Republic of Estonia
Staff Report for the 2009 Article IV Consultation
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

This 2009 Article IV Consultation highlights that the credit-fueled boom has resulted in a relatively large nonfinancial private sector debt stock in Estonia. With declining incomes, unemployment increasing sharply, and asset prices depressed, balance sheets of households and firms are under strain, weighing on domestic demand. Nonperforming loans have increased to more than 6 percent of total, and some banks are reporting losses. Executive Directors have supported the authorities’ aim toward speedy adoption of the euro, noting its effects in fostering stability and confidence.

Abstract

This 2009 Article IV Consultation highlights that the credit-fueled boom has resulted in a relatively large nonfinancial private sector debt stock in Estonia. With declining incomes, unemployment increasing sharply, and asset prices depressed, balance sheets of households and firms are under strain, weighing on domestic demand. Nonperforming loans have increased to more than 6 percent of total, and some banks are reporting losses. Executive Directors have supported the authorities’ aim toward speedy adoption of the euro, noting its effects in fostering stability and confidence.

I. Summary and Appraisal

1. Following a credit boom, the Estonian economy is now undergoing a severe recession, although a full-fledged crisis has been avoided. Sizable fiscal reserves and swift adjustment measures taken in 2008 and throughout 2009 prevented funding problems of the government and supported the currency board arrangement (CBA) at a time of regional stress. Banks’ capital and liquidity cushions, including from their Nordic parents, headed off liquidity problems. And relatively high reserve requirements and a proactive approach to contingency planning, including a precautionary swap arrangement with the Swedish central bank in support of Swedish banks operating in Estonia1, provided additional insurance and further boosted confidence. The non-bank private sector has also reacted quickly, with wage cuts and adjustments in employment, further enhanced by a new labor law.

2. As a result of present and past efforts, euro adoption in 2011 appears within reach. Following recent budget measures and assuming continued fiscal consolidation efforts, Estonia could meet all Maastricht criteria, while the policy record to date provides assurances for continued stability-oriented policies. This is remarkable, as it is being achieved against the background of severe dislocations due to the crisis. Joining the euro zone would remove residual currency and liquidity risks, adding stability to the Estonian economy.

3. The focus should now be on restoring economic stability and laying the foundations for more balanced growth. Euro adoption by itself is unlikely to trigger any major change in the pace of recovery, which staff—unlike the authorities—expects to be relatively protracted given high unemployment and debt burdens, necessary deleveraging by banks, and the need to fundamentally reorient the economy towards the tradable sector. Within the authorities’ export-oriented growth strategy, a slower than expected rebound among Estonia’s main trading partners represents a key risk to the outlook.

Putting Fiscal Policy on a Sustainable Path

4. Staff supports the authorities’ goal of meeting the 3 percent Maastricht deficit criterion. The benefits of euro adoption outweigh the mildly procyclical effects of fiscal tightening during the crisis. Given considerable macroeconomic and implementation risks, staff recommended additional structural measures of some 1 percentage point of GDP in the context of the 2010 budget. This would provide an adequate safety margin for 2010, offset one-off and potentially reversible measures, confront an anticipated shift in tax bases, and help achieve the targeted medium-term structural balance. Following staff’s visit, the authorities decided to further increase excise taxes by about ¼ percent of GDP.

5. While there is some room for further expenditure reductions, much of the adjustment effort may need to fall on the revenue side. The need to protect social safety nets limits the room for spending cuts. Tax administration could be further strengthened and, in keeping with Estonia’s streamlined tax system, poorly targeted exemptions eliminated. Significant deferral benefits in the corporate income tax could also be reviewed. Consideration could be given to enhanced use of environmental and property taxes, which would broaden the tax base and reduce economic distortions. A further increase of the VAT rate would support a shift from consumption to investment and exports.

6. A strengthened fiscal framework could limit the budget’s procyclicality. The annual balanced budget rule could be replaced by multi-year expenditure ceilings consistent with the existing goal to bring the budget to structural balance by 2012. Reduced revenue earmarking and tighter control over local government finances would also help in this regard.

Strengthening Competitiveness

7. The economy needs to regain competitiveness lost during the boom years. Labor and product markets seem capable of delivering the necessary adjustment. The recently enacted labor law provides a timely boost to flexibility, although the agreed-upon increase of unemployment compensation should be implemented as soon as fiscal space allows. Targeting EU-funded projects to the tradable sector and other supporting structural policies can also help to deliver the necessary rebalancing of the economy and spur economic convergence.

8. Seeking euro adoption at the current fixed exchange rate parity remains the best exchange rate policy for Estonia. The economy’s flexibility suggests that the moderate overvaluation identified by staff can be corrected through factor price adjustment alone. While theoretically offering some advantages, a repegging of the kroon at a more depreciated level would be unnecessarily disruptive, both for Estonia and the region.

Addressing Private Sector Debt

9. The large stock of debt by households and corporates is expected to weigh on growth, suggesting a focus on strengthening the credit enforcement and resolution framework. Debtors’ financial difficulties may have eased somewhat recently, thanks to low interest rates and banks’ willingness to reschedule a portion of debt payments. This relief is likely to be temporary, however, as price and wage deflation and increases in euro zone interest rates could result in higher debt servicing burdens. In dealing with private sector debt, heavy-handed policy intervention, such as retroactive limits on debtors’ liabilities, must be avoided. Appropriately designed credit enforcement legislation can facilitate the rehabilitation of viable and speedy exit of non-viable firms and help good faith debtors make a fresh start. In this spirit, the bankruptcy and reorganization acts could benefit from enhanced flexibility to accommodate on a case-by-case basis the need for debt reduction and institutional capacity could be strengthened. Changes to the corporate tax code would be desirable to discourage excessive debt accumulation at the firm level.

Safeguarding the Financial Sector

10. Though the financial sector has proven resilient, deteriorating credit quality and high private sector debt present challenges. Overdue loans are likely to increase further over the course of the year, amid limited near-term growth prospects, a depressed real estate market and rising unemployment. Moreover, some debt restructuring agreements may turn out to be unviable. This will necessitate banks setting aside additional provisions. High capital adequacy ratios should not detract from the need for continued supervisory vigilance.

11. Some recommendations of the last FSAP update still await implementation. In particular, pending legislation on a bank resolution framework should be passed. This would complement ongoing contingency planning for liquidity pressures. Complacency now would risk future problems being less tractable and thus undermine public confidence.

12. Estonia should remain on a standard 12-month consultation cycle.

II. The Crisis and Policy Responses

13. Following a period of severe overheating, the economy is contracting sharply (Figures 1 and 2). Investment already started to slow in mid-2007, along with a bursting of the property bubble, when the two main banks tightened lending conditions. The collapse of global external financing and foreign trade in the Lehman bankruptcy aftermath exacerbated the downturn. Output plummeted by almost 16 percent in the first nine months of 2009. Deflation and wage declines are projected to persist through 2010; the latter may temper the rise in unemployment, which nevertheless will likely reach 16 percent by the end of 2009. The current account should remain in a small surplus in the short term, but declining nominal GDP will worsen external debt and NIIP ratios in 2009. Staff expects the economy to resume growth only in the middle of 2010, with a negative output gap peaking at 8½ percent of GDP.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Estonia: The Boom, 2000-08

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Estonian Statistical Office; and Bank of Estonia.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Estonia: Effects of the Bust

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Eurostat; WEO; Bank of Estonia; Ministry of Finance; and Eurostat.

