Designing Labor Market Institutions in Emerging and Developing Economies
Evidence and Policy Options
Author:
Mr. Romain A Duval
Search for other papers by Mr. Romain A Duval in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-2775-7172
and
Mr. Prakash Loungani
Search for other papers by Mr. Prakash Loungani in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: RDuval@imf.org; PLoungani@imf.org

This paper discusses theoretical aspects and evidences related to designing labor market institutions in emerging market and developing economies. This note reviews the state of theory and evidence on the design of labor market institutions in a developing economy context and then reviews its consistency with actual labor market advice in a selected set of emerging and developing economies. The focus is mainly on three broad sets of institutions that matter for both workers’ protection and labor market efficiency: employment protection, unemployment insurance and social assistance, minimum wages and collective bargaining. Text mining techniques are used to identify IMF recommendations in these areas in Article IV Reports for 30 emerging and frontier economies over 2005–2016. This note has provided a critical review of the literature on the design of labor market institutions in emerging and developing market economies, and benchmarked the advice featured in IMF recommendations for 30 emerging market and frontier economies against the tentative conclusions from the literature.

Abstract

This paper discusses theoretical aspects and evidences related to designing labor market institutions in emerging market and developing economies. This note reviews the state of theory and evidence on the design of labor market institutions in a developing economy context and then reviews its consistency with actual labor market advice in a selected set of emerging and developing economies. The focus is mainly on three broad sets of institutions that matter for both workers’ protection and labor market efficiency: employment protection, unemployment insurance and social assistance, minimum wages and collective bargaining. Text mining techniques are used to identify IMF recommendations in these areas in Article IV Reports for 30 emerging and frontier economies over 2005–2016. This note has provided a critical review of the literature on the design of labor market institutions in emerging and developing market economies, and benchmarked the advice featured in IMF recommendations for 30 emerging market and frontier economies against the tentative conclusions from the literature.

Executive Summary

As they try to close gaps in living standards with advanced economies, emerging market and developing economies face the challenge of providing greater social protection to workers while preserving economic efficiency and growth. Building sound labor market institutions is a key part of this agenda. It is also a challenging one; the need for such institutions and the risks of policy failure are both greater in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies.

This note reviews the state of theory and evidence on the design of labor market institutions in a developing economy context and then reviews its consistency with actual labor market advice in a selected set of emerging and developing economies. The focus is mainly on three broad sets of institutions that matter for both workers’ protection and labor market efficiency: (1) employment protection, (2) unemployment insurance and social assistance, (3) minimum wages and collective bargaining. Text mining techniques are used to identify IMF recommendations in these areas in Article IV Reports for 30 emerging and frontier economies over 2005–16. Keeping in mind that IMF recommendations are shaped not only by efficiency and equity objectives (the focus of this note) but also by political economy, technical capacity, and fiscal sustainability constraints, the main findings are as follows:

  • Overall, advice has been broadly consistent with the available consensus on how to foster flexibility while strengthening safety nets; for example, in advocating reliance on worker rather than job protection. The advice has evolved along with the increasing emphasis on the need for more inclusive growth.

  • At the same time, scope remains for better integrating efficiency and equity considerations, accounting for interactions between different policy areas, and considering more specific policies in each area.

  • On unemployment insurance, the advice has focused primarily on strengthening social safety nets. In the future, greater attention could be paid to the design features of unemployment insurance systems; how they could be scaled up over time; and the need to complement them with well-designed tax systems, active labor market policies, and broader policies to curb informality.

  • On employment protection, while advice to ease legislation in many countries is broadly consistent with existing evidence, the focus has often been on reducing severance pay. Reducing uncertainty about the cost and duration of firing procedures might be more important. In the future, the policy stance in this area could be linked to the buildup of unemployment insurance—as the latter is put in place, employment protection could be scaled back.

  • On minimum wages, growing attention has recently been paid to reducing inequality, which is a welcome development. When advocating the scaling down of minimum wages for efficiency reasons, governments and advisors could more systematically provide alternative options—such as cash transfers or income tax credits—to meet their equity goals.

  • On collective bargaining, different (more or less centralized) systems can in principle achieve efficiency and equity, so analysis should focus on the detailed features needed for a given system to deliver, for example, the required degree of representativeness, coordination, and trust between bargaining parties.

Introduction

1. The overarching goal of labor market policies and institutions is to deliver high and stable employment and productivity (efficiency) while providing adequate protection to workers (equity). The goal is easy to state but difficult to fulfill; this is true in advanced economies and even more so in emerging market and developing economies. Efficiency needs still loom large in emerging market and developing economies as they try to close the income gap with advanced economies. At the same time, workers in these economies, particularly lower-income workers, often lack basic protections, so considerations of equity cannot easily be set aside on the path to more efficiency. What is known about the optimal design of labor market institutions and policies in emerging market and developing economies? And what advice have these countries received from the IMF on these issues?

2. To shed some light on these questions, the analysis in this note proceeds in two steps. First, based on our reading of the theoretical and empirical literature, general policy lessons are drawn about how to (re)design labor market institutions in emerging market and developing economies, focusing on issues of greatest relevance to the more advanced among them: emerging market and frontier economies. The note examines the details of each institution, the interactions among them, and the need to adjust them over time as the country develops. Second, it identifies IMF recommendations to 30 emerging market and frontier economies on labor market policies over the period 2005–16. These recommendations are then benchmarked against the general lessons from the literature review. The structure of the note is thus comparable to Blanchard, Jaumotte, and Loungani (2013), who carried out a similar exercise for advanced economies.

3. The focus is on three broad sets of institutions that matter for both workers’ protection and labor market efficiency: (1) employment protection legislation (EPL), (2) unemployment insurance (UI) and social assistance, and (3) minimum wages and collective bargaining. These institutions interact with other labor market policies such as labor taxation and active labor market policies, which are also touched on. This note does not cover social welfare systems in general (for example, pension or health), whose design raises a host of issues that go beyond the scope of this paper.

4. For advanced economies, Blanchard and others (2013) discuss how these institutions can be designed to provide the flexibility—micro and macro—needed for efficiency while also keeping equity in mind. For microflexibility (the economy’s ability to carry out the reallocation of workers to jobs needed for productivity growth), the key institutions are UI and EPL, which countries combine in different ways. The Nordic combination of moderate employment protection and high unemployment benefits (flexicurity), but with strong active labor market policies (activation policies) to get the unemployed back into work, is a beacon for many countries. For macroflexibility (the ability to maintain employment at a high level, particularly in the face of large economic shocks such as loss of competitiveness or major recessions), the critical institutions are minimum wages and collective bargaining. Minimum wages obviously serve a distributional purpose but they can have adverse effects on efficiency, particularly on the employment of low-skilled workers. On collective bargaining, Blanchard and others (2013) argue that in theory a combination of national and firm-level bargaining seems attractive—the former provides a mechanism for economy-wide changes in wages when an adjustment is needed, and the latter provides a way to allow some differentiation across “space” (firms, sectors, regions). In practice, however, if trust exists among social partners, other collective bargaining structures can also deliver macroflexibility.

5. How much of this framework and how many of these prescriptions carry over to the case of emerging market and developing economies? On a broad level, the distinction between micro- and macroflexibility is useful. Emerging market and developing economies typically need more of both types of labor market flexibility than advanced economies: they have greater needs for carrying out sectoral reallocation of labor, and their economies are typically subject to larger macroeconomic shocks. However, the “separation” proposed by Blanchard and others (2013), whereby certain institutions matter more for microflexibility and others more for macroflexibility, does not hold so well for emerging market and developing economies. In particular, the setting of minimum wages and the structure of collective bargaining can play a comparatively stronger role even in determining microflexibility.

6. Going beyond these general observations, the specific findings are summarized below under three headings: (1) the combination of UI and EPL, (2) the role of minimum wages and collective bargaining, and (3) benchmarking IMF recommendations against the lessons from the literature.

Combination of UI and EPL

  • The need for labor market institutions that provide insurance against the risk of income loss is greater in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies. However, risks of policy failure are also greater owing to widespread informality and limited administrative capacity. This implies that emerging market and developing economies typically end up with a more restricted set of policy choices than advanced economies, often resulting in both more distortive and less protective policies. In particular, insurance against income loss tends to rely relatively more on distortionary policies (such as overly stringent EPL, which protects only a fraction of formal, regular workers) than on broad-based UI. As countries develop and informality is reduced, the case can be made for gradually rebalancing labor market institutions away from EPL toward UI; that is, expanding UI while converging toward less stringent, simpler, more predictable, and more homogenous EPL.

  • Such gradual rebalancing requires that UI systems be well designed and complemented by other policies to contain the risks of moral hazard. Individual UI savings accounts can play a role, supplemented by a redistributive component to achieve government’s equity objectives. So can complementary policies that help reduce informality, including other labor market and tax policy reforms. While administrative capacity is being enhanced, well-designed cash transfers (which do not involve complex monitoring and enforcement of job search and work availability criteria) can be a cost-effective way of providing income support targeted to the poor.

Role of minimum wages and collective bargaining

  • Statutory minimum wages are helpful to alleviate in-work poverty and reduce income inequality. At the same time, poor targeting and the possible adverse effects on formal (if not overall) employment if they are set too high suggest that minimum wages should be complemented by other, better targeted tools. These might include cash transfer programs or, where possible, earned income tax credits.

  • Collective bargaining can play a useful complementary role in setting wage and broader working conditions, at least at the firm level. For bargaining at a higher level (for example, industry or regional), stricter conditions arguably have to be met to enhance equity without undermining efficiency, including a high degree of representativeness, coordination, and trust between bargaining parties. These conditions are typically much more difficult to meet in emerging market and developing economies than in those advanced economies with deep social dialogue roots, making it harder to make sector-level bargaining work.

IMF recommendations

  • Overall, IMF recommendations have been broadly consistent with the available consensus on how to foster flexibility while strengthening safety nets. They have also evolved over time along with the increasing emphasis on inclusive growth. Advice has included introducing or expanding UI systems in a number of cases and, more strongly and more often, easing EPL. At the same time, the complementarity of UI with active labor market policies and the need to consider the design of UI and EPL in tandem have not received much attention.

