The Fiscal Consequences of Shrinking Populations
Author:
Mr. Benedict J. Clements
Search for other papers by Mr. Benedict J. Clements in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Kamil Dybczak
Search for other papers by Mr. Kamil Dybczak in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Vitor Gaspar
Search for other papers by Vitor Gaspar in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Sanjeev Gupta
Search for other papers by Mr. Sanjeev Gupta in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mauricio Soto
Search for other papers by Mauricio Soto in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

This Staff Discussion Note looks at the stark fiscal challenges posed by the decline and aging of populations between now and 2100. It finds that without reforms, pensions and health spending would rise to 25 percent of GDP by end-century in more developed countries (and 16 percent of GDP in less developed countries), with potentially dire fiscal consequences. Given the uncertainty underlying the population projections and associated large fiscal risks, a multi-pronged approach will be required. This could include entitlement reform—starting now but at a gradual pace; policies that affect demographics and labor markets; and better tax systems and more efficient public expenditure.

Abstract

This Staff Discussion Note looks at the stark fiscal challenges posed by the decline and aging of populations between now and 2100. It finds that without reforms, pensions and health spending would rise to 25 percent of GDP by end-century in more developed countries (and 16 percent of GDP in less developed countries), with potentially dire fiscal consequences. Given the uncertainty underlying the population projections and associated large fiscal risks, a multi-pronged approach will be required. This could include entitlement reform—starting now but at a gradual pace; policies that affect demographics and labor markets; and better tax systems and more efficient public expenditure.

Introduction

1. With fertility rates falling across the globe, populations will start shrinking in many countries over the next few decades. According to the latest UN projections (2015 Revision of the UN World Population Prospects), the world’s population is projected to peak around 2100 and begin to shrink soon thereafter. Populations are already shrinking in several countries, and by the end of the century, populations would be shrinking in nearly 70 percent of the more developed countries and in about 65 percent of the less developed countries (Figure 1).2 These developments would gradually raise the ratio of old individuals to young. The global old-age dependency ratio (population ages 65 and older to population ages 15 to 64) would triple over the next 85 years, driven by a rapid aging in the less developed economies, which account for 83 percent of the world population today (Figure 2). In the more developed economies, the old-age dependency ratio would double over this period.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Countries with Declining Population, 2015–2100

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: UN 2015.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Old-Age Dependency Ratio, 2015–2100

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: UN 2015.

2. In many countries, population aging will pose a formidable fiscal challenge. Today, the more developed economies spend 9½ percent of GDP on public pensions and 6.8 percent of GDP on public health care, compared with 2½ and 3 percent of GDP, respectively, in the less developed countries. Going forward, potentially large increases in age-related expenditures, associated with the projected population aging, could place extreme pressure on public finances in both country groups.

3. This note focuses on the long-term fiscal implications of these demographic developments and explores potential policy options to address them. The contribution of this Staff Discussion Note is threefold. First, using demographic projections from the UN, it provides long-term projections of public pension and health care spending for all countries where data are available, between 2015 and 2100.3 By focusing on projections to 2100, the paper presents the fiscal implications of demographic trends that will be fully realized only over the longer term. Second, it highlights the risks to public finances from the large uncertainty surrounding demographic projections—long-term projections are subject to a high degree of uncertainty. Identifying these risks and devising mitigation strategies is a crucial element of prudent fiscal policy management (Gaspar, Hughes, and Jaramillo, 2015).4 Third, it reviews potential options to address these fiscal pressures. In this regard, the paper also examines the potential role of migration in providing breathing room to reform age-related spending. The remainder of the note is structured as follows. In Section II, we examine the likely development of demographics and age-related spending between now and 2100. Section III reflects on how the “medium” demographic projections from the UN World Population Prospects compare with past trends, highlighting the potential downside risks to fiscal sustainability arising from uncertain demographic projections. Section IV discusses different policies to help address these risks, and Section V concludes.

Long-Term Trends: the Prospect Of Aging, Shrinking Populations, and Higher Age-Related Expenditure

4. Population aging will have a large direct impact on public spending across the globe. Raising the number of elderly increases the costs of public programs, such as pensions and health care. Absent further reforms, age-related expenditures in more developed economies are projected to increase by nearly 8½ percentage points of GDP over 2015–2100 (Table 1).5 These increases would be driven mainly by health care, while pension spending would remain relatively contained owing to past pension reforms. Expenditure pressures are expected to continue beyond 2050, reflecting further population aging, particularly in the less developed economies. The implications are far-reaching. Take, for example, the case of health spending in the more developed countries where these spending increases could catapult public debt ratios over the next 85 years: in present value, the increase in public health spending over 2015–50 is equivalent to 57 percent of today’s GDP, and the present discounted value (PDV) of the increase between 2050 and 2100 would be a staggering 163 percent of GDP.6

Table 1.

Global Public Expenditure on Age-Related Programs, Baseline Scenario 2015–2100

(Percent of GDP)

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations. Notes: Figures refer to unweighted averages for the respective country groups. Projections cover 37 more developed countries and 64 less developed countries. Pension spending projections up to 2050 follow the methodology from Clements, Eich, and Gupta (2014). After 2050, pension projections assume that replacement ratios and coverage rates remain constant, therefore pension spending to GDP increases broadly in line with the old-age dependency ratio. Projections for health care spending, as a share of GDP, are driven by demographic and other factors. The difference between the growth of health care spending and real GDP growth that is not explained by demographics (“excess cost growth”) is assumed to converge to the sample average by 2050, and decline to zero by 2100. The present discounted value is estimated assuming an interest rate-growth differential that converges to 1 percent by 2025 from their current levels of −0.8 for the more developed and −3.8 for the less developed, based on the medians from World Economic Outlook (IMF 2015c) for the respective country groups.

5. Demographic changes also affect fiscal sustainability through their impact on growth.7 The projected slowdown in population growth can translate into lower economic growth (Appendix 1).8 Empirical evidence suggests that changes in economic growth are typically matched by changes in real interest rates (Appendix 2). However, there could be periods over which the interest rate-growth differential may not be constant, including because of demographic changes. Since small changes in the interest-growth differential have large effects on public debt dynamics, one concern is that slower growth could make it more difficult to reduce debt-to-GDP ratios over time. 9 The relationship between interest rate (r) and growth (g) is complex and surrounded by uncertainty, reflecting factors other than demographics, growth, or fiscal policy (Kogan and others 2015; Summers 2014; Escolano 2011). In this note we focus on long-term trends, and thus to estimate PDVs assume that the interest rate-growth differential converges from their current level (−0.7 percent of the more developed and −3.6 for the less developed) to 1 percent by 2025—reaching the average observed in the advanced economies over the past 25 years (Escolano 2010; Turner and Spinelli 2012).

Impact of Demographic Changes on Pension and Health Care Expenditure

Pension expenditure to GDP (PE/GDP) is the product of four main factors: benefit generosity (average pension to GDP per worker), coverage (number of pensioners to the population 65 and older), the inverse of the labor force participation rate (workers to population ages 15–64), and aging, represented by the old-age dependency ratio (population 65 and older to population 15–64).