14. A full-fledged crisis has been avoided due to existing buffers and a determined response by both the public and the private sector. Sizable fiscal reserves accumulated during the boom years, a very low level of public debt, and, importantly, swift and far-reaching adjustment measures taken in 2008 and throughout 2009 have helped the government to keep the deficit in check and avoid financing problems. At the same time, the increased use of EU structural funds provided some countercyclical fiscal stimulus. In the financial sector, banks’ own capital and liquidity cushions—further boosted by relatively high reserve requirements—and support from Nordic parents prevented liquidity problems in spite of rising nonperforming loans. The private sector has also reacted flexibly, with wage cuts and adjustments in employment, further enhanced by a new labor law. As a result of these supporting policies, Estonia’s CBA has proven resilient to regional tensions: although local currency interest rates, CDS spreads and forward exchange rates increased (Figure 4), Eesti Pank did not experience a significant loss of reserves.

uA01fig01

GDP Growth, 2001-2010

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: WEO.

Implications of Fund Policy Advice

Relations between Estonia and the Fund remain excellent. While policy formulation and implementation has been characterized by a high degree of ownership—a key factor in Estonia’s economic successes—the authorities report that their decisions benefit considerably from Fund advice. Indeed, policies have been generally consistent with Executive Board recommendations. In 2007–08, however, large increases in current spending, which were contrary to Fund advice, resulted in a structural loosening of the fiscal stance. But recent corrective action, including expenditure reversals and increased indirect taxes (the latter despite initial reluctance) have been in line with staff suggestions. Most of the key recommendations of the 2009 FSAP update have been adopted, except implementation of a bank resolution framework.

III. Outlook and Risks

15. As the economy rebalances, a quick rebound to pre-crisis growth rates seems unlikely. Growth in recent years was unsustainably bolstered by a disproportionate rise in nontradable sectors (construction, financial intermediation, real estate), with negative implications for competitiveness. Adjusting the economy to a more sustainable growth pattern and correcting imbalances will take time and cause temporary dislocations, especially in the labor market. Moreover, the need to reestablish fiscal sustainability, and for the private sector to address the legacy of sizable debt stocks will likely reduce domestic demand for several years (Figure 3). Growth prospects will therefore be constrained, with staff estimates suggesting a slow-down of potential growth to 3–4 percent, compared with 6–7 percent before the crisis.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Estonia: Stock Legacies

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia; Eurostat; European Central Bank, Estonia Financial Services Authority; Courts Information System; and staff calculations.

Contributions to Growth, 2006-10

article image
Sources: Estonian Statistical Office; and staff calculations.

Includes changes in stocks.

uA01fig02

Growth and Output Gap

(Production Function Method)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Estonia Statistical Office; and IMF staff estimates.

16. Relatedly, inflation pressures are expected to remain subdued. Under staff’s central scenario, the current period of deflation will only be temporary, driven by the sudden drop of global energy prices in 2008–09 and the collapse of wages and consumption. Based on earlier precedent, recent price declines are not expected to present an obstacle to a positive assessment of the Maastricht inflation criterion, which should be formally met in late 2009. Staff projects inflation to resume in 2011 with the output gap closing and global commodity prices rebounding, but—due to depressed domestic demand growth—remain at 2–3 percent annually in the medium term. Price levels are close to 80 percent of the EU average (more than in most new member states), suggesting that a substantial degree of nominal convergence has already taken place.

uA01fig03

HICP Inflation and Maastricht Criterion

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Haver; and IMF staff estimates.

Staff and authorities agreed that regional instability represents the main short-term risk. While Estonia has evaded financial contagion from neighboring Latvia to date, the difficult situation there could pose challenges to economic sentiment and banks’ liquidity. Such risks are mitigated by considerable liquidity buffers and the authorities’ determined contingency planning efforts. Moreover, the high share of external liabilities with foreign parents suggests that potential liquidity, and even solvency tensions can be resolved at a group level and rollover risks are considerably smaller than implied by standard measures of reserve coverage (Box 2). The authorities also pointed to their ambitions for speedy euro adoption, which would not only resolve residual currency and liquidity risks, but also differentiate Estonia from regional peers by confirming its strong policy record. By the same token, a postponement of euro adoption plans would likely lead to an increase of borrowing spreads, which have recently declined on the back of reduced regional tensions and growing anticipated supportive statements by public officials.

How Meaningful is the Ratio of Estonia’s External Short-Term Debt to Reserves for Vulnerability Analysis?

Estonia’s short-term external debt is large. At around 360 percent, Estonia’s ratio of short-term external debt (at remaining maturity) to international reserves is among the highest in Europe, which raises concerns about the potential emergence of liquidity problems. The short-term external debt is mostly owed by banks and private nonfinancial corporations.

Nevertheless, the country has faced little roll-over problems so far. Why?

  • Composition of the debt. Most of the short-term external debt is owed to parent companies, which reduces the likelihood that liquidity problems will be resolved in a disorderly manner. Furthermore, a non-trivial part of the debt is in the form of trade credits, which are usually backed by merchandise.

  • Buffers. Estonia’s private sector holds relatively large assets abroad. This is particularly important for banks, which keep half of their reserve requirements in liquid external assets (Estonia’s reserve requirements are set at 15 percent of banks’ total liabilities).

  • Policies. The Swedish authorities put in place liquidity facilities to support banks, including those active in the Baltics. This has benefited Estonia since its financial sector is primarily Swedish owned. Furthermore, the central banks of Sweden and Estonia concluded a precautionary agreement to compliment the high liquidity buffers of Swedish banks.

These factors are likely to continue playing an important role in the future, which would mitigate Estonia’s exposure to roll-over risks. Eventual euro adoption would further contribute to ameliorate these risks.

uA01fig04

Estonia: Deco mposing the Short-term External Debt

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Ba nk of Estonia and staff estimates

17. Staff identified a number of medium-term risks to the outlook related to stock legacies from the boom years. The rapid fall of employment, wages and prices raise the risk of a deflationary spiral, especially given high nominal debt burdens. The need for deleveraging may curtail Nordic banks’ provision of fresh funding to their Estonian subsidiaries. Indeed, net inflows from parents have declined compared to previous years, although external liabilities remain large. Nonetheless, the adjustment that has already taken place in response to the crisis suggests that Estonia’s external debt burden should steadily decline (Table 7) and be robust to several shocks (Figure 6).

Table 1.

