Iceland: Staff Report for the 2006 Article IV Consultation
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Over the last three years, a rapid expansion in domestic demand has dramatically widened the current account deficit in Iceland. Demand expanded faster than supply, and evidence of overheating is widespread. Monetary policy has tightened, but, until recently, the impact has been channeled primarily through the exchange rate. Despite hikes in the policy rate, increased competition in the mortgage market eased household credit conditions, and household indebtedness has surged. The financial market turbulence early in the year ended the favorable conditions that had allowed banks to fund rapid balance sheet growth.

Abstract

Over the last three years, a rapid expansion in domestic demand has dramatically widened the current account deficit in Iceland. Demand expanded faster than supply, and evidence of overheating is widespread. Monetary policy has tightened, but, until recently, the impact has been channeled primarily through the exchange rate. Despite hikes in the policy rate, increased competition in the mortgage market eased household credit conditions, and household indebtedness has surged. The financial market turbulence early in the year ended the favorable conditions that had allowed banks to fund rapid balance sheet growth.

I. Introduction

1. An economic boom initiated by expansion in the aluminum sector has generated large and growing imbalances. During the upswing, the current account deficit widened appreciably and the balance sheets of Icelandic banks grew tremendously. Early in the year, international markets became concerned that the macro imbalances and the rapid pace of banks’ growth had generated vulnerabilities that could threaten financial stability should the imbalances unwind sharply.

II. Background

2. Over the last three years, a rapid expansion in domestic demand has dramatically widened the current account deficit (Tables 12, Figure 1). Following a 3 percent increase in 2003, GDP growth jumped to 8.2 percent in 2004, and slowed only modestly to 5½ percent in 2005. With the expansion being stimulated by new investment projects in the aluminum sector, a rapid pickup in investment was expected. However, the response of consumption surprised on the upside. The stimulus to household income and confidence was amplified by income taxcuts and increased competition in the mortgage market. The current account deficit reached 16½ percent of GDP in 2005, double the initial forecast, with the bulk of the surprise reflecting increased imports of consumption goods. Roughly one-third of the deficit reflects the new investment projects.

Table 1.

Iceland: Selected Economic Indicators, 2000-07

article image
Sources: Statistics Iceland; Central Bank of Iceland; Ministry of Finance; and staff estimates.

Staff estimates. Actual minus potential output, in percent of potential output.

In percent of labor force.

A positive (negative) sign indicates an appreciation (depreciation).

National accounts basis.

A positive (negative) sign indicates a decrease (increase) in gross official foreign reserves.

Excluding imports from the construction of hydropower facility and smelters in 2003-04.

Table 2.

Iceland: Balance of Payments, 2000-05

article image
Source: Central Bank of Iceland.
Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Growth and the Current Account

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

3. Demand expanded faster than supply and evidence of overheating is widespread (Figures 23). Staff estimate a positive output gap of over 4 percent in 2005, larger than the estimated peak in the late 1990s. During this upswing, temporary work visas have made it easier for firms to utilize imported labor and labor market participation remained strong. However, this has not prevented the unemployment rate from falling below 1 ½ percent, and reported vacancies remain high. CPI inflation has been persistently above the central bank’s 4 percent upper tolerance limit. Inflation has been driven by house price rises that more than offset the effect of earlier currency appreciation and rapid increases in service prices. In light of labor productivity developments, wage inflation of over 8 percent is well above the rate consistent with the central bank’s inflation target. Limited pass-through of exchange rate appreciation into import prices over the last half of 2005 suggests that pressures on capacity are high. Equity prices rose more than 50 percent in each of the last three years.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Indicators of Excess Demand

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

1/ Data prior to 2003Q1 constructed using OECD growth rates.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Evidence of Overheating

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

1/ Deflated by CPI

4. Monetary policy has tightened, but, until recently, the impact has been channeled primarily through the exchange rate (Figure 4). In response to growing inflationary pressures, the policy rate was increased from 5.3 percent in May 2004 to 12¼ percent at end-June 2006. However, households and firms have not felt the full impact of the tightening and bank credit growth has accelerated. Benign conditions in global financial markets enabled some firms to borrow at low foreign rates, and real mortgage rates declined. Also, through early February, the currency appreciated in response to interest rate spreads, focusing the impact of the tightening on the export sector. However, the market turbulence that set in thereafter has led effective lending rates to better reflect the policy rate.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Monetary Policy and Its Transmission

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

Source: Central Bank of Iceland.

5. Despite hikes in the policy rate, increased competition in the mortgage market eased household credit conditions, and household indebtedness has surged. In July 2004, the publicly owned Housing Finance Fund (HFF), designed to provide equal access to mortgage financing throughout the country, changed the way it funded and priced mortgage loans. This change lowered rates to households and prompted domestic banks to aggressively enter the market. Banks offered comparable rates, higher loan-to-value ratios, and allowed the refinancing of existing mortgages, giving households newfound access to built-up home equity. Household debt is now more than double the level of disposable income.

ufg01

Household Debt

(In percent of household disposable income)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

6. Against the background of accumulating imbalances, a series of negative reports from ratings agencies and analysts stoked market concerns early this year (Figure 5). In mid-February, a report from Fitch Ratings changed the outlook on sovereign debt from stable to negative, citing concerns over widening macro imbalances and vulnerabilities in the highly leveraged financial sector. Some additional negative reports followed, heightening the sensitivity to loss among leveraged investors (global carry trades) as global monetary policy conditions tightened (Box 1). Consequently, the exchange rate depreciated, the equity market declined, banks’ bond prices fell, and spreads widened—all by appreciable amounts.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Recent Developments in Financial Markets

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

1/ Exchange rate on inverted scale.

