Euro Area Policies
Staff Report for the 2012 Article IV Consultation with Member Countries
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

The 2012 Article IV Consultation report on euro area policies highlights that investors are withholding funding from member states most in need, moving capital “north” and abroad to perceived safer assets. Executive Directors have noted that the euro area continues to face a number of economic challenges amid increasing financial stresses and market fragmentation. Directors have also stressed that it is important that policymakers continue to demonstrate shared and unequivocal commitment—with a clear, credible roadmap—to a deeper integration of the euro area.

Abstract

The 2012 Article IV Consultation report on euro area policies highlights that investors are withholding funding from member states most in need, moving capital “north” and abroad to perceived safer assets. Executive Directors have noted that the euro area continues to face a number of economic challenges amid increasing financial stresses and market fragmentation. Directors have also stressed that it is important that policymakers continue to demonstrate shared and unequivocal commitment—with a clear, credible roadmap—to a deeper integration of the euro area.

A Deepening Crisis

The euro area crisis has reached a new, critical level

1. Market tensions have increased further. Still-pressing banking problems and continuing sovereign funding concerns in some euro area countries have raised doubts about the viability of the monetary union itself. This has driven sovereign borrowing costs and risk premiums to very high levels in several countries, adding to the already-severe pressures on many bank and sovereign balance sheets in an environment of very low confidence and growth.

uA01fig01

Credit Default Swap Spreads

(basis points weighted by gross debt)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Bloomberg L.P.; IMF, World Economic outlook database; and IMF staff calculations
uA01fig02

Financing Needs and Sovereign Stress

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Bloomberg L.P.; and IMF staff calculations

2. The adverse bank-sovereign feedback loops at the heart of the crisis have intensified. Concerns about banks’ solvency have increased because of large sovereign exposures, particularly in periphery countries. Some sovereigns, in turn, are struggling to backstop weak banks on their own. Depositor confidence is increasingly fragile. As investors have moved capital “north” and abroad to perceived safer assets, official financing—including in the form of programs and ECB liquidity support—has become more important. This is largely mirrored in widening Target 2 balances between euro area national central banks.2

uA01fig03

Net Balance with the Eurosystem (Target 2)

(billion of euros)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: National Central Banks

3. And the single financial market has become increasingly fragmented. Despite low policy rates, credit conditions vary widely among euro area countries. This is mainly due to starkly diverging perceptions of sovereign and banking risks, as well as a drastic decline in interbank activity (as banks reduce cross-border funding, shore up capital and liquidity buffers in their home jurisdiction, and accumulate overnight deposits at the ECB). As a consequence, financing conditions are now the least supportive in countries where the crisis is the most acute.

uA01fig04

EONIA Volume and ECB Deposit Facility

(billions of euros)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: European Central Bank
uA01fig05

Monthly Interest Rates

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics; and European Central Bank

4. Against this backdrop, the real economy has been weak, reinforcing adverse bank-sovereign feedback loops. GDP was flat in the first quarter of 2012, after contracting at an annualized rate of almost 1 percent in the last quarter of 2011. Demand was depressed, particularly in the periphery countries (Figure 1). Tightening financing conditions and weak confidence held back private investment and consumption, and fiscal consolidation dampened demand further. Consequently, the euro area unemployment rate increased further, to over 11 percent in May, its highest level since the start of EMU. In turn, the weakness in real activity has added to budgetary pressures and the deterioration in banks’ loan portfolios.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Short-term Activity Indicators

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics; Markit; and Eurostat.

Weak Outlook with Substantial Risks

5. With the crisis deepening, the outlook remains for very low growth. After averaging 1.5 percent in 2011, euro area GDP growth is expected to be -0.3 and 0.7 percent in 2012 and 2013. A number of factors will weigh on the outlook:

  • Private domestic demand is expected to remain subdued as banks and households continue to repair balance sheets and consumers and investors act cautiously amidst heightened uncertainty. With many of these headwinds significantly stronger in the periphery, growth is expected to be much lower there than in the core. Germany and France are expected to post weak-but-positive growth in 2012.

  • Substantial and frontloaded fiscal consolidation will weigh on growth. In the aggregate, on current policies, the euro area structural deficit is projected to narrow by about 1½ percent of GDP in 2012, ½ percent of GDP in 2013, and an additional ½ percent of GDP over 2014-17. The pace of fiscal adjustment is particularly accelerated in the hard-hit periphery countries: the projected consolidation over this and next year ranges from around 3½ percentage points or more of GDP in Portugal, Greece, Italy, and Spain, compared with ½ percentage point or less in Germany, Austria, and Finland (see also Figure 3).

  • At the same time, the global outlook has deteriorated, reducing export demand despite the recent depreciation of the euro. External imbalances within the euro area will narrow, but the decline in periphery deficits will materialize largely as a consequence of weak activity and import compression.

  • Trend growth remains low. Even abstracting from current factors, euro area medium-term growth is set to disappoint in the absence of policy action. Reflecting well-known area-wide structural weaknesses, staff sees trend growth at only about ¾ percent over the medium term.

Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Euro Area Inflation Developments

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Eurostat; ECB; European Commision; Haver Analytics; IMF, World Economic Outlook, and staff calculations.
Figure 3a.
Figure 3a.

Fiscal Outlook in the Euro Area: 2012 April WEO

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: 2012 April WEO1/ Euro Area, US and the UK shown in primary axis: Japan shown in secondary axis.
Figure 3b.
Figure 3b.

Fiscal Consolidation in the Euro area: Challenges

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: WEO; 2011 and 2012 Stability Programs; and J. P. Morgan1/ The chart shows fiscal consolidation over 2011-13 required at the 2012 Stability Programs in excess of fiscal consolidationenvisaged in last year’s Stability Program. A positive sign indicates that fiscal policy is tighter under current plans.2/ The figure for 2013 includes the measures recently agreed by the Dutch parliament.3/ The chart focuses on Euro area countries currently under EDP.4/ Targets under program commitments.5/ Ajustment in CAPB required between 2011 and 2020 (and sustained for the 2020-30 decade) to bring down the debt-to-GDP ratio to 60 percent by 2030, or to stabilize debt at the 2012 level if the ratio is less than 60 percent of GDP.
uA01fig06

GDP Growth Contribution, 2012

(percentage points)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations
uA01fig07

Annual Change in EA17 Structural Balance

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations

6. Unemployment will remain high because of weak growth. In 2012, unemployment rates are expected to span a wide range, from about 5 ½ percent in Germany to 24 percent in Spain. Staff projections also indicate that these differences will persist, as growth in countries under pressure (Portugal, Greece, Ireland, and Spain) will not be sufficient to return unemployment to pre-crisis levels.

uA01fig08

Euro Area: Unemployment Rates

(Percent; April 2012 1/)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: Eurostat
uA01fig09

Returning to Pre-Crisis Unemployment Rates; Average Growth, 2012–2016

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations

7. Inflation is set to decline significantly and could even become negative. Headline inflation is expected to fall well below 2 percent in 2013 and remain there through 2014. Although survey-based inflation expectations are still broadly anchored, market-based indicators are clearly pointing downward and core inflation (stripping out the most volatile components, such as energy and food prices) signals very low underlying inflation pressures (see Figure 2). Moreover, given the subdued growth outlook, there is a sizable risk that inflation could even turn negative in the medium run. Specifically, the IMF’s GPM projections indicate about a 25 percent probability of below-zero inflation by early 2014. This risk of deflation is relatively low in the faster-growing economies but significant in the periphery, where administrative price and tax increases are masking more severe downward price pressures from still substantial output gaps. For example, staff estimates suggest that fiscal factors contribute over 1 percentage point to inflation in Italy in 2012. This disinflationary environment in much of the periphery will make it difficult for many countries to reduce the burden of debt.

uA01fig10

Euro Area: Price Indices

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Eurostat; and IMF staff calculations
uA01fig11

Euro Area: Headline Inflation

(Percent; year-on-year)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF; and Global Projection Model

8. The outlook is subject to a number of severe downside risks (see text Table 1). Greater-than-expected bank deleveraging and fiscal consolidation could further lower confidence and hamper growth; this would have a strong negative impact on public debt trajectories. Where growth is already weak, there is a risk of stagnation and long-term damage to potential output as unemployed workers lose skills and new workers find it difficult to join the active labor force. A failure of a large and systemic bank could test the ability of the ECB and crisis facilities to stem contagion. And reform slippage at the country level could have large negative spillovers throughout the euro area. The fear of euro area exit, if not countered swiftly and effectively, could spread to other economies perceived to have similar characteristics, potentially leading to increased financial market stress and depositor flight from several banking systems.