  • While the pervasiveness of informality is often mentioned, the issue of how best to design labor market institutions (UI, EPL, and the level of the minimum wage) in the presence of informality has not been tackled in depth so far. Focusing on this issue will help enhance the granularity of future labor market policy advice.

  • Advice on collective bargaining is becoming prominent in the IMF’s labor prescriptions, including those for some emerging market and developing economies. The key in this area is to focus on the detailed features that can make the difference between a functioning and a dysfunctional system, most crucially for sector-level bargaining.

  • Efficiency and equity considerations are being integrated into the provision of advice on labor markets, consistent with the increasing emphasis on inclusive growth. For example, recommendations on lowering or restraining the growth of the minimum wage for efficiency considerations are more likely than in the past to include a discussion of alternative ways of supporting workers.

7. The remainder of this note is organized as follows. The next section examines available theory and evidence on the design of labor market institutions in emerging market and developing economies. The following section identifies IMF recommendations for the sample of countries over 2005–16 and benchmarks them against the literature. The final section concludes.

Designing Labor Market Institutions in Emerging Market and Developing Economies: Theory and Evidence

A. Are Emerging Market and Developing Economies Special?

8. Labor market institutions provide (various forms of) insurance against the risk of income loss, and they often pursue inequality and poverty reduction objectives, either explicitly (for example, social assistance programs) or implicitly (for example, UI systems that entail de facto income redistribution toward groups at higher risk of income loss).

9. Because equity objectives can in principle be pursued through other policy tools (for example, the tax system), efficiency arguments have provided the strongest theoretical rationale for labor market institutions. The following market failures and imperfections provide a rationale for public policy intervention.

  • Information asymmetries. Information regarding job loss risk and job search effort is asymmetric, creating moral hazard and risks of adverse selection.2 As a result, private UI markets may fail or remain underdeveloped, as has been the case even for advanced economies in which public UI provisions are not generous. Credit constraints imply that self-insurance is an imperfect substitute, even leaving aside the fact that it provides no risk sharing. These limits to insurance and credit markets yield a clear case for a collective UI system to smooth consumption (Blanchard and Tirole 2008; Chetty 2008). Likewise, minimum wages can help overcome moral hazard by acting as “efficiency wages” that motivate workers and boost their productivity.

  • Externalities. Insofar as a collective unemployment benefit system is needed, laying off a worker imposes a financial cost on society that the firm does not internalize. This provides a case for layoff taxes (Blanchard and Tirole 2008).3

  • Transaction costs. The state can in principle collect contributions to a benefit system and distribute benefits more cost-effectively than a private agency can because it already runs tax and spending policies and thus has established administrative capacity (for example, information records regarding taxpayers and spending recipients, tax collection, and benefit distribution vehicles).4

  • Monopsony power of firms and other risks of employer abuse owing to uneven bargaining power. This situation provides a rationale for minimum wages and labor regulations.

10. The case for addressing market failures needs to be weighed against the risk of policy failure. For example, although the risk of moral hazard can be potentially better contained under a public UI scheme than under a private one, it is always a concern, as monitoring is intrinsically imperfect and costly. This concern is compounded by the broader risk that policy design might be far from optimal, reflecting pressures from interest groups and, more generally, the nature of the political decision process. For example, EPL typically does not come in the form of layoff taxes but instead often consists of distortive administrative constraints and procedures regarding layoffs. Likewise, collective bargaining systems might be partly designed by and for large firms, with adverse effects on small and medium-sized enterprises. As for minimum wages, they are often the subject of politically heated debate, which can lead to excessively high or low levels.

11. A defining feature of emerging market and developing economies is that both market failures and policy failures are larger than in advanced economies. Larger insurance and credit market imperfections and less personal wealth available for consumption smoothing mean that the potential welfare gains from UI are greater in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies (Chetty and Looney 2006). At the same time, the risks of policy failure are substantially greater for two reasons. The first reason is that limited administrative capacity makes it harder to raise dedicated tax revenue (for example, to finance UI and other types of benefits); to provide benefits (for example, reaching out to potential recipients); to monitor recipients (for example, of UI benefits); and to enforce the law (for example, EPL). The second reason is that widespread informality, whatever its causes, compounds the administrative capacity issue (for example, monitoring job searches of UI recipients).

12. The risks of policy failure owing to informality and limited administrative capacity imply that emerging market and developing economies typically face a more restricted set of policy choices than advanced economies, even though the case for policy intervention is greater for the former. For example, while economic theory provides a case for protecting workers through UI rather than protecting jobs through EPL, in practice it is difficult to extend social protection coverage without creating important distortions in many emerging market and developing economies. Giving (noncontributory) informal workers access to social benefits financed by formal workers undermines formal work incentives both directly (by creating a wedge between informal and formal sector pay) and indirectly (by putting upward pressure on social spending and formal labor taxation, and thereby the wedge). These distortions are amplified when benefit receipt has an adverse effect on labor supply (as is the case with UI benefits but not health benefits, for example) and recipients cannot be properly monitored. As a result, policymakers are often restricted to a few suboptimal options; namely, covering (1) only formal workers, (2) both formal and informal workers but with high benefits and high distortions, or (3) both formal and informal workers but with low benefits and low distortions, often supplemented with tight, distortive, or poorly enforced EPL restricted to the formal sector.

13. These considerations, over and above general lessons from advanced economies’ experience, guided our analysis of how to design and sequence the buildup of labor market institutions in emerging market and developing economies.5

B. Unemployment Insurance and Social Assistance

UI: Key design challenges and lessons in an emerging market and developing economy context

14. UI can enhance the individual and social welfare of risk-averse workers by smoothing consumption in the presence of credit and insurance market failures, particularly in emerging market and developing economies, where such failures are typically greater (Chetty 2008; Chetty and Looney 2006). By addressing credit constraints, UI also enables the unemployed to look for better jobs that match their skills; this can improve the quality of job matches and, ultimately, productivity (Marimon and Zilibotti 1999; Tatsiramos 2009). By providing insurance to risk-averse workers, UI can also induce them to take greater risks—seeking higher-paying but higher-unemployment-risk jobs—and thereby raise aggregate output through this risk-taking channel (Acemoglu and Shimer 1999).

15. While these arguments provide a case for unemployment benefits, they do not imply that full insurance—a 100 percent replacement rate for the duration of the unemployment period— would be optimal, particularly in the case of emerging market and developing economies. This is because the choice of benefit levels and duration must strike a balance between, on the one hand, providing income loss insurance and, on the other hand, maintaining job search incentives and avoiding excessive wage levels to ensure continued low unemployment (see, for example, Blanchard and Tirole 2008).6 These issues are compounded in emerging market and developing economies, where risks of moral hazard may be stronger than in advanced economies (and therefore optimal UI generosity may be less) for two complementary reasons: (1) poorer monitoring and enforcement of eligibility and job search criteria,7 and (2) greater opportunities for the unemployed to take up an informal job while collecting UI benefits, which may further lower incentives to search for a formal job (Alvarez-Parra and Sanchez 2009; Hopenhayn and Nicolini 1999).8 This situation calls for keeping benefit generosity lower in emerging market and developing economies and enhancing it only gradually along the development path as administrative capacity improves and informality declines. At the same time, provided they are of short duration, UI benefits can enhance rather than weaken job search by increasing the income of unemployed persons and thereby enabling them to devote less time to informal work and more time to securing a job in the formal sector (Bardey, Jaramillo, and Pena 2015).9 This is likely to be most relevant for low-income, credit-constrained individuals, which argues for granting them higher benefit replacement rates, all else equal.

16. These considerations go a long way toward explaining why UI coverage and generosity are typically much lower in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies. While UI systems exist in virtually all advanced economies, they have been introduced in only a small number of emerging market economies and an even smaller number of low-income countries (Figure 1). Likewise, among those countries where a UI system exists, benefit coverage is much greater in advanced economies than in emerging market economies and low-income countries (Figure 2).

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Share of Countries with an Unemployment Insurance System

(2014, by country income group, percent)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Sources: Author calculations; and International Labour Organization (2014).
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Unemployment Benefit Coverage

(2013, percentage of unemployed workers receiving benefits, by country income group)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Sources: Author calculations; and International Labour Organization (2014).

17. One way to enhance UI provision in emerging market and developing economies—and in general—without creating significant economic distortions is to rely on unemployment individual savings accounts (UISAs). In the canonical version, under which benefits are financed solely through mandatory individual savings, workers incur the full cost from drawing down their accounts, unlike under a conventional UI system, in which risk pooling across workers induces job search disincentives as workers do not fully internalize the social cost of benefit receipt (for theory, see, for example, Brown, Orszag, and Snower 2008; for empirical evidence on Chile, where UISAs and a UI system coexist, see Hartley, Van Ours, and Vodopivec 2011).10 Also, because contributions to UISAs represent individual savings while contributions to a UI system are typically perceived at least in part as taxation, the former are more likely to reduce reservation wages compared with the latter, thereby increasing labor demand.

18. UISAs come with two important limitations, however. First, if they are poorly designed, they might undermine some other dimensions of economic efficiency by creating distortions. For example, they might foster excessive labor turnover if workers are myopic or credit-constrained, or get below-market-rate returns on their savings and therefore seek to run down their accounts for other purposes—as seems to have happened in Brazil (see, for example, Ribe, Robalino, and Walker 2010). Second, and more fundamentally, UISAs may not provide sufficient insurance for certain categories of workers. When UISAs are financed solely through individual contributions, even a 15 percent contribution rate on wages and a 7 percent rate of return on savings provides only about four months of benefits in the event of job loss after two years of work. This is unlikely to provide sufficient coverage to workers with shorter contribution periods and greater unemployment risk, such as young, unskilled workers. Countries in which UISAs exist (for example, Chile) have maintained some degree of risk pooling through a state-provided UI system.11

19. So how can the twin and conflicting goals of expanding UI coverage and preserving work (as well as saving and insurance) incentives be achieved against the background of weak administrative capacity and pervasive informality? One way forward for UI and social protection schemes more broadly could be to move gradually toward a two-tier system featuring (1) a mandatory, nonredistributive first tier fully funded by individual contributions (for example UISAs) and (2) as a complement, transparent and progressive subsidies, financed through general taxation, to enhance coverage of low-income workers with limited saving capacity, including by encouraging informal workers to opt into the contributory system. This approach is roughly in line with World Bank advice for Latin America and the Caribbean (Ribe and others 2010).

