Inequality and Poverty across Generations in the European Union

Contributor Notes

Authors’ E-mail Address: Please contact Jean-Jacques Hallaert jhallaert@imf.org; Maximilien Queyranne mqueyranne@imf.org or Irene Yackovlev iyackovlev@imf.org

This SDN studies the evolution of inequality across age groups leading up to and since the global financial crisis, as well as implications for fiscal and labor policies. Europe’s population is aging, child and youth poverty are rising, and income support systems are often better equipped to address old-age poverty than the challenges faced by poor children and/or unemployed youth today.

Abstract

This SDN studies the evolution of inequality across age groups leading up to and since the global financial crisis, as well as implications for fiscal and labor policies. Europe’s population is aging, child and youth poverty are rising, and income support systems are often better equipped to address old-age poverty than the challenges faced by poor children and/or unemployed youth today.

Introduction

1. There is growing recognition of the adverse economic, social, and political consequences of inequality. Both efficient market mechanisms as well as market failures can lead to inequality. While rewards for innovation, entrepreneurial activity, and job creation in competitive markets exacerbate inequality, they can also have a positive impact. Conversely, rent seeking, abuse of market power, and inequality of opportunity can negatively impact overall welfare. There is a growing body of empirical evidence that highlights the detrimental effects of market failures and, accordingly, findings suggest that lower net income inequality can be associated with faster and more sustained growth (Berg and Ostry, 2011; Ostry, Berg, and Tsangarides, 2014).

2. Over the last decade, overall income inequality has remained stable in the EU, but a closer look reveals that inequality across generations has increased markedly. Income convergence between advanced and developing countries has contributed to a decline in inequality across countries, even as the evolution of inequality within countries, including some advanced countries, is mixed (IMF, 2017). In Europe, the increase has been driven by growing inequality across generations. This reflects higher poverty and joblessness among the young, which have adverse and long-lasting consequences for today’s youth, as well as for tomorrow’s economic prospects. Inequality across generations also erodes social cohesion and polarizes political preferences, and may ultimately undermine confidence in political institutions.

3. This Staff Discussion Note (SDN) analyzes poverty and inequality across generations in Europe and discusses policy implications. During the last decade, the relative poverty rate of the working age population, especially the young, rose while that of the elderly declined markedly. The crisis has exacerbated preexisting high youth unemployment and a structural trend toward less stable jobs. This outcome has hurt real incomes of the working age population, especially the young. Social protection systems are ill-equipped to mitigate the impact of the crisis on the working age population, notably the young. Reversing the trend toward youth poverty requires, in addition to macro-economic policies that avoid large shocks, concerted labor market and fiscal policies, including social protection and fiscal redistribution.

4. This SDN paper is organized as follows. The first section takes stock of recent trends in inequality and poverty across generations in Europe. The second section quantifies the importance of labor market developments and fiscal redistribution for income inequality and poverty across generations. The following two sections discuss how labor market policies and fiscal redistribution affect inequality and poverty across age groups. The SDN concludes with policy implications.

Recent Trends in Poverty and Inequality Across Generations in the EU

Over the past decade, poverty and inequality across generations increased. Today, the young are the age group most at risk of poverty. This generation has been adversely affected by economic stagnation and labor market developments, as well as by gaps in the social safety net.

5. The risk of youth poverty is on the rise in Europe.1 In the years leading up to the global financial crisis, the relative poverty of the young (those 18 to 24 years old) and elderly (those older than 65) was broadly similar.2 With the financial crisis came a significant rise in the risk of relative poverty for the young because they suffered disproportionately from unemployment. Meanwhile, the risk for the rest of the working age population increased only modestly, and the risk for the elderly declined precipitously since their incomes, particularly pensions, were better protected than those of workers. Today, the young are the age group most likely to be poor—in both relative and absolute terms (Figure 1).3

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

EU: Risk of Poverty Across Generations

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat and IMF staff estimates.1 2008 used due to lack of data in 2007.
uA01fig01

EU27: At-Risk-of-Poverty Rate

(Percent of total)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Source: Eurostat.
uA01fig02

EU27: Gini Coefficient of Disposable Income

(Index, 0–100)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat and IMF staff calculations.1 Or latest available.

6. Income inequality in Europe has remained stable at the aggregate level but income developments have diverged across generations and countries. Some of the countries hardest hit by the global financial crisis also experienced sharp increases in the Gini coefficient of market income between 2007 and 2016, driving some of the differences across European regions; however, this topic is not the focus of this SDN (Appendix I). Rather, the focus here is on measures of income inequality by age groups, which are available for the period since the mid-2000s. We find that income inequality across generations increased markedly (Figure 2). The median equivalized net income of the working age population—after accounting for taxes and transfers, including pension benefits—stagnated following the crisis, while it grew for the elderly by nearly 10 percent. Notably, the ratio of median net income of the elderly to the youth rose in most countries. In Germany, the ratio has been stable but income inequality within young cohorts is higher than it was when their parents were young (Box 1).

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Income Inequality Across Generations in Europe

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat; IMF World Economic Outlook; and IMF staff calculations.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes. pps = percentage points; rhs = right-hand scale.

7. The stagnation of workers’ incomes fundamentally changed the profile of inequality across generations, and left the youth with the lowest median income of any age group. Inequality within age cohorts is also markedly different; the ratio of the top and lower quintiles is much lower among those aged 65 and older than in the working age population. Further, the concentration of income tilted markedly in favor of the elderly in the years since the crisis (Figure 2).

Germany: A Within-Cohort Perspective on Inequality

The median net income and the poverty rate of different age groups have been evolving rather uniformly in Germany over the past decade, suggesting a broadly stable picture in terms of intergenerational inequality. This perspective can be usefully complemented by an analysis of the evolution of within-cohort income inequality for various age groups. Such an analysis show that younger cohorts are facing a more unequal within-cohort distribution of income than older cohorts when they were young.

uA01fig03

Germany: Within-Cohort Gini Coefficient of Disposable Income, 1991–2014

(Index between 0 and 1)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Socio-Economic Panel v32; and IMF staff calculations.Note: Each line represents the evolution of the within-cohort Gini index as a function of the age of the cohort’s oldest member. Cohorts are tagged by birth years.

The within-cohort Gini index of disposable income of individuals born in the same decade displays a clear upward drift at any given age. The drift is particularly pronounced for the income received during the time individuals are 15–35 years old. For example, whereas the Gini index of those born in the 1970s when their oldest member was 25 years old was 0.24, it was close to 0.30 for those born in the 1980s and the 1990s at the same age. This finding is reminiscent of the results of Bönke and others (2015), who identified a secular increase in lifetime earnings inequality among men born in West Germany between 1935 and 1969, a pattern which they attributed for the most part to the evolution of the cohort-specific wage structure.

8. The young are more likely to fall into poverty in the event of an income shock in part because they typically lack asset wealth that acts as a buffer. As the accumulation of assets is gradual over the life cycle, younger generations (measured here as 16–34 years old) hold less than 5 percent of net wealth in Europe, and their median wealth is one-tenth of the median for 65-year-olds. They also have the highest debt-to-assets ratio (49 percent) across age groups and are most likely to form part of a credit-constrained household (12.4 percent) (Household Finance and Consumption Survey, 2016).4 Intergenerational transfers and gifts within families are important for household wealth accumulation and could be an important source for mitigating intergenerational inequality, but matter to a smaller extent in reducing overall inequality (Mathä and others, 2014).5

9. Income inequality and poverty across generations are closely related to developments in the labor market. Youth employment prospects were especially hard hit by the global financial crisis. Although labor force participation among the young has fallen, youth unemployment remains well above overall unemployment rates across EU countries (despite a modest decline since 2013) and is correlated with higher poverty rates. Moreover, the prevalence of in-work poverty, involuntarily part-time employment, and temporary work contracts has risen over the last decade and most among the young (Figure 3). One important exception is Germany, where youth unemployment, temporary contracts, and part-time work have declined, and the increase in youth in-work poverty has been more limited than for older age groups (Box 2).

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

The Young and the Labor Market

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat and IMF staff calculations.1 Data for age group 25–64 is unavailable.
uA01fig04

Net Wealth Distribution by Age Group, EA-17

(Thousands of euros)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Source: ECB HFCS wave 2.Note: P25 and P75 refer to the 25th and 75th percentile ranges.