P E G D P = P E p e n s i o n e r s G D P w o r ker s p e n s i o n e r s p o p 65 + p o p 15 64 w o r k e r s p o p 65 + p o p 15 64 ( 1 )

This implies that pension spending grows in line with the old-age dependency ratio. Intuitively, changes in the old-age dependency ratio affect spending through exogenous changes in either the older population or the working-age population. For example, assuming constant benefit and coverage ratios, an increase in the population ages 65 and older due to an unexpected increase in longevity would translate into higher pension spending for the same level of GDP, thereby increasing PE/GDP. Alternatively, the old-age dependency rate can decrease if the population ages 15–64 turns out to be higher than expected (for example, through immigration). Assuming constant labor force participation and GDP per worker, this would increase the GDP, thereby decreasing PE/GDP. In practice, although not all factors would remain unchanged (for example, an increase in immigration might affect labor force participation rates; aging might affect GDP per worker), this simplified model is useful to illustrate the potential effects of aging on pension spending.

Health care expenditure to GDP (HE/GDP) can be expressed as the product of three factors: the generosity of the health package for the young (average health spending per population 0–64 to GDP per capita), the inverse of the labor force participation rate of the population 0–64, and a function that depends on the ratio of the per capita health spending for the older population to the per capita health spending for the young (α) and the old-age dependency ratio. Assuming α is equal to 3.2 (the average for OECD economies), health care spending to GDP would also grow with the old-age dependency ratio, although at a smaller pace than pensions because both the elderly and the young receive health care benefits.

H E G D P = H E 0 64 p o p 0 64 G D P w o r ker s p o p 0 64 w o r k e r s ( 1 + α p o p 65 + p o p 0 64 ) , w h e r e   α = H E 65 + p o p 65 + H E 0 64 p o p 0 64 ( 2 )

Similarly to pensions, an exogenous increase in the number of elderly increases health care spending (more people receive a relatively high per capita health benefit). In addition, assuming constant GDP per worker and labor force participation rates, an increase in the younger population—say from higher migration than projected—has two somewhat offsetting effects. It increases health spending (related to each additional person age 15–64, with a lower health care cost than the elderly), but GDP also increases, reflecting a larger workforce than expected. The GDP impact dominates (increasing with α), and the result is a decrease in health spending to GDP.

6. The links between demographics and growth are numerous and subject to considerable uncertainty. For example, lower fertility could increase the labor force participation of women in more developed countries (Bloom and others 2007), but not necessarily in developing countries (Lim 2002). In addition, population aging could have an impact on labor productivity, although the evidence suggests that an older labor force is not necessarily more—or less—productive (Burtless 2013; Maestas, Mullen, and Powell 2014). Furthermore, shrinking populations might have positive consequences for welfare that are not captured in their effects on growth. In particular, a declining global population will, other things being equal, reduce energy consumption and pollution.

7. It is important to bear in mind the assumptions underlying demographic projections. Fiscal projections for age-related spending to GDP largely depend on the expected evolution of old-age dependency ratios (Box 1).10 The UN periodically reports population data and updates its long-term projections, which currently go up to 2100. The UN “medium variant” scenario—the baseline projections used in this note—relies on probabilistic models to produce the trajectories of fertility and mortality assumptions at a country level (Appendix 3). For migration, the UN assumes that net migration remains constant up to 2050, and then declines gradually to half of this level by 2100.

The Impact of Demographic Uncertainty on Fiscal Sustainability

8. Demographic projections are surrounded by substantial uncertainty. The UN takes into account past demographic trends and country-specific information to inform projections, relying on state-of-the-art statistical techniques and expert judgment, taking into account all currently available information. Nevertheless, these projections must be taken with caution—future realizations of fertility, mortality, and migration might differ substantially from the predicted levels, and the views of experts differ. For example, Lutz and others (2001, 2008, 2014) suggest that the peak of the world population might be as early as 2070 and that, by the end of the century, the population might be a significantly lower than envisaged by the UN, reflecting steeper declines in fertility than envisaged by the UN, particularly in Africa.

9. Past projections have been subject to large errors. For example, the projections from the 1960s to the 1990s assumed a more gradual decline in birth rates than was actually observed. In contrast, the 2000 projection overestimated the recent decline (Figure 3). Past medium variants of the UN projections have proved to be biased upward, mainly due to fertility rates declining faster than expected (Gros and others 2013). The decline in fertility was not completely unexpected—at low levels of income per capita, fertility can be expected to increase with economic activity. However, as income per capita increases, there is a demographic transition toward lower fertility, reflecting changes in the tradeoff between the desired number of children and the costs of raising children (Becker and Barro 1988; Lucas 2001).11 But the demographic transition is due to factors beyond GDP per capita—fertility declines have been observed in countries with similar sociocultural characteristics at different stages of development (Galor 2005). In particular, the decline in fertility is largely associated with the rise of importance of human capital, with its related increase in returns to education, and the narrowing of the male-female wage gap, which have tilted the choice from quantity to the nurturing of children. Hence, families have increasingly chosen to have fewer children (Galor 2005, 2011). However, some of decline might have been the result of developments that were difficult to foresee, including increasing access to contraception, delaying ages of marriage, growing labor market opportunities for women, and declining child mortality rates. To some extent, the rapid decline in mortality rates was not foreseen either. For example, for the less developed economies, the 1963 projection failed to predict the rapid drop in crude mortality rates over 1960–80. Death rates are affected by diverse factors, such as innovations in agriculture, advances in medicine, and improvement in public health management.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Birth and Mortality Rates by Vintage of Projections, 1960–2015

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN (1966, 1985, 1991, 2001, 2012, and 2015).

A. Fertility

10. After declining for over 100 years, fertility rates are projected to increase slightly in the more developed economies over 2015–2100.12 Fertility rates in the more developed countries declined from 2.8 children per woman in 1950 to 1.7 in 2015, a level under the rate needed to maintain a constant population, assuming no immigration, estimated at about 2.1 children per woman (Figure 4, Appendix 4).13 Looking forward, the projections assume a modest increase in fertility rates to 1.8 by 2050 and 1.9 by 2100.14 This expected increase largely reflects recent country experiences. For example, 29 out of 40 European economies experienced a slight increase in fertility rates over 2005–15. Nevertheless, over the entire forecasting period, fertility rates are projected to remain well below the replacement rate.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Fertility Rate, 1955–2100

(Children per woman)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN 2015.

11. For the less developed economies, the projections assume a continued but gradual decline in fertility rates. Fertility rates in the less developed economies have declined from more than six children per woman in 1950 to 2.6 in 2015. This reflects the combination of a rapid decline in Asia and Latin America, and a more gradual decline in Africa. The UN medium projection assumes a continuous decline to about 2.0 children per woman by 2100. These projections imply a more gradual reduction in fertility rates in the less developed countries than what was experienced in the more developed countries over the past few decades.

