Iceland
Improving the Equity and Revenue Productivity of the Icelandic Tax System
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

The Icelandic government has launched a review of the tax system, with a view to improving its income redistribution, growth orientation, and efficiency features, as well as increasing its revenue mobilization potential. It aims at minimizing detrimental effects on employment and growth, and at removing inconsistencies with international practices. The tax measures will boost the revenue potential in line with the government’s objectives while substantially increasing income redistribution. The Icelandic Corporate Index Tax would benefit from adopting financial accounting as the basis to determine taxable income.

Abstract

The Icelandic government has launched a review of the tax system, with a view to improving its income redistribution, growth orientation, and efficiency features, as well as increasing its revenue mobilization potential. It aims at minimizing detrimental effects on employment and growth, and at removing inconsistencies with international practices. The tax measures will boost the revenue potential in line with the government’s objectives while substantially increasing income redistribution. The Icelandic Corporate Index Tax would benefit from adopting financial accounting as the basis to determine taxable income.

I. Overview of the Tax System

A. Tax Levels and Tax Structures in a Regional Context

Tax level

1. International comparisons of tax levels across countries are never perfect, but the comparison of Iceland with other Nordic and OECD countries is particularly difficult. This is because, in contrast to most OECD countries, compulsory pension contributions are made to institutions outside government—and thus, appropriately, they are not counted as taxes. This fact is reflected in Iceland's comparatively low government revenue from social security contributions. One way to circumvent this difficulty is to compare tax levels that exclude social security contributions in Iceland and in other countries. Alternatively, Iceland's tax revenue can be augmented with the compulsory contributions paid into pension funds, and the resulting level compared with the tax levels of other countries (this time including social security contributions). Both methods point to a similar conclusion: Iceland's tax level as a proportion of GDP is among the highest in the OECD.

2. In 2007, the last year for which full comparative tax revenue data are available and the year before the crisis, Iceland had tax revenue (excluding social security contributions) of 37.7 percent of GDP.2 This was the second highest tax ratio (excluding social security contributions) in the OECD, behind Denmark (47.7 percent), and well above both the average EU15 ratio (28.7 percent) and the average OECD ratio (26.7 percent). It was also generally above the ratio of other Nordic OECD countries, where the ratio ranged from 31.1 percent in Finland to 35.7 percent in Sweden (Table 2). However, this approach is not perfect because some countries finance pensions from general taxation rather than social security contributions, and Denmark is an example of this practice. Perhaps a better way to achieve a rough comparability is to add the compulsory pension contributions (99 billion ISK in 2007, which was about 7.6 percent of GDP) to Iceland's tax revenue, which produces a total ratio of 48.5 percent, only slightly below Denmark—the country with the highest tax ratio in the OECD (now including social security contributions for both countries).

3. This position of Iceland as a comparatively heavily taxed country comes out clearly when looking at the taxes levied on specific tax bases (excluding, of course, social security contributions) and implies that considerable care needs to be taken to ensure that any additional revenues are collected in the most efficient manner in order to avoid serious harm to the economy. Table 2 shows that the Icelandic ratio of income tax revenue (personal plus corporate) to GDP was 18.5 percent, which is within the Nordic range (16.9 percent to 29.0 percent) but well above the EU15 and OECD averages (14.0 percent and 13.2 percent). In addition, Iceland's revenue from consumption taxes was a higher proportion of GDP (16.5 percent) than any other Nordic country and was among the very highest for the OECD as a whole.3 This was due to both high VAT collections, which were the highest share of GDP in the OECD, and high levels of excise taxes. On a much smaller scale, it was also above other Nordic countries and the EU15 and OECD averages for the ratio of property taxes to GDP.

Table 2.

Ratios of Tax to GDP for Selected Countries, 2007

(In percent of)

article image
Source: OECD, Revenue Statistics, 1965–2008, © 2009.

This line does not include compulsory contributions to non-government (i.e., private) pension funds, since they are not taxes. In Iceland, these compulsory contributions to private pension funds amounted to 7.6 percent of GDP in 2007.

Tax rates

4. In common with Finland, Norway and Sweden, Iceland has a dual income tax system for personal incomes in which capital income is taxed at a flat rate that is lower than the (usually) progressive rates on labor income. Iceland's taxation of labor income was also based on a flat rate for a short period before the financial crisis, after which one and then another additional tax bracket were added. Progressivity of the earlier flat rate tax on labor income was achieved by a substantial personal tax credit.

5. The flat tax on capital income was 10 percent until the middle of 2009, when it was raised to 15 percent and then to 18 percent in 2010. This rate is low in comparison both to other Nordic countries and to the lowest Iceland rate on labor income. This low rate can partly be explained by the fact that, in contrast to other Nordic countries, there is no general deduction for interest paid (although there is a tax credit related to mortgage interest). Dividends are taxed at the same rate as interest and capital gains. The corporate tax rate was 15 percent in 2009 and was raised to 18 percent in 2010.

6. The main rate of value added tax (VAT) is 25.5 percent, recently raised from 24.5 percent, and is the highest rate in the OECD. There is also a lower rate of VAT of

7 percent on food and a number of other items. Table 3 provides a comparison of Iceland's VAT rates with other selected countries in recent years. It is particularly interesting that Denmark has a VAT rate similar to Iceland's but has no reduced rate. The excise duties on alcohol and tobacco are high by international standards, as is standard for Nordic countries, but the excise taxes on motor fuel are low by Nordic standards. There is also a relatively high excise duty on vehicle import. Like some other Nordic countries, there are also excises on selected food items.

7. The rate of recurrent taxation on residential property is set by municipalities but is typically close to the maximum 0.5 percent of market value, with other rates applying to other types of property including agricultural land. A new net wealth tax has recently been introduced with a rate of 1.25 percent that applies above the thresholds of 90 million ISK (single individual) or 120 million ISK (couples). There is also an inheritance tax of 5 percent with a threshold of one million ISK.

B. The Efficiency of the Tax System

Tax mix

8. In many respects, the tax mix in Iceland is consistent with the promotion of economic growth. It is generally accepted that income taxes (particularly corporate income taxes) are the most harmful for job creation, investment, and growth while consumption taxes and recurrent taxes on immovable property are the least harmful. Thus, compared to other Nordic countries, the relatively low share of income taxes and social security contributions (which have much the same effect on growth as income taxes) and the relatively high share of consumption taxes in Iceland can be expected to be good for growth.

Table 3.

VAT Rates in Selected Countries

article image
Source: OECD, Tax Database, © 2010.

9. It could be argued that the share of consumption taxes could still be increased. However, the standard rate of VAT is already the highest in the OECD and tax fraud and evasion could increase significantly if it were increased further. This suggests that the only consumption items that should be considered for additional taxation are those that are comparatively lightly taxed: the goods that are subject to the 7 percent VAT rate or exempted from VAT, vehicle fuels and natural resources (such as geothermal energy). An additional problem with increasing consumption taxes in Iceland is that long-term loans, such as housing finance, are generally indexed to the consumer price index. This means that any inflationary effect of consumption tax increases would increase the servicing burden of debtors, including those with mortgages.

10. In addition, the fairly high tax revenues from residential property taxes are less harmful to growth. Here, there is a stronger argument for increasing the tax. This is because Iceland is a small country with mobile capital and labor, which could migrate in response to tax increases. This makes the taxation of immovable property attractive from an efficiency point of view. It is worth noting that countries such as Canada, the UK and the US have considerably higher rates of residential property taxes.

Simplicity and stability

11. Iceland's tax system is very streamlined by OECD standards. There are minimal deductions from the labor income tax base, virtually none from the capital income tax base,4 and few special exemptions under the corporate tax. Even with the recent added complexity of the two additional income tax brackets and the introduction of a net wealth tax, the system fits very well with the ideal of ‘low rates and broad base’—a feature that explains to a large extent its high revenue productivity.

12. The most obvious area in which the effective base could be expanded would be by limiting the goods included in the reduced VAT band and raising that rate. In addition, that would clearly reduce complexity.

13. The more serious difficulties that businesses are experiencing with the tax system have to do with two aspects of the tax law. The first is that much of it is rather old and does not provide clear enough rules for the taxation of new arrangements, such as derivatives and other complex operations. The second is that the changes in the tax law at the end of 2009 that were designed to meet the pressing need for additional tax revenue have produced considerable surprises and complaints that the new provisions are not drafted with sufficient detail.

14. This is clearly related to the issue of stability, which is generally regarded as an important criterion for a good tax system. Tax systems do have to change with economic circumstances, but it is best if the changes can be announced well in advance and if there can be adequate time for consultation on the legislative drafting.

C. Fairness in the Tax System

15. Fairness is generally regarded as a crucial element of any tax system. However, the progressivity of the tax system should be seen as a whole rather than requiring each individual tax to be progressive. It is common to find a tax system with considerable overall progression that contains some taxes that are regressive. Typically, the progressivity of the labor income tax can compensate for the inequalities in other taxes that are required for efficiency reasons.