Icelandic Financial Markets in a Global Context

In the first half of 2006, financial market participants became increasingly concerned about several countries with high-yielding currencies, at times citing their external positions as worrisome. Countries frequently mentioned by analysts include Iceland, New Zealand, Turkey, Brazil, and Indonesia. The timing of movements across countries suggests that Iceland and New Zealand may have simply been the first countries to feel the impact of those concerns, possibly reflecting their large external imbalances. In Iceland and New Zealand the depreciations and stock market declines started in February. However, in Turkey, Brazil and Indonesia, they occurred mostly in May, in the context of a broader re-assessment of vulnerabilities and asset valuations in emerging market.

article image
ufg02
Sources: Bloomberg and Datastream.

7. The financial market turbulence early in the year ended the favorable conditions that had allowed banks to fund rapid balance sheet growth (Figure 6 and Table 3). High levels of capitalization, strong profitability, and low default rates resulted in high credit ratings for Icelandic banks. With benign global financial market conditions, banks were able to significantly increase foreign liabilities, with a large portion reflecting banks’ acquisition of financial firms in Europe. Although this expansion diversified banks’ income streams, concerns about the resolution of Iceland’s imbalances and tightening global credit conditions raised doubts about banks’ near-term prospects (Box 2). In particular, concerns centered on their ability to refinance liabilities falling due over the remainder of 2006 and 2007.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Banking Sector Indicators and Foreign Liabilities

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

Sources: Bloomberg, Central Bank of Iceland, FME, and Statistics Iceland.1/ As a percent of appropriate loan category.
Table 3.

Iceland: Financial Soundness Indicators, 1998-2005

article image
article image
Sources: Financial Supervisory Authority and Central Bank of Iceland.

Commercial banks and six largest savings banks. Fisheries Investment Fund and Industrial Loan Fund included 1996-1997. FBA include 1998-1999. Kauphting Inc. included from year 1996. Figures for Islandsbanki include both the banking and insurance part of the corporation.

Deposit money banks, adjusted for FBA and Commercial Loan Fund. Kaupthing bank Inc. included from year 2002 and Glitnir included from May 2003. Figures from year 2003 onwards for sectoral breakdown of lendings is not comparable with the past because of new loan classification.

Item “miscellaneous” also includes individuals’ private business operations. Changed with new loan classification in year 2003. See note above.

Loans for which special provisions have been posted less specific provisions, and other loans which have been interest frozen. Appropriated assets not included. 2003.

Icelandic Banks’ Foreign Expansion and its Impact on their Risk Profile1

The rapid foreign expansion of Icelandic banks in 2004-05 diversified revenues and added deposit base. Banks achieved record profitability in 2006Q1, despite the financial turmoil, partly due to foreign subsidiaries’ performance.

Geographic Diversification of Loan-book and Revenues in 2005 (in percent) 1/

article image
Source: Banks’ Annual Financial Statements, Morgan Stanley.

Loan book exposure for Kaupthing as of 2005Q3.

But risks have also increased. First, banks’ reliance on wholesale funding has increased considerably owing to some foreign acquisitions that are wholesale-funded, increasing banks’ refinancing risks. Second, integrating newly acquired businesses could be challenging in a lesser known environment, which complicates managing credit risk and market risks.

To mitigate such risks, the Financial Supervisory Authority (FME) has signed Memoranda of Understanding with host supervisors to enhance cooperation and information sharing. Moreover, the FME has also conducted onsite supervision in select subsidiaries. Based on FSAP recommendations, the FME now requires banks to report on their policies and procedures for identifying and controlling country risk in their international lending and investments.

1/

Selected Issues Paper "Risks and Vulnerabilities in Icelandic Banks."

8. Fiscal policy was tightened in 2005, but remained less restrictive than during the last cycle (Figure 7 and Table 4). The general government balance moved from a deficit of almost 2 percent of GDP in 2003 to a surplus of roughly 3 percent of GDP in 2005. Approximately half of the 2005 surplus reflects unexpectedly higher tax receipts, buoyed by the consumption and housing market booms. In cyclically-adjusted terms, a deficit of 1 percent of GDP in 2004 swung to a surplus of roughly 1 percent of GDP in 2005. However, given the magnitude of the cycle, fiscal policy has not been as restrictive in level terms as it was in the previous cycle because of income tax cuts and nominal public consumption growth in excess of 8 percent in 2005.

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

The Fiscal Stance, 1999-2005

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

Table 4.

Iceland: Summary Operations of the General Government, 2002-07 1/

(in percent of GDP)

article image
Sources: Ministry of Finance; and Fund staff estimates and calculations.

Official forecast of the Ministry of Finance as of April 2006.

In percent of potential GDP.

Change in percent, deflated by CPI inflation.

Actual output less potential in percent of potential.

