies on “kinks” in the Relationship Between Inflation and Growth

article image

20. Additional considerations in favor of determined inflation control relate to policy credibility and poverty alleviation. For countries that have only recently managed to achieve single-digit inflation—which includes almost all in our sample of PRGF countries—it may be wise to anchor successful disinflation by maintaining inflation in the single-digit range. Indeed, the gains from price stabilization may only be realized in full once low inflation is institutionalized and incorporated in expectations. Another consideration is that price stability may foster poverty reduction directly, in addition to its impact through economic growth. Inflation tends to hurt the poor disproportionally, since they often hold no financial assets that provide a hedge against inflation or are dependent on state-determined income that is not fully indexed.17

21. Some observers have argued that tight monetary policies have adversely affected poverty alleviation by constraining government spending. The main channel through which monetary policy can reduce available fiscal resources is by lowering seigniorage, i.e., government revenue from an increase in reserve money (see Box 4).18 However, the revenue effect of raising inflation from 6 percent to, for example, 15 percent would be modest as, seigniorage revenue would be raised by less than 0.4 percentage points of GDP.

Seigniorage Income

Increases in reserve money beyond the amount that accommodates changes in real money demand would be inflationary, and the associated part of seigniorage is aptly called the inflation tax.1 The reduction in inflation in PRGF countries has, indeed, entailed a decline in seigniorage revenue. Evidence suggests that seigniorage revenue (as measured below) is highest for inflation at 30-40 percent, far above the actual 6 percent average rate in our sample of PRGF countries.2 Seigniorage as a share of GDP can be expressed as: 3

s=rt-1*(1+gr)rt-1/[(1+gp)*(1+gy)]

where r t-1 is the previous-period reserve money ratio (as a fraction of nominal GDP), and gr, gp, and gy are the growth rates of, the reserve money ratio, the price level, and real GDP, respectively. For a constant reserve money ratio of 11 percent (the average in our country sample), and an average real growth rate of 5 percent, the noninflationary level of seigniorage would amount to 0.5 percent of GDP. With 6 percent inflation, seigniorage would amount to 1.1 percent of GDP. The actual 1999-2003 average in the sample was somewhat higher at 1.4 percent of GDP, owing to a trend increase in reserve money as a share of GDP.

However, the revenue benefits from a modest increase in inflation would likely be small. On the one hand, the inflation tax is relatively distortionary (especially at higher rates, see above) and regressive (given the impact of inflation on poverty), implying a strong case against the use of higher inflation as a means of raising government resources. On the other hand, developing countries generally have relatively inefficient tax systems. It is therefore possible that, on balance, a somewhat higher inflation tax would be less distortionary than the regular tax it could replace. But the revenue effect of raising inflation from 6 percent to, for example, 15 percent would be modest—amounting to about 0.4 percent of GDP. Assuming no change in the reserve money ratio, the revenue impact would be equivalent to 0.8 percent of GDP. But higher inflation would likely entail some decline in money demand, and thereby in the reserve money ratio. Incorporating this effect could reduce the seigniorage bonus by half. 4

1/ Seigniorage revenue typically takes the form of a profit transfer from the central bank to the government. In cases where the central bank lends to the government at below market interest rates, reducing the bank’s profits, the transfer may appear as lower interest payments.2/ Phillips (1989).3/ The formula does not take into account the remuneration of commercial bank reserves within reserve money. However, in the country sample, currency in circulation accounts for more than 60 percent of reserve money, on average, and remuneration is limited.4/ During 1994-2003, for disinflating non-transition PRGF-supported programs, a 1 percentage point increase in inflation was associated with a rise in velocity (and thereby in the reciprocal of the reserve money ratio) by about 0.4 percent (IMF, 2004c, Box 5).

22. One strong argument in support of higher inflation targets for developing countries is the need to accommodate exogenous shocks. Developing countries are more prone to supply shocks, such as adverse weather conditions, and sharp terms of trade changes. Moreover, the aggregate impact of such shocks may be more pronounced due to the limited diversification of production and consumption and the prevalence of de facto trade barriers (including, e.g., lack of transportation and integrated distribution networks). Adverse supply shocks would tend to push up prices while limiting economic growth. In the presence of downward nominal rigidities, inflation targets that do not accommodate the supply shocks could serve to amplify their adverse growth effects. This consideration argues for inflation targets that accommodate the first-round effect of supply shocks (unless the shock is expected to be undone within a few months—i.e., before monetary policy is effectively transmitted).

23. Cross-country evidence demonstrates the higher vulnerability of PRGF countries to external shocks. The year-on-year volatility of the terms of trade and export volumes (which may to a large extent be considered exogenous) and of real GDP growth (which also incorporates the policy response) is relatively large in PRGF countries, and in low-income countries more generally, in comparison with advanced and transition economies.19

24. Program design should address such volatility. In particular, programs can accommodate adverse supply shocks (within limits) while avoiding second round effects, thus stabilizing inflation expectations.

  • Programs could be based on a target range for inflation around the operational (core) target, especially in countries where substantial exogenous shocks have occurred. For example, and as illustrated in the text figure, a band of 2 percentage points above and below the central target would capture more than 60 percent of realizations. Such change would not directly alter the monetary targets or the associated conditionality, but would formalize the inflation tolerance that is, in practice, often already exhibited in programs. The change may also help improve policy credibility, by reducing the likelihood that inflation targets are missed. One of the risks associated with this approach is that, in practice, policies may simply be redirected toward the higher end of the inflation range, in which case the result would be an unwarranted policy relaxation with no increase in flexibility.20

  • In some cases, consideration could be given to focusing on measures of core inflation rather than the overall CPI in PRGF-supported programs.21 The monetary targets would remain based on nominal income, and incorporate the first-round effects, while preventing second-round effects that would lift core inflation.

uA01fig06

Inflation: One-year Ahead Projctions and Outcomes

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

25. On balance, the above considerations support the use of single-digit inflation targets. Preserving the inflation gains already achieved by the countries in our sample is of vital importance. There is a need to further ingrain and institutionalize this achievement, enhancing the credibility, and thus the desirability, of the low-inflation strategy. However, pushing inflation too low, say below 5 percent, may entail a loss of output and seigniorage revenue, suggesting a need for caution in setting very low inflation targets in low-income countries. As these countries tend to be subject to larger output volatility and more pronounced price shocks, program design should take these economic attributes properly into account. In particular, inflation targets should be set so as to help avoid risks of an unintended contractionary policy stance.