20. A two-tier system would minimize, although not fully eliminate, the efficiency cost of extending insurance coverage. The first tier (UISAs) would minimize disincentive problems for formal workers. The second tier (the redistributive component) would achieve its inequality and poverty reduction objectives without discouraging informal workers from taking formal jobs. Compared with a standard risk-pooling system—under which redistribution is less transparent, less controlled, and therefore less well targeted—this approach would yield efficiency gains through better targeting and lower labor tax wedges.12 Some efficiency costs would remain, however, owing to the effective marginal tax rate stemming from subsidy withdrawal as individual income goes up. These costs can be reduced by avoiding threshold effects arising from kinks in the subsidy withdrawal rate.

Complementary policies to make UI systems work

21. The efficiency of UI systems depends not just on their design features but also on the implementation of complementary policies to address informality, measures to activate benefit recipients, and tax policies that keep the distortions created by the financing of the system at low levels. The more of such policies in place, the smaller the economic distortions caused by unemployment insurance are likely to be, which allows the system to cover more people and provide more generous benefits. In introducing or expanding UI, it is crucial to exploit these complementarities between different policies and institutions.

22. Informality must be reduced over time and administrative capacity enhanced as the government expands the coverage and generosity of the UI system. The causes of informality are numerous and complex; some of them, such as low productivity of certain activities or low optimal firm size, are outside the immediate reach of governments and can be addressed only gradually as economic development proceeds (Kanbur 2015). However, governments can and should address the regulatory causes of informality, including those arising from labor market policies and institutions. These include EPL, minimum wages, and labor taxation (discussed below), but also the provision of social insurance, including UI. Depending on how the UI system is designed, the buildup of UI might reduce or increase informality, reflecting two offsetting forces (Bosch and Esteban-Pretel 2012). UI makes it more attractive for workers to find a formal job, but financing UI through labor taxation increases informality.13 Ribe and others (2010) suggest that the latter effect dominated when UI was introduced in Mexico.

23. High labor tax wedges can reduce formal employment and possibly overall employment in emerging market and developing economies (Betcherman, Daysal, and Pagés 2010; Heckman and Pagés 2004; Kugler and Kugler 2009; Kugler, Kugler, and Herrera 2017). Binding minimum wages, in particular, increase the pass-through from payroll taxes onto labor costs. They should be reduced where they are high in comparison with other nations and kept low elsewhere; other, less distortive sources of financing should be considered. Even though social protection systems are much less developed in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies, average labor tax wedges (which include employer and employee social contributions as well as personal income taxes) are largely similar, although wide variation exists among countries. A 2010 World Bank study (Ribe and others 2010) puts the worldwide emerging market and developing economy average at about 35 percent, fairly close to the average tax wedge across Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) member countries (OECD 2010). Much scope exists for shifting the burden of taxation away from labor toward other taxes in most emerging market and developing economies. For example, consumption taxes are less likely than labor taxes to distort the decision to create and take up formal versus informal jobs, as they equally affect formal and informal workers; this is a further argument in favor of introducing or extending the use of Value-Added Taxes (VAT) in emerging market and developing economies, over and above its many other merits.14 Other tax and spending reforms also have a role to play to reduce labor taxation, such as broadening tax bases in the context of a simplification of the tax code or cutting inefficient public spending, including in categories (such as energy subsidies) that have been used as highly inefficient de facto social transfer schemes.

24. Finally, a well-functioning UI system can help and incentivize benefit recipients to look for jobs through strong enforcement of job search requirements and well-designed active labor market policies. The more effectively job search is supported and encouraged, the smaller the adverse incentive effects of UI and the more generous the system can be. Advanced economies that have managed to provide generous benefits while keeping employment levels high, such as some Nordic countries, have typically put strong emphasis on activation: the so-called flexi-security model (see, for example, OECD 2006, 2018). The difficulty of designing and implementing effective active labor market policies in emerging market and developing economies may result in lower UI benefit levels and shorter duration of benefits than in advanced economies. However, for a given degree of UI generosity, developing active labor market policies in parallel with the buildup of UI schemes might be even more important in emerging market and developing economies than it is in advanced economies for two reasons: (1) mandatory participation in active labor market programs (for example, job search activities) can partly substitute for job search monitoring—which is plagued by weak administrative capacity—and thereby help ensure that the unemployed do not work in the informal sector while receiving benefits; and (2) such programs can strengthen the insertion and labor market attachment of the most vulnerable categories of job seekers (youth and those with low skill levels) and, more broadly, help reduce locational, sectoral, and job mismatches.

25. For an active labor market policy to pass a cost-benefit analysis test, it must explicitly target well-identified labor market failures. While this sounds obvious, the evidence suggests that many programs have not met this simple criterion. The booming literature on the impact of active labor market policies on employment and income has so far produced mixed results for both advanced economies and emerging market and developing economies (for recent reviews, see, for example, Crepon and van den Berg 2016, and McKenzie 2017). Returns on individual programs have been widely heterogeneous, even leaving aside thorny issues such as scalability or displacement effects.15 Tentative evidence exists that certain interventions, such as those that target geographical and sectoral mobility, may work better than others, but much more research is needed before general lessons can be drawn with any degree of confidence. Meanwhile, a sensible policy approach is to evaluate programs systematically, discard those that fail to pass a cost-benefit test, and gradually scale up and reassess those that do.

Social assistance and cash transfers

26. Cash transfers, a form of social assistance that provides financial support to the poor, can complement UI. However, they are often used as a substitute in many emerging market and developing economies, where the UI systems are still in their infancy. In the presence of weak administrative capacity, well-designed cash transfers can be a cost-effective (less distortive and better targeted) way of providing income support to the poor. They can be unconditional (for example, Dibao in China) or conditional, typically on participation in education or health programs (for example, Bolsa Familia in Brazil). Sizable and well-designed cash transfer programs can reduce poverty; if they are complemented by quality government programs, they can also enhance investment in education and health.

27. An important challenge is to design such schemes to minimize any work disincentives that might arise directly from benefit receipt itself or indirectly from its financing. According to conventional labor supply theory, benefit receipt could induce adverse income and substitution effects on participation in the formal job market. Higher income increases demand for leisure, while benefit receipt (means-tested or conditional on not working) increases the marginal tax rate if the individual takes up or increases hours of formal work. These effects are likely to be small, as benefit levels are often fairly modest,16 target a population (the poor) whose leisure elasticity to income is small, are typically unconditional on labor market status, and are seldom carefully means-tested owing to weak administrative and enforcement capacity. Furthermore, cash transfers might improve the formal labor force participation of the poorest by easing their liquidity constraints and enabling them to devote some time to job search (see, for example, OECD 2011). Nonetheless, benefit levels should not be set too high, and as countries develop means-testing they should be enforced in ways that minimize the substitution effect—for instance, through gradual phasing out of benefits, as is common practice in many advanced economies.17 Making some cash transfer receipts conditional on participation in well-designed training programs might also encourage labor market participation.

C. Employment Protection Legislation

The two components of EPL

28. EPL can be used to pursue multiple objectives, but a central one is to provide some insurance to workers against the risk of dismissal and thus income loss (Pissarides 2001). On this front, an important and largely undisputed role of EPL is to address noneconomic motives for dismissals and thereby protect workers against abuse and discrimination. However, the issue of whether (and, if so, how) EPL should be used to address dismissal for economic reasons is more frequently debated and central to the literature. This issue is focused on here.

29. Although the empirical literature is unsettled and still evolving (see, for example, Betcherman 2012), it has documented that EPL can have the following effects.

30. EPL has two conceptually different components, between which the empirical literature rarely discriminates: (1) a transfer component that includes, for example, severance payments or the notice of termination—the latter amounts to a transfer of information that has economic value (Pissarides 2001); and (2) a tax component that consists of all the administrative procedures involved in individual worker and collective dismissals and does not entail any transfer to the dismissed worker(s).

31. While the tax component of EPL is intrinsically distortive, the transfer component is not necessarily so. In the absence of contractual and market frictions, wage negotiation between firms and workers could be such that predictable severance payments have no effect on labor market equilibrium. Forward-looking firms internalize the expected cost of future severance pay by reducing their entry wage offer, thereby leaving the expected cumulative cost of the employment relationship unchanged (Lazear 1990; Pissarides 2001). Because it rests on strict conditions, this prediction is unlikely to hold in practice; in the absence of full contractual flexibility in the wage-setting process (that is, in the presence of wage rigidities), severance payments can have allocative effects, including on employment (Garibaldi and Violante 2005). Nonetheless, the key message from theory is that the transfer component is likely to be less distortive than the tax component.

32. Therefore, policymakers should try to keep the tax component low. What about the transfer component? Is there a case for a mandatory transfer component (essentially severance pay), and how does this case depend on the presence and design of UI?18

EPL versus UI

33. UI is conceptually superior to EPL in providing insurance against income loss. In the presence of optimal UI, theory suggests that EPL should only take the form of a layoff tax that forces firms to internalize the social cost of layoffs; there would be no case for a transfer to workers, such as severance pay, other than to compensate for the psychic cost of losing a job, which might rise with seniority (Blanchard and Tirole 2008). This is because severance pay suffers from two fundamental weaknesses relative to UI: (1) being a one-off payment to the worker, it provides no insurance against unemployment duration risk; and (2) it offers no risk sharing across workers in different firms, which, coupled with a lack of prefunding, increases the risk of nonpayment, as the likelihood of having to dismiss workers correlates negatively with the firms’ solvency and liquidity. Over and above these two serious limitations, severance pay raises further practical issues: (1) its enforcement requires a well-functioning and adequately funded administrative and judicial system, which partly explains why it is much weaker in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies; (2) litigation costs can be significant; (3) many workers do not qualify owing to short tenure or are not covered owing to informality; and (4) the growing fragmentation of work (and its corollary, the growing complexity of contractual relationships between employers and employees) calls for portability of rights across different forms of labor; that is, for protecting workers (through UI) rather than jobs (through EPL).