Labor Market Institutions, Youth Unemployment, and Income Inequality in Germany

The German labor market has become more flexible over the past 20 years. Starting in the mid-1990s, and in the context of greater offshoring opportunities in neighboring Central, Eastern, and Southern European countries after the fall of the iron curtain (Dustmann and others, 2014), wage-setting became gradually more decentralized. Through the Hartz reforms implemented in 2003–05, employment protection legislation (EPL) for fixed-term contracts and regulation of temporary agency work were loosened, and unemployment benefits became less generous, while active labor market policies were expanded and targeting improved, and job placement services restructured (Engbom and others, 2015).1 The reforms boosted labor demand as well as supply, and matching efficiency (Weber, 2015). Other policy measures have further encouraged higher female labor force participation, including a reform of parental leave legislation in 2007, and an increase of subsidized child care (Geyer and others, 2014). As a result, both labor market participation and employment increased spectacularly over the past decade.

This greater flexibility has served young Germans well relative to their European peers. It helped the German economy weather the severe 2009 recession with minimum costs in terms of overall unemployment (Weber, 2015; Scheffel and Krebs, 2017) and, combined with an effective vocational training system (Cahuc and others, 2013), it has contributed to make the German youth unemployment rate the lowest in Europe from 2011 on. Regarding job quality, while the share of employed young people in atypical forms of employment (including so-called mini-jobs) increased sharply after the Hartz reforms, it decreased again strongly in recent years.

The good performance of the young on the labor market in recent years is also visible in the evolution of their income relative to that of older workers. Median wages of full-time employees aged 15–24 have increased faster than those of all full-time employees between 2009 and 2015. Furthermore, while the overall poverty rate has been slowly creeping up in Germany and is slightly below the EU average both for the whole population and for young adults (Vandenbussche and Grevenbrock, 2017), the in-work at-risk-of-poverty rate of individuals aged 15–24 barely changed between 2006 and 2014, while that of individuals aged 25–54 increased. This suggests that the very good shape of the labor market has benefited the young.

uA01fig05

Difference in Unemployment Rate Between 15–24 Years Old and 25–59 Years Old, 2000–2015

(percent)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat and IMF staff calculations.
uA01fig06

Difference in In-Work Poverty Rates and Relative Wages Between 15–24 Years Old and 25–54 Years Old

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat, German Federal Labor Agency, and IMF staff calculations.1 The effectiveness of active labor market policies is regularly assessed. The Federal Employment Agency’s research institute finds that “occupational training and measures taking place directly at employers have distinctly more positive effects on the labor market prospects of participants [than short training and placement services] conducted by private providers” (IAB, 2015).

Quantifying the Role of the Labor Market and Fiscal Redistribution

10. Labor market developments and fiscal policy play a key role in poverty and income inequality. The labor market can affect poverty and income inequality through its impact on the distribution of wages (Salverda and Checchi, 2015) and unemployment. This section focuses on unemployment because differences in nominal wage growth across age groups have not been significant.6 Fiscal redistribution also affects poverty and income inequality, for example, through generosity and comprehensiveness of social safety nets, taxation, and social insurance contributions (IMF, 2017; Marx and others, 2015).

11. Labor market developments and fiscal redistribution have different impacts across age groups. This section attempts to establish some basic associations between labor market outcome and fiscal policy choice variables on the one hand, and income and poverty variables for different age groups on the other. Specifically, we run regressions using an annual panel data set of EU countries between 2007 and 2015, similar to the empirical approach from Jaumotte and others (2013) and Dabla-Norris and others (2015).7 The main results are presented in Tables 1 and 2.8 Control variables are included to account for other factors that could affect poverty and inequality, including globalization and technological progress (Pavcnik 2011; Kanbur 2015).9 The data feature harmonized measurements of income inequality and poverty. This helps overcome limitations on data comparability faced by other cross-country studies (Clements and others, 2015).

Table 1.

Income Inequality Panel Regressions1

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Labor market flexibility is excluded from the income inequality regressions as the estimated coefficients are statistically insignificant. Other control variables include output gap, per capita income, education, trade openness, constant, year and country fixed effects.

Table 2.

Absolute Poverty Panel Regressions1

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Absolute poverty is measured by the severe deprivation rate. Other control variables include output gap, per capita income, education, trade openness, constant, year and country fixed effects.

12. A key finding from the regressions is a strong and positive association between inequality across generations and long-term unemployment. The reason is that long-term unemployment disproportionally affects the young, driving losses in their incomes relative to those of other age groups. Based on our estimates, a 1 percentage point increase in the long-term unemployment rate is associated with an increase of 0.5 percentage points in the income ratio for the 25- to 49-year-old relative to the 18- to 24-year-old; for those older than 65 the increase is 1.2 percent (Table 1, columns 2–4).10 Furthermore, such an increase in unemployment is associated with an increase in the risk of absolute poverty among the 18- to 24-year-old by 0.5 percentage points versus only 0.3 percentage point for the 50- to 64-year-old and no significant increase for those 65 or older (Table 2, columns 2 and 4). This may reflect lower access to unemployment benefits and minimum income schemes for younger generations. The impact of labor market flexibility on absolute poverty is positive but more uniform across working age groups (Table 2, columns 2–5).11, 12

13. Higher public social spending is associated with lower income inequality and poverty at the aggregate level and with higher incomes for older generations relative to the 18–24 age group. The estimation shows that increasing social spending by 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with a lower Gini index of net income by 1.2 percent (Table 1, column 1).13 Higher social spending is associated with significantly higher incomes for the 50–64 age group relative to the 18–24 age group (Table 1, column 3), possibly reflecting support from early retirement or disability schemes for older workers as well as spending on health care. The negative association between social spending and absolute poverty across age groups suggests a more uniform impact of such spending on poverty than relative incomes (Table 2, columns 2–5).14

14. Direct taxation appears to be effective in combatting income inequality and poverty, especially for the young.15 Raising direct tax revenue by 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with a reduction of the Gini index of net income by 0.6 percent (or 0.2 percentage points of Gini index on average; Table 1, column 1). The estimation also shows that a higher marginal effective tax rate is linked to a lower Gini index, which may reflect the impact from a more progressive tax system. More importantly, coefficient estimates show that a 1 percentage point increase in direct taxes relative to GDP on average associated with a reduction of more than 0.7 percentage points in the income ratio between the older-than-65 and 18–24 age groups (Table 1, column 4). The estimates on the income ratio are not significant for the other age groups. This suggests that income of the elderly is likely to be more affected by an increase in direct tax revenue, for example through higher taxes on pension income. As expected, the estimate of the impact of direct taxes on the risk of absolute poverty is insignificant across all age groups as higher direct taxes do not help reduce absolute poverty (Table 2); however, they reduce measures of relative poverty by bringing down the incomes of wealthier individuals (Table II.3).16

Labor Market Policies

Employment is key to reducing gaps in opportunity, incomes, and poverty of the young relative to older generations. A major finding in the previous section is a strong and positive association between inequality across generations and unemployment, which affects the young disproportionately. Our analysis indicates that the labor tax wedge, labor institutions, and the economy’s overall performance are closely associated with youth unemployment.

16. Unemployment is the result of a broad range of macroeconomic, structural, and institutional factors. The key explanatory variable is GDP growth (or the output gap)—confirming Okun’s law (Banerji and others, 2014, 2015). Structural conditions, including demographic variables such as migration flows (Pissarides and McMaster, 1990), as well as the production structure of the economy (Destefanis and Mastromatteo, 2010), also affect unemployment. Institutional factors such as the functioning of the labor market, product market liberalization, and housing policies are also believed to have an impact on unemployment (Boeri and Jimeno, 2016).

17. Youth unemployment is affected by trends in overall unemployment, as well as by additional structural and institutional factors. Studies that examine youth unemployment generally focus specifically on education and training, labor market institutions, and activation policies.

  • Education and training. Specific elements of education and training systems seem to have a larger impact on youth unemployment than overall educational attainment. Dual-education apprenticeships that link work-based and school-based programs are helpful in reducing youth unemployment (ILO, 2013; Zimmerman and others, 2013). It is also important to strengthen education systems, including through intensified individual support, lengthened compulsory schooling, and more labor-market- oriented curricula.

  • Labor market institutions. The effects of employment protection legislation (EPL) and temporary contracts—which contribute to labor market duality—on youth unemployment are mixed. The young are more likely to work under temporary contracts than older workers, which could leave them more vulnerable to losing their jobs during a recession (Choudhry and others, 2012). Conversely, countries with stronger EPL—which tend to have a higher prevalence of temporary contracts—appear to have suffered fewer job losses among the young during the great recession (O’Higgins, 2012).