B. Financial Programming

26. This section considers the effectiveness of reserve money targets and program conditionality as an anchor for monetary policy. There are several reasons for this assessment at this juncture. For one, as demonstrated in the papers on the Design of Fund-Supported Programs (IMF, 2004c), the NDA/NIR framework is not well-suited for controlling inflation, which generally requires a more explicit monetary anchor. These papers also underscore the need to sterilize donor support if inflation targets are to be met. Second, the large build-up of international reserves—beyond program targets—in the mature stabilizers could be indicative of the policy challenges related to reconciling exchange rate and monetary objectives.

27. Reserve money serves as an operational target for 13 of the 15 sampled countries that do not have a formal exchange rate peg (Box 5).22,23 The growth of reserve money that is projected to be in line with the inflation objective, in turn provides the basis for the standard program ceiling on central bank net domestic assets (NDA) and the floor on central bank net international reserves (NIR) or net foreign assets (NFA).24 Importantly, this framework does not constrain reserve money growth—i.e., it does not provide a monetary anchor. In particular, the existence of a floor on central bank net foreign assets provides scope for larger reserve accumulation than projected, with a corresponding rise in reserve money. This feature provides flexibility in accommodating increases in money demand through expanded interventions in the exchange market, thus avoiding below-target inflation.

Monetary Programming in Fund Program Design

Monetary policy targets for low-income countries are generally derived through financial programming. Financial programming involves the use of balance sheet relationships and a few simple behavioral relationships. It helps ensure the consistency of the design of monetary policy with: (i) goals or assumptions regarding real GDP growth and inflation; (ii) projected domestic financing of the budget and the provision of sufficient credit to the private sector; and (iii) the balance of payments outlook as reflected in the net accumulation of foreign assets by commercial banks and the monetary authorities. Within financial programming, the exercise that directly relates to the central bank’s monetary program is also referred to as reserve money programming.1

The level of broad money (M) that would be consistent with the program targets for inflation (P, the GDP deflator) and real income (Y) is derived using the identity:

(1) M*V=P*Y

Where V is the velocity of circulation. Or, in terms of growth rates:

(2) (1+gM)=(1+gP)*(1+gY)*(1+1/(1+gV))

While velocity depends on such factors as interest rates and changes in inflation, it is typically—including in the mature stabilizers sample—assumed to remain constant over the program period. Provided that the assumption on velocity adequately reflects money demand, limiting the growth in money supply in line with the above equation, should help realize the targeted rate of inflation.

The increase in reserve money (RM) that would support this broad money target is generally derived from:

(3) M=m*RM

or

(4) (1+gM)=(1+gm)*(1+gRM)

Where m is the reserve money multiplier, which reflects the ratio of currency in circulation to bank deposits, and banks’ holdings of reserves at the central bank. Like velocity, the multiplier is often assumed constant over the program period.

Target values for the central bank’s net domestic assets (NDA) and net foreign assets (NFA) are derived using:

(5) ΔRM=ΔNFA+ΔNDA

Similarly, for the banking sector (BS) as a whole,

(6) ΔM=(ΔNFABS)+(ΔNDABS)=(BoP)+(ΔCG+ΔCP+ΔBSNW),

with CG = net banking sector credit to the government, CP = net banking sector credit to the private sector, and BSNW = net worth of the banking sector (often assumed constant over the program period). An important application of this equation is that it allows verification if, given the targets and projections for the other variables, projected government borrowing is consistent with—i.e., does not crowd out—the scope for lending to the private sector which, in turn, is important to sustaining private sector growth.

1/ For a more general overview, see International Monetary Fund, 2004b, Appendix I.

28. However, success in attaining monetary and inflation objectives may have been compromised by the simultaneous pursuit of exchange rate stability. In particular, if higher international reserves reflect higher supply of foreign capital—absorbed by the monetary authorities, for example, to avoid appreciation pressures—the increase could be inflationary. In fact, the resulting rise in reserve money (and thereby in commercial bank liquidity) could provide the basis for higher domestic bank credit, and thus result in an even larger increase in broad money, through the multiplier effect. While changes in reserve money supply can be minimized through offsetting domestic transactions, such sterilization can be costly. Even countries labeled as independently floating (see Box 6) in practice often intervene to limit exchange rate variability. Moreover, the evidence is strongly suggestive of declining exchange-rate flexibility in the mature stabilizers over time. This point is illustrated in the text figure. For the 13 countries in our sample without a hard peg during 1990-94, 1995-99, and 2000-03, the dispersion of the monthly exchange rate changes is more highly concentrated around the mean (0.3 percent) in 2000-03 than earlier periods or relative to other PRGF countries not included in the mature stabilizer sample.25

uA01fig07

The Dispersion of Monthly Exchange Rate Changes to the US Dollar—Kernel Density Diagram

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics.

De Facto Exchange Regimes (2001)1

Currency union: Benin, Senegal

Conventional Fixed Peg to Single Currency: Bangladesh 2

Forward-Looking crawling band: Honduras

Tightly managed floating: Azerbaijan, Guyana, Mongolia

Other managed floating: Ethiopia, Kyrgyz Republic, Rwanda

Independently floating: Albania, Madagascar, Mozambique, Tanzania, Uganda

1/Bubula and Ötker-Robe (2002).2/ Fixed to the U.S. dollar, but with periodic adjustments; until mid-2003, when the currency was floated.

29. The recent experience of the mature stabilizers shows that the expansion of monetary aggregates has generally been higher than targeted, but without leading to a significant overshooting of inflation targets (Table 5).26 On average, actual broad money growth exceeded program projections by some 4-6 percentage points, about a third as much as initially envisaged. The average deviation declines as the target approaches (except between t-2 and t-1), which points to increasing accuracy as the projection period shortens (see Appendix I for evidence of improved program accuracy in consecutive program updates). At the same time, there is little evidence that the higher-than-targeted broad money growth has translated into higher inflation: (i) deviations of inflation from target are not statistically significant, and (ii), regression analysis reveals no statistically significant relation between the deviations from the previous years’ projections of money growth and inflation, as illustrated by Figure 5.27 It is important to recognize that these findings are fully consistent with the expected positive association between money growth and inflation—which is strongly supported by the data in our sample. While there was scope to accommodate somewhat higher-than-projected money demand, a further increase in money supply would still have been inflationary.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Deviations from Previous Year Projections for CPI and Broad Money Growth 1/

(percentage points)

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF staff reports.1/ Regression conditioned on fixed country effects.

30. The evidence that larger-than-programmed monetary growth has not triggered above-target inflation appears limited to the sample of mature stabilizers. Notably, the 2004 review of program design did find statistically significant correlation between slippage relative to the one-year ahead projections in broad money growth and in inflation (IMF, 2004c, Section III.B).28 That analysis, however, covered all PRGF countries rather than a subset of mature stabilizers.29 Moreover, the study also showed that the larger overruns are recorded by high-inflation cases.

