United Kingdom: 2024 Article IV Consultation-Press Release; Staff Report; and Statement by the Executive Director for United Kingdom
Author:
International Monetary Fund. European Dept.
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund. European Dept. in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

1. Weak labor productivity, headwinds to labor supply, and pressures on public services paint a challenging landscape for living standards. Per capita real GDP growth in the UK was above the median for the G7 before the pandemic but has clearly underperformed since then. The policy response to this has included some desirable measures, notably permanent tax incentives for investment and reforms to boost labor supply, but more ambitious reforms to address key bottlenecks to growth—such as planning restrictions and skills shortages, have eluded. Attitudes toward immigration, which was the main source of growth post-GFC and could attenuate skills gaps, are hardening. Meanwhile, there are mounting pressures on public services, notably health and social care, following a period of low public investment, and given an uptick in long-term illness, elevated levels of disability, and population aging.

Backdrop

1. Weak labor productivity, headwinds to labor supply, and pressures on public services paint a challenging landscape for living standards. Per capita real GDP growth in the UK was above the median for the G7 before the pandemic but has clearly underperformed since then. The policy response to this has included some desirable measures, notably permanent tax incentives for investment and reforms to boost labor supply, but more ambitious reforms to address key bottlenecks to growth—such as planning restrictions and skills shortages, have eluded. Attitudes toward immigration, which was the main source of growth post-GFC and could attenuate skills gaps, are hardening. Meanwhile, there are mounting pressures on public services, notably health and social care, following a period of low public investment, and given an uptick in long-term illness, elevated levels of disability, and population aging.

uA001fig01

Change In Real GDP Per Capita

(Actualizedverage percent change)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: IMF WEO.

2. The UK is still adjusting to the post-Brexit environment. A careful review of retained European Union (EU) laws is underway. There has been progress on Irish border arrangements, under the Windsor Framework, after the Northern Ireland Assembly was reconvened in February after two years of stalemate. The feared mass relocation of financial services activity from London to the EU has not yet materialized, with the recent EU decision on clearing rules1 (which will alleviate uncertainty around recognition of UK central counterparties) and the Berne Financial Services Agreement with Switzerland providing further reassurance. At the same time, UK firms exporting to the EU are facing challenges in adapting to new EU rules applying to non-EU countries, while importing firms face additional fees that may lead to higher food prices.2 Without access to price-responsive EU workers, the UK labor market is less flexible, with non-EU immigration only partially compensating. Moreover, while the share of EU trade has returned to levels before January 2021 (when the EU-UK Trade and Cooperation Agreement took effect), aggregate trade volumes have barely risen from 2019 levels (with weaker goods trade and stronger services trade, mainly with the US, largely offsetting each other). The UK has now ratified its accession to the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP) moving it closer to entering into force, however major bilateral trade agreements (e.g., with India and the US) are not yet in sight.

3. On May 22, one day after the Article IV mission conclusion, it was announced that UK general elections would take place on July 4.

uA001fig02

Share of EU Trade

(Percent of total, exports+imports)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics, ONS, and IMF staff calculations.
uA001fig03

Trade Volume

(2019 averages=100, exports+imports)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics, ONS, and IMF staff calculations.

Recent Economic Developments

4. The economy is approaching a soft landing, with growth recovering faster than expected following a mild technical recession in 2023. Growth was 0.6 percent q/q in 2024Q1, marking a stronger-than-expected exit from the technical recession in the second half of 2023, which left full-year growth at 0.1 percent (0.4 ppt. below January WEO). The slowdown in 2023 was driven by weakness in household consumption as higher interest rates and cost of living pressures took their toll, partially offset by somewhat stronger government spending and business investment. High-frequency indicators (PMIs, consumer and business confidence, retail sales, housing market etc.) have been pointing to a recovery and suggest that private consumption should pick up in the coming quarters, allowing the economy to durably return to a growth path.

uA001fig04

Contributions to GDP Growth

(Y/y percentage points)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: ONS; and IMF Staff Calculations.
uA001fig05

PMI by Sector

(SA, 50+=expansion)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: CPS/IHSM and Haver Analytics.
uA001fig06

Consumer and Business Confidence

(Percent balance)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics.

5. Disinflation has advanced faster than expected, though wage and services inflation pressures remain elevated. Headline and core inflation stood at 2.3 percent and 3.9 percent y/y, respectively, in April, after falling rapidly due to stronger energy and imported goods price deflation, and weaker demand from restrictive monetary policy. This said, wage growth and services inflation remain elevated at 5.7 and 5.9 percent (April y/y) respectively, and momentum in both has edged up recently to above 5 percent, but the May DMP survey suggests a meaningful slowing in expected pay growth to 4.1 percent (from 4.6 percent in April). Meanwhile, the vacancy-to-unemployment ratio (a measure of labor market tightness) fell from a peak of 1.4 in 2022 to 0.6 percent in December 2023 and has broadly stabilized at that level. This is still above the 2012–2019 average of 0.4, possibly reflecting the impact of Brexit on labor market flexibility. Rent inflation, at 9 percent in April, remains quite elevated, reflecting a range of factors, including the impact of high interest rates (reduced demand for home purchase; landlords passing higher mortgage costs to tenants; and constrained supply of rental properties).

Figure 1.
Figure 1.
Figure 1.

United Kingdom: Price and Labor Market Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

6. Bank Rate has been left unchanged at the last six Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) meetings and the MPC shifted to a neutral forward guidance in February. As inflation began to fall sharply, the BoE paused rate hikes in September, leaving the rate at 5¼ percent. The BoE also moved toward neutral forward guidance (“we will adjust rates as economic data warrants”) in February. In its most recent meetings in March and May, no MPC member voted for a rate hike, signaling a move toward rate cuts. Market pricing (as of late May) suggests a first 25 bps rate cut in November, and a total of 40 bps cuts in 2024. Meanwhile, the BoE has broadly maintained its current pace of quantitative tightening (QT) at about £100 billion a year (once account is taken of the offloading of the BoE’s corporate bond holdings) for the 12 months starting October 1, 2023. In December, the BoE decided to adjust the QT auction sizes such that there would be a more balanced amount of short-, medium-, and long-term gilts supplied in initial proceeds terms.

uA001fig07

Forward Implied Policy Rates

(Percent, end-of-period)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Note: Dashed lines represent simplifiedtes from the week of May 24, 2024. Policy rate refers to the Bank Rate for the SOS. the Main Refinancing Rate for the ECB and the Federal Funds Target Rate for the Federal Reserve.Sources: Blank of England, Bloomberg Finance LP.. and Haver Analytics.
uA001fig08

Balance Sheet Path Under Announced QT Policies

(Billion £, end of period)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Note: Gashed line* represent balance sheet shrinkage under announced policies.Sources: Bank of England and Haver Analytics.

7. Financial conditions have eased since May 2023. This primarily reflects the effective appreciation of the exchange rate, an easing in credit spreads on high-yield and investment-grade corporate bonds and, to a lesser extent, a recovery in equity and house prices. Private credit has grown in nominal terms, mostly driven by non-bank lending to corporates (for example, through private equity and credit markets), but credit to GDP has continued to decline and the credit gap has remained negative.3 However, the recent bank lending survey points to a recovery in credit supply. Staff views these credit developments as broadly consistent with the evolution of the monetary stance as well as of credit demand in the aftermath of successive adverse economic shocks. Although rate hikes have paused, the full impact of the monetary tightening still lies ahead; in particular, the transmission through mortgages has been slower than in previous cycles due to a higher share of fixed-rate mortgages (see the SIP on monetary policy issues). While the BoE projects that the aggregate mortgage debt service ratio and the share of households with high debt service ratios (after adjusting for cost of living) would continue to increase throughout 2024, the levels are expected to remain well below the GFC peak and have improved compared with their previous estimates in 2023.4

uA001fig09

Financial Conditions Index

(Higher index value -> tighter financial conditions)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources; Bank of England, Bloomberg, IMF staff calculations
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

United Kingdom: Credit Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

8. The real estate market has been broadly resilient in the face of high interest rates thus far. Concerns about a major residential house price correction in the context of tight monetary policy and weak demand have not materialized. Indicators such as the house price-to-income ratio remain above their long-term average and relative to peer countries. Notwithstanding the attendant affordability concerns, a major downward correction looks unlikely at this time, given limited supply and prevailing market expectations of rising house prices in all regions (house price growth has turned positive since December).5 Moreover, net mortgage approvals are rising from low levels as rates have eased from summer highs. Separately, the commercial real estate (CRE) sector, which already experienced significant price adjustment in 2022 (falling by over 13 percent), appears to have bottomed out in 2023 and is showing signs of recovery in 2024Q1.6 The direct exposure of UK banks and non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs) to the CRE sector remains relatively limited (see Annex VIII, 2023 Article IV Consultation Staff Report).

9. Fiscal policy remains restrictive, with modest windfalls used mainly for tax cuts over the past year. In the 2023 Autumn Statement, the Office for Budget Responsibility’s (OBR’s) medium-term revenue/GDP ratio was upgraded by 2 ppts. on account of higher inflation-induced fiscal drag (in the context of income tax thresholds being frozen till FY 2028/29). After accounting for higher interest payments and increases in indexed welfare spending, this windfall was spent on making permanent the full expensing of plant and machinery investment (in line with staff advice) and a 2 ppts. cut to the main rate of National Insurance Contributions (NICs). In the 2024 Spring Budget, the revenue yield from a set of well-conceived revenue raising measures (including reform of the ‘non-dom’ regime) was more than fully offset by a further 2 ppts. cut to the main NIC rate. The overall fiscal stance in 2024 and 2025 nonetheless remains restrictive, including due to tight spending limits through FY2024/25.

uA001fig10

Public Sector Net Borrowing Impact of Nov. ’23 & Mar. “24 Budgets

(Percentage points of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: Office for Budget Responsibility.

10. The external position has deteriorated slightly in the context of a worse income balance, and an appreciation of the exchange rate. The current account deficit widened marginally from 3.1 percent of GDP in 2022 to 3.3 percent in 2023. This masked a sizable 1.6 ppts. of GDP worsening in the income balance (due to higher net interest payments), which was largely offset by a 1.4 ppts. of GDP improvement in the trade balance (mainly due to lower energy prices). Meanwhile, the exchange rate appreciated by about 2½ percent in real effective terms in 2023, as markets expected the policy rate to stay higher for longer in the UK than in other major jurisdictions. Preliminary estimates suggest that the external position in 2023 was weaker than the level implied by medium-term fundamentals and desirable policies (ESR Annex I).7 Separately, while gross external debt remains high, low net debt and exchange rate flexibility are major risk mitigants (External DSA Annex II).

11. Authorities’ Views. The authorities reiterated that their own models tend to have smaller current account and exchange rate gaps and emphasized the significant role of the UK’s recent terms of trade shock as a factor. They also pointed out uncertainties associated with the balance of payments data due to the pause in FDI statistics. That said, the authorities generally agreed with the policy responses on implementing structural reforms to boost UK international competitiveness.

Outlook and Risks

12. Growth is projected to recover on the back of a pickup in domestic demand. Real GDP growth is forecast to accelerate from 0.1 percent in 2023 to 0.7 percent in 2024, before rising further to 1.5 percent in 2025 as disinflation buoys real incomes and financial conditions ease. This represents an upgrade to staff’s 2024 growth forecast in the April WEO (0.5 percent), in light of the significant upside surprise in 2024Q1 GDP. The broadly unchanged growth forecast for outer years reflects the fact that the underlying weakness in private consumption that weighed on 2023 growth is still there in the Q1 data.8 Longer-term growth prospects remain subdued, with staff estimating long-term potential growth at 1.3 percent (see Potential Growth Annex III), reflecting: (i) the uptick in inactivity related to long term illness; (ii) population aging; (iii) a diminishing contribution from migration (as tighter immigration policies take effect); and (iv) a relatively weak recovery in labor productivity growth (staying well below pre-GFC levels), given low total factor productivity (TFP) growth and an extended period of chronic under-investment (partly driven by policy uncertainty, including in the context of Brexit). Although a cyclical recovery is expected over the next few years, labor productivity is not likely to reach the high levels seen in the decades before the GFC without significant and ambitious growth enhancing structural reforms or upside surprises—for example, a bigger-than-expected payoff from AI adoption, although there remains high uncertainty surrounding its impact on productivity.

uA001fig11

Real GDP Growth

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

uA001fig12

CPI Inflation

(Year-on-year, period average)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Table 1.

United Kingdom: Conditioning Assumptions Underlying Staff’s Baseline Forecast

article image

The fiscal impulse is defined as the change in the cyclically adjusted primary balance (in ppts of GDP), multiplied by an impact multiplier of 0.4.

13. Inflation is expected to moderate, with a durable return to target expected in the first half of 2025. Inflation is forecast to fall to around 2 percent in 2024Q2 due to regulated energy price base effects, before rising slightly later in the year to around 2½ percent and falling durably to 2 percent in 2025Q2. This decline assumes that services inflation, currently above historical levels, will moderate sufficiently to offset the abatement of the negative drag to headline from falling energy and import goods prices. Core inflation is projected to decline more slowly than headline, falling to 2 percent levels only in the second half of 2025.

uA001fig13

Headline CPI Projections and its Components

(Year-on-year, percentage points)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Note: Model estimated using data until 2023Q2.Sources: ONS, IMF staff calculations. Sources: ONS, IMF staff calculations
uA001fig14

Contributions to UK Inflation

(Y-o-y percent change)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.

14. Risks to growth and inflation are balanced. Inflation could be higher or lower depending on the persistence of wage and services inflation, with possible repercussions for growth as monetary policy adjusts.9 Growth could be lower if the anticipated pick-up in consumption from current weak levels does not materialize, or higher in the event of stronger-than-expected second round effects from falling energy prices (this also represents a downside risk to inflation). Moreover, growth could be lower and inflation higher in the event of deepening geoeconomic fragmentation and/or an intensification of regional conflicts, like in the Middle East. As a global financial center, the UK also continues to have high exposure to cyberthreats, and to global financial stability shocks. The key downside risk to medium-term growth is that investment and total factor productivity do not pick up as forecast, and labor supply disappoints relative to the baseline due to higher inactivity, lower immigration, and/or stronger aging effects. Bold implementation of ambitious structural reforms (see Policies to Boost Growth section) and AI adoption (see Box 3.3 of April 2024 WEO) present upside risks to labor productivity and growth (see RAM Annex V).

uA001fig15

Real Wage Growth

(Index, 2006Q1=100 (Germany, France) or 2006Mar=100, 3mma (UK, US)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics, and IMF staff calculations.
uA001fig16

Real Unit Labor Cost

(Index, 2006Q1= 100)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics; WEO; and IMF staff calculations.

15. Authorities’ Views. The authorities highlighted that the economy was turning a corner, and noted staff’s forecasts, including the size of the upward revision to 2024 growth as a result of the stronger than expected 2024Q1 outturn. They cautioned against reading too much into the demand composition of the first estimates of Q1 GDP expenditure data, noting this often gets revised, and that underlying growth could be stronger. They pointed out that staff’s medium-term growth forecasts were in the middle of OBR and BoE projections, but that staff’s longer-term potential growth estimate was lower than both OBR and BoE estimates. In this context, Treasury officials were hopeful that productivity could rebound faster, supporting growth, as the effects of recent negative shocks wane. They also noted that recent measures, including the NIC rate cuts and working age benefits reforms, could provide a larger boost to labor supply and growth over the medium term than OBR costings suggested. The authorities’ 2024 inflation forecasts are similar to those of staff, with considerable uncertainty in 2024H2 on the magnitude of favorable second round effects from falling energy prices, as well as the broader degree of persistence in wage growth and services CPI inflation. The authorities concurred with staff’s assessment of risks but saw healthy household balance sheets and precautionary savings as an upside for consumption in the near term, and greater benefits from AI adoption as an upside for growth over the medium term given the UK’s robust technology ecosystem.

Policy Discussions

The overarching policy objective remains sustainably lifting potential growth and living standards while maintaining price and financial stability and strengthening fiscal buffers. Monetary policy is on track to bring inflation back to target, but some recalibration of the QT strategy and BoE communications may be needed. The main medium-term fiscal challenge will be to stabilize public debt, while managing mounting pressures on public services, which will require difficult choices about the level of taxation and public spending priorities. Bold reforms in the areas of planning, skills, and healthcare to boost labor productivity and ensure adequate labor supply can unlock growth. Macroprudential policy remains appropriate, and continued vigilance of financial stability risks, notably from the non-bank sector, is warranted. Moreover, it is recommended that the UK maintains its open trade orientation, and a cautious approach to industrial policy. Finally, the authorities should redouble policy efforts to credibly achieve their green transition targets, which are at greater risk following the September loosening of some climate policies.