  • Active labor market policies (ALMPs). ALMPs share the common goal of putting people to work, but vary widely in scope and funding. It is therefore no surprise that finding an empirical link between this broad category of policies and youth unemployment has proven elusive. Some studies find that ALMPs have a larger impact on youth than on overall unemployment (Choudhry, and others, 2012), whereas others find only limited effect (Crépon and van den Berg, 2016). There is some evidence that the effectiveness of ALMPs is dependent on program design, with wage subsidies, services, and sanctions deemed most effective (Kluve, 2006).

18. To assess the impact of labor market policies on youth poverty and inequality across generations, this section seeks to identify the drivers of unemployment rates of young and older workers, as well as the difference across age groups (Table 3 and Appendix II).17 We use a panel regression covering the period 2007–14 to be consistent with the previous set of regressions. A regression covering a longer period (2001–14) suggests that the results are robust. Results suggest that, in addition to the output gap, taxation, specific labor market institutions, and policies are closely associated with youth unemployment.

Table 3.

Unemployment Rate Panel Regressions

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ALMP = active labor market policy.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

See Appendix II for variable definitions.

  • Output gap. The output gap is significantly negatively associated with unemployment, that is, recovery or boom times are associated with falling unemployment and vice versa for recession times. However, the changes in the economic cycle affect young workers more than their older counterparts—almost twice as strongly, and so also help explain the unemployment gap between younger and older workers. This could be due to a host of factors: younger workers’ more limited job-specific skills; lower protection through EPL with a greater share of the young in temporary and part-time jobs (Figure 3); or even perceptions of social fairness, in which the young are considered more easily able to cope with unemployment compared to, say, older workers who may support families.

  • Taxation. A higher labor tax wedge is associated with higher unemployment (Bassanini and Duval, 2007; OECD, 2006). Our findings suggest that the change in the tax wedge is significant in explaining the unemployment rates of young workers (though not that of older workers). Young workers generally have less accumulated human capital, their productivity is lower than that of more experienced workers, and the marginal cost of taxation is higher, especially where progressivity of taxation is low (as is the case with most social security contributions).

  • Labor market institutions—unionization. Higher union density appears to be associated with higher unemployment levels, particularly for younger workers.18 This outcome may have arisen because unions may be less attentive to the specific challenges facing the young who have trouble entering the labor market. It could also reflect other factors that have driven both union density and unemployment and that are not among the explanatory variables––indeed, in most EU countries, unionization rates declined during 2004–13, particularly among the young even as youth unemployment rose.19

  • Labor market institutions—wage setting mechanisms. The union density variable does not fully capture the role of unions in labor market functioning and in enabling outcomes that address both unemployment as well as inequality: for example, cooperative industrial relations that foster collective bargaining agreements that take the overall macroeconomic situation and unemployment into account can play an important role in lowering unemployment (Siebert, 1997). Whether such strong relations exist is not a function of union density. Here the explanatory variable that captures the degree of coordination in the wage setting process is negatively associated with the level of unemployment, particularly for the young.20 Unions can also contribute significantly to designing effective apprenticeships and training programs for workers (see below).

  • Labor market institutions—temporary contracts.21 Temporary work contracts are more frequent where permanent contracts are subject to more stringent employment protection legislation. While the negative effect on job security is evident, the impact on youth unemployment is more ambiguous. The young, who are typically much more likely to have temporary contracts than older workers, can become more easily unemployed in a downturn (Carmeci and Mauro, 2003). On the other hand, temporary contracts may also make it easier for employers to resume hiring once growth returns. Our findings are consistent with a stronger cyclical response of the youth unemployment rate because a higher share of the young hold temporary jobs.

  • Training and education. Changes in spending on ALMPs that focus on training and education appear to affect the difference in unemployment rates between the young and rest of the working age population (though they are not significant in explaining the unemployment rates themselves).22, 23 However, the effectiveness of ALMPs also depends crucially on design features: early intervention, targeting and tailoring to counteract specific disadvantages, imparting of skills, and responsiveness to labor market needs (ILO 2011, 2013). Programs outside of ALMPs that systematically build skills of labor market entrants (for example, young workers) such as the dual-education apprenticeships in Austria, Denmark, or Germany can also play a significant role in lowering youth employment (Brunello and others, 2007; Checchi, 2006; Zimmerman and others, 2013).24

uA01fig07

Employment Protection and Temporary Jobs, 2013

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat and OECD.
uA01fig08

Training and Youth Unemployment, 20151

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Source: Eurostat.1 Countries with available data.

Fiscal Redistribution

European social protection systems have better protected the elderly from the impact of the global financial crisis than the young. Owing to fiscal constraints, non-pension social benefits have often been curtailed, not indexed to inflation, or more narrowly targeted. As a result, the young were not adequately covered against unemployment risk and the impact of precarious jobs.

19. Europeans’ demand for fiscal redistribution is associated with both income inequality and poverty but not with youth poverty (Appendix IV). This may partly explain why social protection does not adequately protect the young, notably during severe economic shocks. This, in turn, can marginalize the young and have long-lasting social and political consequences (Flash Barometer of the European Parliament, 2014). Moreover, social protection systems were historically designed to address old age risks—a practice that has been reinforced by the political economy of an aging population.

uA01fig09

Preferences for Redistribution and Gini of Net Income, Total, 2002–14

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: European Social Survey; SWIID; and IMF staff calculations.
uA01fig10

Preferences for Redistribution and At- Persistent-Risk-of-Poverty Rate, Total, 2002–14

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: European Social Survey; SWIID; and IMF staff calculations.

A. Social Protection Systems Shielded the Elderly from the Impact of the Crisis and Fiscal Consolidation…

20. Fiscal redistribution in Europe is mainly achieved by focusing on the elderly. This situation reflects two main factors. First, there is the sheer size and large redistributive impact of pension spending. Except for Ireland (Box 4), the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom, most of the reduction in income inequality is achieved through public pension spending (Figure 4).25 Market income inequality among the elderly is significantly larger than among the working-age population but becomes smaller after redistribution, owing to the large share of social spending on pensions (old age spending accounted for 53 percent of EU countries social spending in 2015; Eurostat, 2017), the redistributive impact of minimum pensions and, in many countries, caps on benefits (Avram and others, 2014). In other words, it is through the reduction of inequality among the elderly that most of the reduction of income inequality is achieved in Europe. While the impact of in-kind benefits on inequality across generations is not considered in this analysis, it is likely to be significant as health spending generally increases with the age of a person (European Commission, 2015a), especially toward the end of life. Second, pensioners benefit from a more favorable tax treatment than the rest of the population at the same level of income, such as extra tax allowances and full or partial relief on taxes and social security contributions on pension income (OECD, 2015b). However, the impact of taxes on reducing inequality plays a much smaller role than that of transfers.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Decomposing Fiscal Redistribution by Instrument

(Reduction of the Gini coefficient achieved by fiscal policy, 2015 or latest)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: EUROMOD and IMF staff calculations.Note: Pension spending includes old age, disability and survivors. DT = Direct taxes, MT= means-tested spending, NMT = non-means-tested spending, SC = Social contributions. Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.
uA01fig11

OECD EU Average Redistributive Effect, 2014

(Gini score)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Source: OECD.
uA01fig12

Personal Income Taxes and Social Security Contributions Paid by Pensioners and Workers

(Percent of earnings)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: OECD Pensions at a Glance and IMF staff calculations.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.

21. Pension reforms adopted during the global financial crisis protected current pensioners, while shifting most of the adjustment burden to future generations of retirees. Cuts in pension payments were temporary and more limited than for other social benefits, to protect acquired rights. Minimum pensions were preserved to avoid increasing old-age poverty. Pension reforms were primarily implemented for sustainability reasons. In many countries, most of the reductions in benefit ratios will be implemented after 2025, protecting workers close to retirement, although nearly 60 percent of the changes in eligibility ratio (share of public pensioners to population aged 65 and older) will take place by that date. Thus, though pension reforms make the system more sustainable and will reduce the burden on future working-age population, they also imply lower replacement rates and longer contribution periods for today’s young. These are more difficult to meet as high unemployment and precarious jobs affect their contribution history. When they retire, today’s youth may well face a higher risk of poverty than current pensioners.26 They may also face higher burdens on their disposable income on account of higher public debt; analyzing the long-term consequences of recent fiscal policy, however, lies beyond the scope of this paper.27

uA01fig13

Projected Reductions in Benefit Ratios (2013–60) and Share of Reductions Achieved by 2025

(Percent)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: European Commission, 2015a Ageing Report, and IMF staff estimates.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.

