Abstract
This paper assesses the evolution of Eastern Caribbean Currency Union (ECCU) real exchange rates over time, and examines whether the region has lost competitiveness. The main finding is that there is little evidence of overvaluation of the Eastern Caribbean (EC) dollar. The relationship summarized above permits the calculation of equilibrium current account balances or norms. The financing of ECCU current account imbalances appears stable. This paper also provides evidence on the distinctive impact that tourism plays in the determination of the real exchange rate in tourism-driven economies.
VII. Can the ECCU Afford to Grow Old?48
A. Introduction
1. The demographic transition in the ECCU displays unusual characteristics. The transition now underway is rapid compared with international experience, and emigration is playing a particularly large role (Figure VII.1). Rasmussen and Roache (2007) found that the pension schemes in some ECCU countries are unsustainable, based upon recent actuarial reviews, and require significant reforms to place them on a sustainable path (Figure VII.2). By 2060, ECCU pension funds’ expenditure will exceed contributions by over 6 percent of GDP, based on pension funds’ actuarial projections.49
ECCU: Social Security Reserve Assets per Actuarial Reviews
(In percent of GDP)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates and projections, as shown in Roache and Rasmussen (2007).ECCU: Social Security Reserve Assets per Actuarial Reviews
(In percent of GDP)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates and projections, as shown in Roache and Rasmussen (2007).ECCU: Social Security Reserve Assets per Actuarial Reviews
(In percent of GDP)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates and projections, as shown in Roache and Rasmussen (2007).2. This chapter describes and quantifies several factors which could magnify the challenge of pension reform. First, for some ECCU countries, continued emigration at historical rates would considerably advance the projected date at which pension scheme assets are depleted. Second, there is a significant risk that assets will underperform, given the large exposures to the highly-leveraged public sector and to a lesser extent the record with private sector investments. Third, portfolio diversification away from the public sector could be complicated by age-related pressure for greater central government health spending.
B. Emigration and Sustainability
3. High rates of emigration from the ECCU have significant implications for the sustainability of pension schemes. A large proportion of the labor force emigrated to the OECD during 1970–2000, based on OECD members’ census data (Figure VII.3). ECCU members accounted for five of the top ten countries in the world ranked by this indicator. Dominica’s population actually declined according to its own 1991 and 2001 censuses (ILO, 2003).
Countries with the Largest Emigration to OECD, 1970–2000
(As a percent of labor force)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Docquier and Marfouk (2005), based on OECD census data.Countries with the Largest Emigration to OECD, 1970–2000
(As a percent of labor force)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Docquier and Marfouk (2005), based on OECD census data.Countries with the Largest Emigration to OECD, 1970–2000
(As a percent of labor force)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Docquier and Marfouk (2005), based on OECD census data.4. Large-scale emigration by economically-active workers worsens the dependency ratio.50 In the case of Grenada, the loss of 54 percent of the labor force through emigration to the OECD, as shown in Figure VII.3, implies that the dependency ratio is 35 percent higher than it would have been with no emigration.
5. Actuarial projections in the ECCU are particularly sensitive to the assumed rate of emigration. Actuarial reviews in most ECCU members have calculated the historical rate of net emigration as the residual change in population from 1991 to 2001 after accounting for births and deaths during that period (based on national censuses). In all cases, the baseline actuarial projections assume that the rate of net emigration, which may differ from the calculated historical rate based on the actuary’s judgment, slows moderately over time.
6. Estimating migration as the residual change in population after adjusting for births and deaths is problematic. For instance, the above approach for St. Kitts and Nevis implies annual net in-migration of 90 persons during 1991–2001. The residual by nature captures not only migration but also any weaknesses in census, birth, or death data.
7. OECD census data, which record a foreign-born resident’s country of origin, provide an alternative method of estimating emigration from the ECCU. Below, emigration is estimated as the stock of immigrants in 2000, assumed to have arrived during the previous 30 years, and calculating the average flow of emigration on that basis. Figure VII.4 compares the various approaches.51 The last approach will be referred to below as the “historical OECD rate.”
ECCU: Estimates of Annual Emigration Rates, 2000
(Persons per year)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: National census data per actuarial reviews; and OECD census data per Docquier and Marfouk (2005).ECCU: Estimates of Annual Emigration Rates, 2000
(Persons per year)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: National census data per actuarial reviews; and OECD census data per Docquier and Marfouk (2005).ECCU: Estimates of Annual Emigration Rates, 2000
(Persons per year)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: National census data per actuarial reviews; and OECD census data per Docquier and Marfouk (2005).8. Constant emigration at the historical OECD rate would imply a stronger demographic transition for most ECCU countries than predicted in actuarial reviews. Under this assumption, the ECCU labor force with constant emigration is 15 percent lower by 2050 than under the actuarial projection (Figure VII.5).