Estonia: Selected Macroeconomic and Social Indicators, 2007–10

(In units as indicated)

article image
Sources: Estonian authorities and IMF staff estimates and projections.

Includes trade credits.

Net of portfolio assets (including money market instruments), financial derivative assets, other investment assets, and reserve assets held by Estonian residents.

Includes the Stabilization Reserve Fund (SRF).

The Estonian kroon is pegged at 15.6466 kroons to the euro.

Table 2.

Estonia: Summary of General Government Operations, 2001–101/

(Percent of GDP)

article image
Sources: Estonian authorities and IMF staff estimates and projections.

Cash basis.

Source: Estonia’s Statistical Office.

Table 3.

Estonia: Summary Balance of Payments, 2002-14

article image
Sources: Bank of Estonia and IMF staff estimates and projections.

Excluding interest payments and reinvested earnings.

The large FDI and equity investment flows in 2005 reflect the aquisition of remaining shares of Hansabank, most of which were held by foreigners, by its swedish parent

Includes operations in debt securities.

Excludes Government deposits held abroad (including in the SRF).

Changes in gross international reserves may differ from flows implied by overall balance of payments due to valuation changes.

Includes trade credits.

Short term debt is defined on the basis of original maturity.

Starting in 2000, the definition of external debt was widened to include money market instruments and financial derivatives.

Net of portfolio assets (including money market instruments), financial derivative assets, other investment assets, and reserve assets held by Estonian residents.

Includes government guaranteed debt.

Table 4.

Estonia: Macroeconomic Framework, 2001–14

(Percent of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Sources: Estonian authorities, and IMF staff estimates and projections.

Includes government, private and nonpublic institutions serving households.

Includes private and public capital formation, changes in inventories, and statistical discrepancy.

Cash basis. Public savings minus public investment differs from the fiscal balance by the amount of capital transfers received from abroad.

Medium-term balances consistent with the authorities’ stated targets for cylically adjusted balances..

Mainly EU capital grants, all of which are channelled through the budget.

Table 5

Estonia: Indicators of External Vulnerability, 2005–09

(Percent of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Sources: Estonian authorities, Bloomberg, Standard & Poor’s, and IMF staff estimates.

Total general government and government-guaranteed debt excluding government assets held abroad.

Credit to households and nonfinancial institutions.

Excluding reserve assets of the Bank of Estonia.

By original maturity.

External debt includes money market instruments and financial derivatives.

Net of portfolio assets (including money market instruments), financial derivative assets, other investment assets, and reserve assets held by residents.

Tallinn stock exchange index (OMX Tallinn), end of period.

Standard & Poor’s long-term foreign exchange sovereign rating.

One-month spread between Tallinn interbank borrowing rate (TALIBOR) and the corresponding EURIBOR rate. 2008 data refer to end period.

Table 6.

Estonia: Monetary Survey, 2003–10

(Millions of EEK, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Source: Bank of Estonia and IMF staff estimates and projections.

Currency board cover is equivalent to base money (e.g., the sum of currency issued plus the kroon liabilities of the BOE in its correspondent accounts).

Table 7.

Estonia: External Debt Sustainability Framework, 2003–14

(Percent of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Source: Estonian authorities and IMF staff estimates and projections.

Derived as [r - g - r(1+g) + ea(1+r)]/(1+g+r+gr) times previous period debt stock, with r = nominal effective interest rate on external debt; r = change in domestic GDP deflator in US dollar terms, g = real GDP growth rate, e = nominal appreciation (increase in dollar value of domestic currency), and a = share of domestic-currency denominated debt in total external debt.

The contribution from price and exchange rate changes is defined as [-r(1+g) + ea(1+r)]/(1+g+r+gr) times previous period debt stock. r increases with an appreciating domestic currency (e > 0) and rising inflation (based on GDP deflator).

For projection, line includes the impact of price and exchange rate changes.

Defined as current account deficit, plus amortization on medium- and long-term debt, plus short-term debt at end of previous period.

The key variables include real GDP growth; nominal interest rate; dollar deflator growth; and both non-interest current account and non-debt inflows in percent of GDP.

Long-run, constant balance that stabilizes the debt ratio assuming that key variables (real GDP growth, nominal interest rate, dollar deflator growth, and non-debt inflows in percent of GDP) remain at their levels of the last projection year.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Estonia: The impact of the Recent Global Financial Turmoil, 2007-09

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bloomberg and Staff calculations.1/ Breaks in the series reflect periods when there were no quotes.
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Estonia. External Competitiveness

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia, Statistical Office of Estonia, Eurostat, and IMF staff calculations.
Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Estonia: External Debt Sustainability: Bound Tests, 2003–14 1/

(External debt in percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: International Monetary Fund, Country desk data, and staff estimates.1/ Shaded areas represent actual data. Individual shocks are permanent one-half standard deviation shocks. Figures in the boxes represent average projections for the respective variables in the baseline and scenario being presented. Ten-year historical average for the variable is also shown.2/ Permanent 1/4 standard deviation shocks applied to real interest rate, growth rate, and current account balance.3/ One-time real depreciation of 30 percent occurs in 2009.
uA01fig05

Change in Net Funding from Non-Resident Credit Institutions and Domestic Credit, Billions Kroons 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia and Datastream.1/ Non-resident credit institutions are mostly parent banks.

18. The authorities viewed growth prospects more optimistically than staff, mainly on account of confidence effects associated with euro adoption. This, they expected, will boost foreign direct investment inflows, restart growth as early as 2010 and reduce debt burdens over time. They viewed continued real convergence as inevitable, although they acknowledged that domestic demand cannot play the same role as in the past and growth rates may on average be lower than during the boom. The recovery would therefore be primarily driven by net exports. Staff acknowledged positive confidence effects, but cautioned that euro adoption prospects are already reflected in relatively low risk premia. In any event, it would be no panacea as the authorities’ export-led growth strategy required a reorientation of the economy, which will take time and effort, especially in light of the uncertain global environment. In this context, the authorities agreed that protracted slow growth in Nordic trading partners, especially Finland, represented a key risk to the outlook. With a more optimistic view on growth prospects, they viewed the risks of protracted deflation as minor.

IV. Policy Challenges

19. The authorities’ immediate challenge is to ensure a smooth and speedy adoption of the euro, while managing the fallout of the economic crisis. They appear broadly on track in addressing these issues, although obstacles remain.

  • In the fiscal area, the authorities are focused on containing the public deficit in 2009, 2010, and beyond to below 3 percent of GDP to qualify for euro adoption as of January 2011.

  • In the financial sector, rising loan default rates and bank losses will pose supervisory challenges. Regional contagion risks require continued vigilance.

20. Medium-term challenges are still greater, requiring substantial adjustment by both private and public sectors. While euro adoption would remove residual currency and liquidity risks, it would not provide a substitute for needed internal adjustment.

  • The private sector needs to reallocate resources from past boom sectors to export-oriented and profitable activities to attain balanced and sustainable growth. While Estonia’s history of economic flexibility is encouraging, the task is hampered by high levels of private indebtedness and current deflation, the reduced availability of foreign capital and lower potential growth, both in Estonia and its trading partners.