22. Finally, in most countries, indexation of pensions insulated elderly citizens’ purchasing power from the impact of the crisis. The statutory indexation of pensions,28 though weakened on a temporary or permanent basis in many countries (European Commission, 2015b), contributed to real income increases for pensioners (Figure 2).

B. … But not the Working Age Population and, Notably, the Young

23. In contrast, owing to fiscal constraints, non-pension benefits were:

  • not systematically indexed. In many countries, non-pension benefits adjustments lagged inflation, reducing their real value (Bargain and others, 2015; De Agostini and others, 2014; McKnight and others, 2016) and contributing to the decline in real incomes of the working age population (Figure 2). This is the case of the Czech Republic where all social benefits were de-indexed except pensions and housing benefits (Box 3) increasing the already high share of redistribution achieved through pensions (Figure 4).

  • cut or curtailed in some countries. Family allowances, which play a crucial role in income support of the parents, in most cases regardless of their working status or of the young’s involvement in education and training, were reduced in several countries such as the United Kingdom in 2013 and France in 2014–15 (OECD, 2014a; Social Protection Committee, 2015). Spending on youth work was reduced in many EU countries and more targeted on the needs of disadvantaged people (Social Protection Committee, 2015; Dunne and others, 2014). Thus, Hüttl and others (2015) argue that the growing inequality and poverty gap across generations was in part due to policy decisions because at a time when “youth unemployment and youth poverty rates increased, government spending shifted away from education, families and children towards pensioners.”

  • more targeted/means tested. As universalist programs often seem too expensive when public budget constraints become more binding, there is a tendency to increase the targeting of social spending and reduce universal benefits (Gugushvili and Hirst, 2014; van Oorschot and Roosma, 2015). The global financial crisis reinforced this shift. The impact on poverty and inequality critically depends on the design of the targeting such as eligibility criteria and limited take-up. This is illustrated with two cases, the Czech Republic and Ireland; each has high fiscal redistribution and has increased it in the past decade; Ireland by increasing means testing and the Czech Republic by moving from means testing to another way of targeting benefits based on variables correlated with poverty (notably the number of children) that avoid stigma, reduce administrative costs and burdens, and minimize work disincentives (Boxes 3 and 4). Both approaches were successful. Their experiences show that redistribution can be improved in different ways.

24. Thus, old-age spending grew faster than other benefits, including automatic stabilizers. They contributed to more than 60 percent of the increase in social spending in Europe during the last decade. This is not driven by the aging of the population. Between 2006 and 2012, the number of pension beneficiaries in the EU increased by 3 percent, while real pension expenditure rose by 11.7 percent (Eurostat, 2016).29

uA01fig14

Composition of the Changes in Social Spending

(2007–14, percentage points of GDP)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Source: Eurostat.Note: Social assistance covers family/children, social exclusion, and housing. Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.
uA01fig15

Beneficiaries of Unemployment Benefits in the EU by Age Group and Type of Contract

(in percent of unemployed)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Source: Janine Leschke.

25. The design of unemployment benefit systems also contributed to increased youth poverty. The share of young unemployed receiving unemployment benefits has declined since 2007 and is significantly smaller than the share for older unemployed (Leschke, 2015). Unemployment benefit systems offer less generous protection for the young than for the rest of the working age population mainly because of eligibility criteria and duration of unemployment benefits. Regarding eligibility, because unemployment benefits are insurance-based, they require a minimum contribution period (which varies across Europe), a criterion that the young have difficulty meeting, either because they are unemployed after leaving school or because precarious and short-term job contracts limit their contribution periods. In 2012, youth without employment histories were eligible for unemployment benefits or unemployment assistance in 10 of the 21 European Union members of the OECD. For those not eligible, social assistance was available everywhere except in two countries that had a minimum age requirement (Carcillo and others, 2015). Moreover, duration of unemployment benefits is often linked to a contribution period or the age of the unemployed (Arnold and others, 2015; Queyranne, 2017), leading to a shorter effective duration of unemployment benefits for the young.

C. Taxes Could Play a Larger Role in Reducing Income Inequality

26. Taxes play a much smaller role in reducing inequalities in Europe (Figure 4). This is also evident in the findings above (Tables 1 and 2). First, indirect taxes (35.1 percent of total tax revenues), which are generally considered regressive (IMF, 2017), contribute more than direct taxes (33.8 percent) to revenue. In addition, social security contributions (SSC) are generally levied at flat rates, except in some countries which reduce SSC for low income earners (OECD, 2014). Progressivity of direct taxes (personal income tax and SSC) remains low in many countries at both lower and higher income levels, especially in Eastern Europe, contributing to their limited redistributive impact (IMF, 2017). However, many advanced European economies improved personal income tax progressivity for low-income earners through in-work benefits (Joumard and others 2012), and family benefits for low-income families with children (OECD, 2014b). Taxes on capital income and wealth, which are mostly borne by older generations, play a marginal role (both in terms of GDP and as a share of total taxes) including taxes on inheritances and gifts which could help limit intergenerational inequality. Importantly, there has been a sharp decline in taxes levied on capital and financial transactions in Europe during 2007–15 (Clements and others, 2015; IMF, 2017).

uA01fig16

Personal Income Tax and Social Security Contribution Progressivity, 2015

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: OECD and IMF staff calculations.Note: Progressivity at low (high) income level is calculated as the difference between the average rate of income tax and the employees’ social security contributions for a single person (without children) at 67 percent of average earnings (at 167 percent of average earnings) and at average earnings. Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.

Czech Republic: Reforming the Targeting of Social Spending

The Czech Republic has one of the lowest inequality and at-risk-of-poverty rates in the EU and OECD, while its social spending as a share of GDP remains below the average and heavily focused on pensions. The low inequality level can be explained by the redistributive policies targeted at low-income groups and most at-risk-of-poverty groups: the unemployed, single parent families, and families with two and more children.

In the 2007–08 tax and welfare reform, the Czech Republic moved away from income testing of family benefits to a single eligibility threshold, and simultaneously increased tax credits (basic and per child).1 The objectives were to address some of the well-known drawbacks of means testing i.e., to make the social system simpler, cheaper and more user friendly by reducing the paperwork for the social service users. In addition, families with children enjoy a significantly lower effective tax wedge. Finally, all social benefits, except for pensions and housing benefits, ceased to be automatically indexed to cost of living measures, and the unemployment benefit was tightened.

Social benefits became more efficient at reducing inequalities and alleviating poverty. In contrast to many other countries in Europe, the risk of poverty of the young has declined in the Czech Republic while total spending on family benefits remained almost unchanged. Fiscal redistribution is reducing income inequality by the same amount in 2015 as in 2007 (a reduction of the Gini of 0.22). At the same time, pensions continue to play the biggest role in fiscal redistribution and were safeguarded at the time of post-crisis fiscal consolidation. However, unlike other European countries, it did not result in the increase in inequality across generations. Real incomes of the elderly grew slower than for other age groups and the ratio of 65+/18–24 incomes stayed below 1 (at 0.85 and unchanged).

uA01fig17

Tax wedge Difference and Change in Youth Poverty

(percentage points)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat; OECD; and IMF staff calculations.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.

Recent fiscal measures adopted in 2016–17 include further increases in income tax credits for families with children. While these measures help reduce poverty and inequality, their design could be improved to bring down very high marginal effective tax rate on secondary earners, which is one of the key factors constraining labor force participation of women with young children.

1 Key measures included the introduction of a higher standard tax credit (2008), the change in housing allowance and the social assistance supplement for housing (2007), the changes in family benefits (2007–08), the reform of the minimum living standard and the introduction of the single personal income tax rate. The first four of these reforms apply primarily to households with earnings below the average wage (Dalsgaard, 2008).

Ireland: Increasing the Targeting of Social Spending

The Irish social protection system mainly targets the neediest through highly means-tested social transfers. Ireland combines a progressive tax system with a high share of means-testing of social benefits: about a third of social protection and about 55 percent of pensions, which play a limited redistributive role in Ireland, are excluded (Giustiniani, 2017).