Implementation of Past Fund Policy Advice

The authorities have generally pursued policies consistent with Fund advice in structural, financial, and monetary policy areas. There has been, however, more resistance to Fund advice on fiscal policy.

The 2001 Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) served as the basis for strengthening the financial supervisory legal framework and established standards for controlling and managing risk in the payments system. Following the 2005 consultation, the central bank introduced changes to its communication strategy and the Financial Supervisory Authority increased the breadth and stringency of its stress tests, both consistent with Fund advice.

On fiscal policy, introducing multi-year spending targets into the budget was consistent with Fund advice on strengthening the fiscal framework. However, there has been considerably less agreement with the advice on the appropriate cyclical fiscal stance. Further, the authorities have been reluctant to follow Fund advice on reforming the state-owned HFF, the largest mortgage lending institution in Iceland. The HFF reform process has only recently been initiated.

III. Report on the Discussions

9. Given concerns over the resolution of imbalances and the associated impact on the real economy and the financial sector, discussions focused on the policies to help ensure a soft landing and financial stability. There was agreement that the increased flexibility and sound structural fundamentals of the Icelandic economy were aspects that stood to aid the benign resolution of the current imbalances. However, staff stressed that the heightened level of concern in financial markets and the real costs associated with a hard landing made it imperative that policy actions be taken to stabilize confidence, and help ensure an orderly adjustment and maintain financial stability. Accordingly, discussions focused selectively on the following imperative policy priorities:

  • the needed contribution of fiscal restraint, and in particular, the prospects for achieving a tighter-than-budgeted fiscal stance in 2006 and, if warranted, beyond;

  • the path for the policy interest rate required to return inflation to target without a larger than necessary slowing in economic activity; and

  • the authorities’ role in strengthening the financial sector and ensuring speedy reform of the HFF.

10. Although there was broad agreement in many areas, there were key differences between staff and fiscal authorities who saw less need for a tightening in fiscal policy. The official view on fiscal policy reflected a lower estimate of excess demand, constraints on implementing a tighter stance, and a perception that the market turbulence early in the year was driven by misinformation that had subsequently been corrected.

A. Outlook and Risks

11. In both the authorities’ and staff’s baseline projection, growth is likely to remain robust and imbalances persist for the remainder of 2006, but moderate in 2007 (Table 5). GDP growth is expected to be in the range of 4 to 5 percent in 2006 and 1 to 2 percent in 2007. The completion of the aluminum sector projects and continued strong private consumption are seen to be the drivers of growth in 2006. Accordingly, despite some improvement, the strength in domestic demand is projected to generate a still large current account deficit in 2006 (12½ percent of GDP versus 16½ percent of GDP in 2005). However, with investment returning to a normal level and private consumption contracting due to exchange rate depreciation and tightening credit conditions, domestic demand is projected to fall in 2007, cutting the current account deficit by more than half. In 2007, export growth due to increased aluminum production and a more favorable exchange rate is forecast to rebalance growth and contribute to the improvement in the current account.

Table 5.

Iceland. Medium-term Scenario, 2003-11

(Percentage change, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Sources: CBI; and IMF staff estimates.

Contributions to growth

In percent of GDP

In percent of potential output

Iceland: Current Account, 2005-07

(in percent of GDP)

article image
Source: Central Bank of Iceland and staff forecasts.

12. Although there was broad agreement that inflation would remain above the central bank’s target over the next year and a half, the fiscal authorities forecast less persistence. Staff and the central bank see exchange rate depreciation, and pressures in goods and labor markets keeping CPI inflation well above the 2½ percent target. However, reflecting different assumptions about how quickly aluminum sector investment should be added to productive capital,1 the fiscal authorities estimate less excess demand. In addition, they saw less pressure on wages, assuming a more favorable outcome to the potential revisiting of the wage agreement in November2 and expecting labor market pressures to ease following the opening of the labor market to the new EU member states on May 1, 2006. Most of the mission’s stakeholders projected that house price appreciation, which until recently had been the key driver of inflation, would moderate as mortgage credit conditions tighten and housing supply increases. Few saw a significant risk of house price declines.

13. There were notable differences in views regarding the risks to the outlook. In the absence of decisive and coordinated policy actions that cool the economy and re-anchor confidence, staff saw significant risks that further financial market turbulence could lead to a sharp and severe downturn, a concern shared by the central bank. While in an uncertain environment various scenarios are possible, the main concern was that financial market discomfort, given imbalances and their potential impact on a perceived vulnerable financial sector, could spark tightening in banks’ liquidity conditions and rapid currency depreciation. This in turn could force the banks to curtail domestic credit growth abruptly. Consequently, the contraction in domestic demand could be amplified, with negative implications for incomes and second-round affects on banks. With inflation receiving further stimulus from currency depreciation, the central bank would be forced to sustain tighter monetary conditions longer, resulting in a prolonged period with output below potential. The fiscal authorities, however, saw this risk as low, given their view that market turbulence primarily reflected a temporary misreading of Iceland’s fundamentals.