12. The impact of lower fertility rates on fiscal variables is significant. The secular decline in fertility represents an important transition toward declining populations in many countries, with the total world population stabilizing by 2100. But these projections might prove too high, and populations might start declining earlier. The UN low fertility scenario assumes that fertility rates immediately drop by about 0.5 children per woman in the more and less developed countries. The impact on the size and structure of regions’ populations and age-related spending is large. This can be seen by comparing our projections for age-related spending in 2100 under the baseline and the low-fertility scenario. Age-related spending would be higher by about 8 percentage points of GDP in the more developed economies and 4½ percentage points of GDP in the less developed economies (Table 2). The results show that the public finance implications from demographic uncertainty are considerable.

Table 2.

Impact of Demographic Uncertainty on Aging and Age-Related Programs for the More and Less Developed Economies, 2015–2100

(Percent of GDP, unless otherwise specified)

article image

Population 65 and older as a share of the population 15-65.

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN 2015.

B. Mortality

13. Longevity improvement is expected to slow down in the more developed economies. After a sharp decline in the 1950s and 1960s, child mortality rates reached 0.1 percent in 2015 in the more developed economies (Figure 5). Longevity also improved at older ages, albeit more gradually. Looking forward, however, the projections imply a slowdown in the decline in mortality for those ages 65 and older, partly reflecting the experiences of countries that seem to have hit a plateau in longevity improvements. For example, in Japan the mortality rate of the population 65 and older improved by 1.5 percent per year over 1950–2000, but only by 0.2 percent per year over 2000–15.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Crude Mortality Rate, 1950–2100

(In percent of population)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN 2015.

14. For the less developed economies, the projections suggest continued improvements in longevity. In the less developed economies, child mortality rates are expected to decline to 0.1 by 2060—the level reached in the more developed countries in 1980. Mortality rates for older age groups also decline, but they would remain above those projected for the more developed economies. These projections assume increasing health care coverage of the population in these countries.

15. Improvements in longevity can also have an important fiscal impact. For example, assuming that the annual percentage decline is 1.5 times as large as the annual decline in the baseline similar to the U.S. Social Security Administration “High Cost” scenario for mortality (Office of the Chief Actuary 2014), age-related spending in 2100 could increase by some 2 percentage points of GDP in both the more and less developed economies.

C. Migration

16. The UN medium projection assumes that net international migration rates will gradually decline over the remainder of the century. The main assumption is that net migration flows from less developed countries to more developed countries (in number of migrants) remain constant over 2015–2050, followed by a steady decline to half of the 2050 level by 2100. This contrasts with historic trends—as a share of the population in the more developed countries, migration from the less to the more developed increased from less than 0.5 to more than 2.5 per thousand (or from 0 to about −0.5 per thousand population in the less developed) (Figure 6). Furthermore, migration rates vary substantially across countries. In the more developed economies, net migration rates in 2015 range from about 0.5 per thousand in Japan to over 5 per thousand in Australia and Canada. In the less developed economies, the rate of migration varies from −0.5 per thousand in Africa to −1 per thousand in Latin America.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Net Migration Rate, 1950–2100

(Migrants per 1,000 population)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN 2015.

Policy Options to Address the Fiscal Challenge of Shrinking Populations

17. There are two categories of potential policy responses to the fiscal challenges posed by population trends. The first involves policies that attempt to change underlying demographics. This entails introducing incentives to increase fertility, allowing greater net migration, and raising labor force participation. The second involves policies that contain growth in age-related spending, mostly by affecting health care and pensions systems.

A. Policies that Affect Demographics and Labor Markets

Boosting fertility rates

18. Some governments have attempted to use public policies to raise fertility. In a sample of over 150 countries, the proportion of governments that consider fertility in their countries as too low increased from 11 percent in 1976 to 26 percent in 2011 (UN 2011). These concerns have often resulted in policy action—in Europe, for example, the share of governments implementing policies aimed at raising the rate of population growth increased from 26 percent in 1996 to 52 percent in 2011. Measures typically aim to offset the direct costs (through baby bonuses, family allowances, tax incentives) and opportunity costs (through parental leave, subsidized child care, flexible work schedules) of childbearing (Walker 1995). In contrast, among the least developed economies, containing the fall in fertility rates has been less of a priority, with one exception being China where the one-child policy was partly relaxed in 2013 to allow couples to have a second child as long as one of the parents is an only child (NHFPC 2013).15

19. Boosting birth rates could slow down population aging and gradually reduce fiscal pressures. Assuming an annual increase in fertility of about 0.7 percent—the average increase observed in Europe in the past two decades—starting in 2015, would reduce age-related spending by only 0.7 percentage points of GDP in 2050 in the more developed countries (Table 3). The impact is larger in the outer years; by 2100, the reduction is near 4 percentage points of GDP. This reflects the assumed continued increase in fertility rates—which by 2050 would reach levels not observed since the 1980s—and the time it takes for fertility rates to affect the working-age population. In the less developed countries, the effects of changes in fertility on spending are less dramatic (Figure 4). For many less developed countries, one priority is to manage the transition to a lower fertility rate. This initially helps to boost the share of working-age individuals in the population and provides a temporary “demographic dividend” for growth.16 Taking full advantage of this opportunity requires efforts to enhance infrastructure, open trade, and improve education and health care (IMF 2015b).

Table 3.

Impact of Selected Policy Options on Aging and Age-Related Programs for the More Developed Economies, 2015–2100

(Percent of GDP, unless otherwise specified)

article image

Population 65 and older as a share of the population 15 to 65.

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN (2015).

20. However, a “birth rate” solution to aging is unlikely to work for most countries. The pronatalist policies seem to have only modest effects on the number of births, although they might affect the timing of births, and to have a positive impact on the labor supply decisions of mothers (Gauthier and Hatzius 1997; Ronsen 2004; d’Addio and d’Ercole 2005; Piketty 2005; Thevenon and Gauthier 2011; Kluve and Schmitz 2014; and Brainerd 2014).17 For example, in Spain, part of the temporary increases in fertility seems associated with higher birth rates among immigrants, many of whom might not be eligible for benefits (Haub 2008). In Germany, policies to encourage births in the 1970s and 1980s had only short-lived effects, and the introduction of the parental allowance in 2007 did not have a noticeable impact on fertility rates, which remained at about 1.35 over the past decade, among the lowest in Europe (Kluve and Schmitz 2014). In China, a slight demographic impact could be expected from the relaxation of the one-child policy, but related long-term effects remain highly uncertain (Basten and Jiang 2015). Altogether, even if with a minimum impact on fertility, the evidence points to the need to ensure policies that encourage labor force participation (for example, through tax credits or access to child care) and to avoid policies that support untargeted and costly child allowances.

Table 4.

Impact of Selected Policy Options on Aging and Age-Related Programs for the Less Developed Economies, 2015–2100

(Percent of GDP, unless otherwise specified)

article image

Population 65 and older as a share of the population 15 to 65.

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN (2015).