Text Table 1.

Euro Area: Risk Assessment Matrix1/

(Scale—high, medium, or low)

article image

The Risk Assessment Matrix shows events that could materially alter the baseline path discussed in this report (which is the scenario most likely to materialize in the view of the staff). The relative likelihood of risks listed is the staff’s subjective assessment of the risks surrounding this baseline.

In case the baseline does not materialize.

9. A deeper euro area crisis would have substantial global implications. Staff analyses suggest that further intensification of the euro area crisis—modeled as a jump in sovereign and private yields—could have a significant impact on the rest of the world. The spillovers would be especially strong in the neighboring EU and southeastern European countries. Specifically, output losses across the euro area result in nearly equivalent losses in the UK and Eastern Europe, with peak output losses occurring within two years. However, the extent of the spillovers depends on several factors, including the associated policy responses within the euro area and in the rest of the world, the duration of the crisis, and the pass-through of sovereign spreads to private sector borrowing costs. Some banks in core euro area countries are sufficiently large and connected that they could generate significant spillovers—both in the core and periphery—through cross-border deleveraging and associated increases in counterparty risks.3

The Implications for Policy

10. The deepening of the crisis suggests that its root causes remain un-addressed. EMU still lacks the basic tools that can break the adverse feedback loops between sovereigns, banks, and the real economy. Also, largely missing are ambitious policies to restore strong and balanced growth across the euro area that can counter current headwinds to growth, rectify competitiveness problems, and raise trend growth.

11. Policy makers have responded to the crisis with wide-ranging initiatives. The ECB has reduced policy rates to historical lows and conducted special liquidity interventions to address immediate bank funding pressures, averting an even more rapid escalation of the crisis (Figure 4). The enlarged European and global firewall will provide more liquidity insurance to sovereigns while the ongoing reform of fiscal governance will help strengthen fiscal discipline. National governments have also embarked on fiscal consolidation and reaffirmed their debt sustainability and deficit targets. Importantly, the June 28-29 summit agreed to steps toward a single supervisory mechanism, followed by the possibility of using ESM resources to recapitalize banks directly, in addition to other measures (Box 1). Together, these actions represent a significant commitment to deal with the crisis.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

LTROs: Effects on the ECB balance sheet and bank funding

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: European Central Bank; Haver Analytics; European Covered Bond Council; and IMF staff calculations.1/ Blue circles: 6 month LTROs, green: 1yr, red: 3yr

European Summit Policy Initiatives: Right Steps on the Roadmap4

At their summit meeting on June 28-29, European leaders agreed upon significant positive steps to address the immediate crisis. The agreement, if implemented in full, will help break the adverse links between sovereigns and banks and create a banking union, in line with the Article IV mission recommendations. In particular, once a single supervisory mechanism for euro area banks is established—with key decisions to be taken by end-2012—the ESM would be able to recapitalize banks directly. Moreover, ESM assistance will not carry seniority status for Spain—an important step to support market confidence. In addition, the leaders re-affirmed a willingness to consider secondary purchases of sovereign bonds by the EFSF/ESM, although without expanding the resource envelope. Finally, an agreement was reached on terms for a “Growth Compact”, mainly in the form of infrastructure projects, and a request to pursue the “Four Presidents” proposals, with concrete plans to be delivered to a summit later in the year. Collectively, these steps are consistent with the direction advocated in this staff report.

Implementing these measures in a timely way would help restore longer term confidence in the union. The hurdles to implement these measures are high: the ESM has not yet been ratified by all members, the timing of pan-euro area supervision remains uncertain, and many of the announced measures will require unanimity by Euro group ministers. Furthermore, crucial questions on the terms for direct euro area bank recapitalizations still need to be addressed.

These initiatives are steps in the right direction that will need to be complemented, as envisaged, by more progress toward deeper fiscal integration and a full-fledged banking union. By setting in motion a process toward a unified supervisory framework, the Summit put in place the first building block of a banking union. But other necessary elements, including a pan-European deposit insurance guarantee scheme and bank resolution mechanism with common backstops, need to be added. Staff sees these as necessary to send a firm signal of commitment toward completing the monetary union and decisively breaking the link between sovereigns and banks. In addition, these steps would usefully be complemented by plans for fiscal integration, as anticipated in the report of the ‘Four Presidents’ submitted to the summit. It is encouraging that the leaders have asked the Council President to develop proposals for a more complete union over the next three months.

12. But the crisis calls for a much stronger collective effort now to demonstrate policymakers’ unequivocal commitment to sustain EMU. Only a convincing and concerted move toward a more complete EMU could arrest the decline in confidence engulfing the region. A credible roadmap toward a full banking union and fiscal integration will make the short-term crisis measures more effective. Structural reforms throughout the euro area will also be necessary to revive growth in the long run, while macroeconomic policies can smooth the needed adjustment in the short run.

A. The Case for Completing EMU

13. The euro area is in an uncomfortable and unsustainable halfway point. While it is sufficiently integrated to allow escalating problems in one country to spill over to others, it lacks the economic flexibility or policy tools to deal with these spillovers.

  • Economic adjustment to country-specific shocks is limited. Labor mobility across countries is low, partly owing to institutional factors such as housing market rigidities, non-transferable social benefits, and the absence of an area-wide social safety net. Wage and price flexibility can be limited, slowing the correction of macroeconomic imbalances. And while capital moves freely across the euro area, it is susceptible to sudden swings that can paralyze financial markets and threaten financial stability.

  • Crucially, the euro area also lacks essential financial and fiscal policy tools to stabilize the monetary union. As the crisis has illustrated, without a strong common financial stability framework, banking problems are hard to contain and resolve in an integrated market (Box 2). Absent sufficient instruments of fiscal risk sharing, there are no common backstops to support banks or other tools than can soften the fiscal consequences of country-shocks before they spread beyond national borders. At the same time, without robust fiscal governance, there are only weak incentives to keep sovereign debt levels low before a crisis hits (Box 3).

The Case for a Banking Union5

The euro area crisis has revealed the flaws in a framework in which responsibility for financial stability remains national. Before the crisis, the euro area had achieved a high degree of financial integration. For example, sovereign risks of periphery countries were de facto shared between core euro area and domestic investors (see figure below). But faced by a funding freeze affecting large euro area banks dependent on wholesale funding and contagion of sovereign stress to Italy and Spain, the euro area financial system has fragmented away from an area-wide system to within national borders. This has created de-integrating forces in sovereign bond markets, interbank markets and lending and deposit markets. Sovereign bond and interbank markets have been the most deeply affected by the withdrawals of intra-euro area cross-border capital flows (see figure below). As a result, financial markets have become more fragmented, which has impaired the transmission channels of euro area monetary policy (see Box 4).

uA01fig12

Share of Foreign-held Debt Securities Held within the Euro Area (2010)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: IMF, Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey.
uA01fig13

Change in EA MFI Cross-border Claims, 2011 and 2012Q1

(Billions of euros)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: ECB, cross-border positions of EA MFI, excl ESCB.Note: changes in cross-border claims not adjusted for potential valuation effects.