B. Fiscal Policy

14. Although some merit was seen in tightening the fiscal stance over the remainder of 2006, the authorities pointed to several factors that would make it difficult. With imbalances larger than expected at the time of the 2006 budget, staff recommended that additional public investment projects be delayed and growth in public consumption be reduced from the 8.2 percent budgeted. Staff suggested that, at a minimum, the target for the 2006 fiscal surplus as a share of GDP be unchanged from 2005. Although. the authorities perceived less need to take urgent fiscal action, they did note that the strength in the economy would likely deliver stronger revenues, improving the surplus relative to even their most recent forecast. They also pointed to several factors that would make it difficult to reduce 2006 expenditures: limited scope for discretionary adjustment, lags in the planning process, and the political economy setting provided by the upcoming general election.

General Government: Options for Measures in 2006 and Conditional Measures for 2007 1/

(in percent of GDP)

article image
Source: Staff estimates.

Conditional on stronger grow th in 2007, thus cyclically-adjusted balances are not comparable.

Iceland: General Government 2002-07 1/

(in percent of GDP)

article image
Source: Ministry of Finance; and staff estimates.

Official forecast of the Ministary of Finance as of Aptil 2006. Staff projections, consistent with Table 4.

In percent of potential GDP, based on staff’s estimate of the output gap.

15. The authorities saw some scope for tightening the fiscal stance in 2007. Staff advised that an announcement be made that the 2007 budget would contain measures to reduce aggregate demand should the economy not cool as required. Staff pointed to delaying planned income tax cuts, slowing public consumption growth and reducing the pickup in public investment as possibilities. The authorities noted that the latter possibility was indeed being considered and talks to this end were underway.3 While reiterating that the 2007 tax cut would come when domestic demand was expected to be contracting, they noted that the cut could be modified to help avoid an inflationary change to the multi-year wage agreement.

16. The authorities noted that the fiscal framework had been improved in a number of ways and did not see much scope for further strengthening in the near term. Building on previous mission work, staff noted how a rules-based fiscal policy delivering a consistently countercyclical fiscal stance could contribute to stabilizing the Icelandic economy (Box 4). Because of the large economic shocks in Iceland, it is more important than in other industrial countries that fiscal policy strongly reinforce monetary policy. The authorities agreed in principle, and argued that the current framework, with multi-year spending targets and countercyclical adjustments to public investment, was a “quasi” fiscal rule. However, they acknowledged that generating the three-year spending targets using the central bank’s inflation target rather than their inflation forecast would increase the counter cyclicality of fiscal policy, transparency, and accountability. Nevertheless, because of the strong indexing culture in Iceland, building the political consensus for such a change would take time. However, the authorities expressed interest in working with staff to develop a range of feasible rules-based frameworks.

Rules-based Fiscal Policy and Inflation and Output Variability in Iceland

Efficient policy frontiers constructed using estimated macroeconomic models suggest that the inflation-output variability trade-off faced by the monetary authorities in Iceland is considerably less favorable than in other industrial countries. This reflects the relative magnitude of economic disturbances in Iceland.

ufg03
1/ From B. Hunt, “Simple Efficient Policy Rules and Inflation Control in Iceland.” (IMF Country Report No.05/366).2/ Fiscal policy defined as above, where fiscal balance (FB) is determined by a cyclical component (Ygap- output gap) and the debt gap (D-D* - deviation from the debt target).

Systematic coordination of monetary and fiscal policy, however, could help improve the trade-off. The introduction of a simple fiscal rule designed to simultaneously ensure a consistently countercyclical fiscal stance and achieve a stable public debt target shifts the efficient frontier toward the southwest, reducing inflation, output, interest rate, and exchange rate variability.1

1

Selected issues paper “Rules-Based Fiscal Policy and Inflation and Output Variability in Iceland.”

C. Monetary Policy

17. The tightening in monetary policy over the last year was jointly viewed as appropriate, but mortgage market developments had limited its impact on domestic demand. With inflation persistently above the central bank’s 4 percent upper tolerance limit, monetary conditions needed to tighten. However, competition in the mortgage market between the banks and the HFF kept real mortgage rates low and loan conditions easy. Consequently, the increase in the policy rate was prevented from having a significant impact on household credit conditions. There was agreement that reform of the HFF would help restore a more traditional transmission mechanism for monetary policy and thereby improve its effectiveness. However, with predominantly long-term fixed-real-rate mortgages that amortize inflation surprises over the remaining term, the policy rate was likely to be less effective than in other countries having largely shorter-term, nominal-rate mortgage contracts. Nonetheless, it was thought possible that following effective HFF reform, mortgage contracts could evolve to give the policy rate greater impact on household credit conditions.4

18. The authorities outlined the initial proposal for reforming the HFF; however, banks expressed strong reservations to which staff were sympathetic. The proposal involved a new state-owned entity that would raise funds, design mortgage products, and control credit approval. Banks would sell these products under their own brands, and bear the credit risk during the initial few years of the mortgage. The banks expressed their desire for the state to withdraw from the mortgage market, wind down the HFF, and create a new privately held wholesale financing entity. Such a system would allow them to retain the mortgages on their balance sheets, design products they felt best suited the market, and retain loan approval authority.