Allowing greater migration

21. Immigration can have an impact on long-term expenditure trends. Assuming a continuation of trends in migration into the more developed countries over time (similarly to the migration risk scenario illustrated above) would reduce age-related expenditure by 0.4 percentage point of GDP by 2050 and by 2 percentage points of GDP by 2100, without affecting age-related expenditure by much in the less developed countries (Table 3). Under this scenario, by the end of the century, average migration rates would still be below the current levels of net migration into Australia or Canada. Nevertheless, migration cannot fully eliminate the impact of population aging in more developed countries. For example, keeping the old-age dependency ratio constant over the next 85 years in the more developed economies would require an immediate eightfold increase in net migration (from 2.5 million to eventually over 21 million per year net migrants from the less developed to the more developed countries). These levels of migration would eventually deplete the working-age population in the less developed economies. Furthermore, migration alone does not alter the balance between public benefits received and taxes paid by individuals over their lifetime. That is, migration provides a temporary boost to the work force and can increase growth and fiscal revenue, but eventually these new workers will also retire and exert pressure on spending. Nevertheless, migration can provide more time for countries to implement needed age-related reforms.

22. The impact from migration goes beyond age-related programs. Migration can boost human capital and lifetime income for migrants, and facilitate trade, investment, and knowledge transfers across countries. In addition, remittances from migrants stimulate long-term growth, reduce poverty, and promote financial deepening in countries receiving remittances (Gupta, Pattillo, and Wagh 2009). However, there are concerns that greater migration could increase public expenditure in the migrant-receiving countries (particularly those with extensive social safety nets), erode human capital and tax bases in migrant-exiting countries (especially if migrants are high skilled), and reduce job opportunities for domestic workers. The literature suggests that, on balance, the benefits from migration outweigh its potential costs (Gibson and McKenzie 2012), and that the overall effect of immigrants on current public budgets tends to be very small (Box 2).

23. Migration remains a politically sensitive issue. Migration is an important factor in shaping the social, political, and economic fabrics in many countries—in the OECD countries there are about 115 million immigrants (OECD 2014). Survey data suggest that, although the desired degree of openness to migration varies substantially across OECD countries, a large proportion of respondents remain in favor of controlled or reduced migration (OECD 2010).

The Economic Impact of Migration

Migration can affect the finances of public pension and health care systems, depending on the characteristics of the migrants, progressivity of the tax system, and the structure of the social safety net. For example, young migrants can augment the size of the labor force, thereby increasing the tax base used to finance traditional pay-as-you-go systems. This impact depends on the effect of migration on domestic wages for the native population, the skills and productivity of the migrants (which determine the income earned by immigrants), and the ability to collect taxes from this additional labor force. In the expenditure side, immigrants are likely to increase the demand for public services (for example, health care). Immigrants would also eventually be eligible for pensions, which they could receive at old age.

The overall effect of immigrant workers on the domestic economy is likely to be positive. It is commonly believed that immigrants take over jobs of domestic workers, depress their wages, and negatively affect domestic economy. This view is based on the analysis of the labor market where immigrants and native workers have identical characteristics and skills (that is, they are perfect substitutes and that the rest of the economy does not adjust to the inflow of immigrants). The most recent theoretical and empirical evidence provides the opposite perspective. First, immigration does not mean just the inflow of cheap homogeneous labor. It does not have to be the case that immigrants always compete with native workers; they can actually complement and benefit each other (Ottaviano and Peri 2012). Second, the recent literature supports the view that companies do not lay off domestic workers due to higher supply of cheaper labor from abroad. On the contrary, as companies are faced with larger availability of workers, they realize higher returns to capital and are motivated to invest more in order to realize larger profits. As a consequence, existing companies expand and new ones emerge. Besides, as documented by Hanson (2012), immigrants are often paid less when compared to domestic workers of similar characteristics and skills, and they allow companies to save costs and increase their productivity and competitiveness. Hence, in the end, immigrants increase the size of the domestic economy. As the domestic economy expands, the number of jobs increases as well. Some of the newly created jobs are taken by immigrants, some by native workers. In addition, immigrants can also add dynamism to entrepreneurship. For example, in the United States about a quarter of the technology company startups over 2008–12 included one foreign-born founder (Wadhwa, Saxenian, and Siciliano 2012). All in all, the overall effect of immigrant workers on the domestic economy is likely to be positive.

In general, immigrants have different characteristics than domestic workers and their labor market outcomes are often less favorable. In addition, the immigrants might not spend their whole lives in the host country, which may affect the amount of taxes paid and public benefits received. In general, whether the impact is positive or negative depends on a number of different circumstances, and the evidence to date suggest that the overall effect of immigrants on current public budgets is likely to be small (OECD 2013).

Raising labor force participation

24. Raising labor force participation rates—especially for women and older workers—could help mitigate the impact of aging. Assuming constant productivity per worker, increasing labor force participation rates can increase GDP by increasing the number of workers, which would offset or delay some of the projected impact from aging. For ages 25–49, female labor force participation rates are below those of men by about 10 percentage points in Europe and North America, and by 25–30 percentage points in Asia, Latin America, and Africa. Cutting the gap between men and women by half over 2015–50 would reduce age-related spending by about 1 percentage point of GDP in 2050 and by 1.5 percentage points by 2100 in both the more and less developed economies. This means that it would be beneficial to remove obstacles in the way of women becoming economically active, if they so choose. These include addressing gender differences in property rights, inheritance claims, and property titling; the ability to pursue a profession, obtain a job, or open a bank account; and rights to initiate legal proceedings, sign a contract, and to head a household (Gonzales and others 2015). In addition, it is crucial to review fiscal disincentives that might deter women from participating in the labor market, including the taxation of households that can raise marginal rates for second earners (Pereira 2015). Older individuals also have lower participation rates—those ages 55–64 have lower rates of labor force participation than do those ages 25–49 (with the exception of Africa). Cutting in half the gap in participation between individuals 55–64 and 25–64 would reduce age-related spending by almost 1 percentage point of GDP in both 2050 and 2100 in the more developed countries. The effect is only about a third of this in the less developed countries, where labor force participation does not decrease as sharply with age as in the more developed countries.

B. Reforms to Age-Related Spending Programs

Addressing the growth of age-related costs

25. Reforming public pension systems can help offset the effects of aging. Raising retirement ages is an especially attractive option and would help complement efforts to boost the labor force participation of older workers. It would also help to better align retirement ages with the sharp improvements in life expectancy realized in recent decades (Clements, Eich, and Gupta 2014). For example, raising retirement ages over 2015–2100 by an additional five years (about 7 months per decade) beyond what is already legislated would reduce pension spending by about 2 percentage points of GDP by 2100 (relative to the baseline) in both the more and less developed countries. This could be achieved by linking additional increases in retirement age to longevity gains, with adequate provisions for the poor, whose life expectancy could be shorter than that of the average population (Chetty and others 2015; Clements, Mooij, Gupta, and Keen 2015). In this context, enhancing antipoverty programs for the elderly and increasing the role of private retirement saving schemes could be helpful in offsetting the potential decline in lifetime retirement income. Starting reforms early can allow for a more gradual adjustment—for example, if the adjustments were to start in 2050 instead of 2015, retirement age increases would have to be one year per decade to achieve the same savings. Other policy options to put pension systems on more sustainable footing include reducing pensions relative to wages, increasing taxation of pensions for upper income groups, and increasing pension contributions. The latter is the least preferred option because of the likely impact on labor demand.