34. Despite the conceptual superiority of UI, the labor market institution mix in emerging market and developing economies relies comparatively more on EPL and less on UI than in advanced economies. While UI is still in its infancy in most emerging market and developing economies, the average stringency of EPL differs only marginally from that observed in advanced economies (Figure 3).19 This holds across most of the components of EPL, including both administrative procedures and, particularly, transfers to dismissed workers. The practical limitations of UI noted earlier may partly underpin the rather high average severance payments mandated by EPL in emerging market and developing economies and might contribute to the mild substitutability between UI and EPL across countries (Figure 4).20 Still, much room seems to exist for reform in this area and even more so for streamlining administrative procedures, and the tax component of EPL. Beyond the severance pay issue, most existing systems could also be better designed. In particular, deferred compensation (so-called severance savings, which can be drawn upon after any dismissal or voluntary quit) can provide more efficient income insurance than a transfer upon being laid off. This is because deferred compensation avoids nonpayment by the firm—a frequent issue in emerging market and developing economies—while delivering better employment performance (for example Heckman and Pagés 2004).

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Employment Protection Legislation for Regular Contracts: ILO EPLex Indicator and Components

(2010, scale 0–1, country income group median)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Source: International Labour Organization.Available at http://www.ilo.org/travail/areasofwork/WCMS 435450/lang--en/index.htm.Note: EPLex indicators measure the level of de jure employment protection in a given country and a given year. All indicators are distributed on a 0–1 scale. Lower values represent lower levels of de jure employment protection, while higher values represent higher levels of de jure employment protection. There are eight EPLex component indicators, each governing a specific area of employment protection: valid grounds for dismissals, prohibited grounds for dismissals, probationary period, procedural notification requirements for dismissals, notice periods, severance pay, redundancy pay, and avenues for redress.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

UI Coverage versus ILO Indicator of Job Protection for Regular Contracts

(2013 and 2010, advanced and selected emerging market and developing economies)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Sources: Author calculations; and International Labour Organization (2014, 2015).

Labor market dualism

35. Poorly designed EPL can foster labor market dualism, with adverse implications for both efficiency and income inequality. This is one important lesson for emerging market and developing economies from past experience in a number of advanced economies, where EPL for regular contracts remained largely unchanged while temporary contracts were deregulated beginning in the 1980s, in part to address demands for contractual flexibility and in part owing to political obstacles to more widespread deregulation. Such partial deregulation can foster the creation of temporary jobs and discourage their conversion into permanent ones, thereby increasing worker turnover and creating a two-tier system under which stable, regular jobs held primarily by higher-skilled prime-age workers coexist with unstable jobs held primarily by more disadvantaged groups, such as youth, migrants, and low-skilled women (see, for example, Boeri 2010; Centeno and Novo 2012). Beyond its negative impact on equity (see, for example, European Commission 2010), asymmetry between regular and temporary job protection and the resulting increase in job and worker turnover can have an adverse effect on aggregate unemployment (Blanchard and Landier 2002), on-the-job human capital accumulation, and productivity.

36. These costs of EPL fragmentation have led some to advocate a single labor contract (for example Blanchard and Tirole 2003). While this remains an aspirational goal more than actual institutional practice even in advanced economies, the general lesson is that reducing contract dualism would help reduce labor market dualism. This objective could be better supported by targeting only mild, rather than stringent, protection levels for all workers. This approach could be particularly important for emerging market and developing economies, where overly stringent job protection for regular workers can itself foster labor market fragmentation (for example, job seekers queuing for highly protected jobs in the public sector) and informality (which is ultimately an extreme form of labor market dualism that can increase inequality).21

Way forward

37. Overall, the discussion in this section suggests a strong case in emerging market and developing economies for expanding UI gradually along the economic development path while converging toward less stringent, simpler, more predictable, and more homogenous EPL. EPL should be moderate to minimize its economic costs and the adverse side effects on equity among different groups of workers. It should be simple and predictable, taking the form of well-designed severance pay rather than burdensome administrative procedures with uncertain outcomes. Finally, it should be homogenous, rather than fragmented into multiple types of contracts that provide widely different protection levels, notably for regular and temporary workers.

D. Minimum Wages and Collective Bargaining

Minimum wages

38. Minimum wages pursue two fundamental objectives. One is to address market failures and promote economic efficiency, an objective for which minimum wages are well suited provided they are well calibrated. In particular, minimum wages can alleviate risks that firms’ monopsony power might lead to excessively low market wages and employment or improve workers’ productivity in a context in which their work effort cannot be fully observed owing to information asymmetry (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984). The other objective, which is broader and more challenging, is to reduce overall inequality, for which minimum wages compete with other policy instruments, notably tax-benefit systems.

39. The effectiveness of minimum wages in reducing wage inequality and poverty is weakened by a number of factors, some of which may be more prevalent in emerging market and developing economies. One limitation is that minimum wages are rather poorly targeted; they target individuals rather than households, and employed workers rather than both employed and unemployed people. In an emerging market and developing economy context, targeting is generally even poorer, since minimum wages apply only to workers on formal jobs,22 although they can partly spill over to the informal sector by serving as a focal point for wage demands and through labor mobility—the so-called lighthouse effect (see, for example, Cunningham 2007). The smaller the share of formal workers in total employment and the less they live in poor households, or the higher the starting level of the minimum wage (which determines whether it is binding only for low-income households or for middle-income households too), the less the minimum wage reduces inequality (see, for example, Gindling 2014). A further issue in many emerging market and developing economies is low compliance among supposedly covered workers. These considerations point to complementarities between minimum wages and other policies to address informality and enhance enforcement, such as strengthening administrative capacity and legal systems.

40. The impact of minimum wages on overall inequality also depends on their employment effect, which is the main channel through which they affect economic efficiency.23 While these employment effects remain hotly debated, 24 an emerging consensus seems to be that they may be small under the levels that have historically prevailed in most countries (see, for example, Kuddo, Robalino, and Weber 2015, or more recent studies discussed in Kugler, forthcoming). But set at too-high levels, minimum wages can have adverse effects on less productive population groups such as less educated youth (Abowd and others 2000; Kramarz and Philippon 2001; Neumark and Wascher 2008).25 In emerging market and developing economies, a further issue is that the distribution of productivity levels across firms is typically much wider than in advanced economies, often as a result of various distortions in the economy (Hsieh and Klenow 2009).

41. The risks of adverse (overall or at least formal) employment effects must be considered seriously in emerging market and developing economies, as the average ratio of the minimum wage to the median wage across countries that have a minimum wage is higher than it is across advanced economies (Figure 5). This might partly reflect low absolute median wages, which means that the minimum wage needs to be set at a high relative level to fulfill its antipoverty objective. Another factor might be that minimum wages have often been used as a substitute for weak collective bargaining institutions in emerging market and developing economies (Saget 2008).

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Ratio of Minimum to Median Wage: Selected Emerging Market and Developing Economies and Advanced Economies

(2010, simple average across available countries in each country income group)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Sources: Author calculations; and International Labour Organization, ILOSTAT database).Note: The vertical axis indicates the average ratio of the statutory monthly minimum wage to the median nominal monthly earnings of all employees. Minimum wages are not reported for countries for which they are set through collective bargaining. In cases where a national minimum wage is not mandated, the minimum wage in place in the capital or major city is used. In some cases, an average of multiple regional minimum wages is used. In countries where the minimum wage is set at the sectoral or occupational level, the minimum wage for manufacturing or unskilled workers is generally applied.

42. One way to address any adverse employment effects of too high a minimum wage is to allow for differentiation across population groups, regions, or industries, particularly where productivity levels vary widely along some of these dimensions. An extreme form of differentiation is the outright exemption from the minimum wage legislation of certain categories of workers, such as youth or agricultural workers. By easing risks that less productive categories of workers might be priced out of formal employment, differentiation can also enable governments to set the standard minimum wage at a higher level than would be feasible otherwise. At the same time, a case exists for keeping differentiation simple and transparent (limited to youth, regions, or states, for example) for two reasons: (1) excessive differentiation entails administrative complexity, an acute challenge in emerging market and developing economies, where labor administration services often have low resources and enforcement is challenging, especially where informality is high; and (2) it can weaken the poverty and inequality reduction objectives of minimum wages. When a government differentiates across regions, it must take price levels into account, because the yardstick for measuring equity should be purchasing power rather than nominal minimum wages.

43. Minimum wages also need to be flexible enough to ensure employment resilience to changes in business conditions. This raises the issue of whether adjustments to the minimum wage should be discretionary or should rely on an automatic formula. The latter has the advantage of avoiding lengthy political negotiations and securing outcomes, but it can also impede or delay wage adjustment to adverse macroeconomic shocks, with adverse implications for low-skilled employment. A possible compromise might be regular reviews informed by the recommendations of an independent specialized body, whose impact could range from providing advice to legally setting minimum wages (11 percent of cases globally in 2012; see Table 9 in ILO 2013).

44. In principle, minimum wages set through collective bargaining rather than statutory decisions could bring about the needed differentiation and flexibility, but this is typically even harder to achieve in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies. To start with, collective bargaining is less widespread in emerging market and developing economies than it is in advanced economies. According to the International Labour Organization (ILO), only two of the 12 countries in which minimum wages are set by social partners are emerging market and developing economies (Eritrea and Namibia). Setting minimum wages through collective bargaining requires some degree of bargaining centralization, which in turn makes it more difficult to ensure that wages are tailored to local economic conditions except under a high degree of representativeness, coordination, and trust between bargaining parties (see IMF 2016). These conditions are difficult to meet in general but more so in emerging market and developing economies than in advanced economies.