  • The public sector will also need to adapt to an environment of lower growth (and hence revenues), while rolling back the unsustainable expenditure increases of the last two years and replacing temporary fiscal measures by permanent ones. This will require substantial structural reforms. A convincing medium-term fiscal adjustment strategy will be key to making euro adoption successful.

A. Consolidating Public Finances

21. The authorities’ fiscal policy is firmly geared towards qualifying for euro adoption. Meeting the Maastricht deficit criterion appears within reach as budget implementation has held up remarkably well during the downturn—indeed, Estonia’s public deficit and debt remain among the lowest in the EU. This can be attributed to a large and timely fiscal effort, a favorable starting position, as well as strong budget institutions (Box 3). While the deep recession may have suggested to let fiscal stabilizers work fully, staff endorsed the authorities’ all-out fiscal push on the grounds that speedy euro adoption would sharply reduce remaining vulnerabilities (see above) and merely move forward fiscal adjustment measures that are necessary anyway. Further, the procyclical impact is mitigated by the increased use of EU grants funding as well as the limited domestic demand impact of some fiscal measures (such as dividends from Eesti Pank and state owned enterprises). Staff argued, however, that when designing measures the short-term focus on qualifying for euro adoption should not distract from the need to initiate structural reforms that achieve a balanced cyclically adjusted fiscal position in the medium-term.

What Explains Differences in Fiscal Performance Among the Baltic Countries?

Estonia’s fiscal performance in 2009 has been markedly better than in the other two Baltic countries. This was achieved despite seemingly similar macroeconomic trends. Why?

Better fiscal starting position. The fiscal cash deficit in 2008 was about ½ percent of GDP lower than in Lithuania and Latvia. Further, Estonia, where the recession started first, began already with fiscal tightening in 2008 (by passing a contractionary supplementary budget and revising the 2009 budget late in the approval process), while Lithuania and Latvia continued expansionary fiscal policy paths through late-year wage and pension increases with a large carryover into 2009.

Lower automatic effects. The fiscal deterioration in Estonia due to the crisis was about 9 percent of GDP less than in Latvia and 5 percent less than in Lithuania. This is related to:

  • Spending rigidities. In light of real rigidities, spending as a ratio of the GDP is expected to increase in all countries automatically as the economy collapses. In Estonia, where nominal GDP is dropping by around 15 percent (compared to close to 20 percent in the other two Baltics), spending rigidities are projected to increase the fiscal deficit by only 6½ percent of GDP compared to 10 percent in the other two countries.

  • Social benefits. The increase in Estonia has been much lower than in Latvia (but not as low as Lithuania), primarily reflecting lower replacement rates for unemployment benefits.

  • Lower revenue elasticity to GDP. In Latvia the wage bill and private consumption are dropping at a much faster rate than GDP than in the other two Baltics. In addition, there was a large claim of accumulated VAT refunds. In Lithuania, the drop in VAT revenue is partly explained by cross-border shopping following the depreciation of the polish zloty. In contrast, revenue collection in Estonia has held up very well, even above macroeconomic parameters, suggesting recent improvements in tax administration.

  • The larger interest bill in Latvia and Lithuania is directly related to their higher fiscal deficits.

Differences in the 2009 Fiscal Positions of the Baltics

(in percent of GDP, unless indicated otherwise)

article image

Adjusted for 2nd pillar pension diversion.

A fiscal adjustment effort fully offsetting the automatic effects mentioned above. Latvia’s adjustment package was in fact larger than in Estonia (and Lithuania), but a significant share was used to offset expansionary fiscal initiatives taken in 2009, including PIT cuts and pension increases. Estonia’s smaller package was sufficient to compensate for the recession’s automatic effects on the budget.

Estonia: Selected Fiscal Indicators

(Percent of GDP)

article image
Source: Data provided by the Estonian authorities and Fund staff projections.

Virtually all EU funds in Estonia are channelled through the budget.

First difference in the cyclically adjusted structural balance, with sign reversed.

22. The 2009 deficit target of 3 percent of GDP is achievable, but risks remain. The authorities responded to a widening fiscal gap as early as late 2008 by making revisions to the 2009 budget. In 2009, they passed two supplementary budgets in February and June, totaling 7½ percent of GDP in measures, 2/3 of them on the expenditure side and 1/3 reversing planned or enacted previous expansionary policies. An additional 1½ percent of measures taken in September relies heavily on one-off dividends from state-owned enterprises. Altogether, adjustment was achieved in equal parts through durable structural reforms, potentially reversible measures once fiscal space emerges, and pure one-offs. Key risks to the outcome are larger than anticipated deficits of local governments and the health fund, lower than projected non-tax revenues, and a weaker macroeconomic framework.

Estonia: Overview on the 2009 Fiscal Measures

(in percent of GDP)

article image
Sources: Estonian authorities; and Fund staff estimates.

23. For 2010 and beyond, staff advocated a redoubling of the already planned fiscal effort. The draft 2010 budget contains further spending cuts and some increases of excise taxes, in addition to a number of one-off measures such as property sales (about 3 percent of GDP in total). Staff estimates, however, that the current plans fall short of the deficit target of 3 percent of GDP. In light of considerable macroeconomic and implementation risks (notably in local governments and land sales), additional structurally sound measures of about 1 percent of GDP would provide an appropriate safety margin. The procyclical effect would be compensated by the expected increase in absorption of EU funds. Staff argued that this was all the more necessary as many temporary measures (such as the diversion of contributions from the second to the first pension pillar) will expire in 2011 and medium-term fiscal balances are set to deteriorate under unchanged policies. Early implementation, if possible as part of the 2010 budget, would also provide further evidence of Estonia’s medium-term commitment to fiscal sustainability—a key consideration when assessing preparedness for the euro—and provide assurances should early euro adoption plans falter. The authorities agreed that some additional adjustment may be needed, although they would prefer to wait until the 2010 fiscal picture has become clearer. Following discussion with staff during the mission, additional excise increases on energy, amounting to about ¼ percent of GDP, were added to the 2010 budget.

24. While scope remains for further expenditure rationalization, staff argued that much of the adjustment effort will need to fall on the revenue side. The size of government in proportion to the economy rose substantially in the last years of the boom, mainly in pensions and health. While some of this spending surge has since been unwound, the authorities agreed that there remains scope for better targeting child and family benefits, and further rationalizing public services (health and administration); pension reform represents an important longer-term goal. The key medium-term fiscal challenge lies, however, in a likely erosion of the tax base as economic activity shifts toward more lightly taxed activities such as exports and investment. With the need to protect social safety nets limiting the scope for further spending cuts, staff laid out a range of options to strengthen tax revenues (Box 4).

uA01fig06

Fiscal Expenditures and Deficits

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Estonia Authorities; and Staff estimates and projections.
uA01fig07

Tax Bases

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Estonia Statistical Office.