During the global financial crisis, the share of means-tested benefits increased. Aimed at improving the social conditions of the most disadvantaged, while keeping adequate incentives to return to work, the system of social benefits was significantly recalibrated: eligibility criteria were tightened, means testing was strengthened, the duration of some benefits was shortened, and allowances were in some cases reduced, while back-to-work/school programs were reinforced. Recently, Ireland has sought to address work disincentives created by the tax benefit system by tapering the withdrawal of benefits when beneficiaries return to work.

Ireland’s welfare system performs strongly in mitigating income inequality and poverty. Social benefit spending in cash (in purchasing power and per capita) is in line with the EU average but its welfare system seems to be more focused on poverty reduction (measured by the difference between the share of population at risk of poverty before and after transfers) than on income redistribution. However, if pensions are excluded, Ireland’s efficiency in redistributing income and fighting poverty is well-above EU peers. This suggests that the degree of income redistribution that other EU countries achieve through pension spending, is achieved through social benefits in Ireland and direct taxes.

uA01fig18

Income Redistribution and Social Benefits, 2007–14

(averages)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

uA01fig19

Income Redistribution and Social Benefits, 2007–14

(excl. pensions, averages)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

uA01fig20

At-Risk-of-Poverty and Social Benefits, 2007–14

(averages)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

uA01fig21

At-Risk-of-Poverty and Social Benefits, 2007–14

(excl. pensions, averages)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Contributor: Alessandro Giustiniani.Sources: EUROMOD, Eurostat, and IMF staff calculations.1 Positive values indicate a lower Gini coefficient after social transfers and hence a more equitable income distribution.2 Positive values indicate a decline in the at-risk-of-poverty ratio due to social transfers.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.

Conclusion: Policy Implications

27. Overall income inequality has remained broadly stable in the EU over the past decade but disparities in poverty and income inequality across generations have increased markedly. Developments and drivers of overall inequality are well documented but the generational dimension of inequality has received much less attention. In Europe, real disposable incomes of the young have fallen behind those of other generations. Also, the young are facing increasing risks of poverty relative to those faced by other generations. This SDN is a first step in documenting these widening income and poverty gaps across generations in Europe and in discussing the role of labor market developments and public policies.

28. The ongoing cyclical upturn is likely to improve opportunities for the young, but policy measures aimed at labor markets, social protection, and fiscal redistribution are nonetheless needed to stop the young from falling further behind over time. Low youth incomes and youth poverty are rooted in high youth unemployment and weaknesses in public policies. These problems, around for some time, have been aggravated during the latest recession. In many EU countries, the youth unemployment problem has reached macroeconomic proportions, with potentially grave social and political consequences. Addressing them may involve trade-offs between different generations but there are many measures that would be mutually beneficial, notably those that improve labor market functioning and the skills of the young and macro-economic policies that avoid large shocks. With significant disparities in income inequality and poverty across countries and regions in the EU, policies to address these problems will need to take into account each country’s specific circumstances.

29. High youth unemployment has been a major source of growing youth poverty. Unemployment disproportionately affects the young. Also, there is a strong association in the data between unemployment and youth poverty. Facilitating the integration of the young into the labor market is a crucial task facing policymakers. In this regard, market-based and meritocratic institutions in general can help mitigate inequality of opportunity, offering relatively larger benefits for the young. Turning to more specific measures, these could target:

  • Raising labor demand. As the labor tax wedge is contributing to higher unemployment, consideration could be given to reducing it for low wage workers—a segment of the labor market where there are many youth—through targeted cuts in social security contributions but without reducing eligibility for benefits. Alternatively, higher in-work benefits such as tax credits could create space to lower costs for employers.

  • Strengthening supply. Well-designed apprenticeship systems, as well as ALMPs that emphasize on-the-job training and reduce skill mismatches, could provide a pool of workers with job-related experience and skills, improve the quality of available jobs for the young, and thereby help reduce labor market duality. To this end, careful design, monitoring, and evaluation, are required. This would, however, imply strengthening cooperation among employers, employee representatives, and the state, which is a long-term task.

  • Ensuring adequate social coverage in a changing job market. Better protection of workers against the impact of less-stable working conditions through stronger integration into social protection systems could mitigate the insecurity associated with labor market duality, and could yield significant gains for the youth—while preserving labor market flexibility. This is becoming ever more important as automation and digitalization tend to increase the prevalence of such working conditions, particularly for the young. In the medium term, countries may need to revisit their social protection systems which are largely insurance-based and whose benefits mainly depend on employment history.

30. Fiscal redistribution needs to be more inclusive to better tackle youth poverty. Social protection schemes have reduced old-age poverty but they have not prevented an increase in youth poverty following the global financial crisis. Reducing youth poverty is likely to require additional resources. However, for countries with an already high level of social spending and a heavy tax burden, as well as limited fiscal space, this may not be an option. In these countries, reducing youth poverty and inequality across generations in a fiscally-neutral way may require partially rebalancing fiscal redistribution to better protect the young, while continuing to protect minimum pension assistance schemes to avoid reversing the trend decline in old-age poverty. Reducing youth poverty and inequality across generations can be achieved by:

  • Reforming unemployment and non-pension benefits to better address challenges arising from high youth unemployment and job instability. Rather than creating new allowances, this calls for reviewing eligibility requirements as well as the design and efficiency of transfers. It also implies better consideration of the distributional impact across age groups of spending measures and reforms implemented to achieve fiscal consolidation when needed.

  • Reforming pensions to increase sustainability and reduce inequality across generations. In addition to ensuring a more uniform approach to indexation across benefits (pension vs. non-pension), pension reforms should aim to improve burden-sharing across current pensioners and future retirees.

  • Ringfencing and increasing the efficiency of education spending and training of high school drop-outs to increase the capacity of the young to integrate more easily and on a more sustainable basis into the labor market. Investment in education reduces persistence of income inequality from one generation to the next and increases potential growth (IMF, 2017).

  • Increasing the redistributive impact of fiscal policy with a more progressive tax system. Besides its direct impact on inequality, increased progressivity could raise the redistributive impact of non-means tested, taxable social benefits. Moreover, taxes on capital income and wealth could play a larger redistributive role.

  • Rebalancing the tax burden across generations. This can be achieved in various ways, such as via reductions in social contributions paid by employees, while increasing a tax on all incomes paid by all households, as is being implemented in France, where this rebalancing can be revenue neutral but will have a redistributive impact.

Appendix I. Regional Disparities in Poverty and Real Income Across Europe1

Although this SDN focuses on aggregate European trends, undoubtedly inequality and poverty across generations also vary significantly across regions. To tease out the main insights from these regional disparities, we classify countries into six distinct regions, based on geographical location and key features in the design of their social protection system. Figure I.1 provides a snapshot of real incomes and poverty rates across age groups in each of these regions for the years 2007 and 2015.

  • In Western Europe, real income rose across all age groups, but changes in poverty were less evenly distributed. The working age population experienced an increase in poverty, which was especially pronounced for the young—those aged 18 to 24 years old. Conversely, poverty among the elderly declined.

  • In Ireland and the United Kingdom, real incomes declined slightly for the working age population, whereas real income of the elderly increased significantly. While poverty declined across all age groups, the decline was especially pronounced for the elderly.

  • Southern European countries were hard hit by the global financial crisis. Real incomes declined for the working age population, most notably for the young. Whereas poverty among the elderly declined, all other age groups experienced a rise in the risk of poverty. Among the youth, the increase of more than 6 percentage points means that today one in four youths in Southern Europe is at risk of poverty.

  • In Northern Europe, real incomes today are above their pre-crisis level for all age groups, but youth poverty is significantly higher in relative terms.

  • In the case of Eastern Europe and the Baltics, real incomes across all age groups experienced growth relative to pre-crisis levels, and therefore the risk of poverty was more muted. However, it is also worth noting that, although the percentage change in the poverty rate was relatively low, the increase was nevertheless higher for the youth.

Figure I.1.
Figure I.1.

EU: Real Income and Poverty by Region, 2007–151

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: Eurostat and IMF staff calculations.1 Panel shows the compound annual growth rate of median equivalized real income and the change in percentage points of the persistent at-risk-of-poverty rate. Income as change from 2010–15 for Croatia. Poverty as change from 2008–15 for Eastern Europe and the Baltics, change from 2010–15 for Romania, change from 2009–15 for Bulgaria, and excluding Croatia.