16. More generally, government policies achieve redistribution of income through both the tax system and the social benefit system. The redistribution that is achieved in selected OECD countries is shown in Table 4. This shows that, before the application of taxes and benefits, Iceland's inequality is very low in comparison to other countries, including other Nordic countries. However, its tax and benefit system does not achieve as much redistribution as other Nordic countries, and so the income inequality after taxes and benefits is at the high end of the range of Nordic countries, although still below the OECD average.

17. However, increasing the overall redistribution does not mean that Iceland's taxes need to be made substantially more progressive. Figure 1 (for which Icelandic data were not available5) shows that other Nordic countries have put more of the responsibility for redistribution on the benefit system and have chosen to finance the large public expenditures required by efficient but not particularly redistributive taxes.

18. Indeed, Figure 1 shows that the extent of redistribution across countries is closely associated to the redistribution achieved through the benefit system, while tax progressivity is relatively uncorrelated with overall redistribution through public policies. Effective redistribution through the benefit system, in turn, typically requires relatively high tax collections which results in tax systems geared towards revenue productivity rather than redistribution. This is partly because attempts to make the tax system progressive beyond a point erodes its revenue productivity and ultimately undermines the redistributive effectiveness of the overall public system. For example, Sweden achieves the highest percentage reduction of the Gini coefficient among all OECD countries (46 percent). However, the redistribution achieved through the Swedish tax system is below the OECD average. In contrast, the tax system of the United States is among the most redistributive, but the overall redistribution achieved through the combined effect of taxes and benefit policies is the second lowest in the OECD sample. In conclusion, the key role for Iceland's tax system in reducing inequality is to provide an efficient means of raising revenue to finance social benefits, rather than achieving a great deal of redistribution itself.

Table 4.

The Redistribution Produced by Taxes and Transfers

article image
Source: OECD, Growing Unequal, © 2008
Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Reduction in Inequality Due to Public Cash Transfers and Household Taxes

Point reduction in the concentration coefficient

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 213; 10.5089/9781455207947.002.A001

Source: OECD, Growing Unequal, © 2008

II. Corporate Income Tax (CIT)

19. The taxation of corporate profits in Iceland—a classical system—is generally in accordance with the systems that are found in other European countries. It is a consistent and efficient tax system that does not require major changes. There are specific aspects, however, where the current economic situation has brought to the surface some shortcomings related to the treatment of holding gains and losses, debt forgiveness, complex financial operations, and excessive leverage. This chapter deals with these topics, which probably apply primarily to relatively large corporations. Issues related to closely held corporations and incorporated self-employed workers, as well as to the CIT rate and its interaction with the PIT are covered below in a separate chapter, as they require the prior discussion of the PIT.

A. Financial Versus Tax Accounting

Issue

20. The income tax law currently does not contain any rule dealing with the status of the financial statements for tax purposes. However, in practice, principles of accounting seem to play a certain role in determining taxable profit. This leads—amongst other—to uncertainty about the tax treatment of derivatives, an artificial and too broad definition of interest, and an undue deferral of the recognition of capital gains and losses on some assets.

Analysis

21. In most OECD countries the financial statements are—to a various degree—used as starting point to determine taxable profit. Some countries (e.g., Austria, Germany, and Hungary) use a strict linkage between financial statements and tax accounts, whereas other countries are more liberal in allowing deviations between financial statements and tax accounts in specific cases.

22. The main argument to use financial statements as the starting point is that they measure ‘distributable’ profit; i.e., profit that is not necessary for continuation of the business activities. As Iceland has adopted—in line with other European countries—the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS), another advantage would be the use of an internationally accepted income concept familiar to most investors. Finally, the tax system would benefit from the international experience gained in financial accounting, especially regarding the treatment of derivatives and other complex operations that are currently poorly covered by the tax law.

Recommendation
  • Introduce the necessary provisions in the Income Tax Act that make the profit determined according to the financial statement the basis for the taxable profit, allowing only those deviations explicitly provided for in the Income Tax Act.

B. Capital Losses and Debt Forgiveness

Issues

23. Currently capital losses are only recognized upon realization. When recognized, they are ring-fenced and they cannot be offset against other income categories, such as income arising from debt forgiveness. Many corporations suffered significant capital losses during the crisis on their holdings of equity and other financial assets, to the extent that they are now in negotiations with creditors to restructure their debt. However, a successful completion of debt restructuring negotiations is hindered by the tax implications, as forgiven debt would give rise to taxable income that cannot be offset against the accounting losses.

Analysis

24. Financial accounting rules typically recognize capital gains and losses on portfolio financial assets when they accrue—e.g., by using a mark-to-market valuation or other fair value methods. The idea is that those assets—as opposed to fixed assets or stakes held for strategic long-term investment purposes—can be easily made liquid. Most European countries use—to some degree—accounting rules to value their assets for tax purposes. As a consequence, most capital gains are taxed and losses deducted even if not (yet) realized.

25. Furthermore, all European countries, except for the United Kingdom and Ireland, treat capital gains and ordinary profit in the same manner for tax purposes; i.e., capital losses can be used to absorb ordinary profit. This treatment is justified since corporations maximize overall profit, and can freely distribute it regardless whether it relates to ordinary income or capital gains.

26. By applying financial accounting valuation for tradable financial assets in combination with the tax treatment of capital losses as ordinary income, debt restructuring becomes neutral for tax purposes in most cases. Creditors will forgive debt only if the debtor cannot fulfill its liability due to accumulated losses. In that case, the debtor would recognize the forgiveness of debt as taxable income, but would be able to absorb it with the accumulated tax losses. Any part of the forgiven debt in excess of losses would be a genuine net income and would be subject to tax.

27. This treatment however would not resolve legacy cases. In these, losses were incurred in the past and were accounted for according to the current tax treatment—that is, they may not have resulted in tax losses eligible for offsetting the income from debt forgiveness. A satisfactory resolution of these cases requires a one-time transitional treatment, which should provide guarantees against abuse.

28. In cases where the debtor is an individual taxpayer, the tax authority appears inclined to exempt income from forgiveness of mortgage debt to the extent this does not result in a debt below the fair market price of the residence. Arguably, however, the tax authority could accept a tax exempt debt forgiveness income slightly higher, as lenders could go below the market value of the residence by the extent of their foreclosure and disposal expenses.

Recommendations

  • For companies, the income tax should follow the valuation provisions as used in the financial accounting rules.

  • The income tax should treat as ordinary profits capital gains and losses on business assets that are recognized in accordance with financial accounting rules. Consequently, income arising from debt forgiveness should be considered taxable income but would be offset against these losses. Income in excess of losses, if any, should be taxed.

  • A one-time transition mechanism should be adopted to allow the tax recognition of capital losses incurred during the crisis up to an amount commensurate to the income arising from debt forgiveness. This could be closely monitored and authorized by the tax administration on a case by case basis in accordance with publicly announced rules.

  • For individuals, the tax authority should exempt income from mortgage debt forgiveness up to the point where the debt is equal to the market value of the property reduced by reasonable foreclosure and sale costs to the lender.

C. Excessive Interest Deductions

Issue

29. The corporate tax system in Iceland, as in most countries, introduces a bias in favor of debt—as opposed to equity—financing. This is because in the hands of the corporation, profits are taxable while interest payments are deductible. The tax authorities consider that there are indications of excessive debt financing, often motivated by tax avoidance objectives—such as the high amount of loss carry forward6 and highly leveraged takeovers followed by reversed acquisitions.7

30. At present, the tax authorities' only possibility to confront these practices is by using either the arm's length provision (article 57 ITA) or the anti-avoidance concept developed in case law. Neither of these approaches seemed to be effectively applicable in Iceland and the authorities consider that their capacity to challenge and prevent thin capitalization practices should be strengthened.

31. Within OECD countries, apart from the arm's length test (mainly used in the Nordic countries) one can distinguish two other main methods of protection against excessive debt financing (Table 5): the debt-to-equity ratio test, and the earnings test. Both place a cap on the amount of interest that can be deducted for tax purposes from the taxable base. In the discussion below, it is assumed that interest is computed based on IFRS (as recommended above) and therefore it does not include foreign exchange gains and losses, as it currently does in Iceland for tax purposes. Also under both methods, financial institutions should be exempt from the caps on interest deductibility. A related approach to resolve the bias towards debt financing—the introduction of an Allowance for Corporate Equity (ACE)—is described in a later chapter of this report. It is not recommended at this time as it would likely have a negative revenue impact, as discussed in the corresponding chapter.