19. There was consensus that the policy rate would need to rise further to contain expectations and return inflation to target over a reasonable horizon. With additional inflationary pressures expected from currency depreciation, and tight goods and labor markets, it was agreed that the central bank needed to act decisively to raise real interest rates and anchor expectations. ISK Euro bonds maturing in the last quarter of the year were anticipated to weaken the currency and there were no strong indicators that demand pressures were starting to ease. Given the very high output costs of re-anchoring inflation at target once high inflation becomes entrenched in expectations, there was broad agreement that, at this juncture, the central bank should be biased toward a tight monetary stance. Following the mission, the central bank raised its policy rate by 75 basis points, and markets expect additional increases will be forthcoming.

20. The authorities viewed the introduction of the preannounced schedule for monetary policy meetings as successful and stressed that the framework would continue to evolve. It was noted that the preannounced policy meetings had enhanced internal procedures and communication, and helped anchor expectations. There was some agreement with staff’s suggestion of having more than 6 preannounced meeting per year, particularly when the time comes to ease policy. Smaller, more frequent steps might allow for more caution. Further, the response has been favorable to the authorities’ public discussions of their assessment of the interest rate adjustment necessary to return inflation to target. They expect the presentation of this assessment to become more detailed and explicit as their experience increases. The authorities expressed disagreement with the Mishkin and Herbertsson report5 recommendation to alter the way house prices enter the inflation target. The authorities argued, and staff concurred, that house price inflation is often a leading indicator of general inflationary pressures and cannot be ignored. Further, the wide use of headline CPI inflation in indexed contracts means that it is the appropriate index to stabilize from a welfare perspective. However, research will proceed, as staff previously advised, to identify less volatile indices that include house prices and are highly correlated in the medium-term with headline CPI. Once headline CPI inflation has been re-anchored at the target rate, it would then be appropriate to consider alternatives.

D. Competitiveness

21. There was agreement that the year-to-date depreciation in the currency was an appropriate adjustment from an overvalued level. Although the depreciation, reflecting market forces, occurred sooner and faster than expected, the currency is now close to most observers’ estimate of equilibrium. Despite the high degree of uncertainty associated with such estimates, particularly in a country undergoing such large structural changes as Iceland (Box 5), there is broad consensus that the equilibrium for the nominal effective exchange rate (ISK) index lies between 125 and 140. Given the magnitude of imbalances in the economy, most observers expect some undershooting of the exchange rate before it stabilizes in the medium term. The export sector, which has become adept at adjusting to currency fluctuations, will nevertheless receive a needed boost to profitability. In turn this should spur investment, further improving competitiveness.

The Equilibrium Exchange Rate in Iceland

The recent sharp widening of the current account balance in Iceland has raised concerns about the country’s long-term external sustainability. Using the estimated parameters from Chinn and Ito (2005), the current account balance consistent with long-run balances in saving and investment in Iceland lies in the range of -½ to -1½ percent of GDP.1 A simple regression of the changes in the current account balance and the real exchange rate suggests that the real exchange rate would need to depreciate by roughly 10-15 percent to bring down the deficit to the level implied by the S-I norm. Such adjustment could take the form of lower inflation or depreciation in the nominal exchange rate, but assuming that inflation will decline to target, the implied equilibrium rate for the nominal ISK exchange rate index would need to be in the range of 125-140 (at the end of June the ISK index stood at 130). However, estimating the equilibrium exchange rate entails large uncertainties. This is in part attributed to differences in methodology, the choice of variables used as proxies for the fundamental determinants of the equilibrium rate, and the period studied. Also, the various estimation approaches are particularly difficult to implement in a country like Iceland, where substantial structural change in recent years make underlying economic relationships unstable. Moreover, it is not clear whether such adjustment will stabilize the ratio of net foreign assets to GDP given the growing role played by banks’ assets in the Iceland’s net IIP position.

ufg04

Current Account Balance and Net IIP Position

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

ufg05

Effective Exchange Rates 1/

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

1/ Preliminary Q2 data for 2006.
1

Chinn and Ito (2005), “Current Account Balances, Financial Development and Institutions: Assaying the World Saving Glut”, NBER Working Paper 11761, November 2005.

22. Although there are pockets of support, euro adoption is not broadly viewed to be viable for Iceland. The authorities noted that support for euro adoption only arises during periods of market stress. Even those currently in favor see it as part of a medium-term rather than a near-term strategy. Those opposed argue that the probability is quite low that euro area monetary policy would ever be set appropriately for Iceland’s cyclical conditions. For example, it was noted that the current boom could have been much larger if Iceland had enjoyed euro area interest rates.

E. The Financial Sector

23. There was consensus that banks’ rapid expansion had increased their risk profile, but measures have and should continue to be taken to make those risks manageable (Box 6).The authorities shared staff’s view that the key risks in the banking sector were liquidity, credit, and interconnectedness through crossholdings of equity. The discussions revealed the following:

  • banks have taken considerable steps to ensure their liquidity requirements are met (see Box 6 for details);

  • credit quality has remained high and appears robust to large movements in exchange and interest rates; and

  • crossholdings of equity are being reduced and associated connected lending is monitored closely by supervisors.

Despite the steps banks have taken, there was broad agreement among staff, supervisors, and banks that the process needs to continue. In particular, banks must further diversify their funding, grow their balance sheets cautiously, be increasingly vigilant regarding credit quality, and continue to reduce crossholdings of equity.

