Cyprus: Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix

This Selected Issues paper and Statistical Appendix analyzes labor market institutions and reforms for Cyprus. The paper describes the legal and institutional framework of the Cypriot labor market, and discusses the voluntary framework for negotiations, the degree of unionization and the system of tripartism, the wage setting mechanism, and labor market programs. The paper makes an assessment of the flexibility and efficiency of the Cypriot labor market, and in particular, the wage-setting mechanism. It also examines the trends and developments in the external competitiveness of Cyprus.

Abstract

This Selected Issues paper and Statistical Appendix analyzes labor market institutions and reforms for Cyprus. The paper describes the legal and institutional framework of the Cypriot labor market, and discusses the voluntary framework for negotiations, the degree of unionization and the system of tripartism, the wage setting mechanism, and labor market programs. The paper makes an assessment of the flexibility and efficiency of the Cypriot labor market, and in particular, the wage-setting mechanism. It also examines the trends and developments in the external competitiveness of Cyprus.

I. Labor Market Institutions and Reforms1

A. Introduction

1. The Cypriot labor market contains a number of specific features that render it of interest, despite the fact that relatively little has been written about it internationally. Some of the features characterizing the Cypriot labor market are arguably very positive, such as the low level of unemployment, consensus decision making, which in turn contributes to maintaining labor peace, a voluntary framework with limited legislation, flexible hiring and firing rules, non-binding minimum wages, an efficient unemployment insurance system, and a tax system favorable to labor income. At the same time, there are important sources of rigidity in the Cypriot labor market, in particular the wage-setting mechanism and labor supply bottlenecks. In the past, these rigidities have contributed to real wage growth that is in excess of productivity growth, and to Cypriot competitiveness falling behind that of its competitors. Looking ahead, with accession to the European Union, such rigidities may prove to be even more disadvantageous as the Cypriot economy faces increased competition from other European enterprises and an inflow of EU workers.

2. This paper is structured as follows. Section B describes the legal and institutional framework of the Cypriot labor market, and discusses the voluntary framework for negotiations, the degree of unionization and the system of tripartism, the wage setting mechanism, entry and exit conditions and working hours, labor market programs, employment by sectors etc., the roles of foreign and Turkish-Cypriot workers, and lastly, the recently issued National Action Plan for Employment. Section C makes an assessment of the flexibility and efficiency of the Cypriot labor market, and in particular the wage-setting mechanism. International comparisons are made, and wage indexation is examined from both a theoretical and an empirical perspective. Section C also provides some suggestions for reform to enhance the efficiency of the wage-setting mechanism, and to enhance labor utilization. Lastly, Section D summarizes and concludes.

B. Legal and Institutional Framework

Voluntary Agreements2

3. Since the establishment of the Republic of Cyprus in 1960, social partners have approached industrial relations and conflict resolution mechanisms in a voluntary manner, with a minimum of legislative measures governing the relations between employers and employees. Framework laws guarantee the right of workers and employers to form associations, bargain collectively, and strike (or lock out). Meanwhile, voluntary norms, such as collective agreements and codes of conduct, determine the procedural framework for the bargaining process and the guidelines for labor relations.3

4. The Industrial Relations Code of 1977 sets the framework for collective bargaining in the private sector and for the semi-government organizations (public enterprises).4 The code asserts the rights to organize and to bargain collectively, and defines the proper issues for collective bargaining. It affirms the strict adherence to the provisions of international labor conventions ratified by the government, contains limitations regarding the right to resort to industrial actions, and assigns the government the function of mediator in labor disputes. In 2004, the code was extended with a voluntary agreement on the provision of essential services during labor disputes.

5. The government’s philosophy behind the promotion of a voluntary system has been the fostering of strong employer and employee organizations, with a view to maintaining a balance of power between the two sides. The focus of the government has been on assisting the two sides in reaching agreement, thereby safeguarding peaceful labor relations and preventing the outbreak of labor actions. All in all, the system has contributed to maintaining good industrial relations and labor peace in Cyprus and reducing the number of labor disputes and work days lost to conflicts, in particular in the sectors covered by the Industrial Relations Code.5

Unionization and Tripartism

6. A second characteristic of the Cypriot labor market is its high degree of centralization. On average, some 65 percent of all workers belong to industry-based trade unions, which are organized in a small number of closely coordinated national federations. If one excludes the retail trade sector, union membership is even higher. Public sector employees, teachers, and bank employees have separate unions that are not affiliated with the national federations but which cooperate with them on issues of common interest. Despite the high degree of unionization, trade union membership is not a condition for employment in any sector.