26. In a similar vein, health care reform can be effective in containing the growth of public health spending. Market failures in health care imply an important public role for the provision and financing of health care, and in regulating the sector. Policies can help to ensure that new technologies reduce, rather than raise, health care costs, without adversely affecting health outcomes (Clements, Coady, and Gupta 2012). There is past success in improving health outcomes without raising costs through promoting some degree of competition among insurers and service providers. Governments can also support primary and preventive care—which helps improve health and reduce the need for more costly treatments at a later stage—and improve provider payment systems to control costs. In addition, the use of health information technology (for example, to collect, store, and share patient data) has the potential to reduce costs while protecting outcomes. In this regard, there are many lessons that less developed countries can learn from the experience of more developed ones.

27. Containing the growing costs of health care would help reduce long-term fiscal risks. On average, health care costs are projected to increase faster than economic growth. This is due not only to population aging but to technological improvements in health care that result in better but more costly services (see footnote 6). Assuming policies are able to keep the growth of health care costs per capita in line with GDP per capita, health care spending will increase at a slower rate, reflecting only demographics. Under this scenario, public health care spending pressures would be greatly subdued: by 2100, health spending would be reduced by 4½ percentage points of GDP in the more developed countries and 3 percentage points in the less developed.

Conclusions

28. The fall in fertility and the slowdown and eventual decline in world population are part of the transition to a sustainable growth path. Population growth that implies the population doubling every 35 years or so is unsustainable. Easing population pressure helps to contain the use of energy and fossils fuels, which benefiting the environment. Investment in people promises inclusive growth and raised standards of living.

29. Nevertheless, shrinking populations pose a grave fiscal threat. Absent further reforms, age-related spending is expected to rise because of higher longevity and lower fertility in both more and less developed countries. Without the implementation of further reforms of public pension and health care systems, age-related outlays are expected to increase over 2015–2100 from 16½ to 25 percent of GDP in the more developed economies, and from 5½ to 16 percent of GDP in the less developed economies. The fiscal consequences of this outcome are dire: spending increases of such a magnitude could lead to unsustainable increases in public debt and, sharp declines in other spending, or it could necessitate large increases in tax rates that could stymie economic growth.

30. The projected size and age composition of the population—and our projections for age-related spending—are surrounded by substantial uncertainty. Long-term projections are inherently uncertain: relatively small changes in fertility, mortality, or migration rates can have a substantial impact on the course of age-related spending over the remainder of the century. Risks are especially acute with respect to fertility, which has declined much faster than expected. In this light, spending pressures could be even greater than typically assumed on the basis of the UN’s medium demographic scenario.

31. There is no escape from reforming entitlements. In the more developed economies, one priority remains to limit the excessive growth of health care costs. Further reforms would also be needed to contain the growth in pension spending, which seems relatively mild reflecting past reforms. Increasing retirement ages in line with longevity gains seems a promising option. In the less developed economies, the challenge is to strengthen public pension and health care schemes, while ensuring the expenditure increases are fiscally sustainable. Tax and spending policies encouraging higher labor participation rates for women and for young and old workers will also be necessary in both more and less developed countries (IMF 2013b, 2015b).

32. Migration and labor market policies can ameliorate the impact of aging in the more developed economies. To fully address the effect of population aging, the expected size of migration flows from less to more developed countries would need to be unrealistically large. While recognizing that this is a politically sensitive issue, increases in migration, in combination with other labor market policies, can reduce age-related spending and provide more time for countries to implement entitlement reform.

33. Given the magnitude of the fiscal challenge, reforms should start now but be gradual. A gradual pace of reform to pension and health systems would help to spread the burden across generations. There is greater urgency to move on health care as countries have been slow in implementing reforms in this area. In this regard, policy reversals should be avoided to circumvent disruptive adjustments in the future. In many countries, a multipronged approach will be needed, as it will be impossible for reforms to fully offset the impact of demographics on age-related spending. In this context, many countries will need to strengthen their tax systems and improve the efficiency of public spending programs outside of pensions and health (IMF 2013a, 2014, 2015b).

Appendix 1. The Impact of Population on Economic Growth

The size of the labor force is one of the main determinants of economic output. For example, in the basic Solow Growth Model, output depends on the evolution of the capital stock (K), labor (L), and technological progress (E). The steady-state, long-run growth rate of output is directly proportional to the growth rate of the labor force (Box).

Solow Growth Model

article image

In practice, the relationship between employment and output might not be one-to-one. Countries might not be in the steady state (capital per worker might vary over time). Furthermore, this relationship might be affected by other factors, such as the intensity of labor (average number of hours worked), which can vary over the economic cycle. Nevertheless, over the long term, the data suggest a high correlation between employment and GDP growth over 1990–2015 (Figure).

Demographic developments can affect the size of the labor force, thereby having an effect on output. Employment (L) is a function of the working-age population (POP15-64), labor participation rate (LFPR), and the unemployment rate (UR) (Lt=POPt1564LFPRt(1URt)). Assuming constant LFPR and UR, employment moves in direct proportion to the working-age population. This also suggests that increases in labor force participation—for example, of women or the elderly—can partially offset the impact of lower population growth.

A01ufig1

Output and Employment Growth in the Advanced Economies, 1990–2015

(Annual growth rate)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations.

Appendix 2. The Impact of Growth on Fiscal Sustainability

How will the projected slowdown in the growth of the working-age population affect fiscal sustainability? One channel is through its effects on age-related spending, such as pensions and health care. Another is through its potential effects on economic growth, which we explore in this appendix.

A common concern is that slower growth could make it more difficult to reduce debt-to-GDP ratios over time. This is typically illustrated using public debt dynamics, as the change in public debt to GDP (dt - dt-l) can be approximated as the interest rate-growth differential (r - g) multiplied by the debt-to-GDP ratio in the previous period, minus the primary balance (pbt) in the current period (Escolano 2010; Turner and Spinelli 2012):

d t d t 1 ( r g ) d t 1 p b t .

The crucial question is whether the decline in economic growth (g), will be also lead to changes in the interest rate (r). Even small increases in the difference between r and g can have large effects on public debt dynamics (Turner and Spinelli 2012; Kogan and others 2015). For example, at the current levels of gross debt in the advanced economies, a permanent increase in r – g of 0.5 percentage points would raise the ratio of debt to GDP by nearly 40 percentage points of GDP by 2100.

Overall, data on the advanced economies over the past 25 years suggest a very low correlation between r – g and output growth over 1990–2014 in the advanced economies (Figure). Assuming this continues in the future, the decline in economic growth would be accompanied by lower real interest rates, and there would be no adverse effects on debt dynamics.