Revenue-raising options in support of fiscal consolidation

Estonia has a revenue-productive and cost-effective tax system, characterized by an internationally acclaimed low compliance burden (with some 90 percent of taxpayers filing electronically). Thus, additional revenue sources focus on broadening tax bases while maintaining low marginal tax rates.

In addressing under-collection risks due to the anticipated lower wage bill share and subdued private consumption expenditure, a useful short-term focus would be on eliminating tax privileges. These could include the following:

  • VAT: Elimination of the reduced rate for hotel accommodation, journals and other printed materials.

  • PIT: Phased elimination of the tax deductibility of mortgage interest payments, and the withdrawal of the additional child allowance and tax exemptions for annuity income and interest earnings from credit institutions. Pension incomes also enjoy a special tax-free minimum annual allowance, which could be re-examined.

  • CIT: Based on preliminary quantitative analysis, the current CIT regime may create some bias towards debt financing as the law provides for unlimited and immediate deduction of debt servicing costs. The introduction of thin capitalization rules can shore-up the corporate tax base.

  • Annual motor vehicle tax: In the EU and international context, the non-taxation of motor vehicles appears anomalous, especially in view of environmental objectives.

  • Revenue administration: Tax gaps in VAT, fuel taxes, under-declared employment income are reportedly increasing, tax arrears are rising and the administrative capacity to tackle transfer pricing practices seems limited. Addressing these shortcomings will require increased budget appropriations, but with potentially material payoffs.

Over the longer-term and in support of the tradable sector, the authorities could consider enhancing the revenue potential of core taxes. These measures could also increase fiscal space to reduce the tax wedge on labor.

  • PIT: Collection potential and progressivity could be enhanced by increasing the personal tax-free allowance. Revenue-neutrality could be preserved through the elimination of multiple other allowances or by introducing a second higher marginal tax rate on high-income earners.

  • CIT: The dividend distribution regime is attractive in an expanding economy with ample reinvestment opportunities. Revenue productivity is low and the system encourages tax planning with long tax deferrals locking in dividends. It also discourages equity finance and could increase the attraction of transfer pricing practices. The authorities could revisit other corporate tax options such as the re-introduction of a low-rate classical system; the advanced corporate tax whereby tax on distributions is credited against the regular tax; or a split-rate system with a higher tax rate on distributed earnings and a lower tax rate on retained profits.

  • Social Tax-VAT rebalancing: The statutory social tax burden on employers could be lowered by increasing VAT: a one percentage point hike in the latter is almost equal to the revenue loss from a one percentage point reduction in the former.

  • Converting the urban land tax to a property tax on improvement value: Estonia underutilizes this revenue source compared to OECD member states. As an interim step, stagnating land tax collections could be improved by more frequent land valuations, the imposition of higher centrally legislated rates, and less exemptions and exclusions.

The authorities indicated that some elements of Estonia’s tax system could indeed be adjusted to the post-boom environment. In doing so, they would place a priority on growth over distributional considerations and therefore prefer to focus on indirect and environmental taxes, in line with their aim to move the economy from consumption to export-led growth. They were also open to measures to broaden the tax base, consistent with Estonia’s traditionally simple tax system.

25. While the authorities’ “balance or better” budget rule has served them well, a new medium-term framework could limit the budget’s procyclicality. The economic boom allowed for maintaining low government debt and the creation of sizable fiscal reserves, but it did not prevent a surge in current spending and tax cuts. Staff therefore advocated to shift revenues to less procyclical taxes, to reduce revenue earmarking and to strengthen multi-year expenditure ceilings. Further, tighter control over local governments finances and limiting contingent fiscal risks (including from local public-private partnerships) should support medium-term fiscal consolidation. The authorities acknowledged that such institutional arrangements, especially limits on local government borrowing, could aid in achieving structural fiscal balance by 2012—a goal to which they remained committed. Staff encouraged them to spell out their fiscal strategy in support of this target.

B. Boosting Competitiveness

26. Although the current account has turned into a surplus, staff expressed some concerns about Estonia’s external competitiveness (Figure 5). Staff calculations suggest that the real exchange rate remains overvalued, in spite of the large swing in the current account (Box 5). The performance of Estonia’s exports has been broadly comparable to regional peers in recent years, falling sharply during the crisis. On the other hand, depreciations in some trading partners, which temporarily put additional pressure on the real exchange rate, have recently been partly reversed while at the same time unit labor cost reductions in Estonia have taken hold. Its share in world export markets remained broadly stable during the 2006–08 period of real appreciation, suggesting that competitiveness has not been materially dented. The authorities pointed out that the decline in Estonia’s exports was not much different from what was recently observed in very competitive countries, such as Finland, Germany, and Sweden. Their assessment is that Estonia’s competitiveness remains adequate, particularly in light of the turnaround of the current account and wage declines that are taking place throughout the economy.

uA01fig08

REER, 2003M1-2009M9

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: INS.

Exchange Rate Assessment

Standard methods for exchange rate assessment give mixed signals. On the one hand, current-account-based methods suggests that Estonia’s real exchange rate is slightly undervalued, which constitutes a sharp reversal vis-à-vis the assessments those indicators suggested less than a year ago. On the other hand, methods based on direct assessments of the real exchange rate still suggest that the real exchange rate is substantially overvalued. More broadly, since the previous assessment the overvaluation range (now -3 to 21 percent) has widened and the mid-point overvaluation has declined somewhat.

Estonia: Estimates of Real Exchange Rate Overvaluation

(In percent)

article image

Based on end-June 2009 data.

Based on end-October 2008 data.

Uses the end-point WEO projection (for year 2014) as the underlying current account. This method is not used in the current assessment given that the end-point WEO is projected assuming a more depreciated real exchange rate (so, it is not an appropriate underlying current account).

Uses the coefficients of Isard and Faruquee (1998) to estimate the underlying current account.

For February 2009 SR NFA stabilized at the end-September 2008 level (-77 percent of GDP). For current calculations NFA stabilized at the end-June 2009 level (-79 percent of GDP).

Average deviation (of CPI-based REER and ULC-based REER) from their past five-year historical averages.

Excludes projections-based method, which was only calculated for the February 2009 SR.

Staff, nevertheless, thinks that real exchange rate overvaluation remains an area of concern. The expansion in domestic demand observed during the credit boom put pressure on the labor market, and generated wage increases that ran ahead of productivity growth even in tradable sectors not immediately affected by the domestic credit boom. These developments are being partially reversed as firms have seen profitability decline, but the process is not complete and it is being achieved in part with a large decline in employment. Staff believes that the outcome of the current-account-based methods needs to be interpreted with caution given the global crisis in financial markets. Rather than an indication of undervaluation, the reversal may be illustrating the magnitude of the sudden stop in international financial flows, and a stronger-than-estimated cyclical decline in Estonia’s demand for imports (particularly after a period of over-consumption and over-investment).