7. The strength and importance of unions differ. The three large private sector unions, PEO, SEK, and DEOK, are divided along more or less politically-driven lines, with each union associated with one or more of the large political parties. Workers in the semi-government companies are also mainly organized in SEK and PEO, by far the two largest unions in Cyprus. While SEK is mainly a white-collar union, allied with the right-wing DYSY party, PEO is a blue-collar left-of-center trade union that is closely allied with the socialist ruling coalition member AKEL party. Private sector unions are generally seen as less “driven,” in part reflecting the dispersion of private sector employees across a large number of small firms. In fact, parts of the private sector, in particular the retail sector, have basically no unionization. Meanwhile, the banking and insurance sectors are dominated by one strong union, ETYK, which enjoys virtually 100 percent membership. Over the years, ETYK has acquired a role, rights, and status that, according to Messios (2004), in many cases reach into fields that typically are considered management prerogatives.6 The public sector is represented by one strong union, PASYDY, which enjoys effectively a 100 percent unionization rate. Membership rates also reach 100 percent in case of the teachers union.

8. Most employers are members of industrial associations, in particular Cyprus Employers and Industrialists Federation, and the Chamber of Commerce and Industry. Both organizations have equal representation in the various tripartite bodies, such as the Labor Advisory Board, the Economic Consultative Committee, the Social Insurance Board, and others.

9. The existence of highly concentrated representative organizations of labor and employers facilitates the process of tripartism. This process, which also includes the government, has become the main mechanism for discussion not only of a wide range of labor issues but also economic issues more generally. For example, the recently published medium-term Convergence Program has been the subject of an extensive discussion between the government and the social partners.7

Wages

10. The common process in which the terms and conditions of employment, including wage setting, are determined is collective bargaining.8 Negotiations are usually first conducted at a broad sectoral level and then concluded at the branch level. At times, negotiations take place at the national level, either to define a framework for the sectoral discussion, or when issues of broader impact are being negotiated, such as the indexation of wages, and the length of the work week. Furthermore, the organization of unions into main federations ensures that agreements reached at the different sector and branch levels do not deviate greatly from a “national target.” Most collective agreements last two years although in some cases sectoral collective agreements are signed for a 3-year period.

11. One important part of the wage determination process in Cyprus is the cost-of-living allowance (COLA). Through the COLA, wages are indexed to average CPI inflation in the preceding six months twice a year, on January 1 and on July 1.9 The COLA is strongly supported by the trade unions and has remained a non-negotiable issue at the time of collective wage bargaining. Only minor changes to the system have been accepted in the last few years, in particular the exclusion of excise tax increases since the second half of 1999. In turn, the existence of the COLA has facilitated achieving long-term contracts and private sector wage increases in line with average productivity growth.10 Meanwhile, employer organizations have increasingly expressed concerns that the system undermines flexibility and competitiveness, and that it does not respond to real increases in productivity in specific sectors or individual enterprises.

12. Minimum wages in Cyprus remain relatively low and do not constitute effective constraints on employment. The legal minimum wage applies only to a few non-unionized occupations like clerks, salespersons, and day care and elderly care personnel, and is increased annually roughly in line with the minimum wage set in collective agreements.

13. While minimum wages so far have been effectively non-binding, a recent government decision may change that. According to this decision, which was taken in October 2004, minimum wages, which currently are about 42–43 percent of the national median wage, will be raised to 50 percent of the national median by 2008, implying some 10 percent increase a year. As a result, the legal monthly minimum wage was increased by 8 percent to ₤C 345 upon hiring, and by 6 percent to ₤C 367 after six months of employment.