A. Monetary Policy

16. Monetary policy has reached an inflection point. While wage and services inflation remain high at around 6 percent and the upper tails of survey- and market-based inflation expectations still exceed historical averages, wage and price-setting expectations for the next 12 months have eased notably (to 4.1 and 3.8 percent, respectively, in May), and core inflation momentum (3m/3m) has moderated. In this context, staff’s baseline foresees headline inflation to already reach 2 percent this quarter; inflation will then rise to around 2½ percent in Q4. The current real shadow rate using staff’s 1-year ahead inflation projection (2 percent in 2025Q2) is 325 bps, which, given an estimated real neutral rate of around 100 bps, implies a significantly restrictive monetary stance.10 Therefore, the next phase of monetary policy is to ease.

uA001fig17

Monetary Stance

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Notes: Monetary stance is calculated as the difference between the real interest rate (the Bank Rate plus QT impact and minus different reference rates on inflation) and the real natural rate ar1 percent. The iorecastof the Bank Rate is based on the team's baseline conditioning assumption.Sources: Haver analytics and IMF staff calculations.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

United Kingdom: Inflation Expectations and Monetary Stance

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

17. In deciding when and how fast to cut rates, the MPC will need to balance the risks of premature vs. delayed easing. The MPC has highlighted the need to see-through regulated energy price base effects and wait for clearer signs of receding inflation persistence to guard against the risk of premature easing.11 At the same time, there is a risk of delayed easing. Keeping Bank Rate constant as inflation and inflation expectations fall would raise ex-post real rates, which could stall or even reverse the recovery, and lead to an extended undershooting of the inflation target. Staff sees that 50–75 bps rate cuts in 2024 would appropriately balance these risks.

18. Still, a “meeting by meeting approach” is warranted given significant uncertainties. Since the start of the year the market has lowered its expectations of rate cuts in 2024 (to about 40 bps since late May), in light of the higher-than-expected inflation data both in the US and in the UK. Should inflation deviate notably from the baseline path on the upside or downside, monetary policy will need to be adjusted accordingly. Moreover, model-based policy rate paths (see SIP on monetary policy issues) show, intuitively, that concerns about below-potential growth could justify earlier cuts than the path staff recommended, while concerns about a prolonged period of above target inflation leading to de-anchoring of inflation expectations could call for a more cautious approach.

19. The possible divergence from the US Fed’s rate path will place a premium on effective MPC communication with markets. Our empirical work shows that Fed announcements were largely supportive of UK monetary policy transmission during the pre-COVID period, given that market reactions were largely reinforcing (see SIP on monetary policy issues). However, staff also finds that, in the current tightening cycle, market reactions to Fed and MPC decisions sometimes went in opposite directions (as in December 2023). Looking ahead to a period where the BoE could diverge from the Fed (including by cutting rates earlier), there is a risk of spillovers from Fed announcements working against MPC objectives. In this context, staff proposes that the BoE enhance the frequency of its monetary policy communications with markets, including by holding a press conference after each MPC decision, akin to the approach taken by other major central banks.12 This will enable the BoE to elaborate or caveat MPC views when the market’s reaction to Fed decisions is inconsistent with the direction the MPC’s policy decision would lead the market toward.

20. The MPC’s QT strategy has been implemented well thus far but may need recalibration going forward. According to the current pace of QT (£100 billion gilt reduction per 12 months) and the expected maturities of the Term Funding Scheme with additional incentives for SMEs (TFSME), the level of reserves may approach the estimated range for the BoE’s steady-state balance sheet size as soon as the second half of 2025.13 Therefore, a clear rationale for future QT plans, including how it will help the BoE converge to a steady-state balance sheet, will be critical. The QT strategy should continue to be guided by the MPC’s key principles, which include leaving Bank Rate as the active monetary policy instrument and not disrupting smooth market functioning. At the same time, the BoE should continue to monitor undue pressure on short-term money market rates and gilt markets and adjust QT implementation as needed. In this context, staff supports the BoE’s adjustment on QT auction sizes to smooth gilt supply across maturities. Moreover, staff stresses that the steady-state composition of the BoE’s balance sheet (gilts vs. short-term repos) should ensure that money market rates remain aligned with the policy rate (i.e., minimizing wedges),14 while taking into consideration various aspects of demand for reserves, including banks’ needs for high-quality liquid assets.

21. For future cycles of Quantitative Easing (QE)/QT, consideration could be given to adjusting the treatment of QE/QT profits and losses. QE programs have been employed to underpin the economy at times of financial crisis and to avoid sustained periods of below target inflation. Staff’s analysis indicates that QE/QT could be neutral or even beneficial to the fiscal position over the cycle, with direct profit transfers and indirect fiscal benefits via higher tax revenue and lower interest payments during the QE phase outweighing the losses arising during the QT phase (Annex VII). Moreover, the full ex-ante backstop guarantee from the Treasury was intended to protect central bank independence. That said, the fiscal implications of large APF losses during the current tightening cycle have led some stakeholders to suggest that QE/QT decisions pass a narrow value-for-money test, which could potentially affect the BoE’s ability to independently carry out its mandate.15 While this is still an evolving issue for many central banks implementing QT, staff suggests some high-level principles for capital policies governing future QE/QT rounds: (i) the treatment of profits/losses should be fully transparent, ex-ante, and symmetric (as is currently the case); (ii) the size and frequency of transfers between the Treasury and the BoE arising as a result of QE/QT profits/losses should be reduced, to insulate the BoE from any political pressure associated with the fiscal implications of the transfers; and (iii) the profits/losses should be included in the debt definition used for the fiscal rule, as is currently the case, but there would be a case to exclude the profits/losses from any annually-applying deficit rule.

22. The Bernanke review provides a timely opportunity to strengthen the BoE’s data and forecasting infrastructures, and communications. The Review found, inter alia, that (i) the BoE’s forecasting performance has worsened in recent years but is not worse than that of other central banks and other UK forecasters; (ii) there were significant shortcomings in the BoE’s central forecasting model (COMPASS) and data platforms; and (iii) the central forecast, used as a communication device, may not fully reflect MPC’s view of the economy as the central forecast is conditioned on a set of standard assumptions, which “may not always accurately represent the views of the MPC” (see Annex VIII). The Review made 12 recommendations on improving forecasting infrastructure, publishing alternative scenarios, and retiring the inflation fan chart, but stopped short of formally recommending that the MPC publish its own policy rate path(s); the Review left it as a possible solution to issue (iii) above for the BoE to consider later. Staff welcomes the BoE’s commitment to act on the recommendations. Staff advises that in designing the proposed “alternative scenarios”, consideration should be given to including scenario-specific monetary policy paths generated by BoE staff, to better support MPC decision-making and communications. Accordingly, allocating adequate resources to enhance and maintain the required modeling infrastructure is also critical.

23. Authorities’ Views. The MPC voted to maintain Bank Rate at 5.25 percent in May and stated that it would: “continue to monitor closely indications of persistent inflationary pressures and resilience in the economy as a whole”. There is still a range of views among MPC members on the role second-round effects are playing in the persistence of domestic inflationary pressures. While MPC members did not seem overly concerned about immediate spillovers from Fed decision announcements to UK markets (including in a context of divergence between BoE and Fed rate paths) and, therefore, did not see a case for major changes to the MPC’s communication plan, the BoE said they would consider staff’s suggestion for a press conference after every rate decision in the context of implementing recommendations from the Bernanke Review. On other recommendations of the Review, the BoE said they will consider the pros and cons of including more scenarios, and accompanying them, as staff suggests, by scenario-specific monetary policy paths generated by BoE staff. In particular, the BoE agrees on the importance of ensuring adequate resources to durably enhance the required data and modeling infrastructure, and work is already underway. The BoE noted that QT has been operating in the background as intended, leaving Bank Rate as the active policy tool. The BoE will conduct its annual QT review this summer, which will inform the MPC’s decision on the pace of QT for the next 12 months. At the same time, ongoing work at the Bank on the size and composition of the steady-state balance sheet (SSBS) is progressing. The availability of the Short-Term Repo (STR) facility (launched in 2022) means the MPC can continue to make independent decisions on the path of QT, even as the balance of the APF reduces reserve supply towards the estimated size of SSBS. The BoE views the current indemnification arrangement on the APF as clear and transparent but noted the Fund staff’s high-level principles on capital policies for future QE/QT rounds.

B. Fiscal Policy

24. The fiscal consolidation strategy pursued since November 2022 has delivered an appropriately restrictive near-term fiscal stance that should be maintained to rebuild fiscal buffers. The consolidation helped bring the primary deficit from 3.6 percent of GDP in FY2021/22 to 1.3 percent of GDP in FY2023/24 (broadly its pre-pandemic level), while stabilizing debt in year 5 in the OBR’s forecast (one of two fiscal rules introduced in the Autumn 2022 statement; the other being that the public sector borrowing requirement be below 3 percent of GDP in year 5). The consolidation was the net result of a number of measures. The 6 ppts. increase in the corporation tax rate, freezing of personal income tax thresholds, and tight limits on spending were deficit-reducing. At the same time, as noted earlier, the government included tax cuts in the last two budgets. Although the fiscal stance remains restrictive, staff would have recommended against the NIC rate cuts, given their significant cost (½ percent of GDP per year) in a context of significant medium-term spending pressures, described below. But staff does recognize the potential labor supply benefits of the NIC cuts and that they were accompanied by well-conceived measures (e.g., reform of the ‘non-dom’ regime, consistent with staff’s recommendations to close loopholes (see Annex IX)) that will partially offset their fiscal cost over the medium-term.

uA001fig18

Fiscal Impulse

(Percentage points of GDP; change in eye.-adj. pr. clef. adj. by 0.4 multiplier)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

United Kingdom: Fiscal Projections

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

25. The main fiscal challenge, also identified in the 2023 Article IV consultation, is the unrealistically-low medium-term spending path in official budget projections, given mounting spending pressures (See Selected Issues Paper on Spending Pressures). The current official plans assume limited growth of Departmental Expenditure Limits (DEL) (around two fifths of total public spending), with recurrent DEL spending rising by one percent per year in real terms from FY2025/26, with flat nominal capital spending. The OBR has assessed these plans as lacking detail, with similar sentiments echoed by both business groups and leading think tanks. The assumed pace of spending growth is likely inadequate to accommodate widely reported pressures on public services, particularly health, education, and social care, as well as critical growth-enhancing investments, including for the green transition. Some of the announced sectoral spending commitments, such as the NHS long-term workforce plan, the ‘triple lock’ policy (likely implying above-inflation pension increases), and the aspiration to increase defense spending to 2½ percent of GDP, would require significant real cuts (as yet unidentified) to other spending areas, to be consistent with the announced pace of aggregate spending growth.

26. Accounting for some of this spending pressure, debt continues to increase over the 5-year projection horizon under staff’s baseline. Staff’s projections assume real growth of DEL spending will be around two percent per year over the medium term, accommodating critical spending needs in public services (particularly the NHS Long-Term Workforce Plan, meeting demand for social care, pension spending under the ‘triple lock’ and higher defense spending), as well as real growth of public investment, which is presently very low, and spending for the green transition. Non-interest Annually Managed Expenditure (AME) (mostly non-discretionary, including welfare) is assumed to rise with inflation and the rate of population growth. On a net basis, staff’s projections imply that non-interest spending declines by only ¾ ppt. of GDP between FY2023/24 by FY2028/29, compared with a 1.7 ppts. decline in the OBR forecast, so that public sector net borrowing will be 1½ ppts. above the OBR forecast by FY2028/29. Under staff’s more realistic forecast, public sector net debt (excl. BoE) continues to rise over the medium-term to reach about 97½ percent of GDP by FY2028/29 (OBR projects about 93 percent of GDP), an 8 ppts. of GDP increase from end-FY2023/24 levels (see Figure 4). Although the risk of sovereign stress is still assessed as low (see Annex X) and the UK still retains some fiscal space, the non-stabilization of the debt/GDP ratio over five years is a deterioration from the last Article IV, where debt just stabilized in year 5; it is also consistent with the observed deterioration in the SRDSF’s medium-term mechanical risk signals.

27. Absent a major boost to potential growth, additional consolidation will be needed for debt to stabilize with high probability. The amount of fiscal effort required will depend on (i) the target probability by which debt must stabilize (higher probability will imply larger effort); (ii) the horizon over which debt is to be stabilized; and (iii) the extent to which spending pressures are accommodated. As shown in the table below, relative to staff’s baseline, the annual primary balance would need to be higher by 0.8 ppt. of GDP on average during FY2025/26–FY2029/30 to stabilize debt in year 5 (FY2029/30) with 50 percent probability. In order to reduce fiscal sustainability risks, staff recommends an adjustment path such that debt is projected to stabilize with a higher probability (e.g., 75 percent) over five years (using the SRDSF debt fanchart methodology), requiring keeping the annual primary balance on average at least 1.2 ppts. of GDP above staff’s current baseline.16

Text Table 2.

United Kingdom: Fiscal Effort to achieve Debt Stabilization: Adjustment Scenarios (ppts. of GDP)

article image

28. High-quality consolidation measures will be required to realize the additional effort required.

  • On the revenue side, there is considerable scope to raise revenues, including through (i) aligning the rates of capital gains tax with the equivalent rates of personal income tax (around ½ percent of GDP), to treat capital and labor income equally; (ii) removing unnecessary VAT exemptions (around ½ percent GDP), to broaden the consumption tax base; (iii) reforming property taxation (replacing Council Tax with a broad-based property tax) (around ¼ percent of GDP); and (iv) broad-based wealth taxation (around ½ percent of GDP), or reforms to inheritance taxation, by removing unnecessary reliefs. Stronger carbon taxation (use of feebates) could be a further source of revenue, while supporting the green transition.17 These measures should be implemented as part of a broader pro-growth structural reform agenda (see below) and will support the climate transition while making the tax system more efficient and fairer.18

  • On the spending side, the overly-generous pensions ‘triple lock’, under which the state pension will likely grow above the rate of inflation, should be abolished, saving around 0.1 percent of GDP per year. Other options could include expanded or enhanced charging for public services, while taking care to protect the vulnerable, as well as pursuing productivity gains, such as from the government’s announced investment in digitalization and AI within the public sector (including the NHS), although the savings associated with these initiatives are difficult to quantify at this time.

29. Against the backdrop of these challenges, as a general principle, staff advises against additional tax cuts. The UK’s revenue/GDP ratio is well below the level in G7 European peers but its welfare state is, in some ways (e.g., healthcare), similarly expansive as in those peers. In this context, the bar for further tax cuts needs to be set very high: specifically, staff advises that tax cuts be eschewed unless they are credibly growth-enhancing and appropriately offset by high-quality deficit-reducing measures. Of course, in the event that growth disappoints, automatic stabilizers should be allowed to operate, but, again, considering the fiscal challenge at hand, any discretionary stimulus should be well targeted, including, to protect the vulnerable, and with strong regard to debt sustainability risks.

uA001fig19

Revenue

(Percent of GDP, general government)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: October 2023 World Economic Outlook.
uA001fig20

Primary Expenditure

(Percent of GDP, general government)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: October 2023 World Economic Outlook.

30. There is also a need for broader reforms to fiscal institutions and processes.

  • Fiscal Rules. The current rules under which PSND (excl. BoE) must fall by the fifth year and PSNB must fall below three percent of GDP are insufficiently constraining in the near-term and encourage unrealistic assumptions further out. Staff proposes a probabilistic approach (which takes better account of uncertainty) for the debt rule under which debt must decline in the fifth year with a high probability (the “additional effort” table above shows results with 75 percent); this will increase the likelihood that debt does eventually decline.19 This approach could be nested within a higher-level fiscal standard that sets a bar for “responsible” fiscal policy (see Annex VI, 2023 Article IV Consultation Staff Report). Separately, as noted in the monetary policy section, staff does not support the exclusion of QE/QT profits/losses from the fiscal aggregates used to assess compliance with the debt rule, since net losses of QE/QT are liabilities of the public sector. However, staff could support exclusion from flow aggregates in a future fiscal rule, such as an annually-applying deficit rule, subject to the principles discussed in the monetary policy section.