31. The above-target monetary expansion has accommodated a trend decline in velocity. The gradual decline in inflation (Section II) seems to have fostered an increase in broad money demand in real terms (i.e., a decrease in velocity)—with lower inflation expectations, the opportunity costs of holding non interest-bearing financial assets also falls.30 Financial sector developments has likely also contributed to this trend. However, the baseline assumption in most programs has been for velocity to remain largely unchanged (see Figure 6), with only a minor average decline. As a result, velocity has on average been 3-5 percent lower than projected (Table 6).31 By contrast, the 2004 program design review found that the null hypothesis of equality of the relationship between money growth and inflation in the program and in reality could not be rejected.32 Findings concerning average velocity mask the pronounced variation in the changes in this parameter—which have a RMSE for velocity growth (in percent) of 7.0 for the final projection.33 This volatility imparts greater uncertainty to estimates of money demand, complicating the conduct of monetary policy.

Table 6.

Monetary Projections and Projection Deviations

(averages, in percent)

article image
Source: IMF Staff Reports and World Economic Outlook database.

The year the projections are for is t. The projections as of Year t-1 and t-2 are those from the last staff reports in the previous year and the year before that, respectively. The projection as of t(SR1) is from the first staff report in Year t, and the one at t(SR2) is from the final staff report in that year. In case only one staff report was issued in year t, the last two observations coincide.

NDA (NFA) contribution is defined as the change in central bank NDA (NFA) divided by previous year reserve money.

Projection deviations are calculated as program values minus outcomes. As the panel is unbalanced, deviations from the t-2 and t-1 projections do not correspond to the difference between the average projection for the sample subset and the average outcome for the full sample.

Indicating significance at 10 percent level (*), 5 percent level (**), or 1 percent level (***).

The contribution of the deviation in NDA growth to the deviation in reserve money growth; transformed to be mapped into (-100, 100)—comparable to the measure in the 2004 evaluation of program design (IMF 2004c, Table 10).

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Projected and Actual Percentage Change in Velocity

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF staff reports and World Economic Outlook database.

32. The overruns in broad money growth were primarily a reflection of higher-than-projected reserve money growth—the aggregate over which the monetary authorities have most direct control. Program targets for reserve and broad money were exceeded in approximately the same degree (Table 6), since the program assumptions for the reserve money multiplier—the parameter that measures the link between the two aggregates—were on average broadly accurate.34 The deviations in the multiplier from the program assumptions were not statistically significant. Averages, however, mask a great deal of volatility (Figure 7).35

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Projected and Actual Percentage Change in the Reserve Money Multiplier

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF staff reports and World Economic Outlook database.

33. In turn, higher-than-targeted reserve money growth has mainly reflected larger-than-programmed accumulation of international reserves. As shown in Table 5 (upper panel), on average, programs correctly project a decline in central bank NDA and a rise in NFA. However, both changes tend to be even larger than projected, with the NFA overrun exceeding the NDA shortfall, resulting in a faster-than-projected expansion in reserve money.

34. This additional liquidity expansion is consistent with the architecture of the Fund-supported programs. Conditionality in Fund-supported programs generally requires NDA to be kept below and NFA to be kept above the targets set under the program.36 Recognizing the uncertainty that attends to estimates of money demand, Fund-supported programs generally do not impose firm limits on the aggregate increase in reserve money. The framework effectively allows for larger-than-programmed monetary expansion to take place as long as it reflects higher reserve accumulation.

35. Larger-than-programmed monetary and reserves expansion likely also reflects the objective of avoiding appreciation pressures in the face of external inflows. The systematic overruns in NFA growth seem related to the above-mentioned potential tension between reserve money objectives and (de facto) exchange rate targets. Had primacy been given to the money target, greater exchange rate flexibility would have been evident, along with less of a build-up in reserves. More than three quarters of these NFA overruns have been sterilized through a lower central bank NDA (see Figure 8).37 Thus, monetary authorities have sought to keep foreign inflows from affecting the exchange rate, while mitigating their impact on (reserve) money. The relative success of this strategy is illustrated in Figure 9: across country episodes, no association between exchange rate stability and overruns in NFA or money growth was apparent.38 Nonetheless, given the serious costs and limits of sterilization—including the adverse impact of higher real interest rates on private sector growth—for those countries in the mature stabilizer sample with the most heavily managed exchange rates, staff has generally advocated a stronger focus on monetary objectives and a more market-based exchange rate.39

Figure 8.
Figure 8.

Deviations from the Programmed Levels of NDA and NFA 1/

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF staff reports.1/ Conditioned on fixed effects and deviations from projected government borrowing.
Figure 9.
Figure 9.

Exchange-Rate Variability and Deviations from Previous-Year Broad Money Projection

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Source: IMF staff reports.

36. These developments in the mature stabilizers point to the potential benefits of some changes in the design of monetary programs. First, there is scope for improving the programming assumptions regarding velocity, which are key to the conduct of monetary policy as well as financial programming. In particular, once inflationary pressures are at bay, monetary projections require a careful assessment of velocity trends and of the need to allow for a (further) decline. With this adjustment, the financial programming framework would continue to provide a useful tool for guiding program design, as monetary management remains focused on monetary aggregates rather than interest rates. Second, the standard NDA/NFA framework for monetary policy in Fund-supported programs appears to provide a useful safety valve for tailoring money growth to unforeseen changes in velocity. However, given the risks to inflation of an unwarranted expansion in reserves and money—evident in the larger set of PRGF programs more than in our subsample of mature stabilizers—the use of this channel merits close monitoring. In this context, indicative targets for reserve money growth could provide a useful check. Money growth in excess of the indicative ceiling should prompt further analysis to determine if monetary policy merely accommodated higher money demand or entailed risk of inflationary pressure.

37. In case of a managed floating exchange rate, interventions in the exchange market in order to resist durable real appreciation pressures may pose risks to the programmed inflation objective. The benefits of a managed float include that it can help absorb real internal and external shocks—which are indeed prevalent in PRGF countries—through nominal exchange rate adjustment. However, the arrangement puts the responsibility for ensuring low and stable inflation firmly on the central bank. Resisting lasting appreciation pressure from such shocks through large-scale—and costly—interventions, building up NFA and fuelling inflation, would negate the adjustment mechanism and undermine price stability.40

C. Is Private Sector Credit Being Crowded Out?

38. Concerns regarding the potential crowding out of private sector credit is an important reason why Fund-supported programs limit domestic financing of the public sector.41,42 The desire to foster credit growth to the private sector is influenced by the fact that financial development, as measured by the volume of intermediated finance has been found to be robustly associated with higher per capita income growth. Crowding out of the private sector, however, is generally difficult to establish. First, credit markets rarely clear through changes in interest rates alone. As higher interest rates are likely to attract less creditworthy clients, banks often resort to credit rationing—a behavior not captured in the data. Second, financial repression remains prevalent in a number of the mature stabilizers (for example, Ethiopia) making interest rates sticky. Third, poor health of the banking sector may inhibit the effectiveness of financial intermediation—limiting the impact of changes in government borrowing on private credit growth. And while there are a few studies (Christensen 2004; Adam and Bevan, 2004) that find some evidence of crowding out in African countries, in particular, this may capture mainly the cases with severe macroeconomic imbalances. Adam and Bevan (2004) have also flagged the absence of crowding-in of private sector credit after recourse to domestic financing by the government has been curtailed and broader macroeconomic stability achieved.