Figure.
Figure.

Output Growth and the Interest Rate-Growth Differential in the Advanced Economies, 1990–2015

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations.Note: The trend line and R2 are estimated excluding the Israel and Ireland.

Nevertheless, there could be periods of time over which r – g may not be constant (Table). The relationship between r and g is complex and surrounded by uncertainty, reflecting factors other than demographics, economic growth, or fiscal policy. The literature typically attributes the variation of r – g to financial repression, inflation prospects, the balance between global savings and desired investments, and monetary policy (Escolano 2011; Turner and Spinelli 2012). This complexity is evident when examining longer horizons or wider groups of countries. For example, Turner and Spinelli (2012) document the median r – g in OECD countries fluctuating between −4 percentage points in the 1970s to +4 percentage points in the 1980s, and then declining in the 1990s and 2000s. Focusing only on the United States, Kogan and others (2015) find that, excluding periods of major wars and the great depression, the average r – g has been negative (an average of –0.2 percentage points since 1792), although r – g remained in positive territory for most of the 1980s to 2000s. Using a wider group of countries, Escolano and others (2011) find that in emerging and low income economies, r – g tends to exhibit more within country volatility and lower persistence relative to advanced economies. They find that the r – g was about –4 percentage points in the emerging economies over 1999–2008.

Table.

Output Growth and the Interest Rate-Growth Differential in the Advanced Economies, 1990–2015

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.

Appendix 3. United Nation Population Projections—Main Assumptions

Fertility. The UN fertility projections are based on a general consensus that the evolution of fertility includes three broad phases: a high-fertility pretransition phase, a fertility transition phase, and a low-fertility posttransition phase). Future long-term fertility levels are projected using probabilistic models, reflecting country-specific assumptions as well as the empirical experience of low-fertility countries that had experienced some increase in fertility in at least two consecutive periods.18 For countries with fertility rates above replacement, this combines a systematic decline with a random distortion term. The pace of the decline is a function of its current level, with the distribution based on historical trends within the country and in other countries that have experienced a fertility decline. For countries that have completed the demographic transition, a time series model is used, using the distribution from all countries with low fertility rates, including those with extended experiences of low fertility and those that have increased slightly over the past two decades—assuming ultimate fertility rates are not higher than 2.1.

Mortality. Life expectancy is generally assumed to rise over the projection period for most countries. By assuming that the asymptotic average rate of increase in life expectancy is nonnegative, life expectancy is assumed to continually increase (on average), and no limit is imposed on life expectancy in the foreseeable future. As with fertility, the results for life expectancy are based on probabilistic models based on country-specific information as well as on past empirical trends. The projections assume random walk with a drift for female life expectancy. Male expectancies are estimated based on the correlation with female life expectancy, and a distribution of the female–male gap that depends on the level of female life expectancy.

Migration. Formulating assumptions about future international migration is very difficult. Not only has international migration shown drastic changes in absolute numbers, but the direction of the flows has changed as well, so that some countries that historically have been primarily countries of origin have become countries of destination and vice versa. Consequently, a number of simplifying assumptions had to be introduced. First, for international migration, it was assumed that recent levels, if stable, would continue for a number of years. Government’s views on international migration as well as estimates of undocumented and irregular migration flows affecting a country were also considered. Second, regarding the movements of refugees, it was assumed in general that refugees return to their countries of origin within one or two projection periods (that is, 5 to 10 years). Third, if a country was known to attract temporary labor migrants, an effort was made to model the return flow of those labor migrants, accounting for aging of the migrants involved. Finally, after 2050, it is assumed that net migration would gradually decline by 2100 to half of its 2050 level.

Appendix 4. Supplementary Figures and Tables

A01ufig3

Fertility Rate, 1955–2100

(Children per woman)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN (2015).
A01ufig4

Crude Mortality Rate, 1950–2100

(In percent of population)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN (2015).
A01ufig5

Migration Rate, 1950–2100

(Migrants per 1,000 population)

Citation: Staff Discussion Notes 2015, 021; 10.5089/9781513544885.006.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations using UN (2015).

References

  • Basten, S., and Q. Jian. 2015. “Fertility in China: An Uncertain Future.Population Studies: A Journal of Demography 69, Sup. 1. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00324728.2014.982898

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basten, S., T. Sobotka, and K. Zeman. 2014. “Future Fertility in Low Fertility Countries.” In World Population and Human Capital in the Twenty-First Century, edited by W. Lutz, W. P. Butz, and S. KC. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Becker, G., and R. Barro. 1988. “A Reformulation of the Economic Theory of Fertility.Quarterly Journal of Economics 103 (125).

  • Bloom, D., D. Canning, G. Fink, and J. E. Finlay. 2009. “Fertility, Female Labor Force Participation, and the Demographic Dividend.Journal of Economic Growth 14 (79101).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burtless, G. 2013. “The Impact of Population Aging and Delayed Retirement on Workforce Productivity.Working Paper CRR WP 2013–11, Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, Boston, Massachusetts. http://crr.bc.edu/wp-content/uploads/2013/05/wp_2013-111.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chetty, R., S. Abraham, S Lin, B. Scuderi, M. Stepner, N. Turner, A. Bergeron, and D. Cutler. 2015. The Relationship between Income and Life Expectancy in the United States. 17th Annual Joint Meeting of the Retirement Research Consortium. Washington. http://www.nber.org/programs/ag/rrc/rrc2015/papers/3.1%20-%20Chetty,%20Abraham%20et%20al.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clements, B., D. Coady, and S. Gupta (eds.). 2012. The Economics of Public Health Care Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies. Washington: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imfbookstore.org/ProdDetails.asp?ID=SCHPEA

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clements, B., F. Eich, and S. Gupta (eds.). 2014. Equitable and Sustainable Pensions: Challenges and Experience. Washington: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imfbookstore.org/ProdDetails.asp?ID=DESPSEA&PG=1&Type=BL

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clements, B., R. Mooij, S. Gupta, and M. Keen. 2015. Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality. Washington: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imfbookstore.org/ProdDetails.asp?ID=IRFPEA&PG=1&Type=RLMb

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cummins, N. 2009. “Why Did Fertility Decline? An Analysis of the Individual Level Economics Correlates of the Nineteenth Century Fertility Transition in England and France.Ph.D. thesis, London School of Economics and Political Science. http://etheses.lse.ac.uk/39/1/Cummins_Why_did_fertility_decline.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • d’Addio, A., and M. d’Ercole. 2005. Trends and Determinants of Fertility Rates in OECD Countries: The Role of Policies. Paris: OECD Publishing. http://www.oecd.org/social/family/35304751.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Escolano, J. 2010. “A Practical Guide to Public Debt Dynamics, Fiscal Sustainability, and Cyclical Adjustment of Budgetary Aggregates.IMF Technical Note and Manual, International Monetary Fund, Washington. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2010/tnm1002.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Escolano, J., A. Shabunina, and J. Woo. 2011. “The Puzzle of Persistently Negative Interest Rate-Growth Differentials: Financial Repression or Income Catch Up?Working Paper 11/260, International Monetary Fund, Washington. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp11260.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2015. The 2015 Ageing Report—Economic and Budgetary Projections to the 28 EU Member States (2013–2060). Brussels. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gauthier, A. H., and J. Hatzius. 1997. “Family Benefits and Fertility: An Econometric Analysis.Population Studies 51: 3741. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2952473.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galor, O. 2005. “From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, Vol. 1A. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galor, O. 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