27. The economy seems flexible enough to rebalance economic activity towards export-oriented sectors. The export sector is diversified and dominated by small and medium-size enterprises integrated in supply chains with Nordic-Baltic neighbors. Domestic prices, wages, and productivity are adjusting fast, to what has essentially been a global shock. In this context, the authorities pointed to the recently enacted labor law which gives more flexibility to the already nimble labor market by reducing high lay-off costs. At the same time, they agreed that the corresponding security component of higher unemployment replacement rates should be introduced as soon as fiscal conditions allow. Targeting EU-funded projects to the tradable sector as well as active labor market policies and research investments are also aimed at boosting competitiveness.

28. The authorities and staff agreed that maintaining the CBA and seeking euro adoption at the current exchange rate parity remains the best exchange rate policy for Estonia. The overvaluation of the exchange rate, albeit moderate, imposes a burden on competitiveness and growth. Nevertheless, Estonia’s negligible level of public debt, the substantial fiscal adjustment that has already taken place, and the implied delay in imminent euro adoption (due to the violation of the Maastricht exchange rate stability criterion) would advise against repegging at a more depreciated level. Moreover, the economy’s proven flexibility suggests that the necessary adjustment can be achieved through factor price adjustment alone. The authorities felt strongly that any change of the parity, which has been in place for over 15 years, would constitute a breach of trust and have a highly adverse impact on the economy. In this context they reiterated their commitment to adopt the euro at the current exchange rate.

C. Addressing Private Sector Indebtedness

29. While not representing a liquidity risk, the large stock of private sector debt, accumulated in the boom years, is likely to weigh on growth prospects.2 With non-financial sector loans at over 170 percent of GDP, private sector indebtedness is high in Estonia relative to its wealth, income level and measures of ‘fundamental’ credit deepening (Figure 3).3 Much of long-term debt (almost all denominated in euros and at floating interest rates) is linked to the depressed real estate sector. Nonetheless, financial difficulties of debtors seem to have lately eased somewhat, thanks to low interest rates in the eurozone and banks’ willingness to reschedule a portion of debt payments into the future. Staff cautioned, however, that this relief was likely to be temporary as price and wage deflation and increases in euro zone interest rates could result in a higher debt servicing burdens in the years ahead. International evidence suggests that high debt levels often slow the recovery of consumption and investment. At the same time problematic legacy loans, if unaddressed, constrain intermediaries to provide fresh lending. Some reduction of debt levels may therefore be desirable to ensure that the convergence process can resume apace. Anecdotal evidence from banks suggest that currently only few loan restructurings entail debt relief in net present value terms.

uA01fig09

Private Sector Domestic Bank Credit

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: IFS and Staff calculations

30. While the authorities accepted that deleveraging was necessary, they were more sanguine than staff about its impact on future economic activity. In the near term, consumption would be more subdued than in the past, but this would not stop the catch-up with the old EU member states, which was underpinned by strong supply-side factors and market fundamentals. They also pointed out that Estonia’s public debt levels are much lower than in comparator countries in the EU and other emerging markets.

31. Staff agreed with the authorities that heavy-handed policy intervention to address the debt overhang must be avoided. Any interference in private contracts, such as retroactive limits on debtors’ liabilities, would severely undermine Estonia’s tradition of the rule of law. Imposing such provisions on new contracts would also likely constrain the availability of credit. Staff pointed out, however, that appropriately designed credit enforcement legislation could promote the rehabilitation of viable and speedy exit of non-viable firms, and help good faith individual debtors make a fresh start. It therefore welcomed the recently enacted Reorganization Act which should facilitate debt restructurings. A preliminary assessment had, however, identified some room for optimizing current legislation. For example, the Bankruptcy Act imposed a relatively long period of inactivity (5–10 years) on individuals in personal bankruptcy. More generally, while existing legislation maintained payment discipline, it did not provide adequate incentives for viable firms and their creditors to pursue debt workouts. The authorities stressed that any legal changes needed to be mindful of moral hazard issues and expressed their strong support for out-of-court restructuring. Regarding the Reorganization Act, they acknowledged some teething problems, attributed largely to insufficient experience and training among judges and insolvency administrators. Going forward, staff suggested that appropriate changes in corporate taxation could discourage excessive debt accumulation at the firm level (Box 4).

D. Improving Financial Sector Resilience

32. The financial sector has proven resilient, owing to high capitalization and earnings, and a strong supervisory framework. Some 95 percent of Estonia’s banking system is Nordic-owned, dominated by two Swedish banks with 65 percent market share and a number of branches. The system successfully handled the real world test of liquidity strains in October 2008. As an additional insurance element, Eesti Pank established in February 2009 a precautionary swap arrangement with the Swedish Riksbank to compliment high liquidity buffers of Swedish banks operating in Estonia (an FSAP recommendation), which has however not been utilized. Contingency plans to deal with possible pressures on deposits have also been put in place. More recently, the liquidity position of parent banks has benefited from the reopening of the European wholesale funding market.

uA01fig10

Non-performing loans

(Percent of total, over 60 days) 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia.
uA01fig11

Banking Sector Capitalisation

(Percent) 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia.1/ The CAR excludes capital held in Estonia but attributed to subsidiaries in Latvia and Lithuania.

33. The main near-term challenge is credit risk, where rising nonperforming loans (NPLs) may test banks’ resilience. While there are signs that the growth of NPLs has slowed recently, this could prove temporary given the expiration of debt repayment holidays, limited near-term growth prospects, and rising unemployment coupled with ending of comparatively short unemployment insurance periods. It is also uncertain if real estate prices have bottomed. Currently, banks have significant buffers against rising NPLs, as they have high capital adequacy levels, which is partly due to a tax regime that has favored the retention of earnings. The authorities’ own stress tests as well as those performed on a group level by the Swedish authorities show that the system is resilient to a substantial increase in NPLs. Nevertheless, staff suggested that the authorities continue to closely monitor banks’ financial conditions, including their debt restructuring practices, to ensure that they are based on sound economic principles. The authorities agreed that banks should continue to maintain adequate provisions for expected losses, and parent banks should stand ready to inject further capital if needed. Consideration will also be given to further developing macrofinancial risk analysis.

34. Staff urged the authorities to accelerate the implementation of measures to strengthen the financial system. Priority should be given to pending legislation on a bank resolution framework—a key recommendation of the last FSAP update. Complacency now would delay or dilute the necessary reforms, risk future problems being less tractable and thus undermine public confidence. The authorities pointed to recent progress in strengthening cooperation on cross-border financial stability in the Nordic region, including through a memorandum of understanding on crisis management and burden sharing principles. Additionally, they recently took steps to strengthen the deposit insurance fund by tripling the annual premium to 10 basis points.

Table 8.

Estonia: Financial Soundness Indicators of the Banking Sector

article image
Source: Bank of Estonia.