39. Against this backdrop, this section briefly considers (i) the magnitude of private sector credit growth (PSCG) accommodated in Fund-supported programs, and (ii) the extent to which crowding out, or lack of crowding in, has been problematic.

How has private sector credit growth fared in the mature stabilizers?

40. PSCG in the countries in the sample has expanded at a rapid pace—albeit from a small base and remaining slightly lower than implicitly allowed for in their PRGF-supported programs. On average, during 2000-2003, PRGF-supported programs envisaged PSCG of the order of 19 percent—in real terms, about twice the pace of real GDP growth. Actual credit growth was marginally less (just under 18 percent, text table).43 More generally, private sector credit growth in the mature-stabilizers compares favorably with other low-income countries. The median increase in ratio of private sector credit to GDP in the sample over the 1995-2003 period was 5 percentage points of GDP, compared to 2½ percentage points in other low-income countries.

Credit to the Private Sector (annual percent growth) 1/

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates.

Credit growth in nominal terms during the first programmed year.

41. However, these averages mask important cross-country variations. Over the somewhat longer horizon of 1995-2003, credit to the non-government sector has grown significantly faster than income for most of the mature stabilizers, but particularly so for Bangladesh, Benin, Ethiopia, Honduras, and Senegal (see the text figure). One possible explanation is in the deeper banking systems—the ratio of credit to GDP was around 18 percent in these five countries, compared to 11 percent in the other 10 mature stabilizer countries. Second, for some countries (Mozambique, Rwanda, and Tanzania), the association between GDP and credit growth is more linear.44 However, at least in the case of Rwanda, this likely reflects GDP recovery from extremely low levels more than a positive effect of private credit on real growth.

uA01fig08

Cumulated Growth in Credit and GDP, 1995-2002 (in percent)

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Crowding Out

42. There is limited evidence of government recourse to domestic financing crowding out private sector borrowing in the mature stabilizers:

  • First, both in the mature stabilizers and for the broader grouping of low-income countries, credit to the private sector tends to be lower as levels of domestic debt are higher (text figure, top left panel). Further, the higher the stock of debt, the more pronounced this negative correlation tends to be (text figure, lower right panel compared to lower left panel). However, when one looks at annual changes in these variables instead of levels (text figure, top right panel), the correlation is still negative but no longer statistically significant.

  • Second, as noted above, over the somewhat longer period of 1995-2003, credit growth in the mature stabilizers has actually been higher than in other LICs—against the backdrop of a similar increase (around 2 percentage points of GDP) in domestic indebtedness in both groups.

  • Third, real interest rates (proxied by average t-bill rates) have remained broadly unchanged in the 15 countries. Beyond this, there is no robust evidence of a negative association between real interest rates and changes in domestic government indebtedness for either the sample or the broader LIC grouping. Although, as noted above, crowding-out could take place through channels other than interest rates (e.g., credit rationing).

43. These considerations suggest that domestic financing should be relied upon only cautiously, especially where domestic and totals debt stocks are high. The absence of convincing evidence notwithstanding, the risk of crowding out should not be discounted too readily—especially given the crucial role of private investment for sustaining growth. Caution in domestic borrowing is also warranted in view of the fact that domestic debt carries higher real interest rates than foreign debt; while many projects may have an expected return exceeding the terms of concessional financing, few projects are likely to have returns exceeding the interest rates on nonconcessional domestic borrowing. For countries that satisfy these conditions, one benchmark that could be used to guide domestic borrowing could be to ensure that recourse to such credits annually are no more consistent with stabilizing the debt stocks.

uA01fig09

Domestic Debt and Private Sector Credit in Low-Income Countries

Citation: Policy Papers 2005, 046; 10.5089/9781498331296.007.A001

Note: Correlations are conditional on financial depth and country fixed effects.

IV. Fiscal Policy Issues in PRGF-Supported Programs

44. This section aims to assess whether program design is consistent with the best practices suggested in the literature. To set the stage for subsequent discussion, it begins with a discussion of the links between fiscal policy and growth, including on the channels through which fiscal policy affects economic activity.

A. The Fiscal Stance and Economic Growth in Mature Stabilizers

45. The links between budget deficits and growth go beyond the traditional macroeconomic channels in low-income countries. A number of studies indicate that low levels of the budget deficit and public debt can promote growth.45 However, the precise channels through which deficits affect growth in low-income countries have received little attention. One study that has specifically examined this topic indicates that budget deficits have only a small effect on growth via the crowding out of investment (Baldacci, Hillman, and Kojo, 2004). The effect of fiscal consolidation on growth through its salutary effects on inflation is also modest. Their study suggests that other factors are at play, including the effect of reductions in expenditure on total factor productivity in countries with poor governance. In light of these findings, this section considers factors that need to be considered in choosing the optimal path for the fiscal balance over the short to medium term in the mature stabilizer sample. A closely related issue is the appropriate measure of the fiscal stance in low-income countries where most of the financing is on concessional terms, and this is addressed in Box 7 and Appendix III.

The Treatment of Concessional Loans in Fiscal Accounts

The appropriate treatment of concessional loans in fiscal accounts has been a subject of lively debate in recent years. Under the accounting rules used by most developing countries, concessional loans are currently recorded in fiscal accounts as a financing item at their face value. Interest payments, at concessional rates, are recorded as expenditure.

Some observers prefer to conceive of a concessional loan as a combination of a non-concessional loan combined with a grant. They argue that the grant element of a concessional loan should be treated in fiscal accounts as revenue, analogous to other grants. This would imply that the grant component of the loan is provided upfront, at the time the loan is disbursed. Consistent accounting would require that interest payments on such loans should then be recorded, not at the actual concessional rate, but rather at the higher, non-concessional rate on the non-grant component of the loan.

These two approaches have different effects on the measured deficit. Given a certain fiscal deficit target, a concessional loan allows higher primary spending over the entire lifespan of the loan through lower interest payments. On the other hand, recording the grant element upfront as revenue would lower the deficit immediately. However, subsequent deficits would be larger reflecting higher interest rates.