Collective bargaining

45. Union density and collective bargaining coverage rates are far lower on average across emerging market and developing economies than across advanced economies, partly reflecting generally weaker organization of labor (Figures 6 and 7). Bargaining coverage—the share of workers covered by a collective agreement—generally depends on the extent of worker unionization (union density); the predominant level(s) at which negotiations take place (for example, firm, industry, or national); and government policies, notably regarding administrative extensions of collective agreements. Considering the whole workforce rather than just formal sector workers, effective coverage also depends on the degree of informality. Formal sector bargaining coverage is generally low across Asia but widely heterogeneous across countries in Africa and Latin America. In Latin America, coverage has also varied widely over time as a result of shifts in government policies, including toward unions.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Union Density Rates

(2013 or latest available year, percent, simple average across available countries in each country income group)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Sources: Author calculations; and International Labour Organization, ILOSTAT database).
Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Collective Bargaining Coverage

(Early 2010s/late 2000s, percentage of salaried employees covered by a collective agreement, simple average across available countries in each country income group)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2019, 004; 10.5089/9781498313261.006.A001

Sources: Author calculations; and International Labour Organization, ILOSTAT database).Note: The collective bargaining coverage rate measures the number of (formal) employees whose pay and/or conditions of employment ar determined by one or more collective agreement(s) as a percentage of the total number of (formal) employees. Collective bargaining coverage includes, to the extent possible, workers covered by collective agreements in virtue of their extension. Collective bargaining coverage rates are adjusted for the possibility that some workers do not have the right to bargain collectively over wages (for example, workers in the public services who have their wages determined by state regulation or other methods involving consultation).

46. Collective bargaining can improve productivity through various means; for example, by strengthening the functioning of internal labor markets, delivering otherwise underprovided local public goods (such as workplace safety), and addressing other market failures (such as the appropriability problem in general training) (see, for example, Freeman and Medoff 1984). Unions can also help reduce horizontal wage inequality between comparable workers, such as men and women (see, for example, Blau and Kahn 1996; Felgueroso, Perez-Villadoniga, and Prieto-Rodriguez 2008; Hartog, Leuven, and Teulings 2002), as well as overall wage and income inequality (see, for example, Freeman 2010; Jaumotte and Osorio-Buitron 2015). Unions can also complement the role of tax and public spending policies.

47. At the same time, a collective bargaining system needs to deliver both macro- and microflexibility, as noted in the introduction. Lack of such flexibility can lead to inefficient (re)allocation of resources across firms and industries and impede the adjustment of working conditions to shocks, thereby undermining productivity as well as the level and stability of employment.

48. What is known about the practical design features of collective bargaining systems that deliver macro- and microflexibility? One dimension that has received a lot of attention in the literature is the level at which bargaining takes place. Like advanced economies, emerging market and developing economies show wide cross-country heterogeneity in the primary level of bargaining, with an overall trend toward decentralization. This is especially true in Latin America, where centralized bargaining is important in several countries, such as Argentina and Uruguay (see, for example, Lamarche 2015). The “hump-shaped hypothesis” put forward by Calmfors and Driffill (1988) held that highly centralized systems (through macroflexibility achieved by inducing unions to internalize the effects of too-high wage claims on economy-wide employment) and decentralized systems (through microflexibility of wages at the firm level) would outperform sector-level bargaining. However, available evidence regarding the hump-shaped hypothesis has been rather mixed. In advanced economies, experiences have diverged noticeably among countries in which sector-level bargaining is widespread, partly because some systems (Germany, Japan, Netherlands, Scandinavian countries) have achieved greater coordination or have provided for higher flexibility at the firm level (for example, through the use of so-called opening clauses)26 than others (for example, Portugal or Spain).27 In emerging market economies, available evidence from the major policy-driven decentralization that took place in Argentina and Uruguay in the early 1990s points to a positive impact of firm-level bargaining on productivity (Cassoni, Labadie, and Fachola 2005; Lamarche 2013). Overall, the emerging evidence suggests that, at a minimum, industry-level bargaining systems need to provide for some flexibility at the firm level.

49. Another important and controversial issue has been the role of administrative extensions of collective agreements, which enlarge coverage beyond the members of negotiating parties to all workers in a sector, thereby increasing overall bargaining coverage rates. Extensions are widespread in some European countries, and they play an important role in some emerging market economies, such as in South Africa. They can help reduce transaction costs (especially for small firms, for which bargaining would be costly) and avoid a “race to the bottom” among firms on working conditions. However, by design, they undermine firm-level flexibility by imposing similar working conditions across firms. There is mounting empirical evidence of adverse employment effects of administrative extensions in both advanced economies and emerging market and developing economies (Diez-Catalan and Villanueva 2015; Hijzen and Martins 2016; Magruder, 2012; Martins 2014). Therefore, any use of extensions should ensure that extended provisions do not harm a significant fraction of firms. Extending only agreements that meet stringent union and employer association representativeness criteria can mitigate adverse employment effects (Hijzen and Martins 2016). Retaining some discretionary power on the extension decision, to be used when rapid macroeconomic adjustment is needed, can also help. More research is needed on these issues and in many other areas of collective bargaining, including the elusive but seemingly important role of trust between social partners for macro- and microflexibility (Blanchard and others 2013; IMF 2016).

Way forward

50. To sum up, statutory minimum wages are helpful to alleviate in-work poverty and to reduce income inequality. At the same time, poor targeting and possible adverse effects on formal employment if they are set too high suggest that they might not be the most effective public policy tool and should be complemented by other, better targeted ones. Simple, limited differentiation by regions or population groups (for example, substandard rates for youth) can ease this tension and enable governments to set standard rates higher than would otherwise be possible without hurting the job opportunities of disadvantaged workers. Perhaps even more important, a case can be made for complementing minimum wages with other, better targeted tools, such as conditional or unconditional cash transfer programs or wage subsidies (see, for example, Cahuc and Carcillo 2015), or earned income tax credits where possible. For instance, Barros and others (2010) argue that for a given resource transfer, the Bolsa Familia program in Brazil was more effective than minimum wage increases in reducing poverty and income inequality. As for earned income tax credits, they have been used extensively as a complement to minimum wages in advanced economies and could be deployed more widely in more advanced emerging market and developing economies, where administrative capacity is strong enough to support their use.

51. Collective bargaining can play a useful complementary role in setting wage and broader working conditions, especially if it takes place at the firm level. For bargaining at a higher level (for example, industry or regional) to enhance equity without undermining efficiency, strict conditions would have to be met, including a high degree of representativeness, coordination, and trust between bargaining parties. These conditions are more likely to exist in advanced economies in which social dialogue has deep roots (for example, in northern European countries) than in emerging market and developing economies.

IMF Advice for Emerging Market and Developing Economies, 2005–16

52. In recent years, the IMF has placed increased emphasis on analysis of labor market issues as part of its attempt to nurture inclusive growth in economies. In 2011, IMF management set up a Jobs and Growth group to enhance its work on these topics. In its paper to the IMF Executive Board, the group noted that while many emerging market and developing economies had enjoyed fairly solid growth, the benefits of that growth had not always been equitably shared—a cause of concern to governments in many of these countries.

53. In addition to the work of the Jobs and Growth group, the IMF has conducted research in recent years into the adverse effects of excessive inequality and lack of gender equality on the macroeconomy. In the labor market, inequality is reflected in the creation of dual labor markets, through which some groups of workers are excluded from access to and benefits of decent jobs enjoyed by others. The IMF has started to operationalize this research; that is, to incorporate the findings into IMF advice at the country level.

54. In short, over the past few years, the IMF has made a concerted effort to better integrate efficiency and equity considerations into its advice to countries. This section describes how IMF advice on labor market issues has begun to reflect this integration.

55. The task of cataloging IMF advice is very labor intensive. This note could not cover the full set of emerging market and developing economies so it studies a sample of countries, using the Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI) definitions of emerging and frontier markets. Table 1 lists the countries in these two groups and indicates the 20 emerging and 10 frontier markets covered. The MSCI definition of emerging markets includes some economies that are classified as advanced in terms of their per capita income (including in the IMF’s World Economic Outlook classification); however, their labor markets share many characteristics with those of emerging markets and thus belong in this study. The sample does not contain countries with very low per capita incomes, so the findings cannot be generalized to such countries.

Table 1.

MSCI Emerging and Frontier Market Countries

(Economies included in the sample are in bold italics)

article image

56. Text mining techniques were used to extract references to labor market institutions in Article IV Reports from 2005 through 2016. Then the extracts were reviewed and IMF policy advice was sifted out from routine descriptions of labor market developments.28 The appendix provides a condensed version of the extracts, as well as five tables describing IMF advice on (1) unemployment insurance, (2) employment protection legislation, (3) active labor market policies, (4) minimum wage, and (5) collective bargaining.

Advice on UI and EPL

57. The IMF advised about 20 percent of the countries on UI at some point over the period 2005–16, and 40 percent of countries on EPL (see Appendix Tables A1 and A2). The most common advice on UI was to set up a system or to extend benefits, while the most common advice on EPL was to lower generous severance payments. The trade-off between UI and EPL was mentioned in only a couple of cases. And while active labor market policies were recommended in about 25 percent of the countries, there was no mention that the extension of UI should be accompanied by such policies.

58. The advice to set up or extend the UI system was more common in higher-income emerging market economies than in other countries. Examples include Chile (2010, 2015), China (2015–16), Malaysia (2013, 2016), and Turkey (2007). UI was seen more as part of the necessary social safety net than as a facilitator of microflexibility;29 hence, the discussion of UI was often bundled with advice on expanding social assistance (which was recommended in about half the countries) and was often part of a broader discussion of reform of the tax and benefit system. In some cases, the advice was not for expansion of social assistance but for better targeting (Hungary, 2011; Mexico, 2015) or for replacing fuel or other subsidies with cash transfers (Indonesia, 2012; Jordan, 2012).