32. The debt to equity ratio test disallows any interest deduction on the part of the debt financing deemed excessive. This excessive part is established by the ratio between debt and equity. Any disallowed interest expense is not allowed to be carried forward. Countries applying this approach typically use an across-the-board debt-to-equity ratio. This approach has some disadvantages as it does not reflect the actual debt-to-equity ratios in the various industries. Another disadvantage is that the debt-to-equity ratio will be unstable due to indexation as the valuation of liabilities—and of equity (through the valuation of financial assets)—may fluctuate. The ratio depends further on whether equity is calculated on fair market value (requires a more narrow ratio) or tax value. If equity—as a result of accumulated losses—becomes negative, additional rules are needed. Also, the corporation could manipulate its equity around the test date in order to increase the allowed deduction. Finally, the limitation of the debt-to-equity test to related parties requires some anti-avoidance rules regarding back-to-back loans and guarantees. The advantage of this test is that it is fairly predictable: corporations have in advance a good idea of how much debt they can take before breaching the test.

33. The earnings test limits the amount of deductible interest expense as a percentage of earnings before interest costs and tax (EBIT) or earnings before interest costs, tax, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA). This approach normally allows first the reduction of interest expenses up to the interest income received in the same year. In addition, any net interest expense—i.e., the excess interest expense over the interest received in the same year—is deductible up to a percentage of the EBIT. Often, the latitude for net interest expenses is broadened by using the EBITDA. Any non-deductible net interest expenses can be carried forward indefinitely. This rule is used in Germany and Italy, and it is being considered in the Netherlands. To prevent administrative difficulties and avoidance, the ratio of allowed interest to earnings is the same across industries as in the above mentioned debt-to-equity test. This method could create difficulties in businesses with unusually volatile profits, which would see some legitimate interest costs disallowed in low-profit years and would be well below their allowed cap in good-profit years. A sufficiently generous limit (as when using EBITDA, for example) and the carry-forward provision, however, would mitigate this shortcoming. On the other hand, the allowable interest deduction ceiling is more uncertain ex ante than in the debt-to-equity test, as it is only known after profits are realized and the income statement is drawn.

Table 5.

Thin Capitalization Rules

article image
article image
Source: Database Europe - Corporate Taxation, International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, © 2010, Amsterdam

Recommendation

  • A thin capitalization provision based on either the debt-to-equity ratio or the earnings test should be introduced. An earnings test based on EBITDA is possibly preferable due to its simplicity and lower potential for avoidance.

D. Interest Payments Abroad

Issue

34. Iceland is confronted with an erosion of its corporate tax base by interest paid to creditors resident in low tax jurisdictions.

Analysis

35. Since 2010 Iceland levies a 15 percent withholding tax on interest payments to safeguard its corporate tax base. Most of the double tax treaties concluded by Iceland with other European countries reduce this withholding to 0 percent or provide for a tax credit.8 If the creditor is a resident of a tax haven country, the withholding tax is a final tax. In practice, the tax incidence of this withholding tax lies often with the debtor (including because contractual stipulations) and results in higher costs on borrowings from abroad. In the current economic situation, such increased finance costs are a hindrance to improving the investment climate.

36. The Nordic countries and some EU countries do not levy a withholding tax on interest paid to a nonresident company. A substantial number of European countries, however, levy withholding tax on interest payments to nonresident companies. They refrain from doing so only in cases where the Interest and Royalties Directive applies (Table 6).9

37. Thin capitalization rules alone may not be sufficient to avoid capital stripping to low tax jurisdictions. Some European countries—amongst which Belgium, France, Spain, and Italy—have provisions that disallow the deduction of interest paid if the creditor is resident in a low tax jurisdiction. A low tax jurisdiction could be defined as either a country with a lower nominal tax rate than 70 percent of the domestic nominal tax rate (for Iceland this would mean a rate of 12.5 percent, i.e.70 percent of 18 percent) or a country with a lower nominal tax rate than the lowest in a certain region (for the EU this would mean a rate of 10 percent, i.e. the nominal rate applicable in Cyprus and Bulgaria), or by issuing a black list.

Table 6.

Withholding Tax on Interest Paid Abroad

article image
Source: Database Europe - Corporate Taxation, International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, © 2010, Amsterdam

Recommendation

  • The 15 percent withholding tax on interest payments to residents in treaty countries should be waived or reduced (as provided by the treaty) at source, using pre-certification of residence. This would make unnecessary for the creditor to request an ex post refund.

  • The authorities could consider disallowing the deduction of interest payments made to residents in a low tax country.

E. Intercompany Dividends

Issues

38. The tax treatment of intercompany dividends received by a parent company resident in Iceland is inconsistent with European practice. Furthermore, the tax treatment is potentially restrictive for legitimate long-term strategic investments in large companies by investors resident in Iceland.

Analysis

39. Currently dividends received from domestic and foreign subsidiaries are included in the tax base. A relief for double taxation of these dividends is provided for in the form of a deduction, if the parent company holds at least 10 percent of the capital in a subsidiary that is:

  • a public limited company, a private limited company, or a partnership resident in Iceland;

  • a similar type of company that is liable to tax and is resident in another country of the European Economic Area (EEA); or

  • a public limited company registered in another country and is taxed abroad in a similar manner as it would be if it were a resident company in Iceland.

40. The deduction of intercompany dividends may not give relief for double taxation in cases of loss carry forward. As the carry forward of losses is effectuated as a deduction, it will potentially reduce the base from which to deduct intercompany dividends. This will especially be the case as long as Iceland does not have an unlimited carry forward of losses. Therefore, subsidiaries may want to refrain from any dividend distribution to their Icelandic parent company as long as it has carry-forward losses.

41. In European countries the double taxation on intercompany dividends is typically eliminated either by an exemption or by a credit for the underlying corporate income tax. Most countries choose for an exemption of the dividends received,10 whereby they may add back a small percentage of the dividend received as compensation for related expenses.

42. The introduction of a threshold of 10 percent of the shareholding is based on the intention to distinguish between portfolio and strategic business investments, whereby only the latter will enjoy a relief for double taxation. However, an investment in a large corporation may not meet the minimum shareholding requirement, but nevertheless be considered a strategic long-term investment by the investing company.

43. In all Nordic countries a threshold of 10 percent of the shareholding is used (Table 7). This requirement is based on the Parent-Subsidiary Directive,11 which allows member states to have a minimum shareholding requirement not in excess of 10 percent. In Belgium and Luxembourg an additional alternative requirement for the intercompany dividend relief can be used. A parent company is eligible for this relief, if one of the following requirements is met: (i) holding—directly or indirectly—a capital participation of at least 10 per cent, or (ii) holding a minimum participation with an acquisition cost of at least EUR 1.2 million. In Iceland, this additional requirement could also be used with an appropriate threshold to facilitate long-term strategic investments in other companies.

Table 7.

Intercompany Dividends in Nordic Countries

article image
Source: Database Europe - Corporate Taxation, International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, © 2010, Amsterdam

Recommendations

  • The participation deduction should be reformed into a participation exemption, bringing the tax treatment of intercompany dividends in line with other European countries.

  • The income tax should be amended to add to the current threshold of 10 percent shareholding a second (alternative) threshold in the form of a fixed amount of investment—calibrated to the specific situation in Iceland.

F. Loss Carry Forward

Issue

44. The high loss carry forward position of Icelandic business—as discussed before the loss carry forward reported in 2007 exceeded 150 percent of corporate tax revenue—may result in a substantial loss of revenue in the near future. Further limitation of the carry forward in time is being discussed.

Analysis

45. The possibility to carry forward losses for tax purposes mitigates tax disincentives to invest in businesses with volatile profits. Given the Icelandic economic circumstances, this is a necessary feature of the tax system. Any further limitation of the carry forward period may result in weakening the competitiveness of its business environment. It would also bring Iceland out of line compared to some of its major trading partners and competitors for capital (Table 8). Information on how Iceland compares with other OECD countries regarding the total amount of the loss carry forward is not available.

Table 8.

Operational Losses

article image
Source: Database Europe - Corporate Taxation, International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, © 2010, Amsterdam

Recommendation

  • Maintain the current 10-year period of loss carry forward.

G. Investment Incentives

Issue

46. Investment incentives—including tax reductions and potentially tax holidays—are currently being considered. Beneficiaries would qualify if they meet certain requirements, including a minimum turnover of ISK 300 million (approx. US$ 2.3 million). The incentives could be obtained for investments in an area that covers almost the entire geographical area of Iceland, including areas close to Reykjavik.

Analysis

47. Incentives of this type typically distort the tax system since they create low tax areas that easily attract taxable profits from other areas rather than greenfield investment. On the medium term this would make it difficult to maintain the relative high level of taxation and compliance. In addition, the proposed incentives are not well targeted to attract major investment projects that would not take place otherwise and that play a key role in the growth prospects of the Icelandic economy.

Recommendation

  • The investment incentives should not be adopted. If this is not feasible, the annual turnover requirement should be increased drastically in order to cover only very large investments of strategic value.