Downward spirals between sovereigns, banks and the real economy are stronger than ever in the periphery.

  • Concerns about bank solvency remain large where the domestic sovereign is weak. Weak sovereigns, in turn, are unable to backstop failed banks without jeopardizing their solvency, as discussed in the accompanying Selected Issues Paper.

  • To strengthen internal funds, banks make loans pricier and adversely reduce credit supply, which weakens growth and the fiscal balance. Staff analysis suggests that bank funding stress has a substantial effect on loan pricing: a 150 bps increase in bank CDS spreads is associated with an increase in lending rates of 0.6 percentage points for corporate loans and 0.4 percentage points for mortgages.

  • These adverse feed-back loops are amplified by the absence of an exchange rate that could offset part of the adverse impact on domestic demand.

uA01fig14

Selected Euro Area Countries: Monthly Interest Rate and Banking Stress, 2010-12

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

A banking union would strengthen the viability of the EMU by helping sever adverse feed back loops between banks and their sovereign and providing incentives to end financial de-integration. Mitigating the adverse effects of the sovereign-bank nexus and reducing incentives to cut cross-border exposures would stabilize financial systems and counteract financial fragmentation, thereby contributing to restore the transmission of monetary policy. It would also help re-start growth by ensuring that healthy euro area firms can obtain credit from financial institutions at a reasonable cost, regardless of the strength of their sovereign.

The Case for a Fiscal Union6

In a common currency area, fiscal integration provides critical tools to enhance the adjustment to idiosyncratic shocks and deal with externalities. Greater centralized risk sharing and support for fiscal adjustment would be particularly valuable in the euro area given that economic adjustment to country-specific shocks is less than perfect. Compared to many other currency areas, labor is not very mobile between countries, intra-area capital flows can prove volatile, and structural rigidities often impede the price adjustment and reallocation of resources (see Section B). At the same time, governance safeguards against excessive debt have disappointed in the past.

Institutions of fiscal risk sharing are at work in most currency areas. In contrast to the euro area, countries such as Brazil, Canada, Germany, Switzerland, and the U.S. offer ex ante insurance through a variety of formalized mechanisms. The literature on the benefits of fiscal risk sharing suggests that, on average, about 10-20 percent of regional income shocks are absorbed through sharing arrangements. This helps prevent contagion and reduces the need for costly ex post bailouts. Among the tools employed are:

  • Financial stability: Common financial stability frameworks with a common, area-wide backstop such as the FDIC in the U.S. that ensure localized banking stresses do not develop into systemic crises (see Box 2).

  • Transfer and tax schemes: Transfers from the central (or federal) government to regions (Figure 1a) and/or tax sharing arrangements between regions, or between regions and the center, account for a significant share of regional income in many currency areas. Although the institutional arrangements can differ, these transfers often respond to cyclical developments at the regional level, providing insurance against idiosyncratic shocks.

  • Public goods: Important public goods and services are often provided by the center but financed through regional taxes (see Figure 1b below). This entails fiscal risk sharing in case of an adverse shock: the benefit of a centrally-provided public good is unchanged, but a region’s relative tax contribution will fall during a downturn.

Figure 1a.
Figure 1a.

Transfers from the Center

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Eurostat, McHugh; and Poghosyan, 2012.
Figure 1b.
Figure 1b.

Central Provision of Public Goods

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Eurostat; IMF staff calculations.Note: Excludes tax sharing arrangements. 1/ For EU, spending of EU budget, data for 2008. 2/ Excludes region of Nunavut which receives 77 percent of GDP in gross transfers.

But fiscal integration also requires strong governance arrangements to address moral hazard. As a rule, instruments of fiscal risk sharing are complemented by governance frameworks that limit fiscal sovereignty at the regional level and help to ensure fiscal behavior in accordance with commonly agreed standards. For example, where public goods are provided centrally, the center usually has tax authority over the entire region. Where transfers are a significant part of regional income, the center often has the right to intervene more directly in the regions’ public finances. In addition, many currency areas use legally enforceable fiscal rules to ensure that regional fiscal positions are sustainable. Some currency areas have a bailout mechanism, while others rely on no-bailout provisions to guard against moral hazard. However, even where no-bailout provisions exist, their credibility is supported by a minimum level of risk sharing that protects basic government functions and helps absorb regional shocks.

14. As a result, the pernicious feedback loop between banks and sovereigns, as well as market fragmentation, have been accentuated during the crisis. In a number of countries, the transfer of banking liabilities to the public balance sheet is continuing, while worsening public finances are still causing direct losses on sovereign bonds. In some cases, the necessary provision of ECB liquidity has led to further sovereign bond purchases by banks, deepening this link even more. Where perceptions of sovereign and banking risks have been increasing, financing conditions have deteriorated markedly, accelerating the re-fragmentation of the euro area’s financial market.

A banking union would help address the underlying problem…

15. A euro area banking union could combine three main elements:

  • A pan-European deposit guarantee scheme. A deposit guarantee scheme can increase depositor confidence by reducing the dependence of banks on their sovereigns and thereby also reduce the risk of sudden deposit movements across the currency area. Eventually, such a scheme could (and should) be funded by a levy on the industry but, to be effective, it would need ready recourse to additional funding in times of stress, from a common pool of government-provided resources or—for the euro area—an ECB credit line.

  • A pan-European bank resolution mechanism. A bank resolution authority, established with powers to bail in private creditors and support directly the resolution of banks, would facilitate an orderly wind-down of failing institutions and smooth the deleveraging process across the region. As with the deposit scheme, resolution could be backed by a common fund financed by an industry levy with recourse to government-provided resources or the ECB.

  • Common supervision. In addition to deposit guarantee and bank resolution schemes, an effective banking union will need the support of a common supervisory framework to foster stability and deter fragmentation. The framework would be most effective if it encompassed the entire banking system but could at first focus on cross-border banks and large systemically-important financial institutions in the euro area. To this end, the June 28-29 summit plan to establish a single supervisory mechanism for euro area banks—to be considered by the Council by end-2012—is an important first step toward a banking union. But it will be important that the necessary decisions be taken and implemented quickly.

16. Several intermediate steps can pave the way for—and add to the credibility of—a banking union.

  • In particular, the recently proposed EU framework for harmonized national bank resolution processes and deposit insurance could become a helpful building block toward a banking union if fully implemented on an accelerated schedule. The new framework can reduce the cost to taxpayers from future bank failures by providing strong powers to resolution authorities, including the power to bail-in unsecured creditors, thus reducing the ‘too-big-to-fail’ subsidy.

  • The existing EFSF/ESM framework could provide immediate financing for the common deposit insurance and resolution frameworks before industry contributions are available. In this regard, the use of EFSF/ESM resources for these purposes could be linked to advances in area-wide supervision, similar to the recent decision to consider direct bank recapitalization by the ESM.

  • Strong coordination of macroprudential policies would also mark progress in the right direction. In this regard, the recent compromise draft of the CRDIV, which provides greater flexibility at the national level by allowing countries to impose stricter capital buffers, offers a helpful balance between the needs of the single rule book and financial stability concerns of national authorities. A common approach to capital and liquidity requirements is essential, with a strong role for pan-European institutions such as the ESRB and EBA.