  • Enhanced OBR Role. The OBR, while empowered to produce the economic and fiscal forecasts underlying the two fiscal events a year, should be required to provide an updated forecast whenever there is a major fiscal policy change (such as that surrounding the ‘mini-budget’). Extending the OBR’s forecast horizon in the Economic and Fiscal Outlooks to ten years is also recommended to better-capture longer-term spending pressures, as well as dividends from growth-enhancing investments, which will help provide a more complete picture of the sustainability of public finances. Furthermore, the OBR’s public views should be sought on any changes to fiscal rules at the time of their consideration, while the recommended addition of escape clauses to the fiscal rules should be accompanied by a role for the OBR to determine when they are triggered.

  • Budget Process. Transitioning from semi-annual to annual budgets is also recommended to streamline the budget process and reduce political pressure for fiscal loosening, which seems to manifest itself in revenue windfalls being mostly spent, but adverse revenue shocks being fully accommodated. There is also scope to improve the credibility of the medium-term fiscal framework, by providing visibility on spending plans for at least three years ahead. This can be done by producing medium-term (four or five-year) spending ceilings, updated every 2 years based on detailed assumptions and policies. This new framework would replace the current system of periodic spending reviews, which fix limits on DEL (i.e., excluding pensions, welfare and interest payments) for three-years, providing progressively less guidance about the medium term as the end of the three-year period is approached, as is the case presently. The medium-term framework would also provide greater certainty for capital spending projects, as found by the 2022 PIMA.

31. Authorities’ Views. While acknowledging the uncertainty over expenditure allocations pending the next spending review, the authorities noted that the fiscal rules were being met under the OBR’s independent forecast. They also explained that the NIC rate cuts and disability benefit reforms were designed to incentivize work in the context of a notable rise in inactivity and a high share of people with disabilities. The authorities acknowledged pressures on public services but felt recent funding increases for the NHS, social care and schools should help address immediate challenges, while longer term needs are being addressed via implementation of the NHS Long-Term Workforce Plan and other strategies. In terms of public investment, the authorities expect to set future plans at the time of the next spending review, to be held after the upcoming general election. Regarding the fiscal framework, the authorities noted its strength and underscored the important role of the OBR. The authorities saw some merit in exploring the role that the probability of debt stabilization could play in any future review of fiscal rules. Staff’s recommendations to have a single fiscal event each year and replace spending reviews with rolling four or five-year spending frameworks updated twice a year were noted. The authorities concurred with staff’s assessment of sovereign risks and underlying assumptions, as well as the extent of fiscal space.

C. Reforms to Boost Growth

32. Like other European peers, the UK has faced a major trend growth and productivity slowdown since the GFC. This, combined with a series of subsequent adverse shocks (Brexit, COVID, energy price surge), and longer-term trends (such as aging), has left the level of UK GDP at around a quarter below the level implied by the trend in the decades before the GFC, accompanied by worsening income, inter-generational,20 and spatial equality.21 Although the UK has done better than peers in terms of total hours worked, the drop in labor productivity growth, the key driver of living standards – from around 2 percent pre-GFC to around ½ percent thereafter—has been noticeably bigger than in other advanced economies. Most of this drop was due to the loss of pre-GFC growth engines such as North Sea Oil and a leverage-driven boom in the financial sector, which was then exacerbated by reduced firm dynamism post-GFC and the recent shocks mentioned above (see Annex IV). Moreover, the impact of a prolonged period of relatively low rates of TFP-supporting investment and high service delivery pressures, notably in health, on economic potential, is beginning to show (e.g., via an uptick in long-term illness-induced inactivity). Finally, aging and policies to rein in immigration will constrain total hours worked going forward, creating additional headwinds to growth.

uA001fig21

Productivity: GDP Per Hour Worked

(Ratio of GDP per hour worked compared to the US, current PPP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: OECD.
uA001fig22

Drivers of Labor Productivity Growth

(Market sector, contribution to GVA per hour growth, 5-year rolling average, percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: ONS.

33. The authorities have responded to this slowdown via a series of initiatives, but further ambitious reforms are needed to boost potential growth. The authorities adopted the “levelling up agenda” in 2022; the “4Es’ strategy” (“enterprise, education, employment, everywhere”) in January 2023; and “110 reforms to boost growth” in Autumn 2023. They have also delivered, since Autumn 2022, a number of helpful measures, most notably, permanent investment tax reliefs for businesses, and strengthened the incentives and capacity to work (in the form of tax cuts, changes in working age benefits, and expansion of childcare support).22 They have also initiated reforms to unlock pension savings for higher-return investments. While supporting the medium-term outlook, these measures are unlikely to sufficiently lift the UK’s long-term potential growth to the 2 percent level seen in the UK in the decades before the GFC, or in US at present. Leveraging the wide body of work by UK academics and thinktanks on impediments to growth, staff has identified three key areas that need the most urgent attention, including by building on past efforts. These key reforms also have the benefit of being relatively less costly in fiscal terms. If implemented, these reforms will also improve competitiveness and the UK’s external position.

  • Easing planning restrictions. The current regime for planning is excessively stringent and has severely inhibited the construction of new housing and infrastructure projects, thus constraining labor mobility (workers are forced into sub-optimal jobs as they are unable to move to more expensive areas with better jobs due to unaffordable housing).23 Cheshire (2015) estimates the attendant TFP effect at a massive 32 percent for some businesses. This has resulted in high and increasing prices overall, and widening disparities between high and low growth regions, given inelastic housing supply. Key reforms: (i) establish up-to-date, binding plans at the local level to streamline the decision-making and avoid the “not in my backyard” problem in designated growth areas, with incentives and additional resources to local authorities to overcome opposition and increase efficiency; (ii) digitalize and standardize planning process to help reduce delays and increase transparency; (iii) institute broader geographic and rules based decision-making for business developments to decrease uncertainty and provide more clarity and predictability to investors; (iv) introduce targeted incentives (to overcome new builds resistance) and resources for local authorities (including skilled staff to facilitate compliance with new environmental requirements); (v) carefully review the scope to release Green Belt land of little environmental or amenity value near stations with easy access to major cities; (vi) ensure better housing standards and higher-quality housing across all income groups, particularly in the private rented sector, alongside flexible land use policies to adapt to changing economic needs and environmental considerations; and (vii) lower stamp duty for both residential and non-residential properties (alongside a reform of the council tax to ensure net revenue gain) to stimulate high-growth firm activity and facilitate workforce mobility (see Planning SIP).

  • Upskilling the workforce. There is an urgent need to upgrade the skills of UK workers, given larger observed skills gaps than in peer countries, and surveys reporting widespread recruitment difficulties that are limiting output, particularly in high skill sectors like digital and software, manufacturing, medicine and life sciences, teaching, and construction. Despite an increase in public funding for primary and post-secondary education since 2019 (reversing earlier cuts), outcomes, particularly science scores, have declined over the past two decades, accompanied by a decline in workplace training and apprenticeship. Since Brexit, there has been an increase in non-EU migrants, but they have not directly offset the loss of EU-workers given different skillsets and hurdles (especially for small firms, in sponsoring skilled worker visas). Key reform: (i) more and better-quality training and apprenticeships to develop skills in high-demand, including via higher government support; (ii) ambitious targets consistent with a reversal of the recent decline in STEM outcomes; (iii) schemes to further encourage younger workers to enter future growth sectors and improve retention; and (iv) a simplified worker visa regime to facilitate smaller employers (who were large employers of skilled EU-labor pre-Brexit) hire non-EU workers (see Skills SIP).

  • Improving health outcomes. The UK has done well to boost labor supply in the past (including through immigration), but this could be at risk going forward from rising inactivity (in the context of weak health outcomes) and an aging population. The post-pandemic decline in UK labor force participation is largely attributable to elevated rates of long-term sickness and disability, with more than 20 percent of the population recorded as having disabilities (above G7 peers). Moreover, illness is a major drag, not just on labor supply but also on labor productivity—for the segment of the population who remain in the workforce but are not healthy. Given that the number of hospital beds, doctors, and nurses per capita are lower than the OECD average, the authorities have responded by committing additional resources to the health system, including through the NHS Long-Term Workforce Plan, which aims to increase NHS staff numbers by around 800,000 over the next ten years, while also announcing £3.4 billion (0.1 percent of GDP) in the Spring Budget to support efficiency improvements using digitalization and AI. The authorities have also announced reforms to the benefit system to incentivize work, including by increasing the stringency of the Work Capability Assessment (WCA), which determines access to incapacity benefits.24 Key reforms: (i) full implementation of the NHS Long-Term Workforce Plan, accompanied by real increases in capital spending, to create a better-resourced and more productive health service;25 (ii) pursue a forward-looking and integrated approach to NHS resource allocation and strategic decision making that is focused on system-wide performance (e.g., integrated and digitalized patient records); (iii) increased funding for social care commensurate with demand over the medium-term; and (iv) improved health services for those with disabilities (including mental health), while ensuring that those capable of work are incentivized to do so and are adequately assisted through training, coaching, and integrated health support, building on recent reforms.

uA001fig23

Variation in Median House Price Across Regions

(Select regions, GBP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: Office of National Statistics
uA001fig24

Qualification Mismatch

(Percentage)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Note: Qualification mismatch is defined by the discrepancy between the highest qualification held by a worker and the qualification required by their job. Over [under) qualification that is above [below] their job’s requirements.Sources: OECD Skills for Jobs Database
uA001fig25

Disability Prevalence

(People with disability as a share of the population aged 15–69, average over 2016–2019)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: OECD calculations based on European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions [EU-SILC] for European countries

34. In this context, staff proposes that the authorities adopt a clear and stable long-term growth strategy, potentially anchored in the advice of an independent growth commission. While progress on post-Brexit arrangements has reduced uncertainty, recurrent and piecemeal policy changes, including at semi-annual fiscal events, have arguably made it harder for businesses and workers to plan. With only one fiscal event a year and a longer horizon for official projections, the government might be better incentivized to articulate and follow through on a stable growth agenda which includes reforms with payoffs going well beyond the electoral cycle. In this context, consideration could be given to establishing an independent growth commission, similar, for example, to the productivity commission in Australia (see Growth Commission Annex XI). Such a body can take a longer-term view of reform priorities (making policy more strategic and focused); better coordinate across different levels of government; and track and report on implementation, serving as a disciplining and communication device (akin to the Climate Change Committee).

35. The authorities should continue their cautious approach to industrial policy. Relative to some G7 peers, the UK has been cautious in deploying vertical industrial policies, instead favoring broad-based tax incentives for business investment and R&D. Direct support to industry has been limited, with the UK government announcing an Advanced Manufacturing Plan in November 2023, together with a Battery Strategy. Under the plan, £4.5 billion (0.2 percent of GDP) will be invested strategically in high technology sectors, including the aerospace, automotive and life sciences, mainly in the form of grant funding for R&D and investment. Around £1 billion each (0.1 percent of GDP) has also been committed to a Green Industries Growth Accelerator, and for creative industries, while 13 investment zones and 12 free ports have been announced, which will offer tax concessions and other targeted support. Staff encourages the authorities to keep these plans and future policies narrowly targeted toward removing obstacles to investment and improving the business environment, focusing on industries and firms where externalities or market failures prevent effective market solutions, while minimizing trade and investment distortions, as well as adverse international spillover effects. Meanwhile, the UK’s active and constructive participation in the WTO is welcome.

36. Authorities’ Views. The authorities’ acknowledged the importance of further ambitious, evidence-based structural reforms to boost investment, productivity and labor supply and noted that this was their preferred means of building fiscal buffers while addressing spending needs. They agreed with staff on key reform priorities and noted recently implemented reforms in these areas. In particular, they highlighted planning reforms and full expensing (for qualifying plant and machinery business investments), and the cuts in the NIC rate, which should support labor supply. While agreeing that rising inactivity due to long term sickness was a challenge, they highlighted reforms to working age benefits, with the view of ensuring that people who are capable of work are incentivized to do so but agreed with the importance of adequately supporting such people through training and coaching; and to ensure that those who need healthcare receive it. The authorities opined that the main issue in healthcare was efficiency but acknowledged the need for capital investment, including in digital infrastructure, which was announced during the Spring Budget. The authorities also noted that addressing skills gaps was a priority with an emphasis on future growth areas such as digital and AI, STEM, life sciences and the creative arts, particularly for the young, but also for older workers through lifelong learning. The authorities explained that they have put in place measures to improve the quality of apprenticeship programs, and this in part explains the decline in total numbers. Recent efforts have also been made to grow apprenticeship numbers in key sectors and incentivise SMEs to create opportunities for young people. They were receptive in principle to the idea of a growth commission.

D. Financial Sector Policies

37. The overall level of systemic risk is assessed as broadly similar to that in the previous Article IV consultation, with the focus shifting somewhat from households to corporations. Household debt vulnerabilities have reduced somewhat, supported by strong wage growth and a lower expected policy rate path, while corporate vulnerabilities have edged up, mainly for firms exposed to some segments of market finance (see below). The banking sector is healthy, while vulnerabilities in the more complex NBFI sector, including high leverage and liquidity mismatch, and lack of data for a comprehensive assessment remain a source of concern (see Annex XII on FSAP recommendations). Moreover, in line with staff’s assessments the recent Financial Policy Committee (FPC) meeting summary highlighted that risk premia have decreased further below historical averages across several asset classes and a sharp correction in a broad range of asset prices could crystalize long-standing vulnerabilities in market-based finance. Moreover, global risks remain elevated, including from heightened geopolitical tensions, corrections in CRE markets globally, as well as the property market in China, which could spill over to the UK financial system.

38. Macroprudential settings are appropriate but continued close monitoring of credit conditions and financial stability risks is merited in future calibrations. Reflective of the macroeconomic development, credit conditions remain muted, particularly for smaller businesses and certain sectors, Moreover, the latest results from the IMF global stress testing showed that in an adverse scenario, UK banks remain resilient, echoing the BoE’s 2022/23 stress testing results. Against this backdrop, staff supports the FPC’s decision to maintain the countercyclical capital buffer (CCyB) at its two percent neutral level. Should tighter financial conditions weigh on corporate and household debt vulnerabilities and increase credit losses materially, the authorities should consider easing prudential policy (for example, releasing the CCyB) to avoid exacerbating the credit downturn. In light of potential valuation risks in several asset markets, continued monitoring and appropriately stringent stress tests would be important.

39. While major UK banks remain healthy, continued strong supervision of all UK banks is warranted. The capital and liquidity positions of major UK banks remain robust (with CET1 ratio at 14.7 percent and LCR at 147 percent in 2023Q4), but the diverse business models of smaller banks merit continued close monitoring as stress in this segment has been idiosyncratic. Staff supports the BoE’s decision to conduct desk-based top-down stress testing this year, which would provide more flexibility to test multiple stress scenarios, and views this as a helpful complement to the bottom-up approach. Staff also encourages further utilization of stress testing tools to identify potential risks in smaller banks. Separately, the Prudential Regulation Authority (PRA) has made careful progress on a new Strong and Simple Framework to simplify the prudential framework for non-systemic domestic banks and building societies, while maintaining their resilience.

40. Ongoing initiatives to enhance risk monitoring and crisis response readiness with regard to NBFIs have gained momentum but challenges remain.

  • Staff welcomes the progress thus far on the System-Wide Exploratory Scenario (SWES) and looks forward to important insights generated on the level of resilience of participants, their reaction functions to stressed financial market conditions, and potential propagation channels. Moreover, staff encourages considering making some data collection permanent for continued risk monitoring to build an ongoing capacity for system-wide stress testing.

  • Staff also welcomes progress on the design of the NBFI lending tool, which, in line with FSAP recommendations, aims to act as a backstop to core markets in the event of systemic stress by providing liquidity to appropriately regulated and systemically interconnected NBFIs, while avoiding moral hazard. The first step is to have the facility accessible for pension funds, insurance companies, and LDI funds.26 Staff urges that the design of the tool ensure an appropriate balance between signaling BoE readiness to provide sufficient support during stress episodes, and preserving incentives for NBFIs to enhance their resilience in normal times and encourages continued regulatory coordination to ensure the resilience of non-UK domiciled funds.

  • Staff supports continued work to enhance the resilience of different segments of the NBFI sector, such as money market funds (MMFs) and pension funds. Staff welcomes the regulatory changes proposed by the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) for MMFs and stresses that work should continue internationally given the large number of non-UK domiciled sterling MMFs.27

  • Reforms to unlock pension savings for higher-return investments, which could provide better outcomes for savers, are welcome, but should not undermine financial stability (see Pensions Annex XII). While investment reallocation could potentially improve returns, the asset allocation of pension funds should not be mandated, and any reforms should not hinder the ability of pension funds to fulfill fiduciary responsibilities effectively and achieve the best possible outcomes for their beneficiaries. Given the ongoing defined benefit (DB) pension fund buy-outs and potential concentration risk created in the insurance industry from these concurrent changes, monitoring possible financial stability implications, including the longer-term structural impact of these developments on gilt demand, will be important. In this context, staff continues recommending that The Pensions Regulator (TPR) be given an explicit financial stability remit, accompanied by a reinforcement of its staffing to achieve this mandate. Finally, staff encourages continued work to ensure adequate pensions for UK employees, including the consideration of expanding auto-enrollment efforts and raising the minimum pension contribution in the medium term.