ECCU: Demographic Profile with Constant Emigration at the Historical OECD Rate, 2005–60
(Thousands of persons)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates.ECCU: Demographic Profile with Constant Emigration at the Historical OECD Rate, 2005–60
(Thousands of persons)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates.ECCU: Demographic Profile with Constant Emigration at the Historical OECD Rate, 2005–60
(Thousands of persons)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates.9. In a scenario with constant emigration at the historical OECD rate, pension scheme assets are depleted earlier (Figure VII.6). It can be argued that this assumption is pessimistic, to the extent that ECCU emigration rates have historically been so high that they must at some point decline. In another sense, however, the projection can be seen as optimistic, since the ECCU’s emigrants have been disproportionately highly educated, and therefore higher than average contributors to pension schemes (Mishra, 2006).
ECCU: Projected Year of Pension Fund Reserve Asset Depletion
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: Actuarial reviews; financial statements; and Fund staff estimates.1/ See Section B; assumes constant emigration at historical levels implied by OECD census data.2/ See Section C; the date by which private performing assets are depleted measures the dependence of pension funds on debt service from the public sector.ECCU: Projected Year of Pension Fund Reserve Asset Depletion
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: Actuarial reviews; financial statements; and Fund staff estimates.1/ See Section B; assumes constant emigration at historical levels implied by OECD census data.2/ See Section C; the date by which private performing assets are depleted measures the dependence of pension funds on debt service from the public sector.ECCU: Projected Year of Pension Fund Reserve Asset Depletion
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: Actuarial reviews; financial statements; and Fund staff estimates.1/ See Section B; assumes constant emigration at historical levels implied by OECD census data.2/ See Section C; the date by which private performing assets are depleted measures the dependence of pension funds on debt service from the public sector.C. Asset Returns and Portfolio Allocation
10. ECCU pension schemes have unusually large exposures to the public sector (Figure VII.7). Thus, understanding the potential for underperformance of claims on the public sector and its implications is essential. Large public sector exposure is a concern, as public sector debt ratios in the ECCU are among the highest in the world. An implicit assumption of asset depletion projections is that pension funds can draw down claims, including those on the public sector, to zero, and this may not be the case. For example, Antigua and Barbuda’s central government is not paying debt service to the pension scheme, and is also in arrears on its contributions as an employer. Grenada’s central government was in arrears on debt service to its pension fund until the 2005 debt restructuring, as part of which the pension fund received a haircut. Grenada’s government is now current on debt service falling due, i.e., with interest on restructured debt at a rate of 1 percent. Dominica’s central government was also in arrears on debt service until a debt restructuring in 2005, as part of which the pension fund also received a haircut. Arrears have not been an issue in other ECCU countries. However, the large share of the public sector in portfolios in St. Kitts and Nevis (87 percent) and St. Vincent and the Grenadines (79 percent) leaves pension schemes exposed if public sector difficulties ever do arise.
ECCU: Social Security Reserve Portfolio Asset Allocations
(Percent of portfolio)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: ECCU social security financial statements.ECCU: Social Security Reserve Portfolio Asset Allocations
(Percent of portfolio)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: ECCU social security financial statements.ECCU: Social Security Reserve Portfolio Asset Allocations
(Percent of portfolio)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: ECCU social security financial statements.11. The performance of some other assets has also been unsatisfactory. These include claims on a housing project and mortgages in Antigua and Barbuda; on the airport and water authorities in Grenada; on a car park, mortgages, and leases on government buildings in St. Lucia; and restructured claims on the government of Belize in St. Vincent and the Grenadines.52
12. A useful indicator is therefore the date by which private, performing assets are depleted, ignoring public or nonperforming assets. Maintaining the previous section’s assumption of constant emigration, Figure VII.6 shows the date by which private performing assets are depleted. This indicator is particularly relevant for Antigua and Barbuda, given the public sector’s arrears to the pension fund; it is projected that by 2011 the pension fund will be unable to cover expenditures without transfers from the central government, whether as debt service or otherwise. This could force a fiscal adjustment if pension arrears are to be avoided.