Appendix II. The Econometrics of Assessing the Effects on Inequality, Poverty, and Labor Market Outcomes

A. Effect of Fiscal Policies and Labor Market Structure on Inequality and Poverty

Fiscal policies such as direct taxes and social spending are important due to their distributional impact (Martinez-Vazquez and others, 2012; Clements and others, 2015). At the same time, labor market structure affects inequality and poverty from the direct impact on employment and wage levels (Jaumotte and Buitron, 2015). We employ a panel regression setup to estimate the impact of fiscal policies and labor market structure on income inequality and poverty in Europe over the past decade. The sample consists of annual panels of EU countries over the period 2007–15. Specifically, the empirical analysis is based on the following fixed-effects specification:

Yit=α(Fiscalvariables)it+β(Labormarketvariables)it+γ(Controls)it+θt+ηi+εit

in which Yit denotes the selected income inequality and poverty indicators (see below), (Fiscal variables)it include direct tax revenue in percent of GDP, public social spending in percent of GDP, and marginal effective tax rate of median income earner, (Labor market variables)it include long-term unemployment and labor market flexibility, (Controls)it is a set of standard control variables, including output gap, per capita income, education level, and trade openness (a proxy for the degree of globalization). As part of the robustness check (see below), we also consider additional variables such as composition of public social spending, labor market duality, and ICT capital stock (a proxy for technological progress). Table II.1 gives a full description of these variables and their source. While we attempt to use the appropriate econometric techniques, the reader should be aware that the estimation method may not adequately address the endogeneity of fiscal and labor market variables (e.g. the degree and persistence of income inequality and poverty may contribute to shaping fiscal policies and labor market structure by influencing public opinion regarding income redistribution.) and omitted variable bias (e.g. impact from market liberalization policies) in such macro-level cross-country estimations.

Table II.1.

Variable Definitions

article image

The analysis focuses on the heterogeneity of the effect of fiscal policies and labor market structure on income inequality and poverty across different age group. Regarding income inequality, we estimate the model described above by using as dependent variables both an aggregate inequality measure (i.e., Gini index of equivalized disposable income) and relative income ratios constructed using the median equivalized disposable income of different age groups against that of the young (i.e., 18–24 years old). On poverty, we look at both absolute poverty measure (i.e., severe material deprivation rate) and relative poverty measure (i.e., persistence of at risk poverty measure). We realign the dependent variables accordingly before estimation, given inequality and relative poverty measures from Eurostat have a one-year lag except for UK and Ireland as the data are based on the EU-SILC survey. We then estimate the baseline model for the overall population and for each age group with robust standard errors clustered at the country level. Tables II.2 and II.3 present the full set of the baseline results, including the results for the relative poverty measure.

Table II.2.

Income Inequality Panel Regression

article image
Source: IM F staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

The baseline results appear to be robust against different model specifications (Tables II.4 and II.5)1.

  • We first extend the model to explore the impact of composition of social spending by adding non-pension social spending in percent of total social spending, as different types of social assistance may induce different behavioral response hence affecting the impact on inequality and poverty (Neihues 2010). The results indicate that impact from a higher non-pension spending contribution to total social spending is small in reducing income inequality once controlling for the overall social spending level, and estimates are generally statistically insignificant (Table II.4, columns 1–2). Non-pension social spending contribution does not appear to affect much the poverty indicators either, except for older age groups (Table II.5, columns 1–3). The positive significant estimates may reflect the importance of pension payment in lifting people out of poverty for these age groups.

  • Secondly, we assess the impact of labor market duality (Cazes and others, 2014) by introducing temporary employment share as a proxy of duality to the model. The results suggest very limited additional explanatory power of the temporary employment share variable. Estimates of impact on income inequality and absolute poverty indicators are statistically insignificant (Table II.4, columns 3–4, Table II.5, column 4). When relative poverty is considered, temporary employment share tends to reduce the risk of poverty for the working age group (statistically significant only for the 25–49 age group), but increase the risk of poverty for the group over 65 (Table II.5, columns 5–6), possibly reflecting impact on the denominator (i.e., the median disposable income level).

  • Finally, we test the variation of standard control variables of the model by including ICT capital stock to control for technological development (Greenwood, 1997, Pavnik, 2011). The coefficient estimates in again show that they do not have any material impact on our baseline results (Table II.4, columns 5–6, Table II.5, column 7).

Table II.3.

Poverty Panel Regression

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.11 For at-persistent-risk-of-poverty variables, lagged independent variables are used for the period in which dependent variables are measured, except for the global competitiveness indicator variable.
Table II. 4.

Robustness Check of Income Inequality Panel Regression

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ICT is Information and Communications technology.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table II.5.

Robustness Check of Poverty Panel Regression

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. ICT is Information and Communications technology.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

B. Impact of Labor Market Institutions and Business Cycle on Unemployment

We study the impact of labor market institutions and business cycle on unemployment using a panel regression setup. The sample consists of annual panels of EU countries over the period of 2007–14 subject to data availability. Specifically, we estimate the following fixed-effects specification:

Yit=α+βXit+θi+ηt+ϵit

in which Yit denotes labor market outcome variables in country i and at time t that include unemployment rates of different age groups (i.e., 15–24 years old and 25–64 years old) and their differences. Control variables Xit include variables on labor market institution, output gap, and interaction terms between output gap and a subset of labor market institution variables. To identify the role of institutional factors, some studies use multivariate estimation (Jaumotte and Buitron, 2015) or employ univariate models with interaction terms (Banerji and others, 2015). We explore a combination of both approaches. Our model includes multiple labor market features. More specifically, we focus on tax wedge, union density, coordination of wage-setting, spending on ALMP training and share of temporary workers (see Table II.1 for variable definitions). In addition, the analysis includes interaction terms with output gap for share of temporary workers to examine the cyclical feature of its impact.

We have also tested additional institutional factors such as opportunity costs, hiring costs, labor market duality, collective bargaining, education, and labor market polices (as in Banerji and others, 2014). For instance, we used net replacement rate, inactivity trap, ratio of minimum to median wage, EPL, share of low- or high-educated workers, LMP categories 2–7, 8 and 9 (Table II.1) in different specifications. However, the result suggests that these variables are not statistically significant. Moreover, given multicollinearity among some of these labor market institution variables, we used a general-to-specific approach to eliminate explanatory variables to arrive at the specification analyzed in Section II. Nevertheless, the reader should be aware of potential biases of these estimates, as endogeneity issues including those from omitted variables are hard to fully tackle (Daveri, 2001).

Appendix III. Data Quality and Comparability

A. Survey Data and Simulations

European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC)

The EU-SILC is a panel survey conducted in EU and other European countries whose micro-household data underpin both the Eurostat Income and Living Conditions (ILC) database as well as the OECD Income Distribution Database. The survey provides both cross-sectional data pertaining to a given time or time-period as well as longitudinal data pertaining to individual-level changes over time, observed periodically or over a four-year period (“European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC), Access to Microdata”). It has been noted that the comparability issues posed by differences in data collection across countries (for example, including reliance on household surveys as opposed to ‘register’ data) as well as the allowance for different concepts of self-employment income are addressed in the survey by conceptual harmonization of target variables and the so called “ex ante output harmonization model” employed by Eurostat. (“Comparative EU statistics on income and living conditions”, 2007)

Limitations still exist, including the exclusion of social transfers in kind from disposable income, the exclusion of capital gains, and the restriction of the data to the population living in private households.

Labor Force Survey (LFS)

LFS data in the period relevant to this note are considered highly comparable across countries and time given the EU-LFS use of output harmonization. Increased content stability and frequency of surveys have also been implemented from 1998 to counterbalance allowances for country-specific surveys. Further information regarding data methodology as well as the underlying microdata can be found at the Eurostat EU LFS webpage (“European Union Labor Force Survey”).

European Social Survey (ESS)

The ESS subjects itself to extremely stringent sampling and collection design, data processing, and quality assessment checks, recognizing that quantifying such concepts as preference or attitude are particularly prone to survey design error, non-representative sampling errors, or timing and national context biases. To this end, the ESS employs periodic reports on measurement quality and equivalence of survey responses vis-à-vis the concept of interest, frequent nonresponse bias analyses, response rate floors, and monitoring and recording of contextual data taken from national media (“Monitoring National Contexts”).

EUROMOD

This multi-country tax-benefit microsimulation model simulates a standard set of tax and benefit instruments to analyze the impact of actual, proposed, alternative and hypothetical national policies on household incomes, work incentives, and government budgets of 27 EU countries both individually and at the EU-level. EU-SILC data constitutes a majority of the micro-data input on individual and household circumstances and ensures comparability at that level.