  • Progress on closing data gaps has been slower than expected, such as data on all Sterling asset holdings and data needed to improve the management of liquidity demands by fund managers and flow-of-funds data, including all cross-border NBFI exposures (see Data Issues Annex XIV). Therefore, it is important to maintain both domestic and international momentum to close NBFI data gaps and to better understand and take action to address the financial stability implications of NBFI leverage. In this context, staff welcomes the FPC’s continued evaluation of risks from private equity and interconnected markets and looks forward to the assessment to be published in the June 2024 FSR.28

41. Structural financial sector reforms are progressing cautiously. The Edinburgh Reforms package (see Annex XV) in December 2022 and the Chancellor’s Mansion House speech on pension reforms in July 2023 have listed some government priorities on regulatory changes in the financial service sector. The government has taken steps on the 31 initiatives in the Edinburgh Reforms and has preserved the primacy of financial stability objectives. Moreover, the authorities are working on enhancements to the special resolution regime, including a proposal to allow the Financial Services Compensation Scheme (FSCS) to provide funds to the BoE to recapitalize and secure operational continuity of a failing small bank through resolution, and then recoup costs through industry levies. While this would help minimize disruptions from small bank failures, staff encourages prefunding the FSCS to an appropriate level to avoid moral hazard.

42. The authorities continue to strengthen the effectiveness of AML/CFT risk-based supervision, considering the UK’s high exposure to the laundering of proceeds of foreign crimes. To mitigate misuse of the financial and professional services sectors and UK-registered corporate structures, the authorities should continue to implement measures under Economic Crime Plan 2023–26 to improve the effectiveness and coordination of the AML/CFT supervisory regime. These include HMT’s consultations on potential changes to the Money Laundering Regulations and the implementation of a data framework to measure the effectiveness of supervisors. The FCA continues implementing a proactive, data-driven supervisory strategy to cover systemically important entities more frequently. To prevent the criminal use of virtual assets, the FCA pursues a stringent risk-based approach to the registration and supervision of virtual asset service providers. Additionally, the Economic Crime and Corporate Transparency Act passed in October 2023 provides broadened powers for law enforcement for quicker seizure and recovery of virtual assets which are the proceeds of crime.

Voluntary Assessment of Transnational Aspects of Corruption

43. The authorities continue to address transnational aspects of corruption, including combatting foreign bribery and preventing laundering of foreign corruption proceeds, but more efforts are needed (Box 1).

United Kingdom: Transnational Aspects of Corruption1

While facing significant foreign bribery risks, the authorities have continued to undertake mitigation efforts.2 Several factors contribute to such risks, including the UK’s size and number of multinational enterprises, scale of outward FDI, its leading position as a global financial center, diverse business sector and exports to high-risk jurisdictions and industries.3 The OECD Phase 4 evaluation of the UK acknowledges the consistent efforts of the authorities as one of the major enforcers among Working Group on Bribery (WGB) members, including enhancing independence of investigation and prosecution, providing training to ensure sanctions through public procurement measures, improving case management system, and strengthening tax-related measures. In the 2023 written follow-up report, the authorities provided clarifications on its legal system in ensuring independence of investigation and prosecution and reported measures to collaborate with the Crown Dependencies (CDs) and British Overseas Territories (BOTs) in their efforts to fight foreign bribery. The authorities should continue to implement the OECD Phase 4 recommendations, including reviewing and raising awareness of its whistleblower protection framework, further ensuring adequate resources for foreign bribery enforcement, independence of investigation and prosecution, and transparency of court decisions, as well as engaging with the CDs and BOTs to extend application of the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention and enhance enforcement.

The authorities should continue their efforts to improve the effectiveness of the AML/CFT supervisory regime, given exposures of ML risks. The UK’s banking, high-end real estate, and TCSP4 sectors are at the highest risk of laundering proceeds of overseas corruption. In response, the Economic Crime and Corporate Transparency Act 2023 introduces key reforms to strengthen beneficial ownership transparency, including new powers for Companies House to verify ownership filings, share information with law enforcement, remove fraudulent companies, and impose financial penalties. The reforms also target high-risk limited partnerships (including Scottish limited partnerships) and expand the scope of trustees and nominee beneficial owners under the UK’s Register of Overseas Entities. The authorities continue to engage with UK Overseas Territories and Crown Dependencies on their commitments to provide publicly accessible beneficial ownership registers (see Table 9). In order to address deficiencies in the effectiveness of the risk-based supervision of the legal and accountancy sector, the authorities have undertaken a public consultation and are assessing reform options. The Home Office, the Office for Professional Body Anti-Money Laundering Supervision (OPBAS), and the National Economic Crime Centre also developed a professional enablers strategy to improve intelligence sharing between the private sector, supervisors, and law enforcement. The Economic Crime Plan 2023–26 and the 2023 International Development White Paper outline measures to strengthen the UK’s international response to foreign illicit finance threats. These include a renewed commitment to law enforcement capabilities, strengthening of cross-border asset recovery outcomes and cooperation with global financial centers, and continuing participation in relevant multilateral fora. The authorities should continue these welcome efforts to strengthen entity transparency and effective supervision of high-risk sectors to counter the risk of laundering of foreign proceeds of corruption in the UK.

1 The United Kingdom volunteered to have its legal and institutional frameworks assessed in the context of bilateral surveillance for purposes of determining whether it: (a) criminalizes and prosecutes the bribery of foreign public officials and (b) has an effective AML/CFT system that is designed to prevent foreign officials from concealing the proceeds of corruption. 2 Information relating to supply-side corruption in this Box is based on information and data provided by the UK authorities. IMF staff has provided additional views and information. The information in this Box has not been verified by the OECD Working Group on Bribery (WGB) or the OECD Secretariat and does not prejudice the WGB’s monitoring of the implementation of the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention. 3 Out of the 500 largest multinational enterprises (MNE) in the world, 20 are headquartered in the UK, with some operating in high-risk sectors and jurisdictions, according to the OECD- UNSD Multinational Enterprise Information Platform. 4 Trust and Company Service Providers.

44. Authorities’ Views. The authorities noted that the financial stability environment was somewhat calmer than last year. While idiosyncratic risks and the exposure of large banks globally to CRE—especially to the US and China—are closely monitored, the FPC reiterated that the UK banking system was resilient, and subject to robust prudential supervision. Regarding the Strong and Simple regime, the PRA noted that careful progress has been made. The FPC viewed macroprudential settings as appropriate and noted that credit conditions overall reflect changes in the macroeconomic outlook rather than defensive actions by banks. Regarding NBFI initiatives, the BoE has completed the first round of the system-wide exploratory scenario (SWES). Final results are expected to be published in 2024Q4. The BoE also plans to launch a new NBFI repo facility, noting that work is underway to determine key design features. The FCA described industry feedback on the consultation on enhancing liquidity management of UK-domiciled sterling money market funds (MMFs) as broadly positive and believed that the market could adjust to the proposed requirements. The authorities noted that work was underway both domestically and internationally to close NBFI data gaps.

E. Climate Policies

45. The recent relaxation of climate policies and decline in the UK carbon price will put the UK’s ambitious climate targets further off track. The UK hosted COP26 in 2021 and adopted an Nationally Determined Contribution (NDC) to reduce emissions by 68 percent by 2030, having already reduced emissions by 50 percent below 1990 levels, mainly due to phasing out coal-fired power stations, so that the UK now accounts for around 1 percent of global emissions. In September 2023, the government softened climate policy by announcing an exemption for 20 percent of homes from the requirement to transition to electric heat pumps, while the transition deadline for homes off the gas grid was delayed from 2026 to 2035, despite a welcome increase of the boiler upgrade grant. In the transport sector, the requirement that 80 percent of new vehicles sold in the UK be ‘zero emission’ by 2030 (100 percent by 2035) has been enshrined in legislation, but the ban on purchasing internal combustion engine vehicles has been delayed from 2030 to 2035 (as in some EU countries). Despite announcing an emissions cap under the Emission Trading Scheme for 2035 that is consistent with the UK’s climate goals, the UK carbon price has declined to around 50 percent of its level in early 2023, to be well below the corresponding EU price, which, if it persists, will make some of the UK’s exports subject to the EU Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) from 2026. The announcement of a UK CBAM, to be implemented from 2027, is welcome. Overall, however, the net impact of recent policy adjustments and announcements is that existing policies are only sufficient to achieve 57 percent of the UK’s NDC emissions reduction target by 2030 (see chart).

uA001fig26

Percent Reduction Below No-Climate Policy Counter-factual in 2030

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations.
uA001fig27

UK Greenhouse Gas Emissions

(Percent of Global Emissions)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: EU Emissions Database for Global Atmospheric Research.
uA001fig28

UK Greenhouse Gas Emissions by Sector

(Million Tonnes of CO2 Equivalent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: EU Emissions Database for Global Atmospheric Research.

46. The UK should stay the course on climate policy, to maintain its status as a climate leader and to realize the benefits of the green transition. Whole-of-economy investment in the green transition should increase to £50 billion pounds per year by 2030 (from £20 billion in 2020), as the Climate Change Committee has recommended, with a public contribution of around one third. Public support to households for the transition from gas heating to electric heat pumps is a priority for the government’s contribution, given that the buildings sector is among the largest contributors to UK emissions, along with the transport and industrial sectors. The recently-announced exemption for certain homes from the requirement to transition to electric heat pumps should be narrowly defined, and the relaxation of energy efficiency requirements for rental properties should be reversed. Strengthening feebates on heating options for non-exempt homes in the near-term (with taxes on new fossil fuel heating funding subsidies for heat pumps) should be considered to accelerate the transition away from gas heating. Given the government’s decision to delay the ban on purchases of internal combustion engine vehicles to 2035, the government should instead consider stronger price-based incentives for zero-emission vehicles in the form of larger feebates, with higher taxes on internal combustion engine vehicles supporting non-discriminatory consumption subsidies for electric vehicles, consistent with WTO rules and without favoring local manufacturers. The CBAM can help to address carbon leakage concerns and encourage trading partners to make more ambitious mitigation efforts, but should be implemented in line with WTO rules including basing charges on actual carbon content in traded products, rather than benchmarks. In line with 2023 Article IV recommendations, consideration could be given to widening the coverage of the ETS to include road transport and buildings (or consider upstream carbon taxes in these sectors), supported by a fixed carbon price floor that rises over time, in order to achieve a more comprehensive, predictable, and uniform carbon price. The authorities should also pursue long overdue action on agricultural emissions, by implementing a self-reporting regime for farmers, with emissions subject to a fee.

uA001fig29

Carbon Prices

(12-month futures, euros)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: Bloomberg Finance L.P.

47. Authorities’ Views. The authorities explained the UK’s strong performance in reducing emissions, noting that emissions have been halved relative to 1990 levels and that the first three carbon budgets have been met, subject to the UK’s strong legal framework for climate policy. The authorities pointed out that recent changes to climate policy (e.g., delaying the ban on purchase of internal combustion engine vehicles) bring the UK more into line with peer countries. The authorities noted the legislative passage of the Electric Vehicles (EV) mandate, requiring 80 percent of new vehicles sold in the UK to be fully electric by 2030, and observed that the uptake of EVs is progressing well. The number of conversions to heat pumps for home heating has also accelerated, albeit from a low base, since the Boiler Upgrade Grant was increased. The authorities explained that a net-zero consistent cap on emission trading scheme allowances has been implemented and believe that this will be sufficient to support an appropriate carbon price in the UK. The authorities note the important role of public investment in the green transition, as well as public-private cooperation, particularly in the power sector. As with all areas, future public spending levels will be set at the next Spending Review.

Staff Appraisal

48. The UK economy is approaching a soft landing. Real GDP growth is forecast at 0.7 percent in 2024 before rising to 1.5 percent in 2025 as disinflation buoys real incomes and financial conditions ease. However, longer-term growth prospects remain subdued due to weak labor productivity and somewhat higher-than-expected inactivity levels, only partly offset by higher migration numbers. Disinflation has advanced faster than expected, and a durable return to the target is forecast by early 2025, although this rests on wage growth and services inflation pressures abating from current elevated levels. Risks to growth and inflation are balanced. The 2023 external position was weaker than the level in line with fundamentals and desirable policies.

49. Monetary policy will need to balance the risks of premature vs. delayed easing, and be supported by strong communications, including around QT. With Bank Rate more than 2 ppts. higher than staff’s estimate of the neutral rate, the next phase of monetary policy is to ease. Rate cuts of 50–75 bps in 2024 would balance the risks of premature and delayed easing, but a meeting-by-meeting approach remains appropriate, given uncertainties. Given a possible divergence from the Fed, there will be a premium on effective MPC communications, and a press conference after each rate decision would be beneficial. The reduction in the APF’s gilt holdings through QT and the redemption of TFSME could lead the level of reserves to approach the estimated range for the BoE’s steady-state balance sheet size as soon as 2025H2. Therefore, articulating a clear rationale for future QT plans will be important. In the context of implementing recommendations from the Bernanke review, consideration should be given to including, in any “alternative scenarios”, scenario-specific monetary policy paths generated by BoE staff, and adequate resources should be allocated to enhance and maintain the required modeling infrastructure.

50. Fiscal plans will need to take better account of pressing spending needs, while assuredly stabilizing debt—this will involve difficult choices. Staff’s analysis suggests that accommodating pressures in key public services and critical growth-enhancing investment needs, including for the green transition, will imply a non-stabilizing public debt to GDP ratio over the five-year projection horizon. Debt stabilization will require the primary balance to be, on average, around 0.8 ppt. GDP higher per year (relative to staff’s baseline) which, absent a major boost to potential growth, will necessitate some difficult tax and spending choices. Possible measures include, on the revenue side, raising additional revenue from higher carbon and road-usage taxation, broadening the VAT and inheritance tax bases, and reforming capital gains and property taxation; and, on the spending side, indexing the state pension (only) to increase the cost of living, and expanded/enhanced charging for public services, while taking care to protect the vulnerable.

51. There is scope to further improve the UK’s sophisticated fiscal framework. First, staff recommends strengthening the debt rule with the requirement that debt be falling by the fifth year with a high probability (e.g., 75 percent), to increase fiscal buffers against adverse shocks. Second, the credibility of fiscal plans should be enhanced by producing 4–5 year expenditure frameworks every two years, replacing the non-rolling 3-year spending reviews; requiring that an OBR forecast accompany each fiscal event; and extending the OBR’s forecast horizon for its Economic and Fiscal Outlooks to ten years to better capture longer-term spending pressures, as well as dividends from growth-enhancing measures, which will help provide a more complete picture of the sustainability of public finances. Third, staff recommends moving to one fiscal event per year to steady decision making and reduce political pressure points for fiscal loosening. Finally, there is scope to adjust the treatment of QE/QT profits and losses in future cycles with a view to protecting the BoE from political pressures.

52. Further ambitious reforms are needed to boost potential growth. The authorities have delivered several helpful measures over the last three budgets, e.g., investment tax reliefs for businesses to boost investment, an expansion of childcare, and active labor market policies, but they are unlikely to sufficiently lift the UK’s long-term potential growth towards pre-GFC levels. Additional ambitious reforms in (i) easing planning restrictions; (ii) upskilling the workforce; and (iii) improving health outcomes are needed, including building on past efforts. These reforms should ideally be nested within a stable, long-term growth strategy, backed by an independent growth commission. Such a body can take a longer-term view of reform priorities, better coordinate across different levels of government; and track and report on implementation, serving as a disciplining and communication device (akin to the Climate Change Committee). Moreover, the UK should continue its cautious approach to industrial policy, while maintaining its open trade orientation.

53. The UK authorities should stay the course on climate policy. The UK has halved emissions relative to 1990 levels, but current policies and spending allocations are insufficient to meet the 2030 target. It is important that the UK stays the course on climate policies to achieve the country’s ambitious emission reduction goals and continues to build on its successes. Key priorities are: (i) ensuring the needed level of investment for the green transition; (ii) enhancing incentives for conversion to electric vehicles and heat pumps, through the use of feebates; and (iii) strengthening the UK’s emission trading system and eliminating the shortfall of the UK carbon price below the EU price, while implementing the UK’s CBAM in a way that minimizes administrative burdens on importing firms.