Assessment of the Risks in the Icelandic Banking Sector

The mission assessed the vulnerability of the banking system—of which Kaupthing, Landsbanki and Glitnir represent more than 80 percent—to the main risks: credit, liquidity, and interconnectedness through the crossholdings of equity.

  • Liquidity risk: The high rate of asset growth of banks and a low deposit base imply that banks are heavily reliant on wholesale funding, mostly from international investors.

ufg06

Loans, 2004

(in percent of deposits)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

ufg07

Interbank Borrowings and Debts, 2004

(in percent of assets)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

The refusal, early in the year, of US money market funds to rollover the banks’ 13-month extendible debts signaled the likelihood of banks facing higher refinancing costs. Bank bond prices have fallen with spreads (above EURIBOR)rising to 100bp before settling at 60bp recently. Although all three banks face heavy refinancing needs in 2006-07, discussions with the banks and the FME suggested that there is no immediate threat of a liquidity crunch due to lack of market access. Although foreign liabilities maturing in 3-6months are more than covered by liquid assets (excluding market securities and credit lines), those maturing in 6-12 months are not. However, banks have mostly closed their 2006 funding gap, and have credible plans for closing 2007 needs. In addition, banks have to meet the central bank mandated liquidity ratio of over 1 in the 0- 3 month horizon and banks have developed foreign exchange liquidity management policies and contingency plans based on FME guidelines.

The vulnerability to liquidity risks is partly mitigated by:

ufg08

3-Bank Aggregate

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

  • committed back-up facilities, mostly from European banks;

  • banks’ steps to diversify their global investor base and lengthen maturities, which has now increased to average 3-5 years;

  • growing deposit bases, especially of subsidiaries; and

  • securitization.

If banks used bond issues to close their 6-12 month liquidity gap, the extra refinancing cost is estimated to have asmall impact on profitability—less than ½ percentage point of aggregate return on assets (ROA) at a spreadof 100bp.

  • Credit risk: Credit growth averaging 44 percent y-o-y 2003-05, in an already deep financial market has increased the risk that loan quality may have been overestimated. Although default rates and the nonperforming loan (NPL) ratio are low, these are susceptible to rapid increases when the cycle turns.

ufg09

Credit Growth Versus Depth, 2005

(in percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

Default Rates and Non-performing Loans 1/

article image

Total of commercial and savings banks.

The FME estimates that the nominal value of NPLs rose by 22 percent y-o-y 2004-05. Being a backward-looking indicator, the NPL ratio can turn with a down-cycle due to highly leveraged counterparties—private sector debt/GDP ratio is nearly 200 percent. But, given that most fx loans are made to hedged customers and most household loan contracts areindexed to inflation, the impact of exchange rate and interest rate changes on loan quality is expected to be small.

Banks’ exposure to credit risk could be aggravated by the following vulnerabilities, although accompanying mitigants exist:

  • Crossholdings: The complex web of ownership extends to crossholdings by banks of companies they lend to. Thisreduces transparency while exposing banks to double-sided risks of being hit on the assets by declining equity prices of their crossholdings, and on capitalization from possible deterioration of credit quality of the borrower. However, banks require equity-collateral of 150-200 percent of the loan, with margin calls starting at 140-160 percent (varying by banks). Also, FME deducts equity holdings in financial companies from banks’ regulatory capital. All three banks have started reducing crossholdings and this process needs to continue.

  • Connected lending: The FME monitors connected lending through its guidelines and reporting requirements to ensure loans to connected parties are made on an arm’s length basis. However, the FME does not have a mandate to set up limits on such loans, to deduct their amounts from capital, or to require banks to collateralize them.

24. Traditional indicators of financial sector health suggest the banks remain sound.Stress tests performed by the FME and central bank indicate that bank capital appears adequate to withstand large shocks (Box 7). Profitability, although having recently been driven to record highs by gains from equity trading and exchange rate movements, should remain strong in the absence of these factors. Core profitability has been increasing, in part reflectingthe impact of banks’ foreign expansion.

Stress Tests on Solvency of the Banking System

Overall, the banking sector achieved record ROA in 2006Q1, but vulnerabilities have slightly increased. FME stress tests done quarterly show that the system is resilient to the simultaneous occurrence of large shocks—increase in write-off of non-performing loans/impaired loans by 20 percent, write-offs of non-mortgage and mortgage loans increasing to their historical highs (1.8 and 0.2 percent respectively), price declines of 35 percent in domestic equities and 25 percent in foreign equities, fall in marketable bond portfolio by 7percent, and depreciation of the ISK index by 25 percent. Applying the tests on 2005Q4 and 2006Q1 results shows that the post-shock capital adequacy ratio (CAR) is marginally closer to the 8 percent minimum in 2006Q1 than in 2005Q4. Each of the bars in the figure show the post-shock effect of each of the tests and all tests together on the CAR.

ufg10

Post-shock CAR Compared--3 Commercial Banks Aggregate

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

The design and magnitudes of the shocks, except the interest rate shock, provide an adequate stress test of the banking system. The CAR is sensitive to the design of the interest rate shock—duration and magnitude—on the trading bond portfolio. It would be preferable if the test was based on the likely change in interest rates along the yield curve as domestic and global monetary policy conditions tighten, rather than by value of portfolio. To enhance transparency, the assumptions underlying the stress tests (especially “credit risk 1”) could be discussed more on the website and with the banks. Encouragingly, the FME has decided not to reduce the stringency of the test followingthe large adjustments in markets that have occurred year-to-date.