III. Personal Income Tax (PIT) and Direct Taxes on Individuals

A. Allocating Labor and Capital Income within Closely Held Businesses

Issue

48. The most salient problem with Iceland's dual income tax is misallocation of labor and capital income within closely held businesses.12 Because dual income tax systems tax income at different rates depending on whether it is generated by labor or capital, they require special rules for allocating income from closely-held companies whose owners contribute both capital and labor. In Iceland, this is done by stipulating that owner-employees attribute to themselves an “arm's-length wage.” Minimum imputed wages for owner-employees in different sectors and sizes of companies are published each year by the Finance Ministry. Closely held companies, whether they are sole proprietors, partnerships, or corporations, must impute wages for their owners and any family members working for the business. Imputed wages are subject to PAYE withholding, social security tax and compulsory pension savings.

49. For sole proprietorships, all income including residual profits is taxed at the relatively high personal income tax rates of 37.2–46.1 percent; only imputed wages are used to calculate withholding tax for this type of business. Residual profits of partnerships are subject to a special partnership tax rate, which is equal to the compound CIT and capital income tax rates. In 2008, with the CIT at 15 percent and the capital tax at 10 percent, the partnership rate was 23.5 percent (= 0.15 + (1-0.15)*0.10). In 2010, as the CIT and capital income tax were both raised to 18 percent, the partnership tax rate was raised to 32.7 percent.

54. This advantageous tax regime for corporate profits and partnership income relative to labor income appears to have resulted in an explosion in the number of incorporated small businesses. By 2009, there were 30,162 corporate enterprises in Iceland—almost one per 10 inhabitants. For 2010, the authorities limited this tax-favored treatment of dividends by closely held corporations to 20 percent of net equity capital. Distributions in excess of this amount are split 50/50 between capital and labor income for tax purposes. Distributions attributed to labor are subject to social security as well as personal income taxes, and are deductible to the corporation in the current year. Introduction of this law in 2009 seems to have produced corporate conversions into partnerships.

Analysis

55. The current system of imputing labor income on the basis of government-specified minimum wages appears unsatisfactory. Returns to labor in small businesses can vary widely depending on proprietors' skills, effort and preferences in ways that are difficult to measure. Current imputed wage levels appear low and have not been raised since 2007 despite a more than 35 percent increase in the CPI over that period. For example, a professional (such as a doctor or lawyer) with more than 15 employees has imputed annual wages of ISK 8.7 million per year (US$ 67,000), likely considerably less than such person could expect to earn in the private sector. The wave of incorporations since 1996 and the high overall number of corporations relative to the population (combined with the dearth of partnerships and sole proprietorships prior to 2010) suggest that the current income-splitting rules are viewed as highly advantageous and widely used for tax planning purposes.

56. A more effective method of allocating profits between labor and capital in closely held businesses is to ascribe capital income on the basis of a company's assets. Some variation of this method is used by other Nordic countries with dual income taxes. Sorensen (2007) and Cnossen (1999) describe the two principal methods for calculating capital income (Table 9):

  • Under the gross assets method, an imputed return to assets is computed by multiplying total business assets by a reasonable rate of return on equity (“R”), typically the intermediate-maturity government bond yield plus a moderate risk premium, or the interest rate on prime business loans. Labor income is the difference between pre-tax net profits (including owner's salary) plus interest paid and the imputed return to assets. Taxable profits (capital income) are the imputed return on assets less interest paid.

  • Under the net assets method, an imputed return on equity is computed by multiplying net equity (total assets less debt) by the reasonable rate of return defined as above. Labor income is the difference between net profits (including owner's salary) and the imputed return on equity. Taxable profits (capital income) are the imputed return on equity.

If a business has no (or only trivial) assets, then all income will be ascribed to labor, as is appropriate. If R is the same as the interest rate charged on business debt, then the two methods are equivalent. Under either method, businesses can of course deduct the computed labor income as wage expense.

Table 9.

Methods for Allocating Business Income Between Capital and Labor

article image
R = reasonable rate of return on equity, e.g. prime loan rate

57. The gross and net asset methods have different strengths and weaknesses. The net assets method requires more elaborated accounting provisions to compute net assets and offers more opportunities for tax planning, typically requiring anti-avoidance rules. The gross asset method is simpler. But if R is greater than the interest rate paid on business debt, then companies have an incentive to undertake debt-financed investment (even if with a low return) in order to increase the share of their profits allocated to lower-taxed capital income.

58. Switching from an allocation formula according to which residual income is ascribed to capital to one that ascribes residual income to labor will reverse the marginal income tax rates faced by closely held businesses. Instead of high labor income tax rates on their initial income and lower capital income tax rates on their subsequent income, businesses will face the low capital tax rate for initial income and the higher labor tax rate for subsequent income. Thus their marginal rate will be low in low-income years and high in more profitable years. Switching to allocation of income based on assets is not expected to reduce revenues, but is also unlikely to increase them significantly in the near term.

Recommendation

  • Allocate revenue in closely held businesses according to either the net or gross assets methods. The gross assets method would be preferable as it offers less opportunity for tax arbitrage. This income splitting regime should apply to both closely held corporations and partnerships.

B. Increasing Revenue and Progressivity

Issue

59. In 2010, revenue considerations and a desire to increase tax progressivity led the authorities to increase both labor and capital income tax rates. In 2009, they raised the basic labor income tax rate from 35.72 to 37.2 percent, and in 2010 introduced two surcharges of 2.9 percent on incomes above ISK 2.4 million and 6 percent on incomes above ISK 7.8 million. The authorities also raised the capital income tax rate from 10 percent to 15 percent in mid-2009 and to 18 percent in 2010. They also introduced two additional allowances: one for the first ISK 100,000 (US$ 770) of interest income and another for 30 percent of the income from the renting of residential property. Finally, a net wealth tax was adopted. This tax has a rate of 1.25 percent and applies to net wealth (real estate and capital assets less debt) in excess of ISK 90 million (US$ 692,000) for individuals and ISK 120 million (US$923,000) for couples.

60. Further tax changes are being discussed including a possible switch to a comprehensive income tax, under which both labor and capital income would be taxed at progressive rates. To offset the resulting higher tax burden on real capital income due to inflation, the authorities have concomitantly considered reducing the taxable interest and capital gains by some proportional allowance in order to avoid taxing inflationary returns. Important considerations with respect to this decision include the tax elasticity of the capital income tax base and the effect of inflation on real tax rates on capital.

Analysis

61. Since the early 1980s, all of the Nordic countries have introduced dual income tax systems,13 which have the common feature of taxing capital income at a lower, uniform rate than the progressive rate levied on labor income. Because capital income is increasingly mobile across international boundaries, it is more difficult than labor income to tax at high progressive rates. The Nordic countries thus found that by lowering tax rates on capital income, they actually increased their revenue collections. Low, uniform rates on capital income also serve to encourage savings, to discourage tax arbitrage among different types of capital income, and to reduce the “lock-in” effect of capital gains taxation and mitigate the taxation of compensation for inflation.

62. Taxation of capital income in Iceland is complicated by the country's high and volatile inflation rate, derived in large part from exchange rate volatility. Since 1990, Iceland has had average annual inflation rate of almost 5 percent, with a standard deviation of 3.5 percent. When a substantial portion of the nominal return on assets represents compensation for inflation, as is typically the case with interest income, taxation based on nominal income can magnify the tax burden on the real return.14 Critics of the recent increase in capital income tax rates argue that, while gross investment income taxation at 10 percent was acceptable to most investors, significantly higher rates (even the current 18 percent) foment political pressure to shift the tax base to net or real investment income. The pressure to create exemptions in the presence of higher rates can be gauged from the creation of an ISK 100,000 interest exclusion that accompanied the recent capital income tax rate increase from 10 to 18 percent.

63. Iceland's capital income tax base is viewed as sensitive to tax rates, particularly at the high end of the income spectrum. Discussions with different experts indicate that individuals with about ISK 100 million or more in financial assets (that is, in the top one percent of the population in terms of assets) could profitably move those assets offshore. Investigations and official reports in the wake of the financial crisis underpin the broadly held view capital flight has taken place, at least in the recent past, despite the low then prevailing capital income tax rate of 10 percent, but naturally, no data on those holdings is available.15 Existing foreign exchange controls would forestall capital flight in reaction to higher capital taxes in the near term, but they will eventually be repealed. It is more difficult for less wealthy individuals to avoid taxes on income paid out by financial intermediaries; however, higher capital tax rates would exacerbate incentives for underreporting income.