17. Fast progress is more critical for the euro area than for the EU. Although the banking union should be consistent with European Union directives, it is particularly urgent for the euro area. This is because deposits move more easily within a currency area, and a deposit guarantee scheme covering all euro area depository institutions would help reassure retail depositors that their savings are safe and avoid sudden depositor flight. In the same way, a euro area bank resolution authority would weaken the bank-sovereign feedback loops operating within the currency union. At the same time, to align supervisory incentives within the euro area, the ECB could play the role of common supervisor. And to further strengthen its financial markets role, the ECB could also be given explicit responsibility for financial stability and full lender-of-last-resort functions, thereby eliminating bank-sovereign linkages present in the current Emergency Liquidity Assistance (ELA) scheme.

…and steps toward a fiscal union would be helpful as well

18. More fiscal integration would support the banking union. Elements of a fiscal union would already be present in a banking union as described above: the provision of common backstops for deposit insurance and bank resolution is a form of fiscal risk sharing. And unified regulatory and supervisory frameworks provide an important element of governance in the form of delegation of national sovereignty to the center.7

19. Fiscal integration means stronger governance arrangements that help to ensure fiscal behavior in accordance with commonly agreed standards. The Fiscal Compact and the proposed “Two Pack” are important steps in this direction. The Compact re-commits signatories to the fiscal discipline of the original Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) while offering some necessary flexibility in the shorter term (see ¶26 and the Selected Issues Paper). If implemented well, it can go some way to reducing fiscally-generated risks while limiting the adverse impact of fiscal consolidation on demand. The “two pack” will reinforce the influence of the European Commission in shaping national budgetary plans and oversight of budgetary execution. This would better align national fiscal policy with common objectives.

20. More ex ante fiscal risk sharing would ensure that member economies can cope better with macroeconomic shocks. Some degree of fiscal risk sharing is already being achieved through crisis management facilities (the EFSM, EFSF, and ESM). But it is provided after a crisis has hit, which can make it expensive. Even worse, it can give rise to recurring market doubts about the adequacy of available resources. By contrast, ex ante risk sharing is commonplace in other currency areas (e.g., Switzerland, the United States). In addition to fully-developed banking unions, these areas feature significant fiscal risk sharing tools, such as transfers from federal to state budgets and central provision of public goods (e.g., social security or infrastructure).

21. Fiscal risk sharing can be achieved in different ways, but all approaches would benefit from a clear roadmap. Ultimately, helping countries smooth adjustment to adverse shocks might require large resources at the center. But reaching this point will imply a form of political union with a substantial reorientation of sovereignty and burden sharing, requiring changes to the EU treaty and national constitutions. This will take time. But the process could start now, with a clear commitment to a broad-based dialogue about what a fuller fiscal union would imply for the sovereignty of member states and the accountability of the center. It should deliver a schedule of discussion, decision, and implementation.

22. The path toward more fiscal integration could start with a limited-but-scalable introduction of common debt, with appropriate governance safeguards. Such euro area debt securities could, at first, be restricted to shorter maturities of small size, and be conditional on more centralized control (e.g., veto powers over national deficits, the pledging of national tax revenues). Among the many proposals discussed in this area, “Eurobills” come closest to such an approach, while “the redemption fund” is also limited. Common bond financing could also be used to provide the backstops for the common frameworks within the banking union.8

B. Restoring Strong and Balanced Growth

A forceful common response would bolster growth in the short run…

23. The ECB can provide further defenses against an escalation of the crisis. These could include policies to support demand in the short run and fend off downside risks to inflation, as well as measures to ensure that monetary transmission, currently impaired by financial stress in some countries, operates well again across the euro area (Box 4).

  • Interest rate reductions. Economic weakness and downside risks to inflation in the euro area warrant further reductions in the main policy rates. Although the room for such reductions is limited, they would deliver a strong signaling effect and, in addition, provide some direct near-term support to weaker banks by reducing indexed borrowing costs under existing LTROs.

The Impaired Monetary Transmission in the Euro Area9

Since the start of the crisis, lending conditions have varied substantially across the euro area. For instance, nonfinancial corporate lending rates have risen sharply in the periphery, but have fallen in the core countries over the past year.

The pass-through of policy to lending rates has weakened, especially in the periphery. Before the crisis intensified, lending rates broadly tracked changes in the ECB policy rate, albeit to varying degrees. But since late 2010, retail lending rates started to rise while policy rates remained low. Staff analysis confirms that both the speed of adjustment and the long-run impact of ECB policy rate changes on a variety of retail interest rates have declined across many euro area countries.

uA01fig15

1. Retail bank lending rates and the ECB policy rate

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: ECB, staff computations. Periphery includes Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Spain, Italy. Rates are volume-weighted.

This is partly due to increased sovereign stress. Banks’ wholesale funding and lending rates are priced off (domestic) sovereign yields. Since the euro area started to experience periods of sovereign stress in late 2010, the impact of ECB policy interest rate changes on domestic bond yields has weakened as financial markets differentiate more strongly between core and periphery countries.

Weak bank capital and liquidity positions contributed to the slowdown in lending. Specifically, based on a panel estimation using data for 100 euro area banks covering the period Q1:2007-Q1:2012, staff analysis reveals the following. First, banks’ quarterly bank lending growth was significantly higher for larger, more profitable, more liquid and better capitalized banks. Second, banks with a higher loan/deposit ratio mismatch (reflecting business/funding model risk or leverage) and higher CDS spreads (i.e., more risky banks) lent significantly less. Finally, bank lending was substantially higher in countries with higher GDP growth and higher house prices.

uA01fig16

2. Slowdown in policy interest rate pass-through

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: ECB, IMF staff computations. Interest rate pass-through is estimated from monthly data (pre-crisis 1997/03–2007/02 and crisis 2007/03–2012/02) using a standard error correction model. Points below the diagonal are markets that have experienced a slowdown in the long-run pass-through.

At the same time, reductions in the policy rate and larger liquidity provision appear to have supported bank lending. The empirical analysis suggests that ECB policy rate reductions were associated with higher bank lending, and reliance on ECB funding cushioned bank lending. A higher ECBEONIA interest rate spread, which is often viewed as an alternative indicator of monetary policy (but also captures liquidity and counterparty stress), was associated with lower bank lending.

The empirical results suggest that improving bank soundness and relieving sovereign stress will help underpin lending in the euro area.

uA01fig17

3. Partial correlations of bank loan growth

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Figures show partial correlations between loan growth residuals (from a model excluding the variable of interest) and the residual of the variable in question regressed on all other model variables.
  • Quantitative easing (QE). The ECB could achieve further monetary easing through a transparent QE program encompassing sizable sovereign bond purchases, possibly preannounced over a given period of time. Buying a representative portfolio of long-term government bonds—e.g., defined equitably across the euro area by GDP weights—would also provide a measure of added stability to stressed sovereign markets. However, QE would likely also contribute to lower yields in already “low yield” countries, including Germany.

  • More SMP purchases. Additional and clearly communicated SMP purchases could ensure the transmission of monetary easing where sovereign bond markets are subject to increased stress.10 With the possible exception of Greece, SMP purchases have been relatively small compared with the outstanding debt stock, in principle increasing the scope for additional intervention. And a well-communicated re-activation of SMP purchases would likely carry strong signaling effects which might mitigate the need for very large purchases. The benefits from lower yields would also ease collateral constraints on official and interbank lending facilities.

  • Further liquidity provision. This could encompass additional multi-year LTRO facilities, coupled with adjusted collateral requirements, if needed—including a broadened collateral base and/or a lowering of haircuts—to address localized shortages. The associated credit risk to the ECB would be manageable in view of its strong balance sheet and high levels of capital provisioning. Nevertheless, one of the disadvantages of the LTRO facility is that it tends to strengthen sovereign-bank links (see Box 5).