The choice between these two approaches would not affect how much spending is sustainable. Under the standard approach, the deficit path that stabilizes the NPV of debt could be identified, conditional on certain financing terms and other macroeconomic assumptions. Under the alternative approach, the measured deficit in the current period might be lower due to the inclusion of the grant element of loans in revenue. However, under this alternative approach, a lower deficit would also be required to stabilize the NPV of debt, since the interest rate on debt would also be higher under this approach. The implications for spending would be the same. The distinction would be that changes in the terms of financing would affect the NPV-of-debt-stabilizing deficit under the standard approach, but not under the alternative approach.

The alternative approach is, however, administratively demanding. Given these complexities, it is appropriate to continue the current practice of recording savings from concessional interest rates at the time interest is paid, rather than at the time the loan is contracted. However, deficit targets measured under the standard approach should be evaluated periodically and appropriately adjusted when the terms of financing change.

46. The implication of the fiscal stance for debt sustainability is of first-order importance in assessing the optimal path of the fiscal balance. Absent sustainability, debt will continue rising to high levels, hindering growth as noted above. Macroeconomic imbalances are also likely to re-emerge, with further adverse effects on development.

47. Given the importance of sustainability, the Fund has recently made efforts to strengthen the framework for assessing debt sustainability. In low-income countries, this has entailed the forward-looking analysis of the evolution of the NPV of public and external debt and the establishment of indicative ceilings for the NPV of public and publicly-guaranteed external debt (see IMF, 2004g and IMF, 2004h). This framework also stresses the need to take a comprehensive view of debt sustainability that examines not just the evolution of debt ratios, but also debt-service ratios and gross financing needs under a variety of alternative scenarios. It also stresses the importance of assessing whether macroeconomic assumptions underlying baseline scenarios are realistic in light of historical averages. Unfortunately, however, such detailed public sector debt sustainability analyses (DSAs) for the sampled countries are limited, since systematic preparation of DSAs for low-income countries started only recently. Assessments of debt sustainability in most mature-stabilizer countries must therefore be based on more limited data.

48. Available data suggest that debt sustainability remains a concern in many mature-stabilizer countries.46 Of the 14 countries for which debt data are available on an NPV basis, half had NPV of debt-to-GDP ratios above 40 percent at end-2003 (excluding debt that has since been forgiven under the HIPC Initiative; see Table 7). Debt remains especially high in Albania, Ethiopia, Guyana, Kyrgyz Republic, and Mongolia. Similarly, staff analysis indicates that less than half the mature stabilizers have been running primary balances in recent years that would be sustainable under somewhat neutral macroeconomic assumptions (e.g., average real GDP growth of 3 percent, constant real exchange rate, and external borrowing with an average grant element of 40 percent; see Appendix IV) although primary balances in a majority of the countries would be sustainable under more optimistic assumptions (e.g., real GDP growth of 5 percent). While staff’s baseline scenarios project a gradual decline in debt ratios in several cases, these scenarios sometimes assume real GDP growth that is significantly higher and fiscal policy that is significantly tighter than in the recent past. In some cases, debt is sustainable in the baseline scenario, but not in the event of modest shocks (see Box 8 for a discussion of the debt sustainability issue in Ethiopia).

Table 7.

NPV of Public Sector Debt for Selected Mature Stabilizer Countries 1/

(In percent of GDP)

article image
Sources: Staff estimates.

The NPV of public debt is defined here as the sum of the NPV of public and publicly-guaranteed external debt plus the nominal value of domestic public debt. Data on domestic public debt are from a PDR database; data on external public- and publicly-guaranteed debt are from the HIPC database as of June 2004. External debt data for non-HIPCs are from staff reports. Figures have been updated for countries that have completed a public sector debt sustainability analysis using the new low-income country template or that reached HIPC completion points after June 2004. Data are not available for Azerbaijan.

For comparison purposes, the NPV of public debt is also expressed net of HIPC debt relief for those countries that reached the completion point after the 2003 fiscal year.

Public Debt Sustainability: The Case of Ethiopia

Staff recently compiled a detailed public and external debt sustainability analysis (DSA) for Ethiopia (IMF, 2004f) using the new DSA templates for low-income countries. Ethiopia thus provides a useful case study for whether program design in such countries is appropriately geared toward achieving debt sustainability.

In staff’s baseline scenario, public sector debt declines gradually. The NPV of public sector debt declines from 55 percent of GDP in 2003 to 52 percent of GDP by 2008 and then to 35 percent of GDP by 2022. Gross financing needs and debt-to-revenue ratios similarly decline.

However, this scenario is based on projected primary deficits and growth rates that are significantly better than historical averages. In the baseline, the primary deficit will be limited to 3 percent of GDP over 2005-10, compared to an average over the last 10 years of 6 percent of GDP, while real GDP will grow at 5¼ percent, well above the 3¾ percent average over the last 10 years.

Under less optimistic assumptions, the NPV of public sector debt will continue to rise. While the past weak fiscal performance was due in part to the conflict with Eritrea, there is no guarantee that internal or external shocks will not re-occur. In the event that the real average growth rate in the baseline scenario is reduced slightly to 4¼ percent of GDP, the DSA projects that the NPV of public sector debt would continue rising slowly to 59 percent of GDP by 2022. If the primary deficit and real GDP growth remain at their historical averages, the DSA projects that the NPV of public sector debt will rise more rapidly, reaching 80 percent of GDP by 2022.

Nonetheless, debt-service-to-revenue ratios are projected to remain moderate even in less optimistic scenarios, presumably due to the long maturity structure of Ethiopia’s concessional debt. In the baseline scenario, the debt-service-to-revenue ratio is expected to remain around the 2004 level of 6 percent. Under the scenario in which the primary deficit and real GDP growth are at their historical averages, the debt-service-to-revenue ratio rises continuously but still reaches only 10 percent by 2022. This indicates that, as long as Ethiopia finances its deficit on very concessional terms, near-term debt-service problems are unlikely, although debt service may still become problematic in the long run (20+ years) unless there are significant improvements in growth and fiscal performance.

Such results highlight the critical importance of obtaining financing on sufficiently concessional terms. Given past experience, there is a distinct possibility that key variables such as the primary deficit and real GDP growth will be less favorable than in the baseline scenario, which could result in rising NPV of debt ratios. If the additional financing for deficits is obtained on less concessional terms and with short maturities, debt-service ratios may also rise quickly. These results underscore the need to ensure that minimum levels of concessionality are sufficiently high and deficits sufficiently low so as to make debt sustainability problems unlikely, even in less favorable states of the world.