54. Financial stability risks have been contained thus far, and continued strong supervision of all banks and NBFIs is warranted. Households and corporates have been resilient, supported by strong wage growth and enhanced regulatory measures. Other financial stability risks, for example, globally stretched valuations across asset classes (notably private equity), as well as spillovers from CRE stress in other jurisdictions warrant continued close monitoring. The capital and liquidity positions of major UK banks remain robust, but the diverse business models of smaller banks merit continued close monitoring, including through stringent stress tests. The BoE is taking important initiatives in the NBFI space, notably the system-wide exploratory scenario exercise and the design of a BoE backstop lending tool for non-banks. While data is adequate for surveillance, staff continues to emphasize the importance of maintaining both domestic and international momentum to close data gaps and reduce NBFI vulnerabilities.

55. Structural financial sector reforms should continue to progress cautiously. The Edinburgh reforms have, so far, proceeded carefully and have preserved the primacy of financial stability objectives. While supporting the government’s plan to reform the special resolution regime to minimize disruptions from small bank failures, staff encourage prefunding the FSCS to an appropriate level to avoid moral hazard. Moreover, caution is warranted around possible financial stability implications of the pension reforms, particularly given the context of ongoing DB pension fund buy-outs and potential concentration risk created in the insurance industry from these concurrent changes. In addition, staff encourages expanding auto-enrollment efforts and raising the minimum contribution to ensure adequate pensions for employees. Finally, the authorities should continue to strengthen the effectiveness of AML/CFT risk-based supervision.

56. It is recommended that the next Article IV consultation be held on the standard 12-month cycle.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

United Kingdom: Real Sector Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

United Kingdom: Labor Market Indicators

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

United Kingdom: External Sector Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure 8.
Figure 8.

United Kingdom: Fiscal Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure 9.
Figure 9.

United Kingdom: Residential Real Estate Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure 10.
Figure 10.

United Kingdom: Financial Sector

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Table 2.

United Kingdom: Selected Economic Indicators, 2019–29

(Percentage change, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Sources: Bank of England; IMF’s Information Notice System; HM Treasury; Office for National Statistics; and IMF staff calculations.

ILO unemolovment: based on Labor Force Survevdata.

Public sector net debt is defined as public sector gross debt minus liquid assets held by general government and non-financial public corporations. It excludes operations from Bank of England. The fiscal year begins in April. Debt stock reported in this table has been transformed into calendaryear by using end-of-fiscal year information on debt and centered-GDP as a denominator.

Corresponds to fiscal year ending in 2019, 2020, etc.

Table 3.

United Kingdom: Medium-Term Scenario, 2019–29

(Percentage charge, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Sources: Office for National Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

Percentage change in quarterly real GDP in the fourth quarter on four quarters earlier.

Contribution to the growth of GDP.

In percent of GDP.

In percent of potential GDP.

In percent of labor force, period average; based on the Labor Force Survey.

Whole economy, per hour worked.

In percent of total household available resources.

Table 4.

United Kingdom: Statement of Public Sector Operations, 2019/20–2028/29 1/

article image
Sources; HM Treasury; Office for National Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.

1/ Fiscal year ends March 30.

2/ On a Maastricht treaty basis. Includes temporary effects of financial sector intervention. 3/ End of fiscal year using centered-GDP as the denominator.
Table 5.

United Kingdom: Balance of Payments, 2019–29

article image
Sources: Office for National Statistics; and IMF staff estimates, Note: a negative sign on the financial account indicates financial inflows.
Table 6.

United Kingdom: Net Investment Position, 2019–29

(Percent of GDP)

article image
Source: Office for National Statistics.
Table 7.

United Kingdom: Monetary Survey, 2016–23

article image
Source: Bank of England. 1/ M4 includes the private sector’s holdings of sterling notes and coins; sterling deposits, including certificates of deposits; commercial paper, bonds, floating rate notes, and other instruments of up to and including 5 years’ original maturity issued by UK monetary financial institutions; claims on UK MFIs arising from repos; estimated holdings of sterling bank bills; and 95% of the domestic sterling interbank difference (the remaining 5% being allocated to transits). 2/ Computed as the ratio of the change in the stock divided by last period’s stock and therefore includes valuation changes.
Table 8.

United Kingdom: Financial Soundness Indicators, 2016–23

article image
Source: IMF FSI database.
Table 9.

United Kingdom: Anti-Corruption Efforts (Authorities’ Self-Assessment)

article image
article image

Annex I. Preliminary External Sector Assessment

article image

Official NIIP data do not record FDI assets and liabilities at market value. The Bank of England’s December 2022 Financial Stability Report estimates that if the UK’s FDI assets and liabilities were also marked-to-market, then the UK’s NIIP would rise from negative territory to close to +100 percent of GDP.

Estimates in Allen and others (2023) suggest that, in 2020, about 93 percent of external assets were denominated in foreign currency compared with 53 percent for external liabilities.

These measurement issues arise primarily because of differences between the statistical definition of income and the relevant economic concept. Both would lead to NIIP valuation changes but are not recorded in the income balance.

Annex II. External Debt Sustainability Analysis

The external debt sustainability analysis complements the External Sector Assessment (Annex I). Under the baseline scenario, gross external debt is projected to decline from 282 percent in 2023 to about 271 percent over the medium term. In historical scenarios, including the pandemic, external debt would increase significantly. In addition, with more than ¼ of external debt denominated in foreign currency, a real depreciation would also lead to a sizable increase in external debt. Still, a net asset position in foreign currency suggests that external debt is sustainable. Structural reforms to increase productivity and preservation of the strong frameworks (for monetary, fiscal, and financial sector policies) would help contain external vulnerabilities as the country continues to adjust to the post-Brexit trade and immigration regime.

1. Background. External debt peaked at 336 percent of GDP in 2020, mainly due to denominator effects as the pandemic depressed nominal GDP. In the period from 2013–19, external debt had averaged around 300 percent of GDP. About half of external debt comprises short-term bank liabilities of the private sector, while public external debt accounts for a tenth.1 Despite the sizable external debt, the net international investment position has been at an average of about -10 percent of GDP since 2000, as positive valuation gains have tended to largely offset current account deficits.

2. Assessment. In the baseline, external debt is projected to gradually decline to 271 percent of GDP by 2029, on the back of the baselined economic recovery and improving non-interest current account. The historical scenario has a significant impact, with debt climbing to 306 percent of GDP by the end of the forecast horizon. This scenario is based on an average of the past ten years (from 2014–23), including a significant pandemic-induced growth shock and a sizeable pound depreciation. Similarly, in the growth shock scenario, one of the standardized shocks (calibrated to ½ standard deviation for interest rates, growth, and the current account), external debt would rise to 306 percent of GDP. A depreciation shock has the largest impact, leaving external debt somewhat higher at 315 percent of GDP. Yet, gross debt assets at about 257 percent of GDP and a net assets position in foreign currency would offer some insurance against such shock. Although external debt is sustainable in the baseline, the large liability positions at twice the value of GDP make the UK sensitive to market sentiment. Upholding robust policy frameworks and implementing appropriate structural reforms would be vital to preserving sustainability going forward.

Table 11.1.

UK: External Debt Sustainability Framework, 2019–2029

(In percent of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
1/ Derived as [r – g – r(1 + g] + ea(1 + r]]/(1 + g+r+gr] times previous period debt stock, with r = nominal effective interest rate on external debt; r = changein domestic GDP deflator in US dollar terms, g = real GDP growth rate, e = nominal appreciation (increase in dollar value of domestic currency], and a = share of domestic-currency denominated debt in total external debt. 2/ The contribution from price and exchange rate changes is defined as [-r(1 + g] + ea(1 + r]]/(1 + g+r+gr] times previous period debt stock, r increases with an appreciating domestic currency (e > 0] and rising inflation (based on GDP deflator). 3/ For projection, line includes the impact of price and exchange rate changes. 4/ Defined as current account deficit; plus amortization on medium- and long-term debt; plus short-term debt at end of previous period. 5/ The key variables include real GDP growth; nominal interest rate; dollar deflator growth; and both non-interest current account and non-debt inflows in percent of GDP. 6/ Long-run, constant balance that stabilizes the debt ratio assuming that key variables (real GDP growth, nominal interest rate, dollar deflator growth, and non-debt inflows in percent of GDP] remain at their levels of the last projection year.
Figure II.1.
Figure II.1.

United Kingdom: External Debt Sustainability—Bound Tests 1/ 2/

(External debt in percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: International Monetary Fund, Country desk data, and staff estimation.1/ Shaded areas represent actual data, individual shocks are permanent one-heft standard derision shade figures in the boxes boxes represent average projections for the respective variables in the baseline and scenario being presented. Ten-year historical average for the variable also shown. The average maturity of long-term external debt is assumed to equal 7 years.2/ For historical scenarios., the historical averages are calculated over the ten-year period, and the information is used to project debt dynamics five year ahead.3/ Permanent 1/4 standard deviation shocks applied to real interest rate, growth rate, and current account balance.4/ One-time real depredation of 30 percent occurs in 2.021.

Annex III. Growth Accounting and Potential Growth

Past Evolution of Drivers of Supply

1. Growth accounting can be used to decompose UK output into contribution from multi-factor productivity (MFP), labor, and capital inputs and shed light on expected potential growth. The growth accounting used here follows standard neoclassical framework where changes in the volume of inputs (capital, and quality-adjusted labor) are weighted by the output elasticities of labor (a) and capital (1-a) and an unobserved residual, which captures MFP.1 This allows us to quantify how different assumptions about the evolution of the various components over time will translate into potential growth.

uA001fig30

Contribution to GVA Growth

(Market sector, 5-year rolling average, percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: ONS.

2. A key observation from the growth accounting exercise for the UK (chart above) is the significant decline in MFP growth and capital growth (or investment). The former is captured by the red bars which noticeably shrink from about 2 percent in the pre-GFC period to 1¼ percent in the period after. The weakness in investment (blue bars) is more evident when compared with the 1990s (when it averaged around ½ percent); since the mid-2000s, it has averaged around ½ percent, and fell to virtually zero in the immediate post-GFC period, and the Brexit vote. The decline in MFP growth and investment has been partially offset by a rise in hours worked (notably during the 2012–19 period), but this too has fallen off in recent years.

3. The decline in MFP growth and investment have meant exceptionally weak growth in labor productivity (i.e., output per hour), when seen in a cross-country context.2 During the two decades before the GFC, output per hour in the UK increased at around 2 percent (1996–2007 average), close to the pace witnessed in the United States, with the Euro Area increasing only at around 1¼ percent. While labor productivity growth has declined in all advanced economies since the GFC, the UK has performed worse that the others. The pace of growth in the UK has slowed down to a mere 0.4 percent (2008–2022 average), compared with 1.2 percent in the United States and 0.7 percent for the Euro Area. While the average pre-GFC labor productivity growth in the Euro Area was only around 60 percent of the UK’s pace, the situation reversed post-GFC, with the pace of growth in the UK now only 60 percent of the growth seen in the Euro Area. Fortunately, as noted in earlier, the UK has been more successful at maintaining the pace of growth in total hours worked, and more broadly the size of its economically active population, unlike in the Euro Area where it declined significantly post-GFC. This allowed the UK to partially offset the larger productivity decline and maintain overall economic growth. These trends in labor productivity and supply are elaborated further in Annex IV.

Figure III.1.
Figure III.1.

United Kingdom: Headline Productivity Trends

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Estimating Potential Growth

4. The growth accounting framework can be used to estimate potential output and its drivers based on bottom-up assumptions. Growth can be broken down into labor productivity growth and labor supply growth (hours worked), and these can be further broken down into subcomponents.

ΔlnGVA=Δln(GVAHW)+ΔlnHW=(1α)Δln(VICSHW)+ΔlnMFP+αΔlnLQLabor Productivity Growth+Δln(PopxLFPxAverageHours)Labor Supply Growth

5. Labor productivity growth over the medium term is expected to around be around 1 percent, gradually picking up from its current low level as the economy normalizes and investment picks up. This incorporates the impact of growth measures already announced and in train, such the full tax-expensing of business investment (that was made permanent in the 2023 Autumn Statement). It is also underpinned by staff’s somewhat higher path (than the OBR’s) for public investments (in infrastructure and the green transition). Bolder reforms (esp. in the areas of planning and skills), faster implementation, better service delivery (e.g., in health and education which affect the quality of labor) or larger investment envelopes would present an upside risk for both labor productivity and potential output. Given these conditioning assumptions, here are our projections for the underlying components of labor productivity, based on past, current and expected trends, and staff and comparators (BoE, OBR and private sector analysts) assessment of drivers behind these trends.

  • MFP growth is expected to contribute 0.3 percentage points, but there is high degree of uncertainty around this assumption. This represents a pickup from current levels and is higher than the “post-GFC pre-pandemic (2013–19) average of 0.2 percentage points but is significantly below the 1.8 percentage points in the decade before the GFC (1998–2007) and the 0.9 percentage point long term average (1975–2022) given the pre-GFC engines of growth are unlikely to be repeated (North Sea oil, financial services, and the information technology boom). That said, AI adoption could provide a new source of MFP growth, akin to the IT boom in the 1990s, and present an upside risk, though there is high uncertainty about potential impact on productivity (see Acemoglu (2024); Box 3.3 of April 2024 WEO).

  • Capital deepening is expected to contribute 0.4 percentage points to potential output in the medium term, with a gradual pickup as Brexit related headwinds on investment abate and the benefits of a favorable tax regime are realized. However, higher depreciation rates due to an increasing share of shorter-lived IT and intangible capital, and prolonged underinvestment since the GFC, that has resulted in a falling capital-output ratio and an ageing and degraded capital stock, limit the scope for a more significant contribution of capital services to growth. Lingering uncertainty regarding post-Brexit trading arrangements, reduced participation in the global value chain, as well as potential geo-economic fragmentation could be hindrances to investment.

  • Labor composition accounts for 0.3 percentage points, driven by a post-Brexit skill-selective migration regime that favors higher skilled workers, and a continuing improvement in the share of graduates and higher skilled workers in the labor force, assisted by favorable reforms to the education and skills sector.

6. Labor supply is estimated to grow at 0.3 percentage points over the longer term. This is primarily driven by ONS population projections, with offsetting effects from aging (participation and average hours worked) and policies to incentivize work. While the focus is on the longer term, population growth is expected to be temporarily higher for the next few years (until 2027) due to strong migration inflows. But its effects on labor supply, and therefore potential growth, are tempered by continued challenges with long-term illness dampening activity rates.

  • Population growth assumption is primarily driven by ONS 2021-based population projections for the working age population (16–64 years) of 0.28 percent (2028–2037 average). However, the total 16 and over population grows at a faster rate of 0.58 percent given the effects of population ageing. Since some people over the state pension age, which is expected to rise over time, continue to work, our overall labor supply assumption assumes a growth rate of 0.5 percent in the long term. But given strong migration seen in 2023, and which is expected to continue over the next couple of years, the contribution of labor supply to potential growth is higher until 2027.

  • Labor force participation is assumed to remain largely unchanged over the long term, given already high activity levels in the UK compared to peers, except for the impact due to an ageing population (increase in share of workers who typically have lower activity rates). Although rising inactivity due to long term illness is a challenge in the short run, decreasing potential labor supply by as much as 0.1 percentage point, particularly in the near term.

  • Hours worked are again to be driven by adverse demographics (older workers put in less hours) being offset by policy actions (including cuts to the NIC rate) to boost supply. Overall, the impact on hours worked is expected to decrease labor supply by 0.1 percentage point, with an even larger negative impact expected in the long term as population ageing accelerates.

7. In line with the above, long-term potential output growth for the UK is estimated at 1.3 percent. This represents a slight markdown from 1.5 percent assumed in recent Article IV consultations and is primarily driven by reassessment of labor productivity growth due to weaker MFP and capital deepening assumptions. However, given strong migration, potential growth is likely to be higher (closer to 1.5 percent) over the next few years.3 The new path for potential growth is lower than the OBR’s assumptions, particularly in 2028 and beyond, given lower labor productivity and labor supply growth assumptions. The estimates are however stronger than private sector estimates which range from 1 to 1.3 percent and the BoE’s supply side stock-take in February, although those do not reflect latest ONS population projections. Staff’s estimate is also in line with the Euro Area (1.2 percent) and other large European economies (Germany 0.7 percent, France 1.3 percent, Italy 0.8 percent and Spain 1.6 percent), but lower than Australia (2.3 percent), Canada (1.7 percent), and the US (2.1 percent).