24. Clarification of the ECB’s seniority status would make its crisis response more effective. Market concerns about the subordination of private sovereign bond holdings should be addressed by clarifying the seniority status of ECB’s holdings. Similar considerations apply to the ESM. A clear commitment to accept equal status with private sector claims, as in the case of Spain, would enhance the effectiveness of official sector crisis management.

25. If the crisis escalates, policymakers will have to stand ready to support the euro area banking system, including through a flexible use of the European firewall. Clarity on common support—including, foremost by the ECB, but possibly also by announcing a pan-European deposit insurance scheme—may be necessary to support depositor confidence. In addition, to effectively reduce bank sovereign links and promote confidence, the EFSF/ESM facilities should be ratified quickly and empowered with sufficient flexibility and resources to support banks of member states. The June 28-29 summit decision to consider direct bank recapitalization marks important progress toward flexibility. In addition, as discussed in ¶16, the existing EFSF/ESM framework could provide financing for common deposit insurance and resolution frameworks in the short run.

Further Use of Long-Term Refinancing Operations (LTROs)?11

The intense funding difficulties for euro area banks prompted significant liquidity support from the ECB. Through two three-year LTROs and a further relaxation in its collateral rules, the ECB allotted €1 trillion to euro area banks, with a net increase in liquidity of about €500 billion. For the second LTRO, the ECB expanded eligible collateral to include additional performing credit claims (i.e., bank loans), after widening the eligibility criteria in previous years.

But further ECB liquidity support may be necessary if bank funding conditions continue to deteriorate. The total wholesale debt roll-over need of the euro area banks is estimated at about €630 billion for 2012, some of which has been pre-financed via the 3-year LTROs and some will be refinanced in the market. However, further long-term LTROs may be required if funding conditions deteriorate or if banks face withdrawals. But can banks generate additional eligible collateral to obtain ECB funding?

According to the ECB, banks on the whole would be able to generate sufficient collateral under the current ECB eligibility criteria to meet additional refinancing needs. LTRO borrowings are around €1.1 trillion (end May), but marketable collateral eligible for Eurosystem operations (including LTROs) is about €13 trillion (not all held by banks). And there may be substantial non-marketable collateral, evidenced by the €3 trillion pre-pledged collateral (typically non-marketable). This could allow borrowing of up to €2.4 trillion (assuming haircuts of 20 percent).

However, some individual banks—mainly in the periphery countries—could be short of collateral. The Greek and Irish banks already need to use the national ELA, which has a wider collateral pool. In Spain, assuming the stability of domestic deposits, collateral and liquidity buffers appear sufficient at the system level, but collateral posted at the ECB is vulnerable to ratings downgrades and margin calls while the capacity to generate new collateral is weakening. Although the LTROs have provided a sizable cushion, the phasing-out of ECB funding will likely prove problematic if market access does not improve. Indeed, liquidity stress tests in the context of Spain’s FSAP show that liquidity risk can potentially become the biggest risk should ECB support not be renewed.

A further relaxation of collateral rules as well as a rethinking of collateral pricing and haircut policies may be necessary to ensure liquidity support to (solvent) banks and prevent liquidity risks from escalating into insolvency risks. In late 2011, among other measures, the ECB allowed national central banks to accept as collateral additional performing credit claims (i.e., bank loans). More recently, it further amended rating thresholds and eligibility requirements for certain asset-backed securities (ABSs) to improve banks’ access to the liquidity operations.

However, additional steps may be needed to cover liquidity risk of the collateral it accepts. The ECB assesses the value of collateral using market prices (or uses a “mark to model” approach if a market price is not available) and then calculates the haircut to allow for sale of the collateral within a short period without loss to the ECB. This feature is unhelpfully pro-cyclical, and may not be necessary since the ECB does not need to sell collateral quickly.12 A fire sale of assets in a systemic liquidity crisis would indeed require large haircuts, but when imposed as part of the LTRO they could substantially reduce liquidity crisis and asset sales at distressed prices, exactly the situation the LTRO is meant to prevent.

26. To help cushion the adverse impact of fiscal consolidation on demand, policy measures would need to be as growth-friendly as possible. To reduce deficits and debt that have risen sharply in recent years, most euro area countries plan significant fiscal adjustment over the medium term. In this setting, the overarching challenge is to implement consolidation plans without exacerbating the adverse feedback loops with the real economy. Countries where market pressure is high have little choice but to proceed rapidly with consolidation. But the adjustment elsewhere should be conducted at a steady underlying pace that balances the need to bring down deficits and to support the recovery. To ensure that unanticipated shocks from the real economy do not automatically set off a damaging wave of further cuts, it is important to focus the fiscal targets on structural, rather than nominal deficits. This calls for exploiting the flexibility built into the Fiscal Compact, as discussed in the Selected Issues Paper. Moreover, anchoring consolidation efforts in fully-specified multi-year plans, with fiscal measures identified in advance, will increase their credibility, mitigating the negative effect on demand.

uA01fig18

Planned Fiscal Consolidation

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations
uA01fig19

Compliance with SGP Rules, 2011

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations

…and support continued national adjustment

27. Timely and credible actions at the national level remain an integral part of the crisis response. Although needs vary across crisis countries, transparent and comprehensive strategies to recapitalize viable banks should be implemented without delay. In this context, the recently announced Eurogroup support for the Spanish banking system is timely. Acting quickly to strengthen the banking system through the ongoing independent assessments of banks’ loan books, by dealing with legacy assets and by strengthening supervision and regulatory frameworks, will help restore confidence and alleviate financial market pressure. In addition, policy actions to restore the health of public finances and structural measures (labor and product market reforms) to enhance competitiveness could support confidence and anchor medium-term expectations (see Table 3 on IMF key policy recommendations).

Table 1.

Euro Area: Main Economic Indicators, 2007–2014

article image
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; Global Data Source; DataStream; and Eurostat.

Contribution to growth.

Includes intra-euro area trade.

In percent.

In percent of GDP.

Latest monthly available data for 2012.

CPI based.

Based on ECB data, which excludes intra-euro area flows.

Table 2.

Euro Area: Balance of Payments

article image
Source: ECB.

End of period stocks.

Table 3.

IMF Policy Recommendations for Selected Countries

article image
article image

Rectifying external imbalances will be crucial for the euro area

28. The euro area as a whole has been close to balance.

  • The current account balance of the Euro area was, on average, zero, for the period from 1999–2006. Since the 2008, the balance has dipped slightly, reflecting greater-than-average deterioration in southern economies.

  • On the capital account side, portfolio flows, in particular into debt, have supported the current account deficit as cross-border financial flows declined with the crisis. Equity balances were substantially affected by valuations during 2008-2009 but have since recovered. Portfolio investments by financial institutions have not recovered, as banks have reduced lending abroad.

  • The net foreign asset position had deteriorated, to nearly -17 percent of GDP, but has since recovered to -12 percent of GDP. Estimates of the cyclically adjusted current account suggest that the NFA position will stay relatively constant going forward.

29. Overall, the Euro area external position appears moderately weaker than implied by medium-term fundamentals and desired policies. Staff analysis suggests that a modest improvement in the current account, in the order of 1 percentage point of GDP, would be desirable to ensure external sustainability.