64. Switching from a dual income tax to a comprehensive income tax would raise the basic capital income tax rate almost 20 percentage points to 37.2 percent, and the top marginal tax rate on capital income almost 30 points to 46.1 percent. Combined with effects of inflation, these rates would eliminate most of the real return on interest income (which accounted for 55 percent of total capital income reported in 2008). Accompanying this increase in rates with a partial exclusion or indexation for inflation would of course reduce the effective tax rate on capital income, though at the cost of reducing any expected revenue gain and, crucially, increasing the complexity, compliance costs, and avoidance opportunities of the tax system. Based on 2008 tax data, two-thirds of financial income was reported by the top ten percent of taxpayers in terms of income, whose capital income would likely be subject to the top rate. These taxpayers are the most likely to have access to offshore vehicles and other tax avoidance mechanisms. It is thus likely that shifting to a comprehensive income tax would fail to raise any significant revenue, particularly if it necessitated a partial exclusion or indexation of capital income, and might even reduce it.

65. There is, however, room to further increase progressivity by increasing labor and capital income tax rates somewhat without losing the positive features of Iceland's dual income tax or bringing tax rates out of line with other Nordic countries. The following covers potential changes to the progressive personal income tax schedule that applies to labor income, while the following chapter discusses the taxation of capital income at both the personal and corporate level.

66. Iceland's basic tax credit of ISK 530,466 (US$ 4,080), which at the basic labor income tax rate of 37.2 percent shields ISK 1.4 million (US$ 11,000), is high by Nordic standards (Table 10). In 2007, it equaled approximately 28 percent of average wage income. By comparison, Norway had the closest ratio at 16–24 percent, but other countries were significantly lower. Denmark had a ratio of 12–14 percent, Sweden 4–9 percent, and Finland 2–3 percent. Almost forty percent of taxpayers fall into this initial zero-rate bracket (although many of these are the very young, since Iceland requires tax filing from the age of 16).

67. Iceland's initial rate of personal income tax of 37.2 percent—comprising the central government rate of 24.1 percent and the local government average rate of 13.1 percent—is also high by Nordic standards. Sweden, Finland and Norway have initial rates of approximately 28 percent. Although Iceland's labor participation rate is high, this large initial rate could potentially discourage low-skilled workers from employment or divert them into the informal economy. Given the comparatively high initial income exemption and tax rate, further increases in progressivity should not be sought by increasing the basic tax credit or the initial 37.2 percent tax rate.

68. The first income tax bracket of individuals subject to a 37.2 percent marginal rate is extremely narrow, comprising only about 11,000 taxpayers or about 4 percent. The first surcharge of 2.9 percent is moreover a fairly low rate increment. The narrowness of the bracket and the low rate of the surcharge are almost tantamount to raising the basic rate by 2.9 percent, which is undesirable given the high initial rate. The second surcharge of 6 percent also affects a very small population of taxpayers—again, about 11,000 or 4 percent of all taxpayers—although this group accounts for a disproportionate share of labor income (slightly more than 10 percent).

Table 10.

Comparison of Nordic Dual Income Tax Systems

(In percent of)

article image
Source: OECD Taxing Wages (2008), Sorensen (2007)

69. A simpler and more progressive rate structure would be to levy a single higher surcharge of 10 percent on all individuals with at least ISK 4.5 million (US$ 35,000) in wage income. This would raise approximately 0.25 percent of GDP in additional revenue and increase progressivity. If the government desires to retain three tax brackets and raise more revenue, the lower surcharge threshold could be raised to ISK 3 million (US$ 23,000) and the surcharge rate be raised to 5 percent, while the higher surcharge threshold could be lowered to ISK 6 million (US$ 46,000) and the surcharge rate lowered to 5 percent. This alternative raises about 0.43 percent of GDP but is slightly less progressive than the single-rate alternative because it does not relieve as many lower-income individuals from the first surcharge.

70. The net wealth tax introduced in 2010 is similar to an increased marginal tax rate on high capital income. A wealth tax is tantamount to an income tax levied on an imputed rate of income generated by capital assets. At the prevailing capital income tax rate of 18 percent, a 1.25 percent wealth tax implies an imputed rate of return on assets of 7 percent (0.07*0.18 = 0.0125). The new tax thus implies a total tax rate of 36 percent on taxpayers with very high net assets, who comprise less than one percent of the population (but hold 20 percent of net assets and receive 10 percent of income, approximately). The authorities expect that this tax will raise ISK 3.5 billion (US$27 million) per year.

71. Financial experts cite several criticisms of the new wealth tax, which requires valuation of business equity based on Icelandic fiscal accounting. Taxpayers with shareholdings in non-traded companies can find their equity difficult to value, particularly if those companies hold shares in other non-traded companies carried at book value. This difficulty could be addressed by allowing shareholders to value their equities at current book value, regardless of whether they hold shares in other companies. Payment of the tax could also potentially cause liquidity problems where assets are not readily fungible; however, most high-net-wealth individuals also have substantial income and/or liquid assets.

72. At the other end of the wealth spectrum, the new exemption for up to ISK 100,000 of interest income creates a zero-bracket rate for capital income. The cost of this tax expenditure in 2010 will be approximately ISK 2 billion (US$ 15 million). These marginal changes at the very low and very high ends of the capital income tax do not greatly undermine its simplicity and integrity, but the authorities should refrain from introducing additional complexity, which could encourage financial arbitrage and/or capital flight.

73. Further, due to the high concentration of capital among high-income taxpayers, a flat proportional tax on capital income is inherently progressive. The Gini coefficient for capital income in Iceland, 0.42, is markedly higher than the Gini coefficient for labor income, 0.33. The top 50 percent of taxpayers receive about 80 percent of capital income, and the top 10 percent receive about 65 percent. Thus a progressive rate structure is not necessary in order to render capital income taxation progressive.

74. The social security tax, which funds unemployment insurance as well as some redistributive benefits, was raised from 5.34 percent to 8.65 percent in response to the increase in the unemployment rate resulting from the financial crisis. An increase in social security tax is justified to maintain the solvency of the unemployment and basic pension funds. To the extent that higher income groups receive more of their income from capital than lower-income groups, however, an increase in proportional taxes on labor income is regressive. The long-run incidence of an increase in wage taxes will be on workers, as real wages fall to offset the additional cost to employers. In the short run, the incidence may fall on employers locked into wage agreements, reducing employment growth. Therefore, considerations of both equity and job creation advise the eventual reduction of the social security tax rate when revenue pressures abate.

75. The current treatment of mortgage interest is inconsistent with the principles of income taxation, according to which interest would be deductible, but owner-occupiers would be taxed on commensurate imputed rents. As Iceland allows a tax credit for mortgage interest without rent imputation, its tax code encourages overconsumption of housing. If the purpose of the mortgage interest tax credit is to stimulate homeownership among segments of the population that would not otherwise be able to afford a house, then it does not fulfill this role efficiently: In 2008, almost 50 percent of mortgage tax credits went to taxpayers with above-median income, and despite means testing 10 percent went to individuals in the top 20 percent of the income distribution.

76. Clearly, in the current situation, in which approximately 40 percent of mortgage holders owe more than the market value of their houses, curtailing the mortgage tax credit could cause undesirable hardship. However, in order to prevent the tax code from encouraging future real estate market bubbles, the mortgage credit should be phased out or limited to low-income first-time buyers when incomes and housing values recover. Alternatively, owner-occupiers could be taxed on imputed rent, but given the administrative complexity that it entails, elimination or reduction of the mortgage interest credit is the simpler solution.

77. The current method of taxing rental income, which subjects 70 percent of gross rental income to the standard capital tax, offers administrative simplicity. The 30 percent exclusion constitutes a standard deduction for rental-related expenses. Given the simplicity of Iceland's business code, proprietors with substantially higher expenses have the option of placing their rental property within a business in order to take advantage of those deductions.

Recommendations

Near-term
  • Retain the dual income tax.

  • Do not raise the basic tax credit or initial tax rate.

  • If needed, to increase progressivity and raise revenue, introduce a single 10 percent surcharge on incomes above ISK 4.5 million.

  • Simplify net wealth tax by allowing the use of financial accounting valuations.

Medium-term
  • Reduce social security tax rate as budgetary pressures decline.

  • Phase out the mortgage interest deduction over time for all but low-income, first-time home buyers.

IV. Capital Income Taxation and Corporate Integration

Issue

78. With the objective of raising revenue in a progressive manner, the government has raised tax rates not only on labor and personal capital income, but on corporations as well, having increased the CIT rate from 15 to 18 percent in 2010.16 There is some leeway to increase these rates further, based on their level in comparison to other Nordic countries. In choosing how to raise them, the relative elasticity of personal savings and foreign investment should be taken into account, as well as their relationship to labor income tax rates.

79. While interest, dividends and capital gains are currently taxed at a uniform rate at the individual level, their disparate treatment at the corporate level, where interest is deductible, provides a tax advantage for debt over equity finance that Iceland may wish to reduce in the medium term in order to discourage excessive leverage.

Analysis

80. Relative to other Nordic countries, Iceland's CIT and capital income tax rates, at 18 percent, are comparatively low. Finland, Norway and Sweden have CIT rates of 26–28 percent (commensurate with their 28–30 percent personal capital income tax rates). Iceland's current CIT rate is similar to that of other small, open European economies, and neighbor Ireland has a low 12.5 percent rate.