Table III.1.

United Kingdom: Potential Growth

article image

The ONS’s updated population projections were not reflected in the MPC’s February supply-side stock take. BoEs May MPR projections are conditioned on the most recent ONS population projections with gives an average supply growth of 1½ percent over the next three years.

Annex IV. Drivers of Labor Productivity and Supply in UK

1. Some of the strong performance in UK Total or Multi-Factor Productivity (MFP) in the pre-GFC period was driven by unique factors. First, the faster growth in manufacturing, while in part due to rising import competition and offshoring, was also a result of expanding North Sea oil production in the mid-2000s. Second, the pre-GFC period witnessed a large expansion in financial services, driven by “leverage”, which was unsustainable and the post-GFC decline represents deleveraging and the long process of normalization. And third, MFP for information and communication was elevated during the tech-boom of the early 2000s. Nevertheless, MFP growth in the UK has remained weak over the past decade, in part due to declining firm dynamism, and while this is true globally, the UK still stands out from its counterparts.

Figure IV.1.
Figure IV.1.

United Kingdom: Drivers of Labor Productivity and MFP

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

2. The post-GFC decline in MFP has been accompanied by weak business and public investment. Capital accumulation in the UK was robust in the years preceding the GFC, but the rate almost halved in 2008–2010, and has since struggled, with the capital stock growing slower than hours worked. Business investment has remained subdued until recently, in part due to headwinds and higher uncertainty since the Brexit referendum in 2016, with the pandemic adding to the drag. And given a more austere fiscal environment, public investment has not picked up the slack (see 2023 SIP for a detailed discussion of drivers of weak investment and policy options).

uA001fig31

Gross Fixed Capital Formation

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: WEO.

3. The UK labor force has grown faster than in peers, but recent trends suggest this may be at its end. Some of the historical growth in hours worked reflects strong gains via higher participation rate among women and older workers, and also high rates of worker migration, particularly from Central and Eastern Europe. Furthermore, the labor force has moved towards higher skill on average, with a higher share of workers with an advanced degree, contributing to labor composition gains. However, the growth in labor supply seen during the 2010s has now plateaued, with increasing inactivity level due to an increase in long-term sickness (see 2023 SIP). While a pickup in migration in the short term should support growth, longer term, population ageing, an increasing dependency ratio, and shifts in the age structure towards age groups who work shorter hours on average, is likely to be a drag on labor supply.

Figure IV.2.
Figure IV.2.

United Kingdom: Labor Market Trends

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Annex V. Risk Assessment Matrix1

article image
article image
article image

Annex VI. Response Rate of the UK’s Labor Force Survey1

1. While the quality of surveys depends on many factors, this note focuses on the “response rate”, which was identified as the main problem in discussions on the UK Labor Force Survey (LFS) over the last years. The response rates for surveys are affected by many different elements in the collection method and survey design. For example, mandatory versus voluntary participation, sample design, fieldwork, length of interviews, incentives to respond, response burdens, as well as public communications and sentiments all affect response rates. The data collection method came to the center of attention when the pandemic required a shift to more remote data collection. Beyond the response rates, sampling variability also affect survey quality.2

uA001fig32

Response Rate

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: ONS, and IMF Staff estimates.

2. The long-term downward trend in the response rate for the UK’s LFS accelerated significantly during the pandemic. The declining trend has been a problem since the 1990s,3 but the deterioration accelerated when face-to-face data collection was suspended during the pandemic (Figure 1). In October 2023, with the response rate at a historical low of 12.7 percent,4 the Office for National Statistics (ONS) took the unprecedented step to suspend the publication of official labor market statistics derived from the LFS due to quality concerns. In response, the ONS has been implementing a recovery plan5 for the LFS to boost the number of respondents, which has shown some impact on the response rate. Since publication of LFS data resumed in February 2024, the ONS has transparently disclosed that LFS data should be treated as “official statistics in development6” until further review and accreditation. While falling response rates have also been an issue in other countries, the drop has not been as persistent and steep as in the UK (Box 1).

uA001fig33

Revisions in Labor Data

(Percentage point)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Note Revisions defined as the difference between first and latest estimate of the labor daia. which are affected by several factors other than higher sampling variability due to low response rate.Source” ONS and IMF staff estimates

3. An alarmingly low response rate could make labor market data unreliable as data becomes more susceptible to higher uncertainty7 (more volatile) and subject to self-selection bias8 (less accurate). As the LFS and LFS data undergo changes, including the regular reweighting exercise to incorporate the latest estimates of the size and composition of the UK population, there is likely more data revisions taking place (Figure 2). These issues pose challenges for macro-critical analyses that are reliant on LFS data, such as gauging inflationary pressures to inform monetary policy decisions, warranting additional caution due to heightened concerns about data quality.

4. The introduction of a new LFS is under way. This significant action reinforces earlier efforts to improve the declining long-term trend of the response rate such as enhancing the quality of interviews, better and more fieldwork resources, and offering monetary incentives. ONS took measures to mitigate the impact of low response rates on data quality, including regular monitoring of biases and reweighting LFS data to reduce biases when the sample becomes unrepresentative. The ONS also recommends supplementing LFS data by using other data sources such as the Pay As You Earn Real Time Information (PAYE RTI). The ONS decided to replace the LFS with the Transformed LFS (TLFS) which has been in development since before the pandemic and run in parallel with the LFS since 2023. The improvements include a larger sample size and the use of additional collection methods to cover online data collection. The TLFS is expected to replace the LFS in September 2024, subject to quality criteria being met.

5. While the TLFS has the potential to address the shortcomings of the LFS over the medium term, we would recommend the following points for ONS’s consideration:

  • Launching the new TFLS is a major modernization step and requires more dedicated resources to prevent further delays experienced since 2023.

  • Offer transparent and timely communication9 when managing the rising scrutiny of users and reviewers as the LFS undergoes major changes and face heightened quality concerns.

  • Independent reviews10 have recommended making the LFS participation mandatory to improve the UK’s long-run response rate, which require a change in the legislation. Although not directly comparable, the average response rate in countries with compulsory participation exceeded the average with voluntary participation. In some cases, a voluntary survey can achieve a higher response rate by incurring a higher cost.

United Kingdom: LFS in Selected Countries

A cross-country comparison among other advanced economies in Europe and North America, which publish comprehensive information about the quality of the LFS, adds perspective to the challenges of UK’s LFS, even though LFS response rates have methodological differences in the definitions.

While the US, Canada, Ireland, Netherlands, and Sweden faced a substantial drop in LFS response rates between 2013 and 2019 (just before the pandemic), none started as low as the UK in 2013 and none has dropped as low in 2019.

Comparing 2019 and 2020, the impact of the pandemic showed a wide variety of experience across countries. Germany was particularly hard hit with the response rate dropping from 98 percent to just over 50 percent, which could be related to the low share of remote collection. Meanwhile, countries with a high share of remote collection experienced a limited drop in the response rate during the pandemic (Netherlands, Sweden, Italy, and Spain).

A simple estimate between 2013 and 2023 showed that the response rate for voluntary and compulsory participation averaged close to 60 percent and 80 percent, respectively, indicating that mandatory participation may have a positive effect on participation rates.

article image
Note: For the US, the response rate is taken from the current population survey (CPS), the primary source of labor statistics. Remote data collection refers to online, telephone and post. Sources: ONS, US Bureau Labor Statistics, Statistics Canada, Statistics Sweden, Eurostat, and IMF staff estimates.

Annex VII. Fiscal Implications of Post-Pandemic Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Bank of England1

1. It is well understood that conventional monetary easing has a favorable impact on the fiscal position. This is because easier monetary conditions reduce debt servicing costs, boost aggregate demand, and increase tax revenues. In contrast, fiscal implications of large-scale asset purchases (LSAP) are less clear as they may adversely affect central bank profits. This can be particularly true if the monetary authority ends up normalizing policy earlier than expected when launching LSAP.

2. These considerations are highly relevant for countries like the United Kingdom, which relied heavily on LSAPs to mitigate adverse macroeconomic effects of the Covid-19 pandemic. The monetary easing by the BOE involved keeping the policy rate at close to zero and purchases of assets worth around 17.5 percent of annual GDP, which came on top of post-GFC purchases cumulatively worth around 20 percent of annual GDP. Global supply chain disruptions and spike in energy prices due to Russia’s invasion of Ukraine called for faster monetary normalization, with the policy rate quickly rising and eventually exceeding 5 percent.

3. To assess the fiscal effects of post-pandemic LSAP by the BOE, we use a two-country New Keynesian model with bond market segmentation.2 The model is augmented to include a rich account of fiscal policy and government debt dynamics, and is calibrated to reflect the key features, initial conditions, and recent developments in the UK economy. We start with the interest rate at the ELB and use a large, negative demand shock to simulate a severe fall in global economic activity, which keeps the interest rate low for a prolonged period. We subsequently use the model to assess macroeconomic developments depending on whether the BOE undertook extra LSAPs or not.

4. By lowering long-term rates, LSAPs helped mitigate the contraction in economic activity and deflationary pressures, and created room for a slightly earlier policy lift-off (see Figure 1). Had the economic recovery proceeded as forecasted at the time of the additional LSAP, its impact on the fiscal stance would have been clearly favorable, implying a reduction in government debt of around 2 percent of annual GDP at the 8-year horizon. This positive fiscal outcome is mainly due to increased tax revenues and lower debt service costs, which more than offset the effect of lower central bank profits that cumulate to around 4 percent of annual GDP.

5. However, LSAPs make the central bank balance sheet more vulnerable to earlier policy normalization. Indeed, this risk materialized as the BOE policy rate needed to be increased much earlier and more drastically than projected at the onset of the Covid-19 crisis. We simulate this scenario in the model by assuming that, about 1.5 years after the LSAPs, positive demand and negative supply shocks trigger a faster global recovery. These shocks are aimed to capture the post-pandemic recovery and sharp increase in energy prices, both contributing to a sharp rise in inflation.

6. In this scenario with earlier monetary tightening, the cumulative decrease in central bank profits due to LSAPs amounted to about 6 percent of annual GDP (see Figure 2). In consequence, ex post fiscal gains from LSAPs were significantly reduced. Even so, according to our simulations, the overall impact of these pandemic interventions on the medium-run level of public debt was still likely to remain favorable, though small.

7. Overall, the last wave of LSAP by the BOE had favorable effects on the fiscal stance, even if we take into account the earlier than expected monetary policy normalization. These outcomes can be contrasted with the consequences of a fiscal stimulus which, if used to provide a similar boost to economic activity, would clearly increase the medium-run level of government debt, at least for realistic values of fiscal multipliers.

Figure VII.1.
Figure VII.1.

United Kingdom: Covid-19 Recession With and Without LSAP

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: IMF staff calculations.
Figure VII.2.
Figure VII.2.

United Kingdom: Covid-19 Recession With Earlier Policy Tightening

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: IMF staff calculations.

Annex VIII. Bernanke Review of BoE Forecasting & Communications

The Bernanke Review made 12 recommendations on improving forecasting infrastructure, publishing alternative scenarios, and retiring the inflation fan chart, but he stopped short of formally recommending that the MPC publish its own policy rate path (although he did float this as a possibility). The BoE stated it is “committed to action” on each recommendation but indicated it would take time to develop and implement responses, with an update on proposed changes to be published by year-end.

1. The Review found that the BoE’s forecasting performance has worsened in recent years, but is no worse than for other central banks and other UK forecasters. Bernanke pointed out significant shortcomings in the BoE’s official central forecasting model, COMPASS: e.g., it does not include much modeling of the financial sector, the monetary transmission mechanism, or energy prices, and it has been subject to “a variety of makeshift fixes.” Hence, the model itself plays a much-diminished role in the forecast process. He also pointed out that this model and similar models have failed to capture wage and price persistence in recent years.

2. Bernanke pointed out that, compared with other central banks, the BoE heavily relies on its central forecast as a communication device, but this central forecast may not fully reflect MPC’s view of the economy. This is because the central forecast is conditioned on a set of standard assumptions, which “may not always accurately represent the views of the MPC.” In addition, he described the BoE’s inflation fan charts as having “weak conceptual foundations” and conveying “little useful information” to the general public.

3. Against this backdrop, Bernanke made 12 recommendations, covering three main areas:

  • Investing in forecasting infrastructure and human resources to improve and maintain a high-quality forecasting framework (recommendations 1 to 4);

  • Enhancing the support to MPC’s decision-making by providing alternative scenarios, highlighting significant forecast errors, and incentivizing qualified staff to improve forecast quality (recommendations 5 to 7); and

  • Better utilizing the forecast to communicate MPC’s outlook and policy rationale by clarifying MPC’s views around the conditioning assumptions, dropping the fan charts, and deemphasizing the central forecast (recommendations 8 to 11). [The last recommendation discusses the order of reforms and stresses that improving forecasting infrastructure should be prioritized.]

4. Contrary to staff’s expectation, Bernanke did not push for producing an in-house interest rate path, which he said would be “a more aggressive approach” to tackling the problem of publishing a central forecast based on what can be unrealistic assumptions and left it open to the Bank, saying it would be a matter for “future deliberations.” Bernanke told reporters that if the Bank decided to publish in-house rate projections, it should “not be the Fed dot plots” but something akin to the collective rate path used by the Riksbank and others.

BoE Response:

In its response to the Review, the BoE committed to taking action on all recommendations, noting that “it will take some time to develop detailed plans as well as to manage their implementation.” In particular, the Bank said that scenarios could better describe the risks around the forecast and illustrate differences of opinion between Committee members but suggested that internal processes would need to adapt to ensure that these worked effectively. So, no immediate decisions are expected.

Annex IX. Staff Policy Advice from the 2023 Article IV Consultation1

article image
article image

Annex X. Sovereign Risk and Debt Sustainability Analysis1

Under the baseline scenario, the primary fiscal deficit declines to 0.5 percent of GDP by FY2029/30 on the back of a gradual fiscal consolidation (including a revenue boost from inflation-induced fiscal drag, and some spending restraint). General government gross debt nonetheless increases each year over the medium term to 108 percent of GDP in FY2029/30 (well-above pre-crisis projections), mainly reflecting less favorable automatic debt dynamics, due to higher interest rates and lower growth, as well as net losses related to quantitative tightening. Gross financing needs (GFNs) average 12 percent of GDP over FY2024/25–FY2029/30 (compared to pre-pandemic levels of around 10 percent), consistent with the higher debt levels and debt interest costs. Moderate risk from debt non-stabilization and high gross financing needs are mitigated by the UK’s long maturity of GG debt, lack of foreign currency debt and substantial market absorption capacity for gilts (once NBFI demand is accounted for) aided by the UK’s large institutional investor base and the sterling’s status as a global reserve currency.

1. Background. The UK economy experienced a mild technical recession in 2023, but has rebounded in 2024 Q1, while CPI inflation has fallen faster than expected, from double digits in 2022 to 2.3 percent in April 2024. Interest rates remain well-above pre-pandemic levels. Meanwhile, the medium-term fiscal consolidation plan set out in the Autumn Statement of November 2022 has been broadly followed, with the overall fiscal deficit declining by 1 ppt. between FY2021/22 and FY2023/24, as revenue increased due to tax increases (including a 6 ppt. increase in the corporate rate) and fiscal drag, while tight limits on spending have been maintained, and the interest bill has begun to decline in percent of GDP. The debt-to-GDP ratio declined by 8 ppts of GDP between the end of FY2020/21 and FY2023/24.

2. Baseline fiscal assumptions. Staff’s baseline is informed by the medium-term fiscal framework contained in Spring Budget 2024, overlayed with adjustments based on staff’s judgment, including that medium-term expenditure (notably discretionary recurrent and capital spending after FY2024/25) will be significantly higher than in the authorities’ plans, due to pressures on public services and critical investment needs (including for the green transition). The primary deficit is nonetheless projected to improve by 1½ ppts of GDP between FY2024/25 and FY2029/30, due to a combination of a ½ ppt of GDP boost to revenue from fiscal drag (reflecting frozen nominal personal income tax thresholds) and a 1 percentage point decline in expenditure as non-discretionary spending (including welfare) declines in percent of GDP as the economy recovers, outweighing faster-than-nominal GDP growth of discretionary recurrent and capital spending (Figure 4).2

3. Realism of baseline projections. Forecast errors point to some optimism in staff’s projections for medium-term primary balances and cyclical conditions, given substantial fiscal support measures and a large output gap during the pandemic that weighed on public finances (Figure 5). The projected medium-term fiscal adjustment and debt reduction paths are nonetheless within the normal historical range observed in peer countries.