30. Consequently, the euro is assessed to be slightly overvalued. Analysis based on fundamental equilibrium models, desired current account adjustment, and aggregation of staff views of individual member states suggests that the euro is overvalued in real terms by 0 to 5 percent.13

31. But individual member states built up large external imbalances. From the inception of the euro, current account deficits by individual member states cumulated to nearly 20 percent of euro area GDP in 2011, while surpluses cumulated to over 20 percent during the same period. During the crisis, external balances of deficit economies have narrowed, to -10 percent in the case of Greece, and all the way to balance in the case of Ireland. However, such reductions have largely been the result of falling imports as a result of sharp declines in domestic demand. Moreover, comparatively little adjustment has taken place in costs: unit labor costs of deficit economies such as Greece, Portugal, and Spain declined, on average, by 1 to 2½ percent per year in 2010–11.

uA01fig20

Current Account Balance

(percent of Euro Area GDP, cumulative)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook database; and IMF staff calculations
uA01fig21

Real Effective Exchange Rate Index (CPI based)

(average 1980–1998= 100)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: IMF, and Information Notice System database

32. Ensuring external sustainability implies more substantial real exchange rate adjustments for individual member economies. Although only a modest adjustment is needed for the Euro area as a whole, some individual euro area economies require more substantial adjustment. For example, in the cases of Italy and Spain, the required adjustments are in the order of 5 to 10 percent and 10 to 15 percent, respectively.

33. Structural policies throughout the region could help address external imbalances.

  • In deficit economies, improving competitiveness of tradable sectors requires policies that help reduce unit labor costs, such as labor market flexibility, reducing entry costs in product markets, and raising labor productivity. Non-price competitiveness may also play a significant role—this implies, for example, microeconomic reforms that make it easier for small firms to expand into foreign markets.

  • In surplus economies, product market reforms—especially in the services sectors—are a priority. Improvements in disposable incomes in surplus economies could have some beneficial spillover effects—via improvements in external demand—to deficit economies. Equivalently, improvements in non-tradables productivity would be matched, ideally, by increases in nominal wages, which, in conjunction with a reduction in unit labor costs in deficit economies, will facilitate relative price adjustment.

34. In the short run, price adjustment can play a role in addressing external imbalances. Wage and asset price increases in the north would be part of the natural process of rebalancing the sources of growth, and would help to appropriately reduce high current account surpluses. Larger inflation differentials would also facilitate the needed relative price adjustment by the south. In addition, for a given level of euro area inflation, higher inflation in the north would reduce the risk of debt-deflation spirals in the south.

uA01fig22

Euro Area: Stimulated Inflation Differentials

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Source: IMF staff simulations

Structural reforms are also needed to raise trend growth across the euro area

35. Weak trend growth has fuelled the crisis. An important reason why bank and sovereign problems have proven difficult to resolve is that debt dynamics are fragile in an environment of low growth and poor growth prospects. At the same time, private capital has fled some economies, reflecting increasing doubts about the ability of member states to service debt. And there has been a corresponding increase in demand for official funding.

36. As the crisis continues, the risks of stagnation grow larger. As unemployment has risen, the proportion of youth and long-term unemployed has increased disproportionately in those euro area economies hardest hit by the crisis. As more new workers fail to enter the workforce and obtain skills, and as existing unemployed workers lose skills, the risk grows that potential output will be lower.

37. Raising trend growth will be challenging because of low productivity and demographic presures. As with most advanced economies, euro area output growth has been steadily falling over the past 50 years. Compared with its best-performing peers, however, the deterioration in euro area growth has been worse. From a growth accounting perspective, the facts are stark. Productivity growth has weakened over time, and effective labor utilization has been relatively low. Moreover, euro area states face particularly challenging demographic trends, with low and declining population growth implying substantial increases within the space of a generation in the ratio of dependents to those of working age.

38. Labor and product market reforms can raise total factor productivity, growth, and employment. Studies suggest four aspects are critical: changes to labor market institutions to improve the performance of the labor market; product market reforms that raise competition and lower regulatory burdens; tax reforms to switch away from labor income to consumption tax revenues and smooth marginal taxes to raise labor participation; and pension reforms to ease revenue burdens and encourage increased labor effort.

39. The gains from reforms are potentially large. Staff estimates suggest that eliminating half of euro area countries’ gaps with OECD best practice in labor market, product market, tax, and pension policies could raise output by 5 percent over 5 years.14 Moreover, such reforms are applicable to all euro area states, not just those that currently have the lowest growth. This offers the potential for significant spillover benefits as higher growth in any one country benefits others—estimates suggest they could account for one quarter of the total gains in growth.

uA01fig23

Impact on GDP Level

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2012, 181; 10.5089/9781475505771.002.A001

Sources: Global Integrated Monetary and Fiscal Model; and IMF staff simulations

40. But the full effects are likely to take time to materialize, which argues for short-run demand support. Some reforms can have immediate effects, if implemented well, particularly active labor market policies (e.g., retraining). There are many reasons for such lags: for example, some reforms necessarily take time to implement; reallocating resources across sectors is costly; and the reform process can create uncertainty that deters long-term commitments for a period. Reforms might even have negative effects on employment in the short run (especially if focused first at labor market measures without correspondingly-deep product market reforms). And in the current situation where economic slack is large, some reforms might initially reduce disposable income if unemployment rises. Thus, support for aggregate demand in the short run would be crucial to avoid stagnation, as discussed in ¶23 and ¶26.

The Authorities’ Views

41. There was very broad agreement between staff and the authorities on the scale of the crisis, and the need for clear statements on the long-run architecture of the monetary union. The authorities—the ECB and European Commission—stressed, in particular, the importance of establishing deeper monetary integration through a banking union and setting out a credible architecture for more fiscal integration to help stabilize the immediate crisis and anchor expectations on the viability of EMU.

42. The authorities broadly agreed with the overall assessment of economic developments in the euro area, and the strong downside risks to growth. They noted a rebalancing in the composition of growth away from domestic demand toward net trade, resulting mainly from a compression in import demand. They also emphasized strong headwinds to growth from ongoing private balance sheet deleveraging, credit supply constraints, fiscal consolidation, and still-weak confidence. The authorities also argued that these factors could be further aggravated by sustained financial market stress. Nevertheless, they currently project a recovery in domestic demand from the middle of this year, driven by improving real incomes and confidence, rising external demand, and lower global commodity prices.

43. There are somewhat elevated risks to inflation this year, but price pressures are projected to decline. Despite weakened demand and staff’s emphasis on subdued core inflation, the ECB stressed that the impact from higher energy prices, a weaker euro, and indirect tax effects will keep inflationary pressures high in the near-term. Looking ahead, the ECB expects inflationary pressures to decline with weaker commodity prices, sluggish growth in the periphery countries, but do not expect strong disinflationary pressures, particularly given what they described as still very well-anchored inflation expectations.

44. Increased financial market fragmentation is impeding the effectiveness of monetary policy. In view of the strong policy response to the crisis and downside risks to growth, the authorities considered the current monetary policy stance to be broadly appropriate. With policy rates at historical lows, the ECB remains cautious on the benefits of further easing, emphasizing that divergences in both liquidity conditions and market lending rates within the euro area weaken the interest rate channel of monetary policy. In this context, the authorities argued that there were limits to the effectiveness of additional unconventional measures, but did not exclude their use to prevent further contagion should the crisis escalate. Against this, they noted that further euro weakness could stoke inflationary pressures and unseat expectations.

45. Ongoing fiscal consolidation efforts—anchored by structural targets—are needed to ensure sustainable debt trajectories and restore market confidence. There was also agreement with the European Commission that the 3 percent nominal deficit target was binding for several countries in the near-term, and that flexibility embedded in the SGP/Fiscal Compact should be exercised if slippages were the result of negative growth surprises. In this context, there was also a consensus that emphasis should be placed on structural, rather than nominal, fiscal targets despite the well-known difficulties in measuring the former.