Data limitations preclude the model from considering benefit non-take-up and tax evasion, and although corrections are included in countries where these phenomena are widespread, further technical refinement is needed before the possibility of an overestimation of taxes and benefits can be rejected. Additional descriptions on methods and data are available in Sutherland and Figari (2013) and at https://www.euromod.ac.uk/using-euromod/statistics/.

OECD Pensions at a Glance

Pension systems of all sample countries are directly comparable and encompass reforms legislated before June 2015 as well as all parameters of the system from 2014 onwards. Values reflect benefits of an individual worker entering the system today at age 20 and retiring at a normal pension age defined the statutory retirement age. A single set of economic baseline assumptions (10) are used for all countries such that observed differences in pension levels reflect differences in the system and policies alone (OECD, 2015b).

B. Measuring Poverty

At Risk of Poverty Thresholds and Rates

Unless otherwise indicated, the relative at-risk-of-poverty threshold is defined as 60 percent of the national median equivalized disposable income. The at-risk-of-poverty rate is then calculated as the proportion of persons with an equivalized disposable income below that threshold. Where figures for subgroups exist, they are calculated based on the poverty threshold for the entire population. (Eurostat, 2014) The persistent at-risk-of-poverty rate shows the percentage of the population living in households where the equivalized disposable income was below the at-risk-of-poverty threshold for the current year and at least two out of three of the preceding years.

Issues with Relative Poverty

The measures of poverty defined above are some of the most commonly used and fall under the category of relative poverty, or the proportion of people earning less than a set proportion of a country’s median income. When examining poverty over time, however, it is important to note that these relative measures obscure the effects of changes to the poverty threshold that occur when the living standards of the entire population change. This was certainly the case after the financial crisis, when countries saw an overall decline in national income which led to a decrease in the median income, allowing relative poverty to remain somewhat stable and masking the absolute deterioration of living conditions.

More conceptual concerns regarding the sole use of income as a proxy for living standards and poverty point out that the omission of other assets and wealth from the calculus, while understandable given the scarcity of data on wealth, presents an incomplete picture of economic well-being (Foster and others, 2013).

A Note on Equivalization

The process of equivalization of household income is necessary to disaggregate households into individual population units for analysis, however the implicit assumption of equally-shared income can be problematic, particularly for the youngest dependents. If the main breadwinners in a household are over age 25, measures of youth poverty (18–24) based on equivalized household income would likely underestimate youth poverty; if the young are the main breadwinners, then youth poverty would be overestimated. Recognizing that youth incomes are closely tied to those of their parents when they live in the same household, we have chosen where possible to exclude children under 18 from the analysis.

Alternative Measures

To isolate the development of poverty over time from the effects of changing poverty lines, some measure of absolute poverty is required. This can be accomplished by fixing the cutoff level of the poverty threshold even in the face of economic distress or growth, as is the case with measures of anchored poverty. Here, the indirect effects of changing standards of living are held constant (except for inflation adjustments).

Material Deprivation is another, broader approach to poverty measurement which includes considerations of both income and wealth, and aggregates various dimensions of non-monetary well-being into a single measure. This sort of asset-based poverty measurement is critical in capturing an individual’s “command over resources”; something that income measures alone cannot communicate (Boarini and others, 2006).

Alternative Approaches in the Measurement of Poverty

article image
Source: OECD.

C. Measuring Inequality

This note relies primarily on EU-SILC measures of median equivalized net income as well as Gini indices to examine income distribution and inequality across regions and age groups. Recognizing the extremely multi-faceted nature of inequality, additional structural dimensions such as labor market dualities, the unevenness of access to social safety nets, and inequities in redistributive schemes are also examined. Wealth inequality, yet another important driver, is outside the scope of this note.

Equivalized Disposable Income

Statistics on disposable income refer to the total income of a household available for spending or saving, divided by the number of household members converted into equivalized adults by Eurostat. People with missing values for equivalized disposable income as well as those living in collective households and in institutions are excluded from calculations. The equivalence scale considers:

  • the first household member aged 14 years or older as 1 person

  • each other household member aged 14 years or older as 0.5 person

  • each household member aged 13 years or younger as 0.3 person (Eurostat, 2014).

For the purposes of regional time-series analysis, these data are converted into 2013 prices by deflating by national consumer price indices, indexed to 100, then weighted by PPP before aggregation into their respective regions.

Gini

One of the most common measures of inequality, the Gini coefficient is advantageous in that it is independent of the sample mean and population size, symmetrical, and sensitive to transfers of income from the top to the bottom of a distribution. Unless otherwise specified, figures and tables referencing Gini coefficients in this note refer to the Gini of equivalized disposable income. Unfortunately, because this index is not decomposable or additive across subgroups like age, it is not sufficient when a more granular analysis of the population is desired.

Labor’s share of income, which has been declining steadily alongside the rise in the Gini coefficient in what appears to be a correlated fashion, has at times enjoyed popularity as a proxy for income inequality. Clements and others (2015) discuss the ways in which changes in labor shares affect the dynamics of income inequality, concluding alongside other recent examinations of this relationship such as Piketty (2014) that the unequal distribution of income within labor’s as well as capital’s share has more weight as a determinant of income inequality, particularly at the top of the wage distribution.

Thus, to provide a profile of income inequality across age groups, simple ratios comparing the median net income of one age group to another are also included in the analysis.

Appendix IV. Preferences for Redistribution

To illustrate the drivers of demand for redistribution in Europe we rely on the European Social Surveys using agreement to statement “Government should take measures to reduce differences in income levels” of the European Social Surveys. Answers range from 1 to 5 with 5 indicating the strongest agreement with the statement. The survey is conducted every two years and is available up to 2014. It covers most but not all EU countries. Changes in demand for redistribution can be measured for 16 EU countries for the period 2006–14 and 18 EU countries for the period 2002–14.

As illustrated in Figure III.1, the demand for redistribution is associated:

  • Positively to the level of income inequality and even more to the level of poverty. This is true for relative poverty (as measured by at-risk-of-poverty and persistence of risk-of-poverty rates) and absolute poverty (as measured by severe material deprivation). This suggests that the population expects fiscal redistribution to tackle both issues.

  • Negatively to the level of social spending. This is a standard result of literature1 that may explain why the three countries where demand for redistribution declined significantly over 2002–14 (France, Finland, and Denmark) are also the countries where social protection spending is the highest in Europe.2 As social spending must be financed, the tax burden may also negatively affect preferences for redistribution. In this context, the period 2006–14 saw a massive increase in taxes for fiscal consolidation purposes in France.

  • Weakly to macroeconomic shocks and unemployment. Though literature highlights the link between demand for redistribution and macro-economic shocks and notably being unemployed (e.g., Alesina and Giuliano, 2009; Guiliano and Spilimbergo, 2014), it appears relatively weak in Europe during the recent period. However, when the period 2002–14 is divided in pre-GFC (2002–06) and global financial crisis/post-global-financial-crisis period (2006–14), demand for redistribution increased significantly in countries that experienced most the impact of the crisis: Ireland, Spain, Portugal. Notably, while demand for redistribution was declining in Ireland and Portugal before the global financial crisis, it increased during the global financial crisis.

  • Differ on which age group it should target. When focusing on poverty, demand for redistribution appears more associated with children’s and working age population’s poverty than with elderly’s poverty. Strikingly, there is a negative association with young adults’ poverty (18–24 years old) suggesting that youth poverty is not the focus of the population concern with poverty. When one considers income inequality, demand for redistribution is more associated with income inequality among elderly than among working age population (Figure IV.2).3

uA01fig22

Change in Preferences for Redistribution, 2006–14

(Scores from 1 to 5; 5 is the most in favor of redistribution)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: European Social Survey; and IMF staff calculations.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes.
Figure IV.1
Figure IV.1

Demand for Redistribution in Europe

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: European Social Survey, Eurostat, and IMF staff calculations.1/ Using at-risk-of-poverty instead of persistence of poverty provides a similar picture.
Figure IV.2.
Figure IV.2.

Demand for Redistribution in Europe and Poverty by Age Group

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2018, 001; 10.5089/9781484338445.006.A001

Sources: European Social Survey, Eurostat, OECD, and IMF staff calculations.1/ Using at-persistent-risk of poverty increases the correlation for elderly to 0.32 but remains significantly lower than for less than 18 years (0.49) or for the 18–64-year-old (0.55) while there is no correlation for the young between 18 and 24 (0.07).2/ Using the market Gini leads to similar results.