D. Other Age-Related Spending
13. The impact of demographics on pension spending can be placed in the context of trends in other age-related spending.53 This section assesses the impact of population aging in the ECCU on age-related budgetary expenditures on health and education, which were larger than pension scheme expenditure during 2004–06 (see Figure VII.8 and Chapter VIII of this paper).54
ECCU: Average Age-Related Expenditure, 2004–06
(In percent of GDP)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: Budget submissions to parliaments; and Fund staff calculations.Note: Spending data for Ministries of Health and Education may include some nonhealth, noneducation expenditure.ECCU: Average Age-Related Expenditure, 2004–06
(In percent of GDP)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: Budget submissions to parliaments; and Fund staff calculations.Note: Spending data for Ministries of Health and Education may include some nonhealth, noneducation expenditure.ECCU: Average Age-Related Expenditure, 2004–06
(In percent of GDP)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Sources: Budget submissions to parliaments; and Fund staff calculations.Note: Spending data for Ministries of Health and Education may include some nonhealth, noneducation expenditure.14. The net budgetary impact of aging during 2006–50 is to increase spending under plausible assumptions on spending trends. The projection below will assume: (i) education spending per youth as a percent of GDP remains constant;55 and (ii) health spending per elderly person as a percent of GDP remains constant.56 A breakdown by age group of the ECCU’s budgetary spending on health care is not available. The projection below will therefore incorporate optimistic and pessimistic scenarios, in which annual health spending per elderly person is twice and five times the spending per working age person respectively, reflecting the observed ratios in the United Kingdom and Germany (see Honjo, 2006; Federal Statistical Office Germany, 2004).
15. Even in the optimistic scenario, the decline in education spending as the population ages (1.4 percent of GDP) is offset by the increase in health spending (1.8 percent of GDP) (Figure VII.9). In the pessimistic scenario, the increase in health spending (3.2 percent of GDP) far exceeds the decline in education spending. The increase in pension spending of 5.6 percent of GDP predominates in either case.
ECCU: Costs of Aging, 2006 vs. 2050
(In percent of GDP, at actuarial emigration rates)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates.ECCU: Costs of Aging, 2006 vs. 2050
(In percent of GDP, at actuarial emigration rates)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates.ECCU: Costs of Aging, 2006 vs. 2050
(In percent of GDP, at actuarial emigration rates)
Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2008, 096; 10.5089/9781451811728.002.A007
Source: Fund staff estimates.E. Policy Recommendations
16. The factors identified above could magnify the challenge of pension reform and heighten the need for early action to address sustainability issues. Continued emigration at the historical OECD rate would advance the date by which pension fund reserves are depleted, and usable reserves would be depleted even sooner if the public sector has difficulty meeting its large debt service obligations.
17. The pension reforms implemented in St. Lucia in 2003 and Dominica in 2007 indicate that these challenges can be tackled:
In Dominica, reforms included: increasing the minimum pension age by one year every three years up until 65; increasing the employee and employer contribution rates by 1 percentage point; increasing the contribution ceiling from EC$1,000 to EC$6,000 per month; and increasing the number of highest-earning years used in the calculation of the final insurable wage from three to ten years.
In St. Lucia, reforms included: increasing the minimum pension age by one year every three years up until 65; increasing the minimum number of years required for a pension from 10 to 12 years; and reducing the maximum pension from 65 percent to 60 percent of the average insurable wage.
18. The recommendations of actuarial reviews and the IMF’s Fiscal Affairs Department (FAD) provide a roadmap for other ECCU countries to address these challenges. Parametric reforms could include: gradually raising the retirement age from 60 (62 for St. Vincent and the Grenadines) to 65; increasing contribution rates, which are low by regional standards, as well as contribution ceilings; reducing pension accrual rates; and increasing the number of years over which the insurable wage is determined.
19. However, parametric reforms could fail unless supported by public sector adjustment and portfolio diversification. In the past, pension schemes have provided a captive source of financing for the budget and broader social objectives. This financing has relaxed governments’ budget constraints, and contributed to the ECCU’s unusually high debt levels. Parametric reforms will generate pension scheme surpluses, which should be used not to further relax budget constraints but to diversify social security scheme assets away from the public sector.
20. The concentration of pension scheme assets in the public sector reflects in part the regional perception that public investment should serve as one of the main catalysts of economic growth and development. The weak record of public investment in promoting growth, as described by Roache (2007), strengthens the case for diversification from public to private sector assets, and for limiting investments in the domestic public sector to government bonds. Increasing the share of international assets in scheme portfolios would diversify risk, which is particularly important given the region’s vulnerability to natural disasters.