49. A tighter fiscal stance and/or higher levels of concessionality in borrowing are therefore required to place public debt on a sustainable path in many countries. In these cases, fiscal policy should target deficits that are sufficiently low and debt management policies should ensure that borrowing terms are sufficiently concessional to avoid debt sustainability problems in the future, including in the event of modest shocks. In many cases, this is likely to require an increase in grant resources (either through direct grants, debt relief or more highly concessional loans) to meet the twin objectives of debt sustainability and providing sufficient funding for MDG-related spending.

50. Once countries achieve sustainable deficits at moderate debt levels, they may not benefit from further fiscal consolidation. A number of studies suggest that the deficit-growth nexus is nonlinear. The level at which deficit reduction no longer boosts growth, however, is subject to considerable uncertainty. One recent study (Adam and Bevan, 2005) suggests a breakpoint for the overall deficit (including grants) centered at 1½ percent of GDP, but with wide confidence intervals. Other studies conclude that reducing deficits has no growth payoff for those that have maintained deficits that average less than 2½ of GDP (Baldacci, Hillman, and Kojo, 2004, Gupta and others, 2004a). In contrast, the average deficit level in the sample countries is about 4½ percent (Table 4).

51. In countries with clearly sustainable fiscal positions, the productivity of additional outlays should be carefully assessed relative to the costs of financing. In countries with poor governance, the low productivity of outlays may be such that higher spending has a limited effect on growth and social indicators (see also Section B). In particular, countries with limited absorptive capacity may also not be in a position to increase spending while ensuring that these outlays are productive (see Box 9). The scope for fiscal expansion would also need to take into account fiscal vulnerabilities in the face of exogenous shocks, including those due to the variability of aid. Furthermore, given the rigidity of spending commitments, especially for current outlays, the fiscal risks associated with increases in spending would also need to be assessed. Finally, in these countries where debt burdens are more moderate, the pace at which new debt is accumulated needs to be monitored closely.

Absorptive Capacity Constraints and Policies to Ameliorate Them

Absorptive capacity is defined as the amount of spending that can be effectively undertaken by a developing country owing to macroeconomic or microeconomic constraints. Absorptive capacity limits are reflected in decreasing returns as spending increases. Macroeconomic constraints refer to conditions in the recipient country that place limits on aggregate spending, while microeconomic constraints refer to specific limitations that can significantly reduce the productivity of spending. The two types of constraints are inter-linked. For example, if aid inflows elicit a strong enough supply response as a result of microeconomic factors, the macroeconomic constraints would be correspondingly reduced. This box focuses on issues related to microeconomic capacity constraints.1

At present, the mature stabilizers sample are under executing their capital budgets.2 In this context, scaling up aid and budgeted expenditure could have little effect on capital spending that is executed unless matched by efforts to tackle absorptive capacity constraints.

Absorptive capacity constraints manifest themselves in a number of ways. These include: (1) weaknesses in public expenditure management (PEM) systems and low quality of governance;3 (2) weaknesses in the selection of donor-financed projects resulting in low-productivity projects;4 (3) weak incentives to adopt good policies and raise the domestic revenue effort to supplement foreign aid;5 (4) limited skilled labor and administrative capacity at the sectoral level;6 (5) high compliance costs of donor conditionality that limit the ability to execute projects;7 and (6) reliance on project rather than budget support.8

Several actions can be taken by both recipient countries and donors to improve absorptive capacity. For recipient countries the actions are: (1) strengthen PEM systems and the quality of governance; (2) improve project selection; (3) reallocate public sector employment to address bottlenecks and improve administrative capacity; and (4) increase the use of the private sector for service delivery. For donors the actions are: (1) work more closely with recipient countries to integrate donor projects into country poverty reduction strategies (PRS); and (2) increase the share of aid as budget support and improve donor harmonization.

Additional analytical work on absorptive capacity at the country level is also needed. There has been only limited analytical work quantifying absorptive capacity constraints. The additional work could analyze the impact of absorptive capacity constraints on measures of execution and effectiveness of spending at the country level, and provide cost estimates of various options to relieve constraints on institutional and human capital and physical infrastructure. Results of these studies could then be incorporated into the countries’ PRS papers and provide vital input into medium-term expenditure frameworks.

1/ For a discussion regarding macroeconomic absorptive capacity constraints, see the accompanying background paper.2/ See Section II.3/ In the 2002 HIPIC tracking assessment, about 90 percent of the countries were found to have inactive and/or ineffective internal audits, which also enforces compliance with procurement procedures. See IMF (2002) for details.4/ See Hanson and others (2003) and World Bank (2004a).5/ This manifestation was documented in Gupta and others (2004b). However, this effect was not clearly evident in the mature stabilizer countries in the 1990s—the change in a country’s official current transfers was uncorrelated with the change in tax revenue over this period.6/ See de Renzio (2005) and World Bank (2004b,c).7/ See Radelet and Clemens (2003), Knack and Rahman (2004), and de Renzio (2005).8/ See World Bank (2004a).

52. With inflation broadly under control, fiscal consolidation is not needed to reduce inflationary pressures. This owes to both the limited impact of changes in the fiscal stance on inflation, as well as the uncertain impact of inflation on growth (see Section II). In the same vein, considerations regarding the possible crowding out of the private sector through public sector deficits may also need to play but a small part in determining the appropriate fiscal stance, given the dearth of evidence that deficits have had a large impact on private investment.

53. PRGF-supported programs have generally sought to accommodate higher externally financed spending, without due regard to debt sustainability considerations at times. Programs have targeted increases in expenditure in line with higher grants and external financing. Higher budget deficits have also been accommodated in some instances (Section II). At the same time, programs have attempted to promote debt sustainability by limiting nonconcessional external borrowing and domestic financing, even when domestic debt has been at very low levels. However, this combination of policies has not always been sufficient to ensure debt sustainability, as noted above. A heightened focus on debt sustainability (both external and public sector) and the need for more grant financing is thus warranted and should be facilitated by the new DSA framework.

B. Public Expenditure

54. In most countries, the government has a central role in providing infrastructure, education, and health services. Thus, the quantity and quality of these services will be critical not only for achieving higher growth, but for the MDGs. The goals of higher growth and meeting the MDGs are interrelated, as human capital can be a powerful engine of economic growth, including in low-income countries, while growth is vital for poverty reduction.47

55. The average ratio of government spending to GDP in the mature stabilizers is about 26 percent of GDP (the median is 23 percent of GDP), which is relatively low compared to other low- and middle-income countries. During the period 1999-2003, this ratio was about 29 percent for all low-income countries and 34 percent for middle-income countries. In OECD countries, the ratio was about 42 percent. There is also a wide variation among these mature stabilizer countries with the ratio varying between 14 and 45 percent. The low ratio in most of these countries and the apparent positive relationship between per capita income and government spending suggests that as these countries grow, the share of government spending in GDP is also likely to increase.