46. There was broad agreement that a concerted move toward a banking union is urgently needed to ensure the viability of the monetary union. The authorities emphasized that this should encompass area-wide supervision, and deposit insurance and resolution frameworks with common backstops. In addition, it was emphasized that the recently-published EU crisis management directive is an important step toward establishing an effective supranational financial stability framework. Although the authorities acknowledged that achieving a banking union is critical for the euro area, they stressed that it should be developed to preserve the single European market at the EU level. Discussions also showed broad agreement that the flexibility embedded in the ESM treaty could and should be used to establish new financial instruments within the framework, including allowing the ESM to directly inject equity into banks.

47. A credible vision for more fiscal integration is needed to raise confidence and anchor the crisis effort. The authorities concurred that a commitment to a roadmap for fiscal integration would be more credible if it includes intermediate steps featuring elements of more centralized governance—such as a strong implementation of the “two-pack”—and some limited form of joint borrowing. It was agreed that meaningful fiscal integration would take time, but should entail a stronger center with enhanced fiscal responsibilities, sufficiently large resources, and proper democratic controls and oversight to help contain budget shortfalls at the national level.

48. Well-executed reforms could yield substantial benefits in terms of enhancing competitiveness, correcting intra-euro area imbalances, and raising output. The authorities stressed the importance of assessing competitiveness in terms of unit labor costs, or productivity, rather than relative price developments alone. Moreover, they emphasized that rebalancing within the euro area was proceeding, albeit currently mainly driven by import compression. In this regard, the authorities agreed with staff that reforms targeted at labor and product markets would help restore competitiveness and external balances over time.

49. There was broad agreement with staff’s analysis on the significance of the global spillovers from an intensification of the crisis in the euro area. The authorities agreed that staff’s focus on financial rather than trade spillovers was appropriate. However, they noted that the analysis depends on the length of the shocks that are imposed, as well as the pass-through of sovereign spreads to private sector borrowing costs. The authorities also indicated that the growth impacts appeared too large, and questioned whether the results have taken into account the flight to safety, notably to German assets.

Staff Appraisal

50. The financial and economic environment continues to deteriorate. Investors are withholding funding from member states most in need, moving capital to safe havens and driving risk premiums to new records. Demand is weakening and unemployment increasing across the euro area. Lower growth and heightened market stress are compounding the difficulties in reducing debt burdens. The risk of stagnation and long-term damage to potential growth will increase as unemployed workers lose skills and new workers find it difficult to join the active labor force.

51. Important actions have been taken. The ECB has lowered policy rates and conducted special liquidity interventions to address immediate bank funding pressures and avert an even more rapid escalation of the crisis. And the larger European and global firewall will provide more liquidity insurance to sovereigns, while the ongoing reform of fiscal governance, especially the adoption of the Fiscal Compact, will help strengthen budgetary discipline. National governments have also embarked on fiscal consolidation and reaffirmed their commitment to debt sustainability and deficit targets. Most recently, the June 28-29 summit set in motion an important process toward a single supervisory mechanism, followed by the possibility of using the ESM to recapitalize banks directly.

52. But the crisis calls for a stronger and more collective effort. Downward spirals between sovereigns, banks, and the real economy are stronger than ever. As concerns about banks’ solvency have increased—because of large sovereign exposures and weak growth prospects in many parts of the euro area—the effectiveness of liquidity operations has diminished. Sovereigns, in turn, are struggling to backstop weak banks on their own. Absent collective mechanisms to break these adverse feedback loops, the crisis has spilled across euro area countries. Contagion from further intensification of the crisis—including acute stress in funding markets and tensions involving systemically-important banks—would be sizable globally. And spillovers to neighboring EU economies would be particularly large. A more determined and forceful collective response is needed.

53. A strong commitment toward a robust and complete monetary union would help restore faith in the viability of EMU. This should encompass a credible path to a banking union and greater fiscal integration, with better governance and more risk sharing. However, achieving this goal will take time and hence requires a clear timeline, with concrete intermediate actions to set the guide posts and anchor public expectations.

54. The immediate priority is a banking union for the euro area. The proposed EU framework for harmonized national bank resolution processes and the progress toward a single supervisory mechanism are appropriate first steps. But they need to go further. A deposit guarantee scheme with a common backstop needs to be established at the regional level to help break the links between domestic banks and their sovereigns, and support depositor confidence. A common bank resolution authority is also needed, backed by a common resolution fund to ensure burden sharing and to limit fiscal costs. These efforts should be supported by a single supervisory mechanism (as envisaged by the June 28-29 summit) and a macro-prudential framework to forestall further financial fragmentation. Although a banking union is desirable for the European Union, it is crucial for the euro area.

55. More fiscal integration, with risk sharing supported by stronger central governance, can reduce the tendency for economic shocks in one country to spill over to the euro area as a whole. Ultimately, this could mean sufficiently large resources at the center, matched by proper democratic controls and oversight, to help insure budget shortfalls at the national level. Getting to this endpoint will take time. But the process can start with a commitment to a broad-based dialogue about what a fuller fiscal union would imply for the sovereignty of member states and the accountability of the center. This should deliver a schedule for discussion, decision, and implementation.

56. Introduction of a limited form of common debt, with appropriate governance safeguards, can provide an intermediate step towards fiscal integration and risk sharing. Such debt securities could, at first, be restricted to shorter maturities and small size and be conditional on more centralized control (e.g., limited to countries that deliver on policy commitments; veto powers over national deficits; pledging of national tax revenues). Common bonds/bills financing could, for example, be used to provide the backstops for the common frameworks within the banking union.

57. To restore growth across the union, long-standing structural rigidities need to be tackled to raise long-term growth prospects. In many countries, labor market reforms are needed to raise participation and address disparities in protection that confine “outsiders” to low-wage, temporary jobs. Southern Europe needs to increase competitiveness in the tradables sector. In addition, targeted investment in infrastructure and human capital will support growth and employment. In northern Europe, product market reforms would help generate a more vibrant services sector and help raise overall productivity.

58. Policy efforts should also focus on improving competitiveness, in particular within the euro area. The euro is assessed to be broadly in line with fundamentals, but there are substantial competitiveness gaps between countries. Services sector reforms in the surplus economies could improve disposable incomes and lead to higher external demand, including for deficit economies. Lowering unit labor costs in the tradables sector is essential for deficit countries. This means productivity-enhancing reforms (e.g., lowering barriers to entry, making it easier for small firms to expand into foreign markets) and labor market measures that ensure nominal wage developments are aligned with productivity growth. To foster relative price adjustment between the North and the South, monetary policy should ensure that overall inflation does not drop far below two percent for the euro area as a whole, while allowing for larger inflation differentials between North and South.

59. The global economic outlook is weakening, reflecting—at least in part—the fragile situation in the euro area. Given Europe’s important role in the global economy, it is important that euro area policymakers strengthen the crisis response through further decisive and collective action. Setting out a credible long-term vision for the monetary union and boosting the near-term crisis response will provide much needed support to the global economic recovery.

60. The staff proposes that the next consultation on euro area policies in the context of the Article IV obligations of member countries follow the standard 12-month cycle.

Appendix I: Statistical Issues1

Statistics for the EU and the euro area are collected by Eurostat from the national statistical institutes. These statistics are generally of sufficient quality, scope, and timeliness to allow for effective macroeconomic surveillance. This appendix summarizes ongoing developments and desirable improvements.

1. The Code of Practice for the European Statistical System has been revised. The new code reaffirms the principles for the production and dissemination of statistics set out in 2005 and reinforces statistical independence, statistical use of administrative data and quality management. Following this revision, a mapping of the revised code and other existing quality frameworks, including the Fund’s DQAF, with the new UN Generic National Quality Assurance Framework was presented at the UN Statistical Commission in 2012. The UN Committee for the Coordination of Statistical Activities was invited to harmonize the different quality assessment frameworks.2

2. Initiatives on National Accounts are underway. These include:

  • NACE Rev. 2: Annual and quarterly euro area aggregates starting in 2000 were released in December 2011 (three months behind schedule due to late reporting by some countries). The legal deadline for reporting long time series 1995-2000 according to NACE rev2 is end-September 2012, which will allow EU/EA aggregates to be released by December 2012. Eurostat expects no significant changes in countries’ GDP under the new method.