  • Gaspar, V., R. Hughes, and L. Jaramillo. 2015. “Dams and Dikes for Public Finance.IMF Direct Blog, March 18, http://blog-imfdirect.imf.org/2015/03/18/dams-and-dikes-for-public-finances/.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gibson, J., and D. McKenzie. 2012. “The Economic Consequences of ‘Brain Drain’ of the Best and Brightest: Microeconomic Evidence from Five Countries.Economic Journal 122 (May). http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02498.x/epdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gonzales, C., S. Jain-Chandra, K. Kochnar, and M. Newiak. 2015. “Fair Play: More Equal Laws Boost Female Labor Force Participation.Staff Discussion Note 5/02, International Monetary Fund, Washington. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2015/sdn1502.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gros, D., C. Alcidi, A. Behrens, S. Blockmans, M. Busse, C. Egenhofer, L. Fontagne, A. Fougeyrollas, G. Koleda, I. Maselli, M. P. Ramos, C. Sessa, and P. Zagame. 2013. “The Global Economy in 2030: Trends and Strategies for Europe.Centre for European Policy Studies. Brussels. http://europa.eu/espas/pdf/espas-report-economy.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, S., Pattillo, C., and S. Wagh. 2009. “Effect of Remittances on Poverty and Financial Development in Sub-Saharan Africa.World Development 37 (104115).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanson, G. 2012. “Immigration, Productivity, and Competitiveness in American Industry.” In Rethinking Competitiveness, edited by K. Hassett. Washington: AEI Press. https://www.aei.org/publication/rethinking-competitiveness/.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haub, Carl. 2008. “Tracking Trends in Low Fertility Countries: An Uptick in Europe?Population Reference Bureau. Washington. http://www.prb.org/Publications/Articles/2008/tfrtrendsept08.aspx.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2013a. Fiscal Monitor October 2013: Taxing Times. Washington. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2013/02/pdf/fm1302.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2013b. Jobs and Growth: Analytical and Operational Considerations for the Fund. Washington. http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2013/031413.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2014. Fiscal Monitor: Public Expenditure Reforms Making Difficult Choices. Washington, April. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2014/01/pdf/fm1302.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015a. “How Can Sub-Saharan Africa Harness the Demographic Dividend?World Economic and Financial Surveys, Regional Economic Outlook, Washington, April. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/reo/2015/afr/eng/pdf/sreo0415.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015b. Fiscal Policy and Long-Term Growth. http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2015/042015.pdf.

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015c. World Economic Outlook. Uneven Growth: Short- and Long-Term Factors. Washington, April. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2015/01/pdf/text.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kluve, J., and S. Schmitz. 2014. “Social Norms and Mothers’ Labor Market Attachment: The Medium-Run Effects of Parental Benefits.IZA Discussion Paper 8115, IZA. Bonn. http://ftp.iza.org/dp8115.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kogan, R., C. Stone, B. DaSilva, and J. Rejeski. 2015. “Difference between Economic Growth Rates and Treasury Interest Rates Significantly Affects Long-Term Budget Outlook.Policy Futures, Center for Budget Policies and Priorities. Washington. http://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/2-27-15bud.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lim, L. L. 2002. “Female Labor Force Participation, Lin Lean.In Report of the Expert Group on Completing the Fertility Transition, United Nations. New York. http://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/completingfertility/bulletin-english.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lucas, R. E. 2001. Lectures on Economic Growth. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.

  • Lutz, W., W. P. Butz, S. KC. W. Sanderson, and S. Scherbov. 2014. “Population Growth: Peak Probability.Science 346 (6209): 561. http://www.sciencemag.org/content/346/6209/561.1.full.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lutz, W., W. Sanderson, and S. Scherbov. 2001. “The End of Population Growth.Nature 412: 54345. http://www.nature.com/nature/journal/v412/n6846/full/412543a0.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lutz, W., W. Sanderson, and S. Scherbov. 2008. “The Coming Acceleration of Global Population Ageing.Nature 451: 716-19. http://www.nature.com/nature/journal/v451/n7179/full/nature06516.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maestas, N., K. J. Mullen, and D. Powell. 2014. “The Effect of Population Aging on Economic Growth.RAND Working Paper WR-1063. RAND Corporation. Santa Monica. http://www.rand.org/pubs/working papers/WR1063.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • National Health and Family Planning Commission of the People’s Republic of China (NHFPC). 2013. “ (Decision to uphold the basic state family planning policy to gradually adjust and improve fertility).http://www.nhfpc.gov.cn/jczds/s3578/201311/2113e68c25704b6c927bc722059e751e.shtml.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Office of the Chief Actuary, 2014, The Long-Range Demographic Assumptions for the 2014 Trustees Report. Available at: http://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2014/2014 Long-Range Demographic Assumptions.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2013. “The Fiscal Impact of Immigration in OECD Countries.International Migration Outlook 2013. Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2010. International Migration Outlook. http://www.oecd.org/migration/mig/48328734.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2014. International Migration Outlook. http://www.oecd.org/migration/international-migration-outlook-1999124x.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ottaviano, G., and G. Peri. 2012. “Rethinking the Effects of Immigration on Wages.Journal of the European Economic Association 10 (1): 15297. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01052.x/abstract.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pereira, J. 2015. “Women in the Labor Market and the Demographic Challenge.Germany: Selected Issues, Country Report 15, International Monetary Fund, Washington (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Piketty, T. 2005. “L’impact de l’allocation parentale d’éducation sur l’activité feminine et la fécondité en France, 1982–2002.In Histoires de familles, histoires familiales, edited by C. Lefèvre

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ronsen, M. 2004. “Fertility and Public Policies—Evidence from Norway and Finland.Demographic Research (10): 14370. http://www.demographic-research.org/volumes/vol10/6/.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Summers, L. H. 2014. “U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound.Business Economics 49 (6573). http://larrysummers.com/wp-content/uploads/2014/06/NABE-speech-Lawrence-H.-Summers1.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thevenon, O. 2011. “Family Policies in OECD Countries: A Comparative Analysis.Population and Development Review 31 (1): 5787. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2011.00390.x.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thevenon, O., and A. Gauthier. 2011. “Family Policies in Developed Countries: A ‘Fertility-Booster’ with Side-Effects.Community, Work & Family 14 (2): 197216. http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/13668803.2011.571400.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Turner, D., and F. Spinelli. 2012. “Interest-Rate-Growth Differentials and Government Debt Dynamics.OECD Journal: Economic Studies 2012 (103–122). http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2012-5k912k0zkhf8.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations (UN). 1966. World Population Prospects as assessed in 1963. New York: United Nations.