Literature distinguishes two motivations for demand of protection: self-interest and social beliefs about fairness and social justice.4 If self-interest is the main motivation, demand for redistribution of a specific age group should be more correlated to poverty / inequality affecting this particular age group than poverty / inequality of the whole population while the reverse would show if social norms are the main driver of demand for redistribution. Except in the case of the young, the correlations do not allow to distinguish the main motivation:

  • For all age groups (less than 18, 18–64, 65 and older), the demand for redistribution is positively associated to all indicators of poverty, whether one considers the poverty of the whole population or poverty of the own age group.

  • The demand for protection of the retirement age population is strongly associated to absolute poverty but little (and much less than for other age groups) to relative poverty. Again, this is true whether we look at poverty of the whole population or poverty of the elderly only.

  • The demand for protection of the young (18–24years old) is positively associated to all indicators of poverty of the whole population. This link is stronger than for any other age group. However, the demand for redistribution of the young is not associated (or in one instance negatively associated) to poverty indicator of their own age group. This is the only case where social beliefs appear stronger than self-interest.

References

  • Alesina, A. and P. Giuliano. 2009. “Preferences for Redistribution.” IZA Discussion Paper 4056, Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, A., S. Stantcheva, and E. Teso. 2017. “Intergenerational Mobility and Preferences for Redistribution.” NBER Working Paper 23027, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arnold J., and C. Farinha Rodrigues. 2015. “Reducing Inequality and Poverty in Portugal.” OECD Economics Department Working Paper 1258, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Avram, S., H. Levy, and H. Sutherland. 2014. “Income Redistribution in the European Union.” IZA Journal of European Labor Studies 3 (1): 129.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banerji, A., H. Lin, and S. Saksonovs. 2015. “Youth Unemployment in Advanced Europe: Okun’s Law and Beyond.” IMF Working Paper 15/5, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banerji, A., S. Saksonovs, H. Lin, and R. Blavy. 2014. “Youth Unemployment in Advanced Economies in Europe: Searching for Solutions.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 14/11, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bargain O., T. Callan, K. Doorley, and C. Keane. 2015. “Changes in Income Distributions and the Role of Tax-benefit Policy during the Great Recession: An International Perspective.” Forthcoming in Fiscal Studies. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/1475-5890.12113/full.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bassanini A., and R. Duval. 2007. “The Determinants of Unemployment across OECD Countries: Reassessing the role of Policies and Institutions.” OECD Economic Studies 2006 1: 786.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benabou, R., and E. A. Ok. 2001. “Social Mobility and the Demand for Redistribution: The POUM Hypothesis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (2): 44787.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., and J. Ostry. 2011. “Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of the Same Coin?IMF Staff Discussion Note 11/08, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boarini, R., and M. M. d’Ercole. 2006. “Measures of Material Deprivation in OECD Countries.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 37, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boeri T., and J. Jimeno. 2016. “Learning from the Great Divergence in Unemployment in Europe during the Crisis.” Labour Economics 41 (C): 3246.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brunello G., P. Garibaldi, and E. Wasmer. 2007. Education and Training in Europe. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Cahuc P., S. Carcillo, U. Rinne, and K. F. Zimmermann. 2013. “Youth Unemployment in Old Europe: The Polar Cases of France and Germany.” IZA Journal of European Labor Studies 2 (1): 123.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carcillo, S., R. Fernández, S. Königs, and A. Minea. 2015. “NEET Youth in the Aftermath of the Crisis.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 164, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carmeci L., and L. Mauro. 2003. “Long Run Growth and Investment in Education: Does Unemployment Matter?Journal of Macroeconomics 25: 12337.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cazes, S., and J. R. de Laiglesia. 2014. Temporary Contracts, Labour Market Segmentation and Wage Inequality. Geneva: International Labour Organization.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Checchi D. 2006. The Economics of Education. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Choudhry, M., E. Marelli, and M. Signorelli. 2012. “Youth and Total Unemployment Rate: The Impact of Policies and Institutions.” Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali 121 (1): 6386.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ciminelli, G., E. Ernst, M. Giuliodori, and R. Merola. 2017. “The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality.” Research Paper 19, International Labour Organization, Geneva.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clements, B., R. de Mooij, S. Gupta, and M. Keen. 2015. Inequality and Fiscal Policy, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

  • Crépon, B., and G. van den Berg. 2016. “Active Labor Market Policies.” Working Paper 2016:17, Institute for Evaluation of Labour Market and Education Policy.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dabla-Norris, E., K. Kochhar, N. Suphaphiphat, F. Ricka, and E. Tsounta. 2015. “Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality: A Global Perspective.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/13, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dalsgaard, T. 2008. “Tax and Welfare Reforms in the Czech Republic—Structural Implications and ChallengesIMF Working Paper 08/52, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Daveri, F. 2001. “Labor Taxes and Unemployment: A Survey of the Aggregate Evidence.” CeRP Working Paper 18, Center for Research on Pensions and Welfare Policies, Turin.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Agostini, P., A. Paulus, H. Sutherland, and I. Tasseva. 2014. “The Effect of Tax-Benefit Changes on Income Distribution in EU Countries since the Beginning of the Economic Crisis.” European Commission, Directorate-General for Employment, Social Affairs and Inclusion Research Note 02/2013, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Destefanis, S., and G. Mastromatteo. 2010. “More Jobs? A Panel Analysis of the Lisbon Strategy.” CSEF Working Paper, Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance, University of Naples.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dunne, A., D. Ulicna, I. Murphy, and M. Golubeva. 2014. Working with Young People: The Value of Youth Work in the European Union. Study commissioned by the European Commission.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dustmann, C., B. Fitzenberger, U. Schonberg, and A. Spitz-Oener. 2014. “From Sick Man of Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28 (1): 16788.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engbom N., E. Detragiache, and F. Raei. 2015. “The German Labor Market Reforms and Post-Unemployment Earnings.” IMF Working Paper 15/162, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2015a. The 2015 Ageing Report—Economic and Budgetary Projections for the 28 EU Member States (2013–2060). Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2015b. The 2015 Pension Adequacy Report: Current and Future Income Adequacy in Old Age in the EU, Volume I. Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General for Employment, Social Affairs and Inclusion.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC), Access to Microdata. n.d. Eurostat. Retrieved June 2017 from http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/microdata/european-union-statistics-on-income-and-living-conditions.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eurostat. 2014. “Income and Living Conditions Dataset.” European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions Working Paper.

  • Eurostat. 2016. Social Protection Statistics—Pension Expenditure and Pension Beneficiaries. http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Social_protection_statistics_-_pension_expenditure_and_pension_beneficiaries

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eurostat. 2017. “General Government Expenditure in the EU in 2015.” News Release 39/2017.

  • Foster, M., H. Levy, M. M. D’Ercole, and N. Ruiz. 2013. “The OECD Approach to Measure and Monitor Income Poverty across Countries.” In UNECE Working Paper 17.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flash Barometer of the European Parliament. 2014. European Youth in 2014—Analytical Synthesis. Brussels: EU Directorate-General for Communications.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Geyer, J., P. Haan, and K. Wrohlich. 2014. “The Effects of Family Policy on Mothers’ Labor Supply: Combining Evidence from a Structural Model and a Natural Experiment.” Discussion Paper 1366, DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giuliano, P., and A. Spilimbergo. 2014. “Growing up in Recession.” Review of Economic Studies 881 (2): 787817.

  • Giustiniani, A. 2017. “Income Inequality and the Welfare System in Ireland: An Overview.” IMF Country Report SM/17/150, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenwood, J. 1997. “The Third Industrial Revolution: Technology, Productivity, and Income Inequality.” American Enterprise Institute Report 435, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gugushvili, D., and D. Hirsch. 2014. Means-Testing or Universalism: What Strategies Best Address Poverty? Loughborough University, Center for Research in Social Policy.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hüttl, P., K. Wilson, and G. Wolff. 2015. “The Growing Intergenerational Divide in Europe.” Bruegel Policy Contribution 2015/17, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Institute for Employment Research (IAB). 2015. “IAB Brief Report 8/2015.” Nuremberg.

  • International Labour Organization (ILO). 2011. Policy Options to Support Young Workers during Recovery.” Youth Employment Programme Policy Brief, Geneva.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Labour Organization (ILO). <