4. Risks and mitigating factors. The Debt Fanchart and GFN Financeability modules both signal moderate risk (Figure 6). For the fanchart, this reflects high uncertainty (as indicated by the fanchart width), a high probability of debt non-stabilization but more moderate end-projection debt levels when adjusted for institutional quality. Moderate GFN Financeability risk reflects moderately high average GFNs under the baseline projections, which exceed 20 percent of GDP in a generalized stress scenario with increased deficits, inflation, lower growth, and a shortening of debt maturities. In this scenario, the needed (residual) absorption of government debt by domestic banks is further increased by limited rollover of external private financing and continued QT by the BoE. Nevertheless, it only cumulates to 18 percent of sterling-denominated bank assets by end-horizon, owing to the current very low level of government exposure of the banking sector (at about 2¾ percent of sterling-denominated assets). While combining the debt fanchart and GFN indices yields a moderate medium-term risk signal (Figure 1), there are several mitigating factors, including: a very long maturity of general government debt (of about 14 years on average) that smoothes GFNs and limits the pass-through from higher yields to effective interest rates; lack of foreign currency debt that mitigates FX risks; and substantial market absorption capacity for gilts aided by the UK’s large institutional investor base and the sterling’s status as a global reserve currency, which mitigate liquidity risks. Staff therefore assesses overall risks of sovereign stress to be low.

Figure X.1.
Figure X.1.

United Kingdom: Risk of Sovereign Stress

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: Fund staff.Note; The risk of sovereign stress is a broader concept than debt sustainability. Unsustainable debt can only be resolved through exceptional measures (such as debt restructuring), In contrast, a sovereign can face stress without its debt necessarily being unsustainable, and there can be various measures—that do not involve a debt restructuring—to remedy such a situation, such as fiscal adjustment and new financing.1/ The near-term assessment is not applicable in cases where there is a disbursing IMF arrangement. In surveillance-only cases or in cases with precautionary IMF arrangements, the near-term assessment is performed but not published.2/ A debt sustainability assessment is optional for surveillance-only cases and mandatory in cases where there is a Fund arrangement. The mechanical signal of the debt sustainability assessment is deleted before publication. In surveillance-only cases or cases with IMF arrangements with normal access, the qualifier indicating probability of sustainable debt (“with high probability” or “but not with high probability”) is deleted before publication.
Figure X.2.
Figure X.2.

United Kingdom: Debt Coverage and Disclosures

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure X.3.
Figure X.3.

United Kingdom: Public Debt Structure Indicators

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure X.4.
Figure X.4.

United Kingdom: Baseline Scenario 1/

(Percent of GDP unless indicated otherwise)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

1/ Data are presented in fiscal years, so that, e.g., 2023 corresponds to FY2023/24, ending in March 2024.
Figure X.5.
Figure X.5.

United Kingdom: Realism of Baseline Assumptions

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source : IMF Staff.1/ Projections made in the October and April WEO vintage.2/ Calculated as the percentile rank of the country’s output gap revisions (defined as the difference between real time/period ahead estimates3/ Data cover annual obervations from 1990 to 2019 for MAC advanced and emerging economies. Percent of sample on vertical axis.4/ The Laubach (2009) rule is a linear rule assuming bond spreads increase by about 4 bps in response to a 1 ppt increase in the projected debt-to-GDP ratio.
Figure X.6.
Figure X.6.

United Kingdom: Medium-Term Risk Analysis

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: IMF staff estimates and projections.1/ See Annex IV of IMF, 2022, Staff Guidance Note on the Sovereign Risk and Debt Sustainability Framework for details on index calculation.2/ The comparison group is advanced economies, non-commodity exporter, surveillance.3/ The signal is low risk if the DFI is below 1.13; high risk if the DFI is above 2.08; and otherwise, it is moderate risk.4/ The signal is low risk if the GFI is below 7.6; high risk if the DFI is above 17.9; and otherwise, it is moderate risk.5/ The signal is low risk if the GFI is below 0.26; high risk if the DFI is above 0.40; and otherwise, it is moderate risk.
Figure X.7.
Figure X.7.

United Kingdom: Long-Term Risk Analysis

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Figure X.8.
Figure X.8.

United Kingdom: Long-Term Risk Analysis

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Annex XI. International Experience with Growth Commissions

There is considerable experience among OECD economies of setting up growth and/or productivity commissions to advise governments on structural reforms (anchored in independent research) needed to power long-term growth. Autonomous commissions in Australia, New Zealand, Norway, and Denmark have had notable success in advancing policies that fostered innovation and productivity.

1. The history of productivity commissions stretches well back into the past century. Chile’s Economic Development Agency (CORFO) was founded in 1939; Danish Economic Councils have been active since 1962; the Australian Productivity Commission and Norway’s Productivity Commission were established in 1998; Mexico’s National Productivity Commission (CONAPO) was launched in 2008; and New Zealand’s Productivity Commission started in 2011 (ended 2024).

2. Autonomy and political influence have varied across these commissions. Although growth commissions only make recommendations and do not make policy decisions (which rest with the government), they do have varying degrees of influence on policy and decision-making, depending on the institutional setup. In Australia, New Zealand, and Norway, commissions have operated independently, drawing on expertise from academia and business to offer impartial policy advice. Similarly, Denmark’s Economic Councils and Mexico’s CONAPO conduct autonomous research and make policy recommendations, though they face some government oversight. In contrast, Chile’s CORFO operates under the Ministry of Economy, with government officials on its board.

3. The aforementioned commissions have been associated with some impressive growth-oriented reforms. Australia’s commission led to significant competition policy reforms, notably in telecommunications, reducing consumer prices. New Zealand’s commission influenced welfare and regulatory policies, fostering innovation and job creation. In Norway, the commission’s research supported sustainable development, making the country an environmental leader. Denmark’s Economic Councils shaped labor market policies and boosted industry-academia collaboration. Mexico’s CONAPO successfully pushed reforms in the telecommunications and energy sectors. These commissions also often regularly reported on reform implementation and outcomes, thereby serving as an effective disciplining device.

4. The experience above suggests that independent commissions can be helpful in advancing politically-contentious but economically-desirable reforms. Governments can have short horizons due to the electoral cycle, which means that reforms with long payback periods are often eschewed. Moreover, governments can find it difficult to push through politically-contentious reforms, e.g., reforms that have wide benefits for the economy, but are opposed strongly by particular constituencies. An independent commission can help in these situations by allowing the government to point to the commission’s evidence-based findings. The commission can also as a disciplining device to anchor implementation, an example of which already exists in the UK in the form of the Climate Change Committee.

Annex XII. FSAP Recommendations

article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image
article image

Annex XIII. Pension Reforms

The government has announced several reforms to direct pension assets toward domestic growth assets, intending to support domestic growth and improve pension outcomes. This analytical piece takes a holistic view of the UK’s pension system, assesses the scope for directing pension investment, and explores additional reform options to support the authorities’ objectives. Staff finds that, despite being relatively small in terms of total assets, defined contribution (DC) pension funds have greater scope to invest in UK equity provided appropriate investment vehicles are available. Moreover, increasing pension contributions (which remain low in the UK relative to peers) will boost pension income and increase pension funds’ assets for high-growth investment.

1. In the 2023 Autumn Statement, the government detailed significant pension reforms initially outlined in the chancellor’s July 2023 Mansion House address.1 The reforms are aimed at providing better outcomes for savers, fostering a more consolidated pensions market, and facilitating diversified investment portfolios of pension funds.2 Key initiatives include: (i) the proposal of a “pot for life” system and the merging of smaller pension pots; (ii) a critical evaluation of “master trust” DC pensions; (iii) exploration of alternatives to buyouts for defined benefit (DB) pensions along with a new approach to managing pension surpluses; (iv) pushing forward the consolidation of local government pension schemes; and (v) emphasizing the importance of cost-effectiveness in DC pensions as well as enhancing the expertise of pension trustees. Following these announcements, in the 2024 Spring Budget, the government announced further reforms as a strategic plan to boost British business and increase returns for savers. This includes requirements for DC pension funds to publicly disclose their level of investment in the UK. Alongside disclosure agreements, the government is introducing a new Value for Money framework to ensure that pension funds deliver good returns and are expected to encourage more investment into high-growth domestic companies. Moreover, the Mansion House compact encourages the largest DC pension funds to allocate at least 5 percent of their assets in unlisted equity by 2030, targeting innovative and potentially high-return domestic ventures.

2. The UK pension system is transitioning from a DB system to a DC system, but total assets are still dominated by DB pension funds. The UK pension fund sector is diversified and analyzing the overall size of the pensions market is difficult given there are different permutations that could be considered. Regulatory and demographic changes since the late 1990s have led many private DB pension funds to close to new members and switch to DC schemes. More recently, private sector DB scheme sponsors with schemes that are in surplus have pursued buy-outs with life insurers.3 Still, according to ONS data the bulk of pension assets are held by private sector DB and hybrid funds (about £1.1 trillion), while private sector DC and public sector DB funds amount to £0.7 trillion.4 Compared to major advanced economies, the UK pension fund assets are roughly similar in size when measured as a percentage of GDP, with pension fund assets amounting to roughly 95 percent of GDP at end-2022).5 The US had the largest pension assets at end-2022 ($35 trillion, 103 percent of GDP), while the Netherlands’ pension assets as a percentage of GDP ranked highest (roughly 180 percent of GDP, $1.8 trillion).

3. The total pension assets generally do not include public sector pensions for government employees, teachers, and health workers which are unfunded, and typically paid out of current government revenues. These unfunded pension schemes are similar to DB schemes, where pension payments are determined based on factors such as salary history, years of service, and age at retirement. The government’s reform proposals for these unfunded pension schemes mainly focused on structural and regulatory adjustments to ensure sustainability and fairness. Experts have suggested more ambitious reforms, such as shifting to an explicitly funded model, that could alleviate government spending pressures, provide additional resources for productive investment, and improve pension outcomes.

uA001fig34

Assets of Defined Benefit (DB) & Defined Contribution (DC) Pension Funds

(GBP billions)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: ONS.
uA001fig35

Pension Fund Assets

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: Financial Stability Board.

4. UK pension funds currently a larger proportion of their assets invested in bonds than in equities, reflecting DB pension funds’ shift in recent years from equity to fixed income. According to the OECD, UK pension funds invested 29 percent of assets in equity and 35 percent in bills and bonds in 2022, broadly comparable to the OECD averages. However, this reflects a shrinking equity exposure by DB pension funds, to overall equity but also UK equities in particular. Equity holdings of DB pension funds fell from 61 percent in 2006 to only 18 percent in 2023, with the share of UK equities declining from 30 percent to only 1 percent. Accordingly, DB pension funds have gone from being the dominant investors in UK equity, to now owning almost nothing. On the other hand, asset allocation to bonds grew from 29 percent in 2006 to just under 70 percent in 2022, broken down further into index-linked bonds (primarily consisting of government bonds and amounting to 30 percent), corporate bonds (25 percent), and other government bonds (13 percent).

5. The shift of DB pension funds out of equity was likely due to asset-liability matching rules and a change in risk preference. Some experts have pointed out that overall regulatory reforms have created an environment in UK pensions to actively reduce risk and discourage long-term investment. Asset-liability matching rules, combined with a discount rate based on the corporate bond yield, mean that pension funds need to match their assets with their liabilities by investing in long-dated debt. Experts also note that an aging pool of pension beneficiaries—even those not being paid – may want a lower risk tilt if they are close to retirement. Accordingly, DB pension funds have increased their asset allocation to fixed income, real estate, and sometimes illiquid alternative investments that are not exposed to the mark-to-market penalty of publicly traded equity.

uA001fig36

Equity Market Ownership

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics: IMF staff calculation.
uA001fig37

Pension Fund Asset Allocation – Selected Countries

(Percent of total assets)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: OECD
uA001fig38

Defined Benefit Pension Fund Asset Allocation

(Percent of total assets)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Sources: Purple Bock

6. DC pension funds in the meantime have a larger relative proportion of their assets invested in equity but still have much smaller total assets. Analysts estimate that around half of DC funds’ assets are invested in equity versus only 15 percent for private DB funds. Moreover, the flows into equity by DC funds (about £3.0 billion per quarter) are bigger than equity outflows from DB funds (£2.5 billion per quarter). Nevertheless, DC pension funds still hold much less equity because of relative size (DB pension funds are still much larger than DC funds by a factor of 7). That said, assets in DB funds are shrinking while those in DC funds are growing, and experts estimate that DC assets will be bigger by around 2032 by extrapolating the trends of the past four years.

7. While DC pension funds have better opportunities to invest in UK equity, the asset allocation of pension funds should not be mandated. Government proposals aimed at increasing pension fund allocation to domestic equity can appear logical on first glance.6 In addition, the requirement of pension funds to publicly disclose where they invest and the returns they offer could also play a role in increasing exposure to UK equities. Growing investment in UK equity could, in turn, deepen the capital market, encourage new companies to list, and attract further investment, thus creating a virtuous circle. Nevertheless, prescribing pension fund asset allocations should not hinder their ability to fulfill fiduciary responsibilities effectively and achieve the best possible outcomes for their beneficiaries. Similarly, the proposal to consolidate small pension funds is appropriate, but caution should be exercised regarding investment limits when consolidations are made. so as to avoid creating a forced sale of those any assets or unintended market volatility.

8. In addition, the minimum pension contribution (and participation rate) could be raised in the medium term to increase the available pension assets to invest in UK equity and retirement income. Estimates show that almost 40 percent of the working age population are under-saving for retirement, with the pension income of roughly 50 percent of the population projected to fall below the Pension and Lifetime Saving Association’s Moderate Retirement Living Standards. 7 Compared with other OECD countries, the minimum contribution rate of 8 percent is low. Moreover, the participation rate declined in 2022 for the first time since the introduction of automated enrollment in 2012. This is likely due to cost-of-living pressures from high inflation and interest rates and the fact that pension participation is voluntary. Staff recommends that consideration be given to increase the minimum contribution rate gradually in the medium-term, potentially via a relatively larger minimum contribution from employers,8 while taking into consideration the impact this could have on precautionary savings of especially the lower-income groups.

9. Experts also suggest more ambitious reforms, such as shifting public unfunded pension schemes to an explicitly funded model, to alleviate government spending pressures, provide additional resources for productive investment, and improve pension outcomes. Public pension funds for government employees, teachers, and health workers are unfunded, and typically paid out of current government revenues. This sector amounts to roughly the same size as private sector DB pension schemes, and are similar to DB schemes, in the sense that pension payments are determined based on factors such as salary history, years of service, and age at retirement. The government’s reform proposals for these unfunded pension schemes have mainly focused on structural and regulatory adjustments to ensure sustainability and fairness. Experts have suggested more ambitious reforms, such as shifting to an explicitly funded model, that could alleviate government spending pressures, provide additional resources for productive investment, and improve pension outcomes. In this regard, experts have suggested that Canada’s provision public service pension transition from unfunded schemes to a funded model, that started at the end of the 1980s, could serve as a potential example to follow.

10. Finally, the proposed pension reforms could have a non-trivial impact on gilt-market demand and financial stability, and these impacts should be carefully weighed in advance. Given the relative share of gilts held by pension funds and the buy-out of DB pension funds by insurers who have different investment preferences, together with reforms to encourage DC pension funds to increase their portfolio allocation to equities – staff recommends that authorities continue to closely monitor demand for gilts and any adverse market developments.

uA001fig39

Minimum or Mandatory Contribution Rates for an Average Earner in Mandatory and Auto-Enrolment Plans

(As percentage of earnings)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: OECD – Pensions at a Glance 2023.
uA001fig40

Change in the Participation Rate in Pension Plans Between 2021 and 2022, by Type of Plan and by Jurisdiction

(In percent of working age population)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2024, 203; 10.5089/9798400279379.002.A001

Source: OECD – Pension Markets in focus 2023.

United Kingdom: Autumn Statement Pension Reform 2023

The authorities have announced a package to improve pension savers’ returns and boost growth in the UK, progressing reforms set out at Mansion House.

“To provide better outcomes for savers, the Government is:

  • introducing the multiple default consolidator model for defined contribution (DC) schemes, to enable a small number of authorized schemes to act as a consolidator for eligible pension pots under £1,000;

  • launching a call for evidence for DC schemes on a lifetime provider model to simplify the pensions market by allowing individuals to move towards having one pension pot for life, and on a potential expanded role for Collective DC (CDC) schemes in future;

  • publishing an update that proposes placing duties on DC occupational pensions trustees to offer decumulation services and products at an appropriate quality and price when savers access their pension assets, either themselves or through a partnership arrangement.