Annex: Debt of non-financial corporates and households in Estonia4

Based on a number of indicators, the balance sheets of Estonia’s non-financial private sector appear stretched, with a relatively large stock of debt facing reduced incomes and assets tied to a depressed real estate sector. This is likely to weigh on domestic consumption and investment, and could be exacerbated by current deflationary trends and future expected increases in interest rates in the euro-zone. Restructuring of bank credits have temporarily eased repayment pressures and hence reduced financial stability risks, but at the cost of a higher future debt burden.

A. Stylized facts

The build-up of private sector debt accelerated with EU accession in 2004. Since 2005-06 domestic private sector bank credit ratios have exceeded estimates of credit depth that are commensurate with Estonia’s macroeconomic fundamentals.5 Both the corporate and household sector participated in this accumulation of liabilities. As a share of GDP, they now exceed levels in other EU new member states.

uapp01fig01

Private Sector Domestic Bank Credit

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: IFS; and Staff calculations.
uapp01fig02

Non-Financial Private Sector Loans over GDP, 2008

(Percent) 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Eurostat; and Bank of Estonia1/ Taken from ESA 95 non-consolidated financial accounts. Data for Estonia are from Bank of Estonia (also ESA 95 financial accounts) as unavailable for 2008 in Eurostat. Data for BG, PL refer to 2007.
uapp01fig03

Corporate Sector Balance Sheets in 2009

(Percent) /1

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia; Eurostat; European Central Bank and IMF staff calculations./1 Net financial wealth over/net value added refers to 2008 for Estonia Debt is defined as all non-equity liabilities.
uapp01fig04

Corporate Sector Debt

(Percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia; and IMF staff calculations.1/ Includes suppliers’ credit and other domestic intercompany loans.

Corporate sector gearing is substantial and has reached similar or higher levels than in the euro area.6 Though Estonian firms are less indebted than the most highly indebted pre-1998 Asian crisis countries, they are not out of line with that region as a whole.

Domestic credit makes up the bulk of corporate debt and given its long maturity and sectoral composition suggests that it may concentrate potential debt overhang problems. Domestic bank loans, together with other domestic debt, accounted for the bulk of increased corporate borrowing over the past four years. While supplier credits are by nature of short duration, domestic bank credit has relatively long maturities. This protects borrowers from liquidity risks, but at a cost of a potential debt overhang problem. More than half of domestic bank credit has a maturity exceeding five years. In addition, domestic more than external credit was directed towards the real estate sector: lending to commercial real estate accounted for around 30 percent of total corporate debt and domestic lending nearly 70 percent of all lending to the same sector. According to industry specialists, around half of total office space entered the market in just two years (2007–09). Current vacancy rates of around 10–50 percent, depending on quality and location, indicate the degree of excess supply in office space, which will probably take several years to clear. Manufacturing, in contrast, attracted less credit than its share in GDP, and half of all credit to this sector was sourced from abroad (two thirds of which from affiliated enterprises). Generally speaking, about 10 percent of total corporate debt is estimated to be owed to affiliated foreign enterprises which should in these cases allow balance sheet adjustments to be resolved at group level.

uapp01fig05

Corporate Leverage in Asia 1996 and Estonia 2009

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Gray and Stone (1999); Bank of Estonia; and Staff calculations. For Estonia, debt includes loans and issued securities only.
uapp01fig06

Maturities of Corporate Debt

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Bank of Estonia and Staff calculations.1/: Based on original maturity.

Corporate Credit by Sector and Origin

(Percent)

article image
Source: Bank of Estonia; and staff calculations. Corporate credit excludes domestic inter-company debt.

Companies’ debt servicing burden has been declining, but is likely to rise in the near term.7 Companies are benefiting from the current low level of interest rates prevailing in the eurozone and banks are reportedly offering repayment holidays in exchange of further collateral. Current deflationary pressures, however, suggest that real interest rates have shot up, well into positive territory.

uapp01fig07

Corporate Sector Interest Payments over Gross Operating Surplus and Real Interest Rates

(Percent)/1

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Bank of Estonia; European Central Bank; and Staff calculations./1 For Estonia, estimated based on outstanding loans and debt securities.

Households in Estonia borrowed mainly to acquire real estate, whose significant depreciation over the past year has weakened their balance sheet position. In relation to gross disposable income, household borrowing is similar to the euro area. However, this is not matched by financial assets. Net financial assets as a percent of income are slightly negative, compared with a large positive buffer of euro area households. While the upgrading of a dilapidated post-Soviet housing stock is welfare enhancing in the long run, the large correction in house prices has severely diminished Estonian housing wealth in the short to medium-run: house prices have halved since peaking in mid 2007 and according to the Financial Services Authority, one fourth of mortgage exposures (15 percent of contracts) was in negative equity in 2009 Q2.

uapp01fig08

Households Balance Sheet at end 2008

(Percent of Gross Disposable Income)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Eurostat; and Bank of Estonia.
uapp01fig09

Prices and volumes of residential real estate in Tallinn

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Land Board.

The debt servicing burden of households has been higher than in other countries and the current respite thanks to record low euribor rates could again prove temporary.8 80 percent of credit to households consists of mortgages, most of which are at variable rates, following movements in 6-months euribor rates with a lag. As for firms, debt servicing payments have therefore declined. Banks are also reportedly rescheduling debt service payments of struggling households. However, this relief will again be increasingly offset by current deflationary pressures. Euro area interest rates are also expected to rise at some point, possibly before the Estonian economy has fully recovered. Finally, unlike in the euro area, only a fraction of households have mortgages. While the data thus underestimate the debt service of indebted households in Estonia, it should also be noted that mortgages are heavily concentrated among high-income households. Unofficial market estimates put overall debt servicing costs at 26 percent of indebted households’ net income.

uapp01fig10

Household Interest Payments

(Percent of Disposable Income) 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: Bank of Estonia; European Central Bank; Hungary Central Bank; and Staff calculations.1/ On loans and leases.

B. Problems of Debt Overhang and Resulting Risks to the Estonia’s Recovery

There is a substantial empirical and theoretical literature linking debt overhang to economic activity. Overleveraged households tend to cut back spending when hit by a shock that changes their perception of permanent income and wealth.9 Investment can also suffer because shareholders with debt overhang are unwilling to take up new projects if the returns benefit solely existing debt holders.10 Overindebtedness can also impair the lending capacity of financial intermediaries. Leveraged investors often have to reduce debt when asset prices fall, while a deteriorating credit portfolio undermines banks’ willingness and ability to lend.11 Finally, asset price busts are relatively costly for economic activity. Particularly, house prices busts tend to be longer lasting and are associated with greater output loss than other asset market corrections.12