59. The advice on EPL focused largely on reducing high severance payments, with some exceptions (for example, Mexico, 2012). Two reasons were commonly given as the motivation for IMF staff advice.30 One was that doing so would enhance productivity through better reallocation of workers (Chile, 2009–15; Malaysia, 2012; Peru, 2006; Turkey, 2007). The other was that it would reduce informality and dualism in the labor markets (Chile, 2009–15; Indonesia, 2013; Morocco, 2011; Peru, 2006; Turkey, 2007) and would thus contribute to making growth more inclusive.

Advice on minimum wage

60. Advice on the minimum wage was pervasive: It was given in 70 percent of the country cases at least once over this period. As noted in the previous section, minimum wages (relative to median wages) tend to be higher in these economies than in advanced economies, and risks of adverse employment effects from this high level need to be taken seriously. Against this backdrop, IMF advice has been to lower the minimum wage relative to some benchmark or to limit the pace of increases to productivity growth or inflation targets.31 Examples include Brazil (2013), Colombia (2011), Serbia (2013), and Turkey (2016). In recent years, discussion increased on using the minimum wage as a tool for equity and on the efficiency–equity trade-offs posed by changes in minimum wage (for example, the Philippines in 2016 and South Africa in 2016).

61. Only modest claims were made regarding the effect such changes would have on aggregate employment, consistent with the empirical evidence. The recommendation was motivated more by the likely effect on specific groups. In many cases, the advice was to differentiate minimum wages across types of workers or regions. For instance, the IMF recommended lower minimum wages for youth and low-skilled workers relative to others in Colombia (2015) and Hungary (2014), and lower minimum wages in some regions of Malaysia (2013) and Poland (2005–06).

Advice on collective bargaining

62. Advice on collecting bargaining has become more prevalent. Such advice was given in about 25 percent of the country cases, and the incidence appears to be growing. The two countries for which advice on collective bargaining was fairly intensive were Greece (2006, 2007, and 2013) and South Africa (2005–06, 2010–14, 2016), with Argentina (2016), Chile (2015), the Philippines (2014), Poland (2007), Romania (2012), and Serbia (2014) making up the other cases. In all these cases, the recommendation was to reduce the extent of centralization of collective bargaining.

63. As discussed in Blanchard and others (2013), in some euro area countries macroflexibility was needed to correct a large competitiveness problem at a fixed nominal exchange rate. In the absence of the option of using the exchange rate to ease the adjustment, the IMF recommended achieving wage reductions through national agreements among social partners. However, such agreements were difficult to achieve or did not take place, in some instances reflecting a lack of trust between social partners. In Greece, with its poor labor relations, no deal could be struck.

64. For South Africa, which is characterized by very high unemployment rates and extensive labor market duality, the advice in 2005–06 was to relax the extension principle “to allow small firms to negotiate agreements that reflect their own economic circumstances.” In 2010, the country was in a recession, but wage settlements remained high and employment declined sharply. In staff’s view, this showed that the “wage bargaining framework is not sufficiently flexible,” and they urged changes in the framework “to allow companies to adjust more easily to economic fluctuations in a way that preserves jobs.” Over 2011–16, staff repeatedly advised changing the sector-wide wage bargaining system to exempt small and medium-sized enterprises from the wage increases “to which the more productive and deeper-pocketed large firms agree.” The IMF also called for a tripartite social accord, including wage restraint, in return for hiring commitments from industry.

Conclusions

65. Getting labor market policy right can play an important role in delivering inclusive growth; that is, growth with equity. This is especially true in emerging market and developing economies, where there is often much scope for scaling up and improving the design of labor market institutions and a strong need for more inclusive growth amid slowing productivity growth (Adler and others 2017) and high (or in some cases increasing) inequality (World Bank 2016).

66. This note has provided a critical review of the literature on the design of labor market institutions in emerging and developing market economies, and benchmarked the advice featured in IMF recommendations for 30 emerging market and frontier economies against the tentative conclusions from the literature. When set against the complexity of the issues involved, the advice is sound and consistent with the broad consensus in the literature, especially considering the fact that IMF recommendations are shaped not only by efficiency and equity objectives (which have been the focus of this note) but also by political economy, technical capacity, and fiscal sustainability constraints. The purpose and content of the advice has evolved over time, along with a growing recognition of the need for labor market and other institutions to promote more inclusive growth. Several issues are worth exploring in greater depth in considering how best to design policies:

  • On unemployment insurance, one challenge is to go beyond generic advice tied only to strengthening social safety nets. It will be increasingly important to discuss the design features of UI systems and how those systems can be scaled up over time.

  • On EPL, the focus has often been on the level of severance payments and advising that it be reduced. However, reducing uncertainty about the cost and duration of firing procedures might be more important than the level of payments. In the future, the stringency of EPL could be linked to the buildup of the benefit system: As the latter is put in place, EPL could be scaled back.

  • On minimum wages, the welcome trend in recent advice is to pay attention to equity–efficiency trade-offs. Overall wages in many emerging and frontier countries are still very low, and developmental objectives should loom large in the minds of policymakers and advisors. When minimum wages are scaled down for efficiency reasons, the process could be systematically accompanied by alternatives to meet equity goals; for example, cash transfers or, where administrative capacity exists, income tax credits.

  • On collective bargaining—a complex area in which more research is needed—it would be useful to develop a consistent view of policies that acknowledges that different collective bargaining systems can achieve efficiency and equity, and to focus on the detailed features needed for a given system to deliver in practice. In this area, as well as on other labor market policy issues, it is important to keep in step with evolving academic and policy knowledge.

References

  • Abowd, John, Francis Kramarz, Thomas Lemieux, and David Margolis. 2000. “Minimum Wages and Youth Employment in France and the United States.” In Youth Employment and Joblessness in Advanced Countries (pp. 42772). National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Acemoglu, Daron, and Robert Shimer. 1999. “Efficient Unemployment Insurance.” Journal of Political Economy 107 (5): 893928.

  • Adler, Gustavo, Romain Duval, Davide Furceri, Sinem Kilic Celik, Ksenia Koloskova, and Marcos Poplawski-Ribeiro. 2017. “Gone with the Headwinds: Global Productivity.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 17/04, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ahsan, Ahmad, and Carmen Pages. 2009. “Are All Labor Regulations Equal? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing.” Journal of Comparative Economics 37 (1): 6275.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alvarez-Parra, Fernando, and Juan Sanchez. 2009. “Unemployment Insurance with a Hidden Labor Market.” Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (7): 95467.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Autor, David, Adriana Kugler, and William Kerr. 2007. “Do Employment Protections Reduce Productivity? Evidence from U.S. States.” Economic Journal 117 (521): 189217.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bardey, David, Fernando Jaramillo, and Ximena Pena. 2015. “Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector.” World Bank Economic Review 29 (suppl): 12634.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barros, Ricardo, Mirela de Carvalho, Samuel Franco, and Rosane Mendonca. 2010. “Markets, the State and the Dynamics of Inequality in Brazil.” In Declining Inequality in Latin America: A Decade of Progress?, edited by Luis Lopez-Calva and Nora Lustig. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bassanini, Andrea, Andrea Garnero, Pascal Marianna, and Sebastien Martin. 2010. “Institutional Determinants of Worker Flows: A Cross-Country/Cross-Industry Approach.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 107, OECD Publishing, Paris..

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bassanini, Andrea, Luca Nunziata, and Danielle Venn. 2009. “Job Protection Legislation and Productivity Growth in OECD Countries.” Economic Policy 24 (58): 349402.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bentolila, Samuel, and Giuseppe Bertola. 1990. “Firing Costs and Labor Demand: How Bad Is Eurosclerosis?Review of Economic Studies 57: 381402.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Besley, Timothy, and Robin Burgess. 2004. “Can Labor Regulation Hinder Economic Performance? Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (1): 91134.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Betcherman, Gordon. 2012. “Labor Market Institutions: A Review of the Literature.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6276, World Bank Group, Washington DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Betcherman, Gordon. 2013. “Designing Labor Market Regulations in Developing Countries.” IZA World of Labor 2014: 57.

  • Betcherman, N. Meltem Daysal, and Carmen Pagés. 2010. “Do Employment Subsidies Work? Evidence from Regionally Targeted Subsidies in Turkey.” Labour Economics 17 (4): 71022.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, Florence Jaumotte, and Prakash Loungani. 2013. “Labor Market Policies and IMF Advice in Advanced Economies during the Great Recession.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 13/02, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Augustin Landier. 2002. “The Perverse Effects of Partial Labour Market Reform: Fixed-term Contracts in France.” Economic Journal 112 (480): 21444.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Jean Tirole. 2003. Protection de l’emploi et procédures de licenciement. Rapport du Conseil d’analyse économique (October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Jean Tirole. 2008. “The Joint Design of Unemployment Insurance and Employment Protection: A First Pass.” Journal of European Economic Association 6 (1): 4577.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blau, Francine, and Lawrence Kahn. 1996. “International Differences in Male Wage Inequality: Institutions Versus Market Forces.” Journal of Political Economy 104 (4): 791837.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boeri, Tito. 2010. “Institutional Reforms in European Labor Markets.” In Handbook of Labor Economics Volume 4, edited by Orley Ashenfelter and David Card (pp. 1173236). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bosch, Mariano, and Julen Esteban-Pretel. 2012. “Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Presence of Informal Markets.” Journal of Development Economics 98 (2): 27086.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bosch, Mariano, Edwin Goni-Pacchioni, and William Maloney. 2012. “Trade Liberalization, Labor Reforms and Formal-Informal Employment Dynamics.” Labour Economics 19 (5): 65367.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Botero, Juan, Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2004. “The Regulation of Labor.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (3): 133982.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bozkaya, Ant, and William Kerr. 2014. “Labor Regulations and European Venture Capital.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 23 (4): 776810.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brown, Alessio, Michael Orszag, and Dennis Snower. 2008. “Unemployment Accounts and Employment Incentives.” European Journal of Political Economy 24 (3): 587604.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, Ricardo, Kevin Cowan, Eduardo Engel, and Alejandro Micco. 2004. “Effective Labor Regulation and Microeconomic Flexibility.” NBER Working Paper 10744, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cahuc, Pierre, and Stephane Carcillo. 2015. “Youth Unemployment in France.” In No Country for Old People? Youth Labour Market Problems in Europe, edited by Juan Dolado. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calmfors, Lars, and John Driffill. 1988. “Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and Macroeconomic Performance.” Economic Policy 3 (6): 1361.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cassoni, Adriana, Gaston Labadie, and Gabriela Fachola. 2005. “The Economic Effects of Unions in Latin America: Their Impact on Wages and Economic Performance of Firms in Uruguay.” In What Difference do Unions Make?, edited by Peter Kuhn and Gustavo Marquez. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Centeno, Mario, and Alvaro Novo. 2012. “Excess Worker Turnover and Fixed-Term Contracts: Causal Evidence in a Two-Tier System.” Labour Economics 19 (3): 32028.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chetty, Raj. 2008. “Moral Hazard vs. Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance.” Journal of Political Economy 116 (2): 173234.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chetty, and Adam Looney. 2006. “Consumption Smoothing and the Welfare Consequences of Social Insurance in Developing Countries.” Journal of Public Economics 90 (12): 235156.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cingano, Federico, Marco Leonardi, Julián Messina, and Giovanni Pica. 2010. “The Effect of Employment Protection Legislation and Financial Market Imperfections on Investment: Evidence from a Firm-Level Panel of EU Countries.” Economic Policy 25 (61): 11763.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crepon, Bruno, Esther Duflo, Marc Gurgand, Roland Rathelot, and Philippe Zamora. 2013. “Do Labor Market Policies Have Displacement Effects? Evidence from a Clustered Randomized Trial.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (2): 53180.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crepon, Bruno, and Gerard van den Berg. 2016. “Active Labor Market Policies.” Annual Review of Economics 8: 52146.