  • United Nations (UN). 1991. World Population Prospects 1990. New York: United Nations.

  • United Nations (UN). 1985. World Population Prospects: Estimates and Projections as Assessed in 1982. New York: United Nations.

  • United Nations (UN). 2001. World Population Prospects: The 2000 Revision. New York: United Nations. http://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/wpp2000/highlights.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations (UN). 2011. World Population Policies. New York: United Nations. http://www.un.org/en/development/desa/population/publications/pdf/policy/WPP2011/wp p2011.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations (UN). 2013. World Population Prospects: The 2012 Revision. New York: United Nations. http://www.un.org/en/development/desa/publications/world-population-prospects-the-2012-revision.html

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations (UN). 2015. World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision. New York: United Nations. http://esa.un.org/wpp/.

  • Wadhwa, V., A. Saxenian, and F. Daniel Siciliano. 2012. “Then and Now: America’s New Immigrant Entrepreneurs.Kaufmann Foundation, October. Kansas City. http://www.kauffman.org/~/media/kauffman_org/research%20reports%20and%20covers/2012/10/then_and_now_americas_new_immigrant_entrepreneurs.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wahl, J. B. 1992. “Trading Quantity for Quality: Explaining the Decline in American Fertility in the Nineteenth Century.In Strategic Factors in Nineteenth Century American Economic History: A Volume to Honor Robert W. Fogel, edited by C. Goldin and H. Rockoff. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6969.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Walker, J. R. 1995. “The Effect of Public Policies on Recent Swedish Fertility Behavior.Journal of Population Economics, 8: 22351. http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2FBF00185251.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

The authors would like to thank Bernardin Akitoby, Nathaniel Arnold, Helge Berger, Annalisa Fedelino, Davide Furceri, Thomas Helbling, Dora Iakova, Takuji Komatsuzaki, Jean-Marc Natal, Geremia Palomba, Joana Pereira, Nagwa Riad, Lucca Ricci, Christoph Rosenberg, Carlo Sdralevich, Ara Stepanyan, Junji Ueda, and Jerome Vandenbussche for their comments; and Nadia Malikyar, Jeffrey Pichocki, and Mileva Radisavljevic for their assistance.

2

Following the UN grouping (UN 2015), we use the “more developed economies” to refer to Australia, Canada, European countries, Japan, New Zealand, and the United States (altogether 17 percent of the world population in 2015), and the “less developed economies” to refer to the rest of the world (83 percent of the world population in 2015). The results (in terms of the spending projections) do not change when the IMF country classification is used for advanced economies instead of the UN classification of “more developed.” For example, pension spending increases by 4.2 percentage points of GDP during 2015 to 2100 in the more developed economies (Table 1), and by 4.1 percentage points of GDP in the advanced economies (IMF classification).

3

The long-term projections are based on individual projections for 37 more developed and 64 less developed countries. Currently, the European Commission (EC) and the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) provide projections of age-related spending for 29 and 24 countries to 2050 and 2060, respectively.

4

By fiscal risks we refer to the risks or chances that the actual outturns for budget balances, public debt ratios, and other fiscal variables could be different than those originally forecasted by the government.

5

The trends in health care spending, and the methodology used to quantify the impact of demographic and other factors on health spending, are discussed in Clements, Coady, and Gupta 2012 and in IMF 2013. The parameters of different pension schemes and trends in pension expenditure in advanced and developing countries are presented in Clements, Eich, and Gupta 2014.

6

The PDV of spending increases provides a sense of how much these increases could add to public debt burdens, assuming no offsetting changes in fiscal policy or reforms. The baseline pension projections presented here are similar to those in the EC’s Aging Report (EC 2015). Our baseline health spending projections, however, are higher than those of the EC. The reason is that our projections take into account the impact of technological change in health care, which—as in the past—is expected to lead to better but more expensive health care (see also Clements, Coady, and Gupta 2012).

7

Fiscal policy affects growth through labor supply, human and physical capital formation, innovation, and productivity enhancements. For a discussion of these channels and evidence, see IMF 2015b.

8

Assuming unchanged labor force participation and productivity per worker, shrinking populations translate into lower economic growth. Moreover, population aging can further reduce employment (and output), since the propensity to participate in the labor force declines with age.

9

Lower growth can reinforce age-related spending pressures, but this effect is minor. For example, assuming a permanent decrease in growth of 0.5 percentage points per year starting in 2015, pension spending would increase by only 0.2 percentage points of GDP in 2030, since pensions depend on the evolution of past wages (which are related to past GDP growth). This impact is temporary—once growth stabilizes, the ratio of pensions to wages will eventually stabilize.

10

In this note, the focus is on changes in expenditure as a share of GDP. Changes to this ratio depend on factors that change the numerator (a higher number of elderly) as well as factors that affect the denominator (a reduction in the working-age population), both of which are affected by population dynamics. This framework implicitly takes into account changes in tax revenue, which, absent policy changes are assumed to remain stable as a share of GDP—as the labor force shrinks, taxes and GDP are expected to fall roughly by the same proportion.

11

The decline in fertility rates has been accompanied by increases in resources invested per child (Wahl 1992).

12

In several European economies, fertility rates declined steadily since the mid-1850s (Cummins 2009).

13

Many demographers are less bullish on fertility rates. For example, Basten, S., T. Sobotka, and K. Zeman 2014 find that the mean fertility rate estimate for 2050 by over 100 experts was below the UN projection in 27 out of 31 low-fertility countries.

14

For more developed countries, fertility rates reached a low point of 1.58 around 2000, and increased to 1.67 by 2015. In less developed countries, fertility rates are expected to decline steadily between now and the end of the century.

15

Many less developed countries are on the road to improve health care and provide more education and labor force options to women, which largely explains the projected decline in fertility rates. These include integrating family planning into primary health care systems, providing access to reproductive health services, raising the minimum legal age for marriage, improving female education and employment opportunities, and providing low-cost, safe, and effective contraception.

16

In theory, population aging could slightly reduce expenditure on some items such as education, particularly in the less developed countries: assuming unchanged spending per pupil, fewer children per working-age population reduces education spending to GDP. However, the impact of this is likely to be offset by increases in school enrollment and per pupil expenditure, which remain relatively low in many less developed countries (IMF, 2014). This expansion in the quality and coverage of education would also be consistent with efforts to increase investment in children that accompany the decline in fertility and the greater returns to human capital.

17

See also Thevenon 2011 for a survey of the different family policies in the OECD.

18

In consequence, fertility projections are not the outcome of the optimizing behavior of individuals (Lucas 2001) or directly linked to economic prosperity (as in Malthusian or Ricardian models), but are exogenous determined by these probabilistic models.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
The Fiscal Consequences of Shrinking Populations
Author:
Mr. Benedict J. Clements
,
Mr. Kamil Dybczak
,
Vitor Gaspar
,
Mr. Sanjeev Gupta
, and
Mauricio Soto