21. As pension schemes diversify away from public sector assets, problems with the performance of private sector assets could become a greater issue. Pension schemes could take advantage of commercial banks’ comparative advantage in allocating resources by limiting domestic private sector investments to placing deposits through banks, and by no longer limiting deposits to those of locally-owned commercial banks. Less emphasis could be given to mortgage lending and other direct private lending, particularly in competition with the private sector. This would also reduce administrative costs, which are high compared with other countries, at the same time that asset returns are increased.
References
Docquier, F., and A. Marfouk, 2005, “Measuring the International Mobility of Skilled Workers,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3381 (Washington DC: World Bank).
Economic Policy Committee and European Commission, 2006, “The Impact of Aging on Public Expenditure: Projections for the EU25 Member States on Pensions, Health Care, Long-Term Care, Education and Unemployment Transfers (2004–50),” European Economy, Special Report No. 1 (Brussels: European Commission).
Federal Statistical Office Germany, 2004, “Cost of Illness 2004 by Diseases and Age,” available at: http://www.destatis.de/basis/e/gesu/gesutab23.htm
Honjo, K., 2006, “Long Term Health Care Costs: Will They Make the Budget Sick?,” in United Kingdom: Selected Issues Papers, International Monetary Fund, Country Report No. 06/87 (Washington DC: International Monetary Fund), pp. 66–78.
International Labor Organization, 2003, Dominica: Eighth Actuarial Review of the Social Security Fund as of 31 December 2002 (Geneva: International Labor Organization).
International Labor Organization, 2004a, Grenada: Seventh Actuarial Review of the Social Security Fund as of 31 December 2002 (Geneva: International Labor Organization).
International Labor Organization, 2004b, St. Kitts and Nevis: Seventh Actuarial Review of the Social Security Fund as of 31 December 2002 (Geneva: International Labor Organization).
International Labor Organization, 2004c, Antigua and Barbuda: Seventh Actuarial Review of the Social Security Fund as of 31 December 2002 (Geneva: International Labor Organization).
International Labor Organization, 2005, St. Lucia: Eighth Actuarial Review of the National Insurance Fund as of 30 June 2003 (Geneva: International Labor Organization).
Mishra, P., 2006, “Emigration and Brain Drain from the Caribbean,” in R. Sahay, D. O. Robinson and P. Cashin (eds.) The Caribbean: From Vulnerability to Sustained Growth (Washington DC: International Monetary Fund), pp. 225–57.
Rasmussen, T., and S. Roache, 2007, “Social Security in the Eastern Caribbean Currency Union” in Eastern Caribbean Currency Union: Selected Issues, International Monetary Fund Country Report No. 07/97 (Washington DC: International Monetary Fund), pp. 67–89.
Roache, S., 2007, “Public Investment and Growth in the Eastern Caribbean” International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 07/124 (Washington DC: International Monetary Fund).
Veira, J., 2005, National Insurance Services of St. Vincent and the Grenadines: Actuarial Valuation as of January 1st 2005 (St. Vincent and the Grenadines: Board of the NIS of St. Vincent and the Grenadines).
Prepared by Hunter Monroe.
These are International Labor Organization (2005; 2004a; 2004b) for St. Lucia, Grenada, and St. Kitts and Nevis; findings by IMF’s Fiscal Affairs Department for Antigua and Barbuda (and ILO (2004c)), Dominica (and ILO (2003)), and Veira (2005) for St. Vincent and the Grenadines. Pension schemes for civil servants are excluded from the analysis below.
Defined as the ratio of economically-inactive population to the economically-active population.
Yet another approach, calculating the change in the stock between 1990 and 2000 OECD censuses, would imply even higher rates of emigration for all ECCU countries but Dominica.
Pension fund financial statements do not provide sufficient detail to calculate the rate of return on nonpublic assets based on interest received rather than interest earned.
A study of age-related spending in the European Union found that population aging will increase costs on pensions, health care, and long-term care by more than it will reduce spending on education and unemployment benefits. See Economic Policy Committee and European Commission (2006).
All spending by Ministries of Health and Education are included, due to data limitations, and includes some spending that is not related to health or education.
In the ECCU, primary education to ages 12–14 is compulsory, while entrance to higher grades is selective.
In the ECCU, government mandates to provide health care are broadly stated, with an evolving practice as to which treatments and medicines are covered.