  • Cunningham, Wendy. 2007. Minimum Wages and Social Policy: Lessons from Developing Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.

  • Diez-Catalan, Luis, and Ernesto Villanueva. 2015. “Contract Staggering and Unemployment During the Great Recession: Evidence from Spain.” Working Paper 1431, Banco de España, Madrid.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, Simeon, and Rita Ramalho. 2009. “Employment Laws in Developing Countries.” Journal of Comparative Economics 37 (1): 313.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dustmann, Christian, Bernd Fitzenberger, Uta Schönberg, and Alexandra Spitz-Oener. 2014. “From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (1): 16788.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Duval, Romain, and Davide Furceri. 2018. “The Effects of Labor and Product Market Reforms: The Role of Macroeconomic Conditions and Policies.” IMF Economic Review 66 (1): 3169.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Duval, Romain, and Joao Jalles. 2017. “Job Protection Deregulation in Good and Bad Times.” IMF Working Paper 17/277, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eslava, Marcela, John Haltiwanger, Adriana Kugler, and Maurice Kugler. 2004. “The Effects of Structural Reforms on Productivity and Profitability Enhancing Reallocation: Evidence from Colombia.” Journal of Development Economics 75 (3): 33371.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2010. Employment in Europe 2010. European Commission, Brussels.

  • Fallon, Peter, and Robert Lucas. 1991. “The Impact of Changes in Job Security Regulations in India and Zimbabwe.” World Bank Economic Review 5 (3): 395413.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Felgueroso, Florentino, María J. Pérez-Villadóniga, and Juan Prieto-Rodriguez. 2008. “The Effect of the Collective Bargaining Level on the Gender Wage Gap: Evidence from Spain.” Manchester School 76 (3): 30119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freeman, Richard. 2010. “Labor Regulations, Unions, and Social Protection in Developing Countries: Market Distortions or Efficient Institutions?” In Handbook of Development Economics, edited by Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig, (pp. 4657702). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freeman, Richard, and James Medoff. 1984. What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books.

  • Garibaldi, Pietro, and Giovanni Violante. 2005. “The Employment Effects of Severance Payments with Wage Rigidities.” Economic Journal 115 (506): 799832.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gazola Hellmann, Aline. 2015. “How Does Bolsa Familia Work? Best Practices in the Implementation of Conditional Cash Transfer Programs in Latin America and the Caribbean.” IADB Technical Note IDB-TN-856, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerard, Francois, and Gustavo Gonzaga. 2016. “Informal Labor and the Efficiency Cost of Social Programs: Evidence from the Brazilian Unemployment Insurance Program.” CEPR Discussion Paper 11485, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gindling, Tim. 2014. “Does Increasing the Minimum Wage Reduce Poverty in Developing Countries?IZA World of Labor 2014: 30.

  • Hartley, Gonzalo, Jan Van Ours, and Milan Vodopivec. 2011. “Incentive Effects of Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts: Evidence from Chile.” Labour Economics 18 (5): 798809.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hartog, Joop, Edwin Leuven, and Coen Teulings. 2002. “Wages and the Bargaining Regime in a Corporatist Setting: the Netherlands.” European Journal of Political Economy 18 (2): 31731.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heckman, James, and Carmen Pagés. 2004. Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hendren, Nathaniel. 2017. “Knowledge of Future Job Loss and Implications for Unemployment Insurance.” American Economic Review 107 (7): 17781823.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hijzen, Alexander. 2011. “The Labour Market Effects of Unemployment Compensation in Brazil.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 119, OECD Publishing, Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hijzen, and Pedro Martins. 2016. “No Extension without Representation? Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Collective Bargaining.” IMF Working Paper 16/143, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hijzen, and Jante Parlevliet. 2017. “Collective Bargaining through the Magnifying Glass: A Comparison between the Netherlands and Portugal.” IMF Working Paper 17/275, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Holzmann, Robert, Yann Pouget, Milan Vodopivec, and Michael Weber. 2011. “Severance Pay Programs around the World: History, Rationale, Status, and Reforms.” IZA Discussion Paper 5731, Institute of Labor Economics, Germany.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hopenhayn, Hugo, and Juan Pablo Nicolini. 1997. “Optimal Unemployment Insurance.” Journal of Political Economy 105 (2): 41238.

  • Hopenhayn, Hugo, and Richard Rogerson. 1993. “Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A General Equilibrium Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (5): 91538.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 140348.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Labour Organization. 2013. Working Conditions Laws Report 2012: A Global Review. International Labour Office, Geneva.

  • International Labour Organization. 2014. World Social Protection Report 2014/15: Building Economic Recovery, Inclusive Development and Social Justice. Geneva: International Labour Office. http://www.ilo.org/global/research/global-reports/world-social-security-report/2014/lang--en/index.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Labour Organization. 2015. Employment Protection Legislation Database—EPLex. Geneva: International Labour Office. http://www.ilo.org/travail/areasofwork/WCMS_435450/lang--en/index.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2014. “Labor Market Reforms to Boost Employment and Productivity in the GCC—An Update.” Note prepared for the Annual Meeting of Ministers of Finance and Central Bank Governors of the Gulf Cooperation Council. Kuwait, October 25, 2014. https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2014/102514a.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Labour Organization. 2016. “Time for a Supply-Side Boost? The Macroeconomic Effects of Labor and Product Market Reforms in Advanced Economies.” In World Economic Outlook (Chapter 3, Box 3.3). Washington, DC: IMF.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaumotte, Florence, and Carolina Osorio-Buitron. 2015. “Inequality and Labor Market Institutions.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/14, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kanbur, Ravi. 2015. “Informality: Causes, Consequences and Policy Responses.” CEPR Discussion Paper 10509, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kramarz, Francis, and Thomas Philippon, 2001. “The Impact of Differential Payroll Tax Subsidies on Minimum Wage Employment.” Journal of Public Economics 82 (1): 11546.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kuddo, Arvo, David Robalino, and Michael Weber. 2015. Balancing Regulations to Promote Jobs. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.

  • Kugler, Adriana. 2004. “The Effects of Job Security Regulations on Labor Market Flexibility: Evidence from the Colombian Labor Market Reform.” In Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean (pp. 183228) Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kugler, Adriana. Forthcoming. “Impacts of Labor Market Institutions and Demographic Factors on Labor Markets in Latin America.” IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kugler, and Maurice Kugler. 2009. “Labor Market Effects of Payroll Taxes in Developing Countries: Evidence from Colombia.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 57 (2): 33558.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kugler, and Luis Herrera. 2017. “Do Payroll Tax Breaks Stimulate Formality? Evidence from Colombia’s Reform.” Economia Journal (Fall, November): 340.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lamarche, Carlos. 2013. “Industry-Wide Work Rules and Productivity: Evidence from Argentine Union Contract Data.” IZA Journal of Labor and Development 2: 11.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lamarche, Carlos. 2015. “Collective Bargaining in Developing Countries.” IZA World of Labor 183.

  • Lazear, Edward. 1990. “Job Security Provisions and Employment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105: 699726.

  • Lommerud, Kjell Erik, Odd Rune Straume, and Steinar Vagstad. 2016. “Employment Protection and Unemployment Benefits: On Technology Adoption and Job Creation in a Matching Model.” CEPR Discussion Paper 11192, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Magruder, Jeremy. 2012. “High Unemployment Yet Few Small Firms: The Role of Centralized Bargaining in South Africa.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4 (3): 13866.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marimon, Ramon, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 1999. “Unemployment vs. Mismatch of Talents: Reconsidering Unemployment Benefits.” Economic Journal 109 (455): 26691.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Martins, Pedro. 2014. “30,000 Minimum Wages: The Economic Effects of Collective Bargaining Extensions.” IZA Discussion Paper 8540 Institute of Labor Economics, Germany.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKenzie, David. 2017. “How Effective Are Active Labor Market Policies in Developing Countries? A Critical Review of Recent Evidence.” World Bank Research Observer 32: 12754.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Micco, Alejandro, and Carmen Pagés. 2006. “The Economic Effects of Employment Protection: Evidence from International Industry-Level Data.” IZA Discussion Paper 2433.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 2008. Minimum Wages. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2006. Boosting Jobs and Incomes: Policy Lessons from the Reassessing the OECD Jobs Strategy. Paris: OECD.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2010. Taxing Wedges. Paris: OECD.