  • ESA 2010: Countries are expected to adopt the new system by September 2014. The supporting legal framework is currently under discussion and should be adopted throughout the year. The main challenges ahead include improvements in the timeliness for the main national accounts aggregates (from t+70 to t+60 days); the backward calculation of time series; and the transmission of a supplementary tables on pension schemes based on SNA 2008 standards, which is being resisted by some countries.

  • Data Gaps Initiative: Eurostat is collaborating actively with the Inter-Agency Group (IAG) on this front. IAG members have agreed on a template for reporting quarterly financial and non-financial accounts by institutional sectors. To enable the provision of this data at both annual and quarterly frequencies, it will be essential that Eurostat reaches agreement with member countries.

3. The new Macroeconomic Imbalances Procedure has involved considerable data collection since last year’s consultation. Eurostat and the national statistical institutes worked closely with the European Commission (DG ECFIN–Directorate General of Economic and Financial Affairs) and the ECB during 2011 to set up a scoreboard of indicators with which to assess internal and external imbalances (the so-called Macroeconomic Imbalances Procedure). Eurostat has created a new platform collecting all relevant indicators3, which will be updated on an annual basis. In a small number of areas further work is needed, in particular house price developments (see next paragraph) and the compilation of private sector debt, where some consistency issues exist in the recording of intra-company loans and the treatment of Special Purpose Entities (i.e., holding companies).

4. Updates on data on property markets under the Principal European Economic Indicators (PEEIs) strategy:

  • Residential property prices: Eurostat is currently releasing quarterly house price data, which will be covered by a new regulation entering into force in autumn 2012 and requiring data transmission at t+85 days. Monthly data is unlikely to become available in the near future with full coverage. Although comparability issues remain, harmonization at EU level has been steadily improving. To help economic analysis, it was advised that more be done to flag countries whose coverage and/or methodology are not fully in line with the harmonized rules.

  • Indicator on house sales: Eurostat expects that a harmonized indicator can be obtained as a byproduct of improvements in transaction price quarterly indexes of residential properties (see above). In staff’s view, where house price indices are derived from a comprehensive and timely Land Registry, sales data could be a useful by product.

  • Commercial Property Price Indices (CPPIs): Collaboration between international organizations (including the Fund) is underway to set standards for the compilation of CPPIs. As lead agency, Eurostat has organized a tender for developing an international Handbook on best practices for compiling such indices. This is an area for which data at present are sparse and of variable quality. However, given the importance of CPPIs, the endeavor is worth pursuing.

5. It was agreed that more information would be provided to explain the impact of the new treatment of seasonal products on the HICP introduced last year. Eurostat has published an impact report (updated regularly) for each country. It was noted that, for several countries the effects were quite marked. Staff asked for more information to be provided on the underlying reasons for changes, especially those due to the changes in methodology.

6. Eurostat is working towards an improved dissemination of quarterly government finance statistics. This includes the improvement of timelines and the production of a new press release on quarterly government debt and actions. One outstanding issue is that a few countries still restrict the dissemination of quarterly government finance statistics for the first quarters of the year because of quality concerns. A new element in the quarterly statistics is the data on intergovernmental lending that will avoid double-counting through consolidation.

7. The Directive on national fiscal frameworks poses considerable challenges to government finance statistics. The Directive calls for the dissemination of monthly data on government operations and balance sheet. This entails some difficulties for statistical compilers, but data are expected to be disseminated from 2014. The provision of additional data on public sector statistics is even more demanding. The analysis of public finances is currently limited to the general government sector, following the ESA 95 and Excessive Deficit Procedure concepts. However, given their magnitude in many countries, a fully-fledged register of debt and deficits of public corporations is essential to the assessment of fiscal risks. Eurostat is working closely with member states to publish new chapters on the ESA 95 Manual on Government Deficit and Debt.

8. Work continues to modernize Balance of Payments statistics:

  • BPM6: The Regulation introducing BPM6 should be adopted in a matter of weeks. Eurostat is engaged with countries to ensure the swift implementation of the new methodology. The 2014 deadline is mandatory and no derogations are envisaged, thus countries should adhere to the deadline.

  • Intrastat reporting: Easing the reporting burden for international trade statistics remains a priority. Eurostat is encouraging countries to collect and exchange micro-export data with other trade partners. This would allow for more flexibility as compared with the current system, which also requires the reporting of import data.

  • Bilateral exchange of micro-data for FDI: While the tool has proved useful to enhance data quality, Eurostat and staff concurred that compulsory reporting would be required to perfect the system.

  • Asymmetries in trade statistics: Asymmetries persist but they are limited and stable over time. Eurostat engages with countries in regular “reconciliation rounds” that facilitate the exchange of micro data. Due to technical limitations faced by some countries, the rounds are voluntary. Eurostat’s efforts to develop tools to resolve this issue are welcome.

1

The mission would like to thank euro area authorities, in particular President M. Draghi (European Central Bank), Chairperson A. Enria (European Banking Authority), Head of Secretariat F. Mazzaferro (European Systemic Risk Board), Vice-President O. Rehn (European Commssion), and President H. van Rompuy (European Council), as well as their staff for their time, support, and accessibility. The mission has also benefited from the Fund’s bilateral Article IV consultations with euro area countries and from discussions with national authorities during meetings of the Eurogroup and the Eurogroup Working Group.

2

Target 2 is the payments settlement system for the euro area, largely reflecting interbank activities settled through the transfer of reserves within the Eurosystem. Currently, large Target 2 deficits in the periphery are offset by corresponding surpluses in northern countries, mostly Germany, but also Finland and Luxembourg.

3

These issues are addressed in more detail in the 2012 Spillover Report.

4

The summit took place after the meetings for this Article IV consultation.

5

Prepared by Thierry Tressel. See 2012 Selected Issues Paper for further details.

6

Prepared by Fabian Bornhorst. See Selected Issues Paper for further details.

7

See 2012 Selected Issues Paper for further details

8

See the 2012 Selected Issues Paper for further details.

9

Prepared by Nico Valckx.

10

See 2012 Selected Issues Paper for further details.

11

Prepared by Simon Gray and Jianping Zhou.

12

The contrast between the ECB and the Swiss National bank (SNB) approaches to haircuts when on-lending USD borrowed from the Fed is interesting in this regard. The ECB required a haircut of 20 percent, but with no variation margining (later reduced to 12 percent with weekly margining); the SNB required a zero initial haircut, but used daily variation margining.

13

Note that, since this analysis was conducted, the value of the euro has depreciated by nearly 2 percent in real terms.

14

See “Fostering Growth in Europe Now”, available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=26006.0

1

The European Department is grateful for the participation of experts from the Statistics Department also in the consultation. Mark Van Wersch acted as the STA coordinator.

2

ibid, p. 14.

3

The indicators comprise the current account balance (as percentage of GDP), the net international investment position (as percentage of GDP), export market shares (goods and services) measures in values, nominal unit labor costs, HICP-based real effective exchange rates relative to 35 industrial partners, private sector debt (percent of GDP), general government debt (percent of GDP), private sector credit flow (percent of GDP), house prices relative to consumption deflator, and the unemployment rate.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Euro Area Policies: Staff Report for the 2012 Article IV Consultation with Member Countries
Author:
International Monetary Fund