81. Under a classic dual income tax, the tax on capital income is set equal to the lowest tax rate on labor income. This reduces the incentive to misallocate labor and capital income for moderately profitable companies. Whereas in most Nordic countries, capital income from unincorporated enterprises is subject only to individual-level capital taxation, Iceland's tax regime wisely harmonizes the tax rate on profits from private corporations and partnerships by subjecting partnership profits to a special tax rate equal to the compound rate on CIT and personal capital income: 0.327 = 0.18 + (1−0.18)*0.18.17 It is therefore this rate, rather than the personal capital tax rate, that should ideally be equalized with the lowest tax on labor income. Since the current combined corporate and individual rate on capital income is 32.7 percent, while the lowest tax rate on labor income is 37.2 percent, some combination of higher CIT and capital income tax rates could narrow or eliminate this gap, raising the combined tax rate on capital income by up to 4.5 percentage points.

82. The relative increase in the CIT and capital income tax rates should depend inversely on the elasticity of their bases. Generally, it is believed that capital income can be taxed more easily at the personal level than the corporate level. Multinational corporations responsible for much foreign direct investment (FDI) allocate resources internationally partly in response to tax differentials, and even domestic corporations can often strip income out of high-tax jurisdictions using debt and offshore vehicles. Conversely, individuals are viewed as being less internationally mobile. However, several experts and academics consider FDI in Iceland to be fairly tax insensitive, being attracted by low energy costs and other natural resources. At the same time, Iceland's high net worth individuals—a very small share of the population, but a substantial share of capital income—are viewed as being quite tax sensitive.

83. Given the uncertainty regarding the elasticity of the two bases, there is an argument for preserving the current equality of the CIT and personal capital income tax rates. When the two rates are equal, there is not a significant incentive for individuals to set up personal investment corporations to hold their capital assets (accumulating undistributed profits), rather than be taxed on their income as individuals. To equalize the combined capital and basic labor tax rates at 37.2 percent, the CIT and capital income rates could be raised up to 20.75 percent each. This report suggests as an option a more modest increase of two percentage points each, to 20 percent. This increase in the CIT rate is estimated to raise about 0.13 percent of GDP, while the similar increase in the capital income tax is estimated to raise about 0.3 percent of GDP.

84. Although income from debt and equity is subject to the same tax rate at the personal level (as is appropriate for preventing financial arbitrage), their disparate treatment at the corporate level, where interest but not profits are deductible, creates a tax advantage for debt finance. Under the current system, the total tax rate on dividends and capital gains is 32.7 percent (although the effective rate on capital gains may be reduced by deferral, since they are taxed on realization even at the corporate level), while for interest income it is only 18 percent. Reduction of this disparity would discourage excessive reliance on debt finance by Icelandic businesses in the future.

85. In order to ensure the financial neutrality of the tax regime, a pure dual income tax system would equalize the total tax rate on debt and equity income. This can be done either by reducing the taxation of dividends and capital gains on shares at the individual level (to offset the deductibility of interest at the corporate level), or by equalizing their treatment at the corporate level by introduction of a modified allowance for corporate equity (ACE).

86. Methods for equalizing the total taxation of capital income at the individual level include dividend imputation or exclusion and a step up in the basis for capital gains based on retained earnings. Under dividend imputation, individual taxpayers receive a tax credit for corporate income taxes paid on earnings distributed as dividends. The full pre-CIT value of the dividend is included in their taxable capital income, and their tax liability is reduced by the value of the prepaid CIT. To alleviate the double-taxation of capital gains, shareholders can be allowed to increase the basis of their shares each year by the amount of total retained earnings on which CIT has been paid. One caveat regarding this system is that the European Court of Justice has ruled that, unless dividend tax credits are extended to foreign as well as domestic shareholders, dividend imputation interferes with the free movement of capital. Most EU members that had imputation schemes have therefore shifted to a less accurate system of relief based on partial dividend exclusion, whereby only a percentage (fixed across all taxpayers) of dividend income is included in taxable income.

87. Rather than breaking the symmetry of capital income taxation at the individual level, introducing opportunities for tax arbitrage, a better solution may be equalizing (or narrowing) the treatment of debt by introduction of a modified ACE. The modified ACE provides a deduction for a normal return on assets (both equity and debt financed) calculated as assets times a “normal rate of return” (for example the rate on medium-term government bonds). Returns on equity (profits) and interest payments in excess of the normal return are taxed. This removes from the corporate tax base the opportunity cost of equity capital. It requires an increase (potentially large) in the nominal tax rate to maintain the same revenue yield. On the face of it, an ACE would radically redistribute the burden of taxation between different companies—those earning below the average return on assets gaining and those with a higher rate of return losing. Notice that the modified ACE would address the issue of excessive debt financing, thin capitalization, and excessive interest deductions discussed in the CIT chapter of this report. At present, only Belgium in the EU has an ACE applied only to equity returns (interest is deductible under standard rules). The creditability of this type of tax for foreign investors in their home country is subject to uncertainty.

Recommendations:

  • If additional revenue is needed, increase both CIT and capital income tax rates to 20 percent.

  • Over the medium term, consider reducing the double taxation of dividends and capital gains by introducing a modified ACE.

V. Value Added Tax (VAT)

88. The value added tax (VAT) in Iceland is a very productive tax. In 2008, it raised a higher proportion of GDP than in any other OECD country, despite the fact that, at that time, it did not have quite the highest VAT rate in the OECD. Nonetheless, Iceland's VAT does contain some inefficiencies, and the removal of some of these could raise substantial revenues. The main of these inefficiencies are the reduced rate, exemptions, and the treatment of unrecoverable input VAT for local authorities.

A. The Reduced Rate

Issue

89. VAT is ideally a tax on all consumption expenditure at a uniform rate that results in minimal distortion. The use of lower VAT rates on specific goods and services moves away from this ideal, introducing economic distortions, complicating the administration of the tax and losing revenue. Nonetheless, many countries have lower rates in the belief that it helps lower income families who spend a particularly high proportion of their incomes on these goods.

Analysis

90. The general argument against lower rates is that they provide a larger absolute reduction in tax for those on higher incomes and so is poorly targeted on lower income families; it would be better to subject all goods and services to the main VAT and use some of the resulting extra revenue to increase social benefits. In the specific case of Iceland, data from the household survey indicate that the percentage of expenditure on the items covered by the reduced rate is 22.3 percent for those in the bottom quarter of the income distribution as compared to 21.4 percent in the population as a whole. That is, the share of expenditure on low-rate goods among the poor is not significantly higher than among the total population—making the redistributive value of the low rate likely negligible.

91. The results indicate that the cost to those in the bottom quartile of increasing the VAT on these goods to 25.5 percent is 3.85 percent of their expenditure as compared to 3.70 percent for the population as a whole; a very small difference. The estimated consequences of moving towards a uniform VAT are shown in Table 11.

92. This removal of the lower rate of VAT would raise about 1.8 percent of GDP. Although the burden of this increase would only be slightly regressive, we propose that one third of this be used to finance an increase in income-tested benefits such as the child tax credit and means-tested pensions in order to protect those on lower incomes. The overall package would then be to increase both revenue and progressivity.

93. When additional revenue needs become less pressing, some of the funds could be used to reduce the main rate of VAT (thus reducing the incentives for fraud and evasion that currently exist).

Table 11.

Revenue and Price Effects of VAT Reforms

(In percent of)

article image
Source: IMF staff © 2010

94. If such an increase is too difficult to implement in a single step, a second-best option would be take a first step by restricting the lower rate to food items (excluding for example restaurant meals) and to reverse the reduction in the lower rate that was implemented a few years ago, increasing the lower rate to 14 percent. This would have a smaller distributional effect but still raise about 1.1 percent of GDP in additional revenue (0.7 percent from increasing the lower rate and 0.4 percent from moving non-food items to the 25.5 percent rate). In order to make this proposal progressive, we suggest that over a quarter of this additional revenue be used to finance increased income-tested benefits.

95. It is recognized that such increases in consumption taxation can be expected to increase the consumer price index and so increase the mortgage servicing costs to homeowners. However, any tax increase is likely to lead to price increases at some point in the future.

Recommendation

  • Move to a single rate of VAT. Ideally, this would be achieved in a single step. However, if necessary, it could be staged, with a first step that raises the reduced rate back to 14 percent and restricts it to food. These changes should be accompanied of a compensation package for the low income sectors of the population, which indicatively could represent between a quarter and a third of the revenue gain.

B. The Exemptions

Issue

96. Iceland has a number of VAT exemptions that go beyond those included in the EU VAT Directive: sports, passenger transport, authors, composers, burials and travel agents.

Analysis

97. The general arguments both for and against exemptions are usually similar to those for a reduced rate of VAT. However, there is an additional argument against exemptions, which is that it can break the refund chain if any of the exempt services are purchased by businesses.