  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2011. “The Labour Market Effects of Social Protection Systems in Emerging Economies.” In OECD Employment Outlook 2011 (Chapt. 2). Paris: OECD.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2013. “Protecting Jobs, Enhancing Flexibility: A New Look at Employment Protection Legislation.” In OECD Employment Outlook 2013 (Chapt. 2). Paris: OECD.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2015. OECD Indicators of Employment Protection Legislation. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. http://www.oecd.org/els/emp/oecdindicatorsofemploymentprotection.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2018. Good Jobs for All in a Changing World of Work. The OECD Jobs Strategy, December. Paris: OECD.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pissarides, Christopher. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  • Pissarides, Christopher. 2001. “Employment Protection.” Labour Economics 8 (2): 13159.

  • Ribe, Helena, David Robalino, and Ian Walker. 2010. Achieving Effective Social Protection for All in Latin America and the Caribbean. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robalino, David. 2014. “Designing Unemployment Benefits in Developing Countries: Is Risk Pooling Better than Individual Savings?IZA World of Labour 2014: 15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sabia, Joseph. 2015. “Do Minimum Wages Stimulate Productivity and Growth?IZA World of Labour 2015: 221.

  • Saget, Catherine. 2008. “Fixing Minimum Wage Levels in Developing Countries: Common Failures and Remedies.” International Labour Review 147 (1): 2542.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shapiro, Carlo, and Joseph Stiglitz. 1984. “Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device.” American Economic Review 74 (3): 43344.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tatsiramos, Konstantinos. 2009. “Unemployment Insurance in Europe: Unemployment Duration and Subsequent Employment Stability.” Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (6): 122560.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wasmer, Etienne. 2006. “General Versus Specific Skills in Labor Markets with Search Frictions and Firing Costs.” American Economic Review 96 (3): 81131.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank. 2016. “Taking on Inequality.” In Poverty and Shared Prosperity 2016. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group.

Appendix

This appendix lists the advice extracted through text mining techniques for each of the countries and policy areas covered in the note. Capitalized words correspond to key word searches. Text in the “Article IV Extract” column corresponds to extracts (direct quotes) from Article IVs.

Table A1.

Unemployment Benefits

article image
article image
Table A2.

Employment Protection Legislation

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
Table A3.

Active Labor Market Policies

article image
article image
article image
Table A4.

Minimum Wage

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
Table A5.

Collective Bargaining

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
1

The authors would like to thank Marc Engher for help with the text mining techniques, Ariana Tayebi for editorial assistance, and Hites Ahir, Zidong An, Jun Ge and Nathalie Gonzalez-Prieto for invaluable research support. They are also grateful to Olivier Blanchard, Carmen Pagés, Adriana Kugler, Aurelio Parisotto, Martin Rama, David Robalino and seminar participants at the International Monetary Fund, the International Labour Organization and the World Bank for helpful comments and discussions. This work was carried out while Loungani was in the IMF Research Department.

2

This includes asymmetric information regarding the timing of future job losses, which workers tend to know about before potential insurers do (Hendren 2017). This further amplifies the adverse selection problem and risks that private markets may fail.

3

It also provides a case for experience rating—the method by which an employer’s contributions to the unemployment insurance system vary based on its own experience laying off workers.

4

Also, a single provider can exploit large economies of scale, although this factor alone need not imply that the provider should be the state.

5

The focus will be on core labor market institutions that affect the broad functioning of labor markets, including UI, EPL, minimum wages, and collective bargaining; in this context, related labor taxation and active labor market policies will also be discussed. The note does not touch on other institutions, such as child care policies or early retirement schemes, that specifically affect certain groups in the labor market.

6

High and long-lasting benefits can raise wages and equilibrium unemployment when workers can (re)negotiate wages after they are hired—a realistic assumption in practice (Blanchard and Tirole 2008).

7

This comes on top of poor administrative capacity to collect taxes, manage UI funds, and distribute benefits, which is a technically related but conceptually separate obstacle to UI provision in emerging market and developing economies.

8

A mitigating factor is that employment rates in the formal sector may be low to start with, even in the absence of any behavioral effects from benefit receipt. Gerard and Gonzaga (2016), using a model calibrated on Brazilian data, find that informality matters less for optimal UI generosity than usually thought.

9

Using individual data for Brazil and an empirical strategy that identifies both effects, Hijzen (2011) finds that both moral hazard and, to a lesser extent, this liquidity effect account for the impact of benefit receipt on the duration of formal unemployment.

10

A continuum of design options exists between a pure UISA and a pure unemployment benefits system, depending on the targeted degree of risk pooling, which in turn depends on what taxes are used to finance the benefits and will ultimately reflect social preferences regarding efficiency versus redistribution/equity (see, for example, Robalino 2014).

11

Furthermore, while UISAs raise smaller administrative and incentive concerns compared with UI systems, they are not free of such issues. In particular, a minimum degree of financial development and macroeconomic stability is required to manage USIAs and to foster workers’ confidence in them.

12

Where multiple schemes already exist, their consolidation would have the advantage of increasing efficiency by broadening the insurance risk pool, further reducing administrative costs and labor taxation, and facilitating portability and thereby labor mobility.

13

UI—particularly UISAs, which provide a stock rather than a flow of funding—can be used as starting capital for informal self-employed work, facilitating the transition from formal to informal employment.

14

VAT itself can promote informality by encouraging consumers and firms to purchase VAT-free goods and services, especially if the VAT rate is set high. This is another reason for the UI system to be highly efficient and to achieve broad coverage: to keep overall tax rates as low as possible.

15

For evidence of sizable displacement effects in an AE context, see Crepon and others (2013).

16

For example, depending on the recipient’s income and family situation, benefit levels under the Bolsa Familia program in Brazil ranged between 2 percent to a maximum of about 15 percent of the average wage in 2015. For details, see, for example, Gazola Hellman (2015).

17

Efficiency also requires accurate and up-to-date beneficiary registers and transparent financial management of the system more broadly, which in turn requires a minimum level of administrative capacity. This is especially important where benefit levels are higher or cover a wider share of the population (for example, in urban areas).

18

The focus here is on public institutions, ignoring voluntary transfer arrangements between firms and workers. Firms have long offered severance pay to their workers as a way to reduce voluntary quits and the associated loss of human capital investment (see, for example, Holzmann and others 2011). Lazear (1990) lays out the theoretical case for such arrangements.

19

See also OECD (2015).

20

On the theoretical front, the case for reducing job turnover through EPL relative to UI can be greater (Lommerud, Straume, and Vagstad 2016), the lower is workers’ degree of risk aversion is (that is, the less valuable unemployment benefits are to them), the higher the job matching externality (the adverse effect of vacancy posting by one firm on the likelihood that other firms fill their vacancies, which implies “excessive” job turnover in an unregulated labor market), the smaller the degree of worker bargaining power arising from sunk job-specific investments (which create a “hold-up” problem that discourages such investments and therefore job creation).

21

Dualism has been particularly strong in some commodity-exporting emerging market and developing economies, where it has been magnified by the prevalence of public sector employment, dualism between domestic and expatriate workers, or employment quotas over and above the role of stringent EPL (see, for example, IMF 2014).

22

In particular, subsistence farmers, the self-employed, and in some cases workers on small firms are not covered.

23

Minimum wages might also have a positive impact on productivity by encouraging worker effort and shifting activity away from lower-skilled toward higher-skilled firms and industries. The prevalence and magnitude of this effect are unclear, however (see, for example, Sabia 2015). Much more research is needed on this topic.

24

Assessing the overall employment effects of minimum wages is even more difficult for emerging market and developing economies than it is for advanced economies, owing to the stronger labor mobility between formal and informal sectors and the comparatively much smaller amount of empirical literature (mostly focused on Latin America) in the former.

25

In a meta-analysis, Betcherman (2012, 2013) argues that the effects of minimum wages and other labor regulations on economic performance are nonlinear; that is, stronger for higher degrees of stringency.

26

Opening clauses allow firms to set less favorable wages and working conditions than those in the applicable sector-level agreement if certain conditions are met. The resilience of the German labor market during the global financial crisis was attributed to such clauses (Dustmann and others 2014).

27

Hijzen, Martins, and Parlevliet (2017) discuss how the detailed design features of the sector-level bargaining systems of Portugal and the Netherlands differ along a number of dimensions that might have contributed to the contrasting labor market performance of the two countries.

28

A team of research analysts did the initial sifting of advice from descriptions. The authors of this paper read the sifted advice; when necessary, they consulted the relevant Article IV Reports to get the context for the advice. In a few cases, the advice was contained in program documents rather than in Article IV Reports.

29

In two cases—China and Malaysia—the expansion of UI was seen as part of an attempt to lower the current account surplus.

30

Sometimes claims of other impacts (which are not totally persuasive, given evidence from the literature) were made, such as an increase in aggregate employment or an improvement in price competitiveness.

31

In one case (Bangladesh, 2013) an increase in the minimum wage in the garment industry, which the authorities instituted along with other protections in the aftermath of a major industrial accident, was welcomed by staff.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Designing Labor Market Institutions in Emerging and Developing Economies: Evidence and Policy Options
Author:
Mr. Romain A Duval
and
Mr. Prakash Loungani
  • Figure 1.

    Share of Countries with an Unemployment Insurance System

    (2014, by country income group, percent)

  • Figure 2.

    Unemployment Benefit Coverage

    (2013, percentage of unemployed workers receiving benefits, by country income group)

  • Figure 3.

    Employment Protection Legislation for Regular Contracts: ILO EPLex Indicator and Components

    (2010, scale 0–1, country income group median)

  • Figure 4.

    UI Coverage versus ILO Indicator of Job Protection for Regular Contracts

    (2013 and 2010, advanced and selected emerging market and developing economies)

  • Figure 5.

    Ratio of Minimum to Median Wage: Selected Emerging Market and Developing Economies and Advanced Economies

    (2010, simple average across available countries in each country income group)

  • Figure 6.

    Union Density Rates

    (2013 or latest available year, percent, simple average across available countries in each country income group)

  • Figure 7.

    Collective Bargaining Coverage

    (Early 2010s/late 2000s, percentage of salaried employees covered by a collective agreement, simple average across available countries in each country income group)