56. Higher spending in MDG-related sectors is also expected to raise the ratio of government spending to GDP. Rough estimates of the size of HIV/AIDS disbursements in selected African countries in 2005 reveal that total potential funding could be in excess of 3 percent of GDP in Uganda, about 2 percent in Ethiopia, and more than 1 percent in Mozambique and Tanzania.48 However, supply bottlenecks (e.g., availability of teachers and health sector personnel) will need to be addressed to facilitate the absorption of this external support (see Box 8). Other considerations include the sustainability and reliability of aid flows (see the companion paper The Macroeconomics of Managing Aid Inflows: Experiences of Low-Income Countries and Policy Implications), and the need to avoid excessive levels of debt (see Section IV.A). Against this background, the research on the impact of government spending and the composition of government outlays is reviewed in this section, along with an assessment of lessons for program design.49

57. The effect of government spending on growth depends on the macroeconomic context. If macroeconomic stability is lacking, even government spending that is productive can have an adverse net effect on growth, owing to its macroeconomic consequences. For the sampled countries, additional spending may be accommodated in some cases without endangering macroeconomic stability, external viability, or public debt sustainability.

58. Public investment can potentially raise economic growth, although empirical evidence on the impact of public investment on growth remains inconclusive. Data reported in Briceño-Garmendia and others (2004) suggest that, of 102 studies that estimate the impact of infrastructure investment on productivity or growth, 53 percent show a significant positive effect, 42 percent show no significant effect, and 5 percent show a significant negative effect.50 Still, in a recent survey, Romp and de Haan (2005) suggest that there is more consensus now that public capital furthers economic growth but that the impact is substantially less than what was found in earlier studies such as Aschauer (1989).51 Recent econometric work suggests that public investment can raise growth in low-income countries and is most productive when governance is good (Tanzi and Davoodi, 2002; Gupta and others, 2004a). In this context, more research will also be needed on the channels by which capital expenditure affects growth and how changes in the composition of government spending, including a shift toward capital expenditure, can support growth.

59. Higher public spending on health and education (both current and capital) can build human capital, but with varying degrees of effectiveness. 52 For example, Baldacci and others (2004) find that an increase in education spending of 1 percent of GDP, holding other factors constant, could increase the net primary enrollment rate by 8 percentage points over a 10-year period. A similar increase in health spending would reduce under-five child mortality by 8 percent over 10 years. Several studies also find that public health care spending may have especially strong effects on the health status of the poor (Gupta, Verhoeven, and Tiongson, 2003; Koenig, Bishai, and Ali Khan, 2001).

60. However, the composition of this social spending, as well as its efficiency, are particularly critical. Rates of return for primary and secondary education, for example, exceed those for tertiary studies (Psacharopoulos and Patrinos, 2002). Similarly, public health spending that does not substitute for private sector outlays—such as preventive health outlays for immunization that have significant externalities—are likely to have the highest social returns (Hammer, 1993).53 Primary education and health care expenditures are also more likely to benefit the poor more than other types of spending.54 At present, however, a large share of spending is allocated to activities that benefit higher-income groups, rather than the poor (Davoodi, Tiongson, and Asawanuchit, 2003). The mix of spending inputs is also inappropriate in many countries, where a large share of budgetary resources is often used for wages, leaving inadequate funds for nonwage inputs with high productivity, such as medicines and textbooks.55

61. Recent research has emphasized the role of good governance in strengthening the link between social spending and social outcomes.56 Where institutions are weak, higher spending will have at best a diminished effect on social indicators (Baldacci and others, 2004). In cases where governance is weak, governments are also likely to allocate fewer resources to the social sectors (Mauro, 1998).

62. The appropriate mix of spending to promote growth and poverty reduction will vary from country to country. Existing research does not provide clear guidance on whether a given country should, at the margin, focus increased spending on health, education, or infrastructure. As such, a country-by-country approach will be needed.57

63. In sum, the literature suggests that countries should focus not only on increasing the level of spending, but improving the efficiency and targeting of these outlays. Two-thirds of PRGF-supported programs incorporate steps to improve the efficiency of such outlays (Gupta and others, 2002). At the same time, given the large degree of inefficiency in spending, there may be scope for further attention to these issues. The design of reform policies in this area generally falls in the domain of other development partners. To raise the profile of these issues, countries could be encouraged to provide more details on specific social sector reforms in their PRSPs or other country-owned documents.

64. Programs should continue to emphasize a strengthening of public expenditure management (PEM) systems to improve governance and the effectiveness of spending. Improvements in PEM systems hold promise as a tangible method to strengthen governance. The average PRGF-supported program contains 4-5 measures to improve PEM systems (Gupta and others, 2002). Given the weaknesses in PEM systems that still prevail in a number of the mature stabilizers, continued integration of PEM reforms into programs remains appropriate.

C. Tax Policy

65. This section discusses the appropriate level and structure of tax revenues, and the main tax policy issues ahead.

The level and structure of taxation

66. The literature provides little practical guidance as to the optimal overall level of taxation. In principle, taxation should be taken to the point at which the marginal social cost of raising an additional $1 equals the marginal social value of the additional expenditure or debt reduction that it finances. In practice, however, the marginal deadweight loss from a tax increase—a key element in this calculation—is subject to considerable empirical uncertainty, while the other elements depend on equity judgments upon which reasonable people may differ. A distinct empirical strand in the literature identifies strong correlations between the overall level of taxation and the level of income per capita, openness, and the importance of the agricultural sector, but these correlations provide little firm guidance for policy, since describing what countries do in general cannot identify what any country in particular should do. Nor does the growth literature provide strong practical guidance. For developed countries, however, the evidence suggests that increasing taxes to finance unproductive expenditure adversely affects growth while higher taxes used for productive expenditure have a positive, albeit mild, effect.58 The question has received less attention for developing countries, but similar findings have started to emerge.59

67. The tax ratio (tax revenue as a share of GDP) varies widely across the mature-stabilizer sample (from 7-10 percent in Bangladesh and Rwanda to 30 percent in Guyana and Mongolia), but has generally increased over the past decade (Table 8). On average, it increased from 13.1 percent to 14.9 percent of GDP during the 1990s, and in only two countries—Guyana (where it was initially very high, at 30 percent), and Tanzania—did it fall by more than one percentage point. This is a somewhat stronger revenue performance than for the broader set of low-income countries, for which the average rose by only 0.5 points, to around 15 percent.60 This result is expected since the sample is a subset that has succeeded in addressing fiscal shortfalls. But the tax ratios they have achieved are not high relative to the wider comparator set, so it is unlikely that many of them have over-shot their appropriate levels.

Table 8.