To drive a more consolidated pensions market, the Government is:

  • welcoming the current trend of DC pension fund consolidation and expecting to see a market in which the vast majority of savers belong to schemes of £30 billion or larger by 2030;

  • welcoming the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) and the Pensions Regulator (TPR) announcements on next steps towards implementing the Value for Money framework in the DC workplace pensions market;

  • publishing a review of the Master Trusts market, 5 years after the 2018 Master Trusts regulations came into force;

  • consulting this winter on how the Pension Protection Fund can act as a consolidator for defined benefit (DB) schemes unattractive to commercial providers;

  • confirming a March 2025 deadline for the accelerated consolidation of Local Government Pension Scheme (England and Wales) assets, setting a direction towards fewer pools exceeding £50 billion Assets Under Management, and implementing a 10 percent allocation ambition for investments in private equity;

To enable pension funds to invest in a diverse portfolio, the Government is:

  • consulting this winter on whether changes to rules around when DB scheme surpluses can be repaid, including new mechanisms to protect members, could incentivize investment by well-funded schemes in assets with higher returns;

  • reducing the authorized surplus payments charge from 35 percent to 25 percent from April 6, 2024;

  • welcoming TPR’s announcement that they will implement a register of trustees and update the trustee toolkit;

  • engaging with industry on proposals to ensure all aspects of the pensions industry are supporting best outcomes for savers, including how to shift employer incentives away from low fees towards long-term pension investment performance;

  • committing £250 million to 2 successful bidders in the Long-term Investment for Technology and Science (LIFTS) initiative, subject to final agreement;

  • following positive feedback from industry, confirming its intention to establish a Growth Fund within the British Business Bank (BBB);

  • developing a fellowship course targeting mid-career science and technology Venture Capital (VC) investors, similar to the Kauffman Fellowship in the US, to be operational in 2024.”

The Authorities’ Consultations and Reviews:

Helping savers understand their pension choices: supporting individuals at the point of access (DWP)

Ending the proliferation of deferred small pension pots (DWP)

Looking to the future: greater member security and rebalancing risk (DWP)

Trends in the Defined Contribution trust-based pensions market (DWP)

Evolving the regulatory approach to Master Trusts (DWP)

Options for Defined Benefit schemes: a call for evidence (DWP)

Local Government Pension Scheme (England and Wales): Next steps on investments (Department for Levelling Up, Housing and Communities)

Pension trustee skills, capability and culture: a call for evidence (DWP, HMT)

Value for Money: A framework on metrics, standards, and disclosures (DWP, FCA, TPR)

Annex XIV. Data Issues

Table XIV.1.

United Kingdom: Data Adequacy Assessment for Surveillance

article image
Table XIV.2.

United Kingdom: Data Standards Initiatives

article image
Table XIV.3.

United Kingdom: Table of Common Indicators Required for Surveillance

As of June 13, 2024

article image

Annex XV. The Authorities’ Update on Edinburgh Reforms 1

article image
article image
article image
article image
1

The decision allows most EU trading entities to have clearing done outside of the EU once they have “active accounts” at EU-based clearing houses and, for large EU traders, to also clear a small number of their trades inside the EU.

2

New border controls on imports of animal and plant products from the EU, which had been postponed since 2021, are now kicking in and have led to complaints by importers about additional charges (phased implementation of inspections and declarations started in January 2024, with full implementation expected from October 2024).

3

The still large negative credit gap may be because the sample period includes the buoyant credit growth of the early 2000s.

4

See “Financial Policy Summary and Record – March 2024”. In addition, mortgage arrears reached a 7-year high in 2023Q4 (more than half were originated before 2008) but remain well below the GFC peak.

5

According to the March 24 UK Residential Market Survey, respondents anticipate house prices will return to growth over the next twelve months. All regions of the UK are expected to experience rising house prices, with particularly strong sentiment in Northern Ireland, London, and Scotland.

6

Tenant demand increased by 4 percent in 2024Q1, up from negative 7 percent at end-2023.

7

The final external sector assessment will be presented in the 2024 External Sector Report.

8

Staff’s projections include the growth impact of recent NIC rate cuts, while also accounting for Ricardian effects (expectations of future tax increases in light of significant public spending needs, and the imperative of stabilizing debt). The OBR and BoE both abstract from Ricardian effects, assessing that the NIC rate cut will boost labor supply by around 0.2–0.3 percent by 2029, mostly in the form of existing workers choosing to work longer hours.

9

Although real wages are now above their pre-pandemic level, their dismal growth in the post-GFC period (relative to other countries) could be a source of real wage pressure going forward. This said, unit labor costs in the UK have evolved broadly in line with peers since the GFC, implying that real wage growth has merely reflected very weak productivity growth. Moreover, there is a risk that the 10 percent increase National Living Wage in April slows the pace of wage moderation beyond the targeted group.

10

The real shadow rate is 245 bps using the 12-month ahead survey-based inflation expectations, which came out at 2.8 percent in May. Based on market-implied inflation expectations, the real shadow rate ranges from 205 bps (using 1-year ahead expectations) to 291 bps (using 5-year ahead expectations).

11

Reliable data on inactivity and unemployment are a pre-requisite for economic analysis and policymaking, underscoring the importance of ongoing efforts by the Office of National Statistics to improve the quality of its Labour Force Survey (see Annex VI).

12

At present a press conference is only held after the February, May, August, and November decisions accompanying a Monetary Policy Report publication.

13

The BoE’s survey of banks’ reserve demand indicates that the preferred minimum range of reserves (PMRR) lies in the range of £345 to £490 billion, similar to the BoE’s model-based estimates. The sum of LCR requirement based on the stock of sterling deposit liabilities amounts to £570 billion (as of Summer 2023).

14

Gilt holdings are longer-term and thus imply interest rate risk, while reverse repos raise the issue of encumbrance of collateral i.e., the use of assets serving as collateral in the repo transaction is restricted until the repo is repaid.

15

Importantly, the BoE, via PRA, is also the banking supervisor and insurance supervisor, and an erosion of BoE independence could compromise the delivery of these mandates.

16

The required adjustment also depends on a range of factors including the underlying growth assumptions and their impact on the budget. In the recommended scenarios, fiscal adjustment is estimated to reduce the level of real GDP by the end of the adjustment horizon by 1.7–2.1 ppts., relative to staff’s baseline; incorporating the effect of this on revenues and on the GDP denominator for the debt ratio, would raise the annual required effort by 0.2–0.4 ppts. of GDP. If potential growth could be increased, this would reduce the required fiscal effort.

17

Detailed options for capital gains tax reform are discussed by the Office for Tax Simplification (2020). VAT exemptions or reduced rates relating to fuel, transport services, water and sewerage could be eliminated, while taking care to compensate low-income households through the welfare system. On property tax reform see the Institute for Fiscal Studies (2020) for further details. There is a potential to use some of the revenue gains from property tax reform to reduce stamp duties. For inheritance tax reform options see Institute for Fiscal Studies (2023), while the UK Wealth Tax Commission discusses both one-off and recurring wealth taxes.

18

It is also time to take action to plan for the eventual loss of fuel duty revenue, once the transition to zero emission vehicles is completed, by implementing a road usage tax based on mileage, the administration of which may require some degree of electronic monitoring of vehicle use.

19

This approach is a variation of what the OBR already does. The OBR is required by the government to report if there is an even chance of the fiscal rules being met. In March 2024, the OBR assessed—based on a debt fanchart— that there was a 54 percent probability of debt falling in year 5 (this result obtains because the OBR uses the government’s unrealistically low spending projections after end-March 2025) (see paras 1.25–1.26 and paras 5.17 onward in the March 2024 Economic and Fiscal Outlook (https://obr.uk/efo/economic-and-fiscal-outlook-march-2024/#foreword). The change that would be needed to the fiscal rules is to raise the even chance to a high probability, like 75 percent or 95 percent.

20

Increasing house prices, in part due to planning restrictions discussed below, represent a transfer of wealth form the young (who need to buy) to the old (who typically own houses), often forcing young people to delay independent living. In the 1950s, 70 percent of UK residents owned house by age 34. This ratio has fallen to less than 34 percent today.

21

Spatial inequality has continued to increase in the UK. While income per head in London was around 22 percent higher in 1997 than the UK as a whole, this figure increased to 37 percent just before the GFC (2008) and reached 43 percent in 2021. In contrast, the figures for Northeast stood at 86 percent in 1997, falling to 81 percent by 2008 and remaining at that level in 2021.

22

Although UK female labor force participation is higher than in G7 peers (following significant improvements in the past decades), there is still room to raise participation to Scandinavian levels. See 2023 IMF selected issues paper for details.

23

People need to move to areas with greater job opportunities, typically cities. But strict land use regulation in countries like United States, Canada and the United Kingdom have made housing supply in cities less elastic, resulting in higher costs and hindering geographical mobility. See Sutherland 2020; Hsieh & Moretti (2019); Erdmann, Furth, Hamilton 2019; Stutts 2021; Rothwell & Massey 2015. Hilber & Vermeulen (2016) estimate that in the absence of regulatory constraints (i.e., refusal of proposed development by Local Planning Authorities), prices would have been 35 percent lower in the 2000s than they actually were.

24

Other recently announced measures include the launch of a consultation to see whether some cash payments (including, notably, the non-means-tested personal independence payment or PIP) to claimants with mental health conditions could be replaced by treatment or access to services. Other steps included: (i) shifting responsibility for issuing “fit notes” away from General Practitioners (GPs) to other “work and health professionals” (ii) plans to close benefit claims for anyone who has been claiming for 12 months but is not complying with conditions on accepting available work; and (iii) asking more people on universal credit working part-time to look for more work.

25

The Institute of Fiscal Studies estimates that health spending may need to rise by 2 percentage points of GDP by the FY2036/37 to fund the NHS Long-Term Workforce Plan, which seeks to avoid a labor shortfall of between 260,000–360,000 staff emerging by the mid-2030’s.

26

The Bank has recently announced some preferred design features (e.g., a contingent—rather than, standing— facility, which would limit its use to systemic liquidity events; and a prudent level of haircuts to protect BoE capital). Staff views a contingent facility would provide a powerful signal to market once it is triggered. While firms indicate a preference for a standing facility to ensure operational readiness, the Bank has indicated that challenges regarding operational readiness will be addressed via the onboarding process and a program of regular test trades.

27

There are two recommended changes: (i) a significant increase in the liquidity requirements for all MMFs; and (ii) the removal of the regulatory link between liquidity levels and the need for the manager to impose tools for certain types of MMFs (so-called’ stable NAV MMFs’, i.e., MMFs that can offer subscriptions and redemptions at a constant net asset value (NAV)).

28

Recent high interest rates have put pressure on private equity funds to raise investment, weighing down asset valuations. A sharp reduction in asset prices could reduce the value of collateral securing existing loans and increase the demand for liquidation at a discount. These could trigger losses for both NBFIs with direct exposures and also banks indirectly and tighten financial conditions. However, FPC highlighted that lack of transparency around asset valuations, leverage, and interconnectedness made assessing financial stability risks difficult.

1

The size of public external debt might be overestimated, given that some government bonds held by UK pension funds via liability-driven investment (LDI) asset managers domiciled outside the UK are recorded as external debt.

1

More formally, ONS calculates ΔlnGVA = αΔlnQALI + (1 – α)Δ In VICS + Δ In MFP, where GVA is the gross value added of the UK market sector, QALI is the labor input, which incorporates both the volume of labor (hours worked, HW) and its quality (labor composition, LQ), VICS measures volume of capital. With GVA, QALI and VICS given, MFP then obtains as the residual. α is the elasticity of output with respect to QALI, and varies over time, but averages around 0.6 percent over the entire sample.

2

The growth accounting framework can be rearranged to provide a decomposition of output per hour to measure labor productivity. Formally, Δln(GVAHW)=αΔlnLQ+(1α)Δln(VICSHW)+ΔlnMFP, where Δln(GVAHW) captures labor productivity growth, while Δln(VICSHW) measures changes in capital per hour worked (capital deepening).

3

The larger markdown in 2024 is because the previous figure already incorporated the effect of post-COVID normalization and stronger migration in 2023–2024 (and hence was larger than earlier the long-term average of 1.5 percent) but did not incorporate the negative surprise from still high and increasing inactivity levels due to long term illness.

1

The Risk Assessment Matrix (RAM) shows events that could materially alter the baseline path (the scenario most likely to materialize in the view of IMF staff). The relative likelihood is the staff’s subjective assessment of the risks surrounding the baseline (“low” is meant to indicate a probability below 10 percent, “medium” a probability between 10 and 30 percent, and “high” a probability between 30 and 50 percent). The RAM reflects staff views on the source of risks and overall level of concern as of the time of discussions with the authorities. Non-mutually exclusive risks may interact and materialize jointly.

1

Prepared by Kue-Peng Chuah.

2

See quality reports for the LFS by Eurostat and ONS, which cover a list of factors such as accuracy, timeliness, comparability, and coherence. Indicators used to measure accuracy include the response rate and size of sampling variability. The assessment here will focus on the response rate due to the significant deterioration.

3

See Barnes et al., “Making Sense of Labor Force Survey Response Rates”, Economic and Labor Market Review Vol. 2 No. 12, 2008 and the quality reviews such as National Statistics Quality Review: Review of LFS, 2014 and Quality of LFS Estimates Produced by the ONS, 2017.

4

Between July and September 2023, 14,180 households responded from a total of 111,281. Source: ONS website, article, LFS Quality Report: July to September 2023.

5

See progress and plans published by the ONS in Labor Market Transformation, April 2024 and improvements of the response rate between January and March 2024 in LFS Quality Report: January to March 2024.

6

See monthly reports from the ONS on Labor Market Overview.

7

A lower response rate in the survey can cause volatility in LFS data due to sampling variability, especially at granular breakdowns. See monthly data in Table A11 from the ONS on LFS Sampling Variability.

8

The LFS data can suffer from bias if LFS respondents have different characteristics from the non-respondents.

9

See recent examples in 2024 when the ONS was explaining LFS changes such as the TLFS and reweighting exercise.

1

Prepared by Marcin Kolasa, Jesper Linde and Pawel Zabczyk.

2

Erceg, C., Kolasa, M., Linde, J., and P. Zabczyk (2024). Central Bank Exit Strategies: Domestic Transmission and International Spillovers. IMF Working Paper 24/73.

1

The 2023 Article IV Consultation was concluded in July 2023.

1

The data are presented on fiscal year basis (April–March) with ratios calculated using fiscal year GDP (not centered-fiscal year GDP). For more information on the methodology, see IMF (2021), Review of the Debt Sustainability Framework for Market Access Countries, IMF Policy Paper 2021/003.

2

The primary deficit in 2024–26 is higher than projected in the 2023 Article IV, given less fiscal drag related revenue due to faster disinflation. In contrast, primary deficits are projected to be lower by the end of the five-year horizon than projected in the 2023 Article IV, given that the 2021 spending review limits restrain spending growth until 2025 and provide a low base for future growth.

2

These measures represent the next steps of the Chancellor’s Mansion House reforms and meet the three golden rules: to secure the best possible outcomes for pension savers; to prioritize a strong and diversified gilt market; and to strengthen the UK’s competitive position as a leading financial center. See https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/autumn-statement-pensions-reform-2023 for more info.

3

The buy-out process involves sponsors with the means exiting the DB pensions business by passing both their assets and liabilities to an insurer in a bulk annuity transfer, or ‘buy-out’.

4

As at Q3 2023. Separate data from the Pension Protector Fund, the local government pension scheme (LGPS) and TPR estimate DB fund assets of funds in the Pension Protection Fund (PPF) at £1.4 trillion as at March 2023, the market value of assets of the LGPS at £361 billion as at March 2022, and the market value the assets and the assets of occupational DC schemes at around £1.4 trillion in 2023. See The Purple book, 2023, LGPS and TPR, 2023.

5

Based on FSB data, NBFI monitoring dataset 2023.

6

Boost the ‘Mansion House compact’ in which big DC pension providers have committed to invest 5% of their assets in unlisted equities by 2030.

8

Of the 8 percent, the employers minimum contribution is set at 3% and the remainder made up by the staff’s contribution.

1

As of May 2024.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
United Kingdom: 2024 Article IV Consultation-Press Release; Staff Report; and Statement by the Executive Director for United Kingdom
Author:
International Monetary Fund. European Dept.