98. In the case of Iceland, there is no distributional argument for these exemptions as those in the lowest quartile spend a smaller proportion of their expenditure on these items (7.5 percent) that does the population as a whole (8.3 percent). It is hard to estimate exactly how much additional revenue would be collected because of the unrelieved input VAT that is currently collected but, if it is assumed that input subject to VAT represent no more than 40 percent of the value of the outputs, the application of the main VAT rate to these services could raise about 0.6 percent of GDP.

99. This change would increase the cost of public transport, which accounts for less than a third of the expenditure on these items. If government policy is against an increase in fares for public transport, it could use one third of the funds generated to finance a compensation package of direct subsidies to public transport while still generating significant additional revenue.

Recommendation

  • Remove the VAT exemptions from those items that are not included in the EU VAT Directive and use one third of the additional revenue to subsidize public transport.

C. Unrecoverable Input VAT

Issue

100. As in other European countries, Iceland's local authorities are exempt from VAT. This results in a disincentive for outsourcing local government services to the private sector. The problem is how to minimize the distortion that is caused by the exemption.

Analysis

101. The only full solution to this problem would be to remove the VAT exemption from local authorities so that they would have to charge VAT on their taxes and service charges but would also be able to reclaim input VAT, as in New Zealand. However, as this is inconsistent with the EU VAT Directive, European countries have adopted a different approach: reimbursing local authorities for some of their unrecoverable input VAT.

102. Iceland follows the European approach but the local authorities claim that only a small proportion (about 12 percent) of their input VAT is reimbursed. However, this does not necessarily mean that it causes a distortion, as the distortion only arises in relation to services that could be outsourced. So, provided all input VAT is reimbursed for services that could be outsourced, the above problem would be avoided.

103. If the central government does decide to reimburse a larger proportion of input VAT, this would increase the real resources available to local government and possibly lead to an increase in total government expenditure. This could be avoided by reducing other income to local authorities but the reduction in individual local authority income should not be related to the amount of VAT reimbursement that they receive. Otherwise, the original distortion would reappear. This means that it may be difficult to prevent local government expenditure from rising without redistributing resources between localities. In the current fiscal situation, it is therefore necessary to limit reimbursements to services that are definite possibilities for outsourcing.

Recommendation

  • Provide reimbursement for input VAT to local government services that could be outsourced. In the current fiscal situation it is best to limit the reimbursements to those services.

VI. Other Taxes

A. Recurrent Taxes on Immovable Property

Issue

104. Property taxes are not high by international standards. Taxation of immovable property is relatively non-distortionary and residential property is favored by the rest of the tax system. As part of a revenue mobilization package, increases in property taxes could be considered as an option.

Analysis

105. Recurrent taxes on immovable property, especially residential property, can offset tax preferences in the income tax and capital gains tax that lead to excessive investment in housing. In addition, its immobility makes it a relatively non-distortive tax base from an efficiency standpoint. The general argument against it is that it is a particularly unpopular tax and is often seen as unfair.

106. In Iceland, as in most other OECD countries, immovable property is taxed by local authorities. However, this does not prevent an increase in the rate of tax contributing more generally to government revenue, by reducing the maximum rates of the local income tax and/or the size of the redistribution fund.

107. Although Iceland's property taxes are high by Nordic standards, there are a number of OECD countries that have considerably higher revenues from this source. In addition, the advantage of the immovable nature of the tax base is particularly applicable to a small island like Iceland with a very open economy.

108. The disadvantage of a property tax is that it can be seen as unfair, and this is the likely reason why local authorities often do not set the maximum allowable rate of property tax even when they set the maximum rate of personal income tax. The main difficulty relates to people with valuable property but low income, usually retired people, who may suffer hardship in case of a rate increase. Many OECD countries reduce the property tax for such groups, although it reduces the incentives for improving the allocation of the housing stock. An alternative solution is applied in some jurisdictions, in which the reduction in the property tax is treated as a loan that is repaid with interest from the estate of the owner when they die.

109. A large and sudden increase in property taxes would be difficult for Icelanders to accept in the current situation of widespread excessive housing debt. Nonetheless, in the long term, an increase in this tax would improve the efficiency of the tax system.

Recommendation

  • A raise in the rates of recurrent property taxes, particularly on residential property, should be considered as the housing market and incomes recover.

B. Stamp Taxes

Issue

110. Should Iceland reduce its stamp taxes on financial transactions and the sale of immovable property, as they are more distortionary than taxes on income, consumption and wealth?

Analysis

111. These taxes produce barriers to the reallocation of finances and real capital. In addition, they can be inequitable as the need to make these transactions (perhaps because of a change in employment) will often not be related to income or wealth. The only general argument against reducing them is that they are often more acceptable than other taxes because of their low rate.

112. In the case of Iceland, the argument for reducing these taxes is particularly strong because of the various shocks that affect a small open economy often require the reallocation of assets and changes to financial arrangements. The potential distortionary effect of these taxes is, therefore, particularly strong in Iceland. However, they do currently raise revenues of about 0.3 percent of GDP. This means that they can only be reduced if sufficient other tax revenues become available.

Recommendation

  • The stamp taxes should be reduced or eliminated when the fiscal situation allows it.

C. Excises on Food

Issue

113. Should Iceland continue with its excise duties on foods with high sugar content in view of the complexity that they introduce in the tax system and their probable ineffectiveness in promoting healthy eating?

Analysis

114. The argument for maintaining them is that they discourage unhealthy eating. The argument against them is that they introduce complexity into the tax system, which their revenue could easily be replaced by a small increase in other taxes and they are poorly designed to achieve their aim.

115. There has been some discussion of the possibility of excise duties of this type in other OECD countries because of the wish to encourage healthy eating, but most countries have not adopted them. One of the difficulties is in deciding which goods should be taxed. Should the taxes just be based on sugar content or should it reflect fat content, and which sorts of fats? Another issue is how high the tax would have to be in order to have a significant effect on behavior.

116. A particular problem with Iceland's food excises is that they do not systematically reflect the sugar content in the food. In particular, they do not tax the sugar in dairy products. This means that it is still possible for consumers to purchase sugary foods without paying the tax, undermining its purpose. It would be better to have an excise on sugar that would then automatically be built into the price of domestically produced foods that contain sugar, providing an incentive for producers to reduce the sugar content of their products. Imports would be taxed on their sugar content.

Recommendation

  • The excises on foods should either be modified to provide a consistent reflection of sugar (and possibly fat) content or else be abolished, when budgetary pressures subside.

D. Excises on Alcohol, Fuel and Tobacco

Issue

117. The excises on alcohol and tobacco are high by OECD and European standards but generally consistent with the rates in Nordic countries. However, the excise duties on vehicle fuels are low by Nordic standards when converted at market exchange rates. Because of the need to combat climate change and because of the current fiscal situation, this raises the possibility of increasing the excise on motor fuel.

Analysis

118. The argument in favor of increasing fuel excises is the need to combat climate change and the fiscal situation. The argument against increasing these excises is that it will increase the consumer price index. In addition, an increased excise duty would probably fall particularly on those in remote rural areas. That is true of almost all countries, including Finland, Norway and Sweden. Nonetheless, the effects on remote areas can be largely offset by using part of any additional revenue as a compensation package to subsidize public transport, particularly in rural areas.

119. The difference between the taxes on fuel in Iceland and other Nordic countries is reduced if the comparison is made at purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rates rather than the usual international comparison at market exchange rates (Table 12). However, the difference in results from the two comparison methods will possibly diminish over the next few years owing to inflation differentials. Also, it is not clear that purchasing power parity comparisons are better than those at market rates. Nonetheless, it might be prudent to take a gradual approach to the raising of these taxes. If the levels of taxation on motor fuels were increased to remove half of the (market rate) difference between Icelandic and Norwegian levels, approximately 0.35 percent of GDP would be raised as additional revenue, of which 0.1 percent could be used to subsidize public transport.

Table 12.

Comparison of Fuel Taxes (In ISK per liter, rates converted using the stated exchange rates)

article image
Sources: National sources, IMF WEO, and staff calculations.

Recommendation

  • If the authorities wish to mobilize additional revenue, the excise duty on vehicle fuels could be raised towards Norwegian levels when the carbon tax (see below) is taken into account. This should be accompanied by increased subsidies to public transport.

E. Taxes on Motor Vehicles

Issue

120. The government is considering changes to the excise duty on car imports and the annual fee for car use, moving from rates based on the engine size (excise duty) and weight (annual fee) of the vehicle to rates based on their carbon emissions, on a revenue-neutral basis. The changes would also extend these taxes to pickup trucks, but with a reduced rate for flexi-fuel vehicles.