Evolution of the Revenue Structure in the Mature Stabilizer Sample

(In percent of GDP)

article image
Sources: World Economic Outlook (IMF); Statistical Annexes (IMF, various issues); Staff calculations.

n.a.: not applicable/not available. VAT includes revenues collected by customs and inland revenue departments. Totals for direct and indirect taxes may not add due to unavailability of data for the subcategories.

Average of two years for all countries and 1999 for Guyana.

Depending on data availability, the average represents two consecutive years between 1990 and 1994.

68. Experience points more clearly to minimum than to maximum levels of taxation, with a ratio of at least 15 percent a reasonable target for most low-income countries.61 Few countries have sustained minimally acceptable living standards at tax ratios below 10 percent.62 At a tax ratio of around 15 percent, most low to lower-middle income countries find that increasing revenue requires an expansion of the tax base that they find difficult, both politically and technically. Achieving a ratio of this order is a reasonable medium-term target for many of these countries. A ratio closer to 20 percent would provide more room for productive expenditures—diminishing returns do not seem to set in quickly—and there is no evidence that it would be intrinsically harmful to growth. Some countries may though reasonably prefer to set somewhat lower tax ratios than this in an attempt to spur economic activity, and the implication is certainly not that all tax rates should be in the 15-20 percent range. A relatively low corporate tax rate, for instance (combined with an appropriate definition of the base) may provide a useful encouragement to private investment.

69. The composition of tax revenue is also an important concern in policy design. In principle, each tax instrument—the rate of VAT, the extent of investment allowances, and so on—should be taken to the point at which the social cost of raising an additional $1 is the same for all: otherwise the same revenue could be raised at lower total social cost. Explicit comparisons of this sort can rarely be undertaken, but two important dimensions of choice are of particular interest. The first is the balance between taxes on consumption—including both broad-based commodity taxes (notably the VAT) and excises—and taxes on labor and capital income. At least for developed countries, there is evidence that countries which rely more on consumption taxes tend to save more and grow faster.63 Against this, personal income taxes provide a better-targeted way of structuring an equitable tax system, although it may well be that spending measures provide an even more effective way of helping the least advantaged. The second is the extent of reliance on customs revenues relative to other sources, there being in principle clear gains to be made in moving from tariffs towards domestic consumption taxes.64

70. The sampled countries have come to rely increasingly on indirect taxes, and the VAT in particular. Indeed twelve of the 15 introduced the VAT in the 1990s (Honduras has had one since 1976, Senegal since 1979); Rwanda and Ethiopia introduced VAT in the early 2000s; only Guyana remains without a VAT (and plans for its adoption are underway). The VAT now accounts on average for nearly 40 percent of tax revenues in the mature stabilizer sample.

71. These countries have also—with some exceptions—reduced their reliance on trade taxes. On average—Azerbaijan and Ethiopia are exceptions—these accounted for revenues equivalent to 2.8 percent of GDP in the early 1990s but 2.3 percent at the turn of the century, a modest but worthwhile structural improvement. It is largely by introducing or improving the VAT that these countries have recovered lost trade tax revenues. In Bangladesh, for example, trade tax revenues fell by about 0.3 percent of GDP, while revenue from the VAT increased by 0.7. This experience runs counter to the emerging evidence that low-income countries, in general, have not succeeded in recovering lost trade tax revenues.65 The success of the countries in doing so is important, not least for the example it provides to others.

Current and future tax policy issues

72. The most prominent tax policy issues that need to be addressed for the mature-stabilizer countries in the coming years are likely to be:

  • Strengthening the VAT. This is not a matter of increasing rates of VAT: these are not low by international standards, averaging over 17 percent and with only Honduras now having a standard rate below 15 percent (Table 9). Further increases would likely put significant pressure on the wider system by increasing the attractions of non-compliance. The issue is rather to expand the base of the VAT, primarily by reducing exemptions and improving compliance. Gains from this source can be seen from Table 9. The ‘C-efficiency’ is the ratio of VAT revenues to the product of the standard VAT rate and total private consumption. If all consumption were subject to the VAT, C-efficiency would be unity.66 That is rarely the case even in developed countries, but a ratio closer to 40 than to 30 percent should be within the sights of most sampled countries. C-efficiency has increased in this sample, but there is still scope for significant improvement in some countries. In Bangladesh, for example, increasing C-efficiency to 40 percent would increase the tax ratio by nearly one percentage point.

  • Reducing reliance on trade tax revenues. At an average of 16 percent of total tax revenue—and around a quarter in some—trade taxes remain an important source of revenue. Some degree of trade liberalization may be possible without reducing trade tax revenues further (e.g., by eliminating exemptions or by reducing protective tariffs set above revenue-maximizing levels). While no summary measure can fully describe potentially complex tariff systems and the range of potential reforms, it is notable that all of these countries have collected tariff rates below the 20 percent estimated to be revenue maximizing by Ebrill, Stotsky, and Gropp (1999).67 With trade tax revenues already declining in most of these countries, continued trade liberalization will intensify the need to improve domestic tax systems. This will often involve strengthening the indirect tax system, including the VAT (reducing exemptions and rate differentiation, for instance). To avoid transitional revenue losses, such measures need to be carefully sequenced with those of trade liberalization.

  • Dealing with pressures on corporate tax revenue. Several of the mature stabilizers have seen a noticeable reduction in their revenue from corporate taxation over the last decade (e.g., 1 percentage point in Albania, and 1.5 in Azerbaijan (Table 8)). Statutory rates of corporation tax have fallen considerably (Table 9), from 42.2 percent, on average, to 32 percent. In most of these countries,68 the loss of revenue has been smaller than the rate reduction alone would imply, suggesting that—again unlike the broader set of all low-income countries—these reductions were accompanied by either a significant supply response or some tightening of tax exemptions. Nevertheless, it seems likely that corporate tax revenues will continue to come under pressure: corporate tax rates continue to fall around the world, and the current rates in the mature stabilizer sample are high relative to the 12.5 percent in Ireland and similarly low rates in the EU accession countries. Mitigating this pressure requires avoiding excessive exemptions, such as tax holidays and direct tax breaks for exporters, that not only seem to do little to attract investment but also erode revenue both directly and by creating avoidance opportunities. The most effective way for countries to avoid giving excessive exemptions may be by entering regional agreements, not least because regional trade integration sharpens internal competition for FDI (as with Tanzania within the East African Community). Experience in the EU suggests that issues of corporate tax coordination are best addressed early in the integration process.

Table 9.

Selected VAT and CIT Indicators 1/

article image
Sources: World Economic Outlook (IMF); Statistical Annexes (IMF, various issues); Technical Assistance Reports (IMF, various issues); KPMG Worldwide Corporate Tax Rates Survey (various issues).

n.a.: not applicable or not available.

Average of two years for all countries and 1999 for Guyana.

Depending on data availability, the average represents two consecutive years between 1990 and 1994.