25. The supervisory and financial stability frameworks continue to be strengthened. The FME has now implemented most of the FSAP recommendations including issuing guidelines on connected lending and monitoring of country risk. Consistent with previous Article IV recommendations, capital-adequacy stress tests have been broadened and made more stringent. The central bank and the FME have strengthened their cooperation and recently undertook a joint contingency exercise simulating various stress scenarios. Early in the year, a Memorandum of Understanding was signed by the relevant ministries, the central bank, and the FME on consultation concerning financial stability and contingency plans in the event of severe stress.

IV. Staff Appraisal

26. Although current imbalances need to be addressed resolutely, the medium-term outlook for the Icelandic economy remains highly favorable. At the current juncture, mounting imbalances in the current account, excess demand, andinflation, plus the associated threats to stability are concerns that policymakers must address promptly. However, the structural fundamentals are sound. Institutions and policy frameworks are strong. Markets are open and flexible, and the skillful management of the country’s natural endowments has diversified the economy and helped to ensure sustainability. Further, these factors are combined with a culture of entrepreneurial dynamism that has led to economic outcomes that belie the country’s small size.

27. Although public debt is low and declining, an adjustment to the current fiscal plan is required to reduce imbalances and avert related risks. Macroeconomic imbalances that are wider than expected at the time of the 2006 budget have increased the risk that the economy could experience an abrupt and disruptive contraction. The downturn could be exacerbated if international financial market conditions become less favorable for Iceland. On current plans, the fiscal surplus will decline in 2006 relative to what was achieved in 2005. The high growth budgeted for nominal public consumption should be reduced and more public investment should be delayed to maintain fiscal restraint in 2006 at the same level as in 2005. The government ought to announce that additional fiscal restraint will be introduced in the budget for 2007 if domestic demand pressures do not abate as required. Areas for potential adjustment include planned tax cuts, public investment, and public consumption.

28. The fiscal framework should continue to be strengthened to help reduce the volatility in the Icelandic economy in the future. The introduction of multi-year budgeting was the first step along the path to a rules-based framework. The next step is to add more structure to the budgeting and implementation processes to ensure that fiscal policy provides consistent and substantial offsets to the fluctuations in private demand that have generated large swings in economic activity in Iceland. Such a systematic approach to fiscal policy would consistently reinforce monetary policy and increase economic stability.

29. Further increases in the policy rate, sufficient to increase real interest rates, will be required to anchor expectations, and return inflation to target. Although house prices, which have driven inflation well above target in the recent past, are starting to show some signs of moderation, rising prices of imported and domestic goods and services are forecast to keep inflation persistently high for an extended period.

30. Given the high output cost of returning inflation to target should expectations of high inflation become entrenched, the central bank should be biased toward a tight monetary stance. There are comforting signs that monetary policy is starting to have more of an impact on the credit conditions faced by households and firms, and these developments will need to be monitored carefully to gauge the appropriate degree of monetary restraint. Moreover, inflation expectations should now be better anchored with the introduction of the preannounced schedule of monetary policy meetings and the central bank’s open discussion of the interest rate path required to return inflation to target.

31. The flexible exchange rate regime, introduced in 2001, has worked well. Although high domestic interest rates attracted carry trade investors, contributing to exchange rate variability, domestic agents did not taken significant currency exposure. Consequently, the depreciation in the exchange rate early in the year, which has moved the currency close to its equilibrium value, has not adversely affected domestic balance sheets.

32. The financial system appears sound, but actions should continue to be taken to reduce vulnerabilities. The balance sheets of Icelandic banks have been growing at a remarkable pace. International markets are concerned that this pace of growth has exposed the Icelandic financial system to vulnerabilities that could undermine its health as the economy adjusts to restore balance. Potential vulnerabilities include considerable near-term refinancing needs, credit quality, the long-term sustainability of the banks’ presence in the domestic mortgage market, and the crossholdings of equity. Banks are taking significant steps to meet their funding needs over the near term. Should systemic issuesarise, the authorities have put in place a consultation process and contingency plans to support financial stability. In addition, the banks have begun reducing crossholdings of equity, thereby making ownership structures more transparent. At this point in the economic cycle, it will also be important for banks to be increasingly vigilant regarding creditquality. Given global credit conditions, banks need to expand their balance sheets more cautiously than in the recent past and diversify their funding. Stress tests performed by the central bank and the FME suggest that banks’ capitalization can withstand very large shocks. Should there be a sharp downturn in the economy, the impact would likely show up in reduced profitability through a reversal of trading gains, higher financing costs, and increases in non-performing loans.

33. The continued strengthening of the supervisory framework is welcome. For example, the broadening and increased stringency in the stress tests should provide positive assurance for international markets, as should the banks’ willingness to make the bank-bybank results of these tests public. To further improve the stress tests, the FME should make the interest rate component more closely match how interest rates along the yield curve adjust as monetary policy tightens.