Price and wage deflation could magnify the contractionary effects of Estonia’s high private debt levels on domestic demand. In Hong Kong, a country with a fixed exchange rate regime like Estonia, deflation and the legacy of a property boom weighted on domestic demand and growth for many years in the aftermath of the Asian Crisis. Real investment has not yet returned to levels in 1997. Sweden’s revival from the 1992 crisis, in contrast, was relatively fast because export-oriented firms benefited from exchange rate devaluation and strong external demand. Corporate deleveraging was quick and relatively short-lived. In Estonia, despite the turnaround in net savings, private sector loans as a percent of GDP have risen further in 2009 and are expected to remain broadly unchanged at that level in 2010.13 Estonian firms will have to rely on improvements in productivity and cost reductions to boost incomes, which takes longer and for the latter depresses domestic demand. Regarding households, in addition to the overshooting of mortgage and consumer borrowing relative to expected permanent income, the short-term dynamics of deflation and rising interest rates are likely to weigh on demand. The negative wealth effects of a depressed housing market, however, are likely to be more muted in Estonia as only few households have mortgages and those who were previously credit constrained should now benefit from improved housing affordability.

uapp01fig11

Inflation and Real GDP Growth in Asian Economies post Asian Crisis

(Percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: ARIC
uapp01fig12

Domestic Demand and Private Sector Credit in Hong Kong

(Percent)1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: DataStream; and IMF staff calculations.1/ For real consumption and real investment, year 1997=100.
uapp01fig13

Domestic Bank Credit to Private Sector in Estonia 2000-2008 and Sweden 1984-1998

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Sources: IFS; Datastream; and Staff calculations.
uapp01fig14

Private Sector Loans, Net Savings (Percent of GDP) and Real Interest Rates

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia; and IMF staff calculations.

The debt overhang may also be constraining credit supply, though the relative strength of Swedish banking groups should help mitigate this risk. Yet, even though housing affordability has improved substantially in 2009, the number of new mortgages has sharply declined.14 Banks’ willingness and ability to provide new loans may be impaired by the build-up of non-performing loans (NPL) in 2009. NPL ratios (for 60 day overdue loans) rose from less than 1 percent in January 2008 to 6.4 percent in October 2009. Banks’ loan loss provisions increased accordingly and lending conditions have been tightened.15 International evidence suggests that legacy loans, if not dealt with, undermine efficient financial intermediation as capital stays locked in underperforming assets, interest income falls and management resource are diverted.16 With unemployment expected to continue to rise and given the lags typically observed between economic activity and credit defaults, a further slow deterioration in banks’ credit portfolio is to be expected.17 The strong capitalization of the Nordic banking groups should however help mitigate the risk of a protracted credit crunch. The three largest banking groups raised substantive amounts of capital during 2009, resulting in tier 1 ratios above 10 percent, well in excess of regulatory minima.

uapp01fig15

Real estate affordability and New mortgages 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia; and IMF staff calcuations.1/ Real estate affordability based on square meters a family in Tallinn can afford earning two average wages; new mortgages assumes average mortgage size is 0.5 million EEK.

The existing debt burden and negative housing equity also bear the risk of accelerating defaults in a ‘disorderly’ manner. Recent research based on household surveys in the United States indicates that households’ probability to default increases nonlinearly with respect to foreclosures in the neighborhood and with respect to depressed housing values. In both cases, the social stigma attached to default fades, accelerating debt failures.18 So far, banks’ proactive rescheduling of both corporate and household debt has prevented an eruption of foreclosures and also contained personal bankruptcies. The relatively strict bankruptcy regime and the high incidence of owner-occupied housing—96 percent in 2007—is also likely to maintain payment discipline. Still, an anticipated further increase in unemployment, rising real interest rates and possibly only slow recovery of the real estate market will test the sustainability of these arrangements in the years to come.

uapp01fig16

Non-performing loans

(Percent of total, over 60 days) 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2010, 004; 10.5089/9781451812589.002.A001

Source: Bank of Estonia and IMF staff projection.1/ Based on simpe ARDL model of NPL ratios and GDP growth (projections) shown in Table 1.
1

Eesti Pank Press Release of February 27, 2009 (www.eestipank.info/pub/en/press/Press/pressiteated/pt2009/_02/pt0227)

2

See Annex for more details.

3

The estimate of ‘fundamental’ credit over GDP is based on the methodology employed in Cottarelli, et al (2003).

4

The principal author of this Annex is Valerie Herzberg.

5

The estimate of ‘fundamental’ credit over GDP is based on the methodology employed in Cottarelli, Carlo et al, 2003, “Early Birds, Late Risers, and Sleeping Beauties: Bank Credit Growth to the Private Sector in Central and Eastern Europe and the Balkans”, IMF Working Paper 03/213.

6

The euro area non-financial sector is also considered highly leveraged. See ECB Financial Stability Review December 2008 p. 49 and June 2009. A comparison of loan-to-equity ratios in 2007 across the EU using Eurostat data suggests that out of the available data on 22 countries, 17 had lower ratios than Estonia.

7

Ideally, the calculations should also take account of amortization payments for which data is however unavailable.

8

Again, information on amortization payments is not available.

9

King, Mervyn, 1994, “Debt deflation: Theory and evidence”, European Economic Review. Debt overhang has also been identified for euro area households. See DG Ecfin Quarterly Report of the Euro Area, 2009, Volume 8, No 3.

10

Myers, Stewart, 1977, “Determinants of Corporate Borrowing,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5, pp. 147–75.).

11

See for example Bernanke, Ben, and Gertler, Mark, 1995, “Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission,” Journal of Economic Perspectives and Ghosh, Swati and Ghosh, Atish, 1999, “East Asia in the Aftermath: Was there a crunch?”, IMF Working Paper, WP/99/38

12

See IMF World Economic Outlook, October 2009, Chapter 3.

13

For the purpose of assessing the more medium-term debt burden the focus here is on loans of corporates and households only. Short-term trade and suppliers’ credits are excluded from the calculations. The share of savings assumed to be used for debt payments is equal to the net savings rate of the private sector plus non-debt creating capital inflows as a proportion of the total savings rate (equal to around 40 percent). The interest rate on the debt stock is assumed to be 4 percent.

14

These figures may however overstate the true number of new mortgages, as restructured mortgages may also be counted as new ones.

15

Many banks for example are charging higher risk premia and lowered loan to value ratios and debt servicing ratios. As a result, 60 percent of new loans in April 2009 had a loan servicing ratio below 30 percent, compared with only 39 percent a year earlier.

16

See for example Krueger, Anne and Tornell, Aaron, 1999, “The role of bank restructuring in recovering from crises: Mexico 1995-1998”, NBER Working Paper 7042.

17

See Berge, Oddvar and Godding Boye, Katrine Norges Bank (2007) “An analysis of banks’ problem loans”, Economic Bulletin. Further expected tightening in global capital and liquidity regulation is also likely to dampen the availability of credit. The projections of NPLs shown in the chart are not based on a long-term cointegrating relationship which is difficult to identify given the numerous structural breaks. The chart is thus merely illustrative to highlight the importance of lags between economic shocks and non-performing loans.

18

Guiso, Luigi et al, 2009, “Moral and Social Constraints to Strategic Defaults on Mortgages”, NBER Working Paper Series

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Republic of Estonia: Staff Report for the 2009 Article IV Consultation
Author:
International Monetary Fund