Analysis

121. The current rates of these taxes are comparable to other Nordic countries, so there is no reason to change the general level of collections. However, the EU is moving towards differentiating the rates of tax according to carbon emissions in order to encourage consumers to purchase more fuel efficient vehicles, something that is needed in order to mitigate the risk of climate change. The plans in Iceland are therefore both sensible and in line with European trends.

122. Currently pick-up trucks are exempt from these taxes. However, this exemption is hard to justify in general (as it is distortionary) and is even harder to justify when the rates embody an environmental objective. There is no justification for exempting pick-up trucks and their potential purchasers from the incentive to purchase fuel efficient cars.

Recommendation

  • The proposed changes to the excise duties are in the right direction and they would be more effective if pick-up trucks were be included.

F. Resource and Environmental Taxes

Issue

123. Are the new resource taxes on electricity and water as well as the new carbon tax improvements to the tax system?

Analysis

124. Natural resources produce rent for their users, and it is a waste of such community resources to allow these rents to be untaxed. The move towards introducing these resource taxes is, therefore, to be welcomed. It is difficult to tell whether they have been introduced at the correct rates but it is probable that, given their low level, the rates could be increased without exhausting the rents. Further analysis is required before a suitable rate for the long-term can be properly decided.

125. The introduction of a carbon tax on the carbon content of fossil fuels is also to be welcomed, partly because carbon content is a rational basis for determining taxes on fuels and partly because it increases the taxation of vehicle fuels, which is currently rather low (see above). It is also good that all consumers of the fuels, and not just road users, are covered by the tax.

126. However, the tax could be improved by applying the same tax to industrial users of carbon, as efficiency requires that all producers of carbon dioxide should be taxed at the same rate. Also, the rate of tax, currently set at about half the permit price in the EU Emission Trading System (ETS) for carbon permits, should be raised to equal the European permit price as that will be the cost that Iceland will face for carbon emissions in the longer term.

Recommendation

  • These taxes are welcome from the environmental and economic efficiency angles. However, there is probably considerable scope for increasing the resource taxes without causing any distortions and the appropriate level requires further analysis. Also, the carbon tax should apply to all carbon consumers and its rate should be increased to equal the ETS price.

Appendix: Summary of Recommendations

CIT and debt forgiveness

  • Introduce the necessary provisions in the Income Tax Act that make the profit determined according to the financial statement the basis for the taxable profit, allowing only those deviations explicitly provided for in the Income Tax Act.

  • The income tax should treat as ordinary profits capital gains and losses on business assets that are recognized in accordance with financial accounting rules. Consequently, income arising from debt forgiveness should be considered taxable income but would be offset against these losses. Income in excess of losses, if any, should be taxed.

  • A one-time transitory mechanism should be adopted to allow the tax recognition of capital losses incurred during the crisis up to an amount commensurate to the income arising from debt forgiveness. This could be closely monitored and authorized by the tax administration on a case by case basis in accordance with publicly announced rules. For individuals, the tax authority should exempt income from mortgage debt forgiveness up to the point where the debt is equal to the market value of the property reduced by reasonable foreclosure and sale costs to the lender.

  • A thin capitalization provision based on either the debt-to-equity ratio or the earnings test should be introduced. An earnings test based on EBITDA is possibly preferable due to its simplicity and lower potential for avoidance.

  • The 15 percent withholding tax on interest payments to residents in treaty countries should be waived or reduced (as provided by the treaty) at source, using pre-certification of residence. Consider disallowing the deduction of interest payments made to residents in a low tax country.

  • The participation deduction should be reformed into a participation exemption, bringing the tax treatment of intercompany dividends in line with other European countries. Add to the current threshold of 10 percent shareholding a second (alternative) threshold in the form of a fixed amount of investment—calibrated to the specific situation in Iceland.

  • Investment incentives under consideration should not be adopted. If this is not feasible, the annual turnover requirement should be increased drastically in order to cover only very large investments.

  • Maintain the current 10-year period of loss carry forward.

PIT and direct taxes on individuals

  • Retain the dual income tax structure rather than switching to a comprehensive income tax.

  • Allocate revenue in closely held businesses according to either the net or gross assets methods. The gross assets method would be preferable as it offers less opportunity for tax arbitrage. This income splitting regime should apply to both closely held corporations and partnerships.

  • If needed, to increase progressivity and raise revenue, introduce a single 10 percent surcharge on incomes above ISK 4.5 million. Do not raise the basic tax credit or initial tax rate.

  • As the economy recovers, phase out mortgage interest deduction over time for all but low-income, first-time home buyers.

  • Reduce social security tax rate as budgetary pressures decline.

  • Simplify net wealth tax by allowing the use of financial accounting valuations.

Corporate and individual capital income taxation

  • If additional revenue is needed, increase both CIT and capital income tax rates to 20 percent. Over the medium term, consider reducing the double taxation of dividends and capital gains by introducing a modified ACE.

VAT

  • Move to a single rate of VAT, using between a quarter and a third of the additional revenue for a compensation package for those on low incomes that will improve overall progressivity. Ideally, this would be achieved in a single step. However, if necessary, it could be staged, with a first step that raises the reduced rate back to 14 percent and restricts it to food. Also, remove VAT exemptions that are not included in the EU VAT Directive, with a compensatory subsidy to public transport.

  • Provide reimbursement for input VAT to local government services that could be outsourced. In the current fiscal situation it is best to limit the reimbursements to those services.

Other taxes

  • If the authorities wish to mobilize additional revenue, the excise duty on vehicle fuels could be raised towards Norwegian levels (including the carbon tax). A proportion of the extra revenue could be used for compensatory subsidies to public transport.

  • Increases in the rates of recurrent property taxes, particularly on residential property, could be considered as the housing market and incomes recover.

  • As budgetary pressures subside and unemployment declines, reduce social security tax rate.

  • The stamp taxes should be reduced or eliminated when the fiscal situation allows it.

  • The excises on foods should either be modified to provide a consistent reflection of sugar (and possibly fat) content or else be abolished, possibly when budgetary pressures subside.

  • There is probably considerable scope for increasing the resource taxes without causing any distortions although the appropriate level requires further analysis. Also, the carbon tax should apply to all carbon consumers and its rate should be increased to equal the ETS price.

  • The proposed changes to the excise duties on motor vehicles are in the right direction and they would be more effective if pick-up trucks were included.

2

Notice, however, that 2007 was a year of particularly high tax revenue in Iceland, as the booming economic activity boosted consumption and other tax bases.

3

Iceland's consumption tax revenues are unusually volatile, reflecting the volatility of private consumption that is noted in the Central Bank of Iceland's Monetary Bulletin 2010–12, Box IV-1, pp. 44–48. Their ratio to GDP can vary by as much as 3 percentage points over the economic cycle.

4

Interest income has an exemption of ISK 100,000; and only 70 percent of rental income is subject to tax (in lieu of itemized deductions, which are not provided).

5

The authorities have started the process of collecting the necessary data and of estimating the redistributive impact of the tax and benefit systems separately.

6

For 2007 a total loss carry forward of almost ISK 383 billion was reported, whereas the total revenue of income tax amounts to ISK 241 billion.

7

Investors typically created an Icelandic subsidiary that acted as the acquiring company and was financed by debt. After the takeover this company was merged into the acquired company, so as to offset its interest expenses with the operational profit of the acquired company.

8

The exemptions are the treaties with Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and Portugal which contain a withholding tax of 10 percent; the treaty with Greece contains a withholding tax of 8 percent; the treaty with Spain limits the withholding tax to 5 percent; and the treaty with Romania to 3 percent.

9

Council Directive 2003/49/EC of 3 June 2003 on a Common system of Taxation Applicable to Interest and Royalty Payments Made Between Associated Companies of Different Member States.

10

Within the EEA and EU, only Belgium and Luxembourg follow a similar relief method as Iceland. Belgium was recently forced by the European Court of Justice in Case C-138/07 of 12 February 2009 (Cobelfret) to provide for an unlimited carry forward of the unused foreign dividend deduction.

11

Council Directive of 23 July 1990 on the Common System of Taxation Applicable in the Case of Parent Companies and Subsidiaries of Different Member States (90/435/EC).

12

Sorensen (2007) describes this problem as “the Achilles heel” of dual income taxes.

13

Denmark, who pioneered the dual income tax in 1987, has largely abandoned it, but Norway, Sweden and Finland retain the dual income tax systems they adopted in the early 1990s. Even without a full dual income tax system, most countries apply a lower rate to all or part of capital income.

14

For example, if the nominal interest rate is 10 percent and inflation is 5 percent, then an 18 percent tax on nominal interest income taxes the real return on bonds, 5 percent, at a 36 percent rate.

15

Some “flight capital” returns to the country as foreign portfolio investment.

16

The CIT rate was cut from 18 to 15 percent in 2008.

17

All income from a third type of private business, sole proprietorships, is taxed jointly with labor income.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Iceland: Improving the Equity and Revenue Productivity of the Icelandic Tax System
Author:
International Monetary Fund