34. The HFF needs immediate reform. The competition between the banks and the state-subsidized HFF has undermined the effectiveness of monetary policy, unnecessarily exacerbated macroeconomic imbalances, and threatened financialstability. The initial reform proposal, with continued public ownership, falls short of what is required. Instead, winding down the existing HFF and creating a new privately-held wholesale funding institution would retain important economies of scale in mortgage funding and allow for healthy competition among the banks in the mortgage market. As international experience proves, the social objective of adequate access to mortgage financing can be achieved with more efficient and targeted public programs.

35. It is recommended that the next Article IV consultation occur on the 12-month cycle.

Appendix I: Iceland: Fund Relations

(As of May 31, 2006)

I. Membership Status: Joined: December 27, 1945; Article VIII

II. General Resources Account:

article image

III. SDR Department:

article image

IV. Outstanding Purchases and Loans: None

V. Financial Arrangements: None

VI. Projected Payments to the Fund

(SDR Million; based on existing use of resources and present holdings of SDRs):

article image

VII. Implementation of HIPC Initiative: Not applicable

VIII. Exchange Rate Arrangements: Iceland adopted a floating exchange rate regime for the kröna effective March 28, 2001 and since that time the exchange rate has been determined solely by market forces.

Iceland continues to maintain exchange restrictions pursuant to UN sanction against Iraq (see EBD/90/242, 7/13/90).

IX. Last Article IV Consultation :

Discussion for the 2005 Article IV Consultation were held in Reykjavik during June 2–13. 2005. The Staff Report (Country Report No. 05/367) was considered by the Executive Board on October 3, 2005. Article IV consultations with Iceland are currently held on the 12–month cycle.

X. Technical Assistance: None

XI. Resident Representative: None

Appendix II: Iceland: External Debt Sustainability

Significant current account deficit, driven by the investment projects coupled with expansion of Icelandic firms andcommercial banks abroad, resulted in a sharp increase of the external debt (from 143.0 percent of GDP in 2003 to 291.3 in 2005). In net term the level of debt has risen by about 60 percentage points to 158.1 percent of GDP in 2005. As Table A1 indicates, in the baseline scenario external debt is projected to stabilize just below 150 percent of GDP. The alternative scenarios and bound tests indicate that while various shocks could drive the net external debt to up to 165 percent of GDP, an additional 30 percent depreciation in real terms could push the level of net external debt to 250 percent of GDP. It should be noted however, that the baseline scenario already assumes 15 percent depreciation in nominal terms in 2006.

Table 1.

Iceland: External Debt Sustainability Framework, 2000-10

(In percent of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

article image

Derived as [r - g - p(1 +g) + ea(l+r)]/(1+g+p+gp) times previous period debt stock, with r = nominal effective interest rate on external debt; p = change in domestic GDP deflator in US dollar terms, g = real GDP growth rate, = nominal appreciation (increase in dollar value of domestic currency), and a = share of domestic-currency denominated debt in total external debt.

The contribution from price and exchange rate changes is defined as [-p(1 +g) +ea(1+r)]/(1+g+p+gp) times previous period debt stock. p increases with an appreciating domestic currency (u > 0) and rising inflation (based on GDP deflator).

For projection, line includes the impact of price and exchange rate changes.

Defined as current account deficit, plus amortization on medium- and long-term debt, plus short-term debt at end of previous period.

The key variables include real GDP growth; nominal interest rate; dollar deflator growth; and both non-interest current account and non-debt inflows in percent of GDP.

Long-run, constant balance that stabilizes the debt ratio assuming that key variables (real GDP growth, nominal interest rate, dollar deflator growth, and non-debt inflows in percent of GDP) remain at their levels of the last projection year.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Iceland: External Debt Sustainability: Bound Tests 1/

(External debt in percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2006, 296; 10.5089/9781451819328.002.A001

Sources: International Monetary Fund, Country desk data, and staff estimates.1/ Shaded areas represent actual data. Individual shocks are permanent one-half standard deviation shocks. Figures in the boxes represent average projections for the respective variables in the baseline and scenario being presented. Ten-year historical average for the variable is also shown.2/ Permanent 1/4 standard deviation shocks applied to real interest rate, growth rate, and current account balance.3/ One-time real depreciation of 30 percent occurs in 2006.
1

The fiscal authorities immediately add investment flows to productive capital whereas staff add investment flows to the capital stock only after the associated plant and equipment has become fully productive.

2

The multi-year wage agreement contains the provision to revisit previously agreed wage increases should inflation persistently exceed the central bank’s 4 percent upper tolerance limit, as is the case this year. At the end of June, the social partners agreed to keep the wage agreement in force given the government’s commitment to change to the personal exemption for income tax. The change will be financed by reducing the 2007 cut in the income tax rate from 2 percentage points to 1 percentage point.

3

On June 27 the government announced a reduction in public investment in 2007 close the amount suggested by staff. Further, the maximum loans and loan-to-value ratios at the government-owned HFF were also reduced.

4

Even in the current market, some banks have introduced mortgages which reset the interest rate every five years.

5

The report, entitled “Financial Stability in Iceland”, was commissioned by the Iceland Chamber of Commerce and published in May 2006.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Iceland: Staff Report for the 2006 Article IV Consultation
Author:
International Monetary Fund