Entry, Exit, and Working Hours

14. Hiring and firing remains quite flexible in Cyprus. There are no hiring quotas in the private sector, except for employees dismissed due to redundancy, which according to law shall have priority for rehiring within eight months of dismissal. Also, termination of employment in Cyprus is less restrictive than in most other European countries, both in case of redundancies and dismissals for other reasons. Employees that are laid off due to redundancy reasons are not entitled to compensation directly from the employer but instead receive a lump-sum payment from a central redundancy fund financed by regular employer contributions. Employers are also required to notify the Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance at least four weeks in advance of planned redundancy layoffs. In case of dismissal for other reasons, the employee receives severance pay of up to two years’ salary depending on the cause of dismissal and the length of service. There are specific rules regarding advance notices and paid leave during the notice period and most sectors impose a “first in first out” rule for such dismissals. In contrast to many OECD countries, there are virtually no legal restrictions on the cause of dismissal. Still, sectors dominated by very strong unions, in particular the banking sector, in reality experience very few dismissals, e.g. in connection with mergers.

15. With a few exceptions, working hours are set through collective agreements. In line with the 1992 national collective agreement, the then 40-hour work week was gradually reduced to 38 hours as of 1998. Recent efforts by the employer organization to return to 40 hours a week have been thwarted by the unions. One curious aspect of the Cypriot labor market is the uniformity as to which hours are worked. Literally all work places, ranging from government offices to schools, are open almost exactly the same hours, from around 7:30 in the morning to around 2:30 in the afternoon, resulting in bunching of traffic, parents dropping off their children at school consistently being late for work.

16. While part-time employment has long been permitted without any special restrictions, it remains rare. In particular, though such employment now is safeguarded through EU harmonized legislation, it still faces strong resistance by the unions, which worry that part-time employment takes place outside the negotiated collective agreements. In 2003, only 8.9 percent of the gainfully employed population was working on a part-time basis, compared with over 17 percent in EU25. Mostly women work part time, or 13.2 percent of employed Cypriot women in 2003 compared with 30 percent of women in employment in EU25, and compared with 5.5 percent of employed Cypriot men. Still, part-time employment is increasing, rising by 7.2 percent between 2002 and 2003.11

Labor Market Programs

17. Unemployment benefits are relatively less generous than in most other EU countries, with a high earnings’ replacement rate offset by shorter duration of benefits. Benefits are paid from the fourth day of unemployment and for a maximum of 156 days, which is relatively short compared with EU standards. Also, in order for unemployment benefits to be renewed, the individual needs to be reemployed for at least 26 weeks. However, replacement rates are relatively high, amounting to about 70 percent of previous gross earnings in 2003.12 The short duration of benefits is mainly meant to encourage efficient job search and reflects the situation of the Cypriot labor market, which is functioning at or near full employment with mainly frictional unemployment. Generally, the unemployment benefits system has not been tested since the early 1980s, as high growth and a limited supply of labor have contributed to a constant decline in the now very low unemployment rate. Furthermore, international labor mobility has functioned as a safety valve at the margin, with Cypriots emigrating initially, and since the early 1990s the recruitment of foreign labor.

18. In total, spending on labor market programs remains limited in Cyprus compared with other European countries. In 2002, spending on unemployment compensation amounted to only 0.4 percent of GDP, while spending on labor market policies, such as measures for public employment services and labor market training, amounted to 0.75 percent.13 Meanwhile, spending on unemployment benefits averaged 1.2 percent of GDP in EU-15 in 2001 while spending on labor market programs averaged 0.9 percent.14

Employment by Sector, Gender, and Age15

19. As in most other rich industrialized economies, primary and secondary sectors in Cyprus have become less important while the tertiary sector has gained in importance over the last decades. In particular, between 1980 and 2003, service sector employment increased from 46 percent to 71 percent of total employment, while employment in agriculture and industry declined from 20 percent and 34 percent, respectively, to 8 percent and 21 percent, respectively. For comparison, industry accounted for 28 percent of total employment in EU-15 in 2003 while the services sector accounted for 68 percent.16

20. The economically active population has increased dramatically since independence. The total labor force participation rate has risen from approximately 40 percent in 1960 (Kontolemis, 1994) to 72.2 percent in 2003, mainly reflecting an increase in female labor market participation. However, there is still a large difference between male and female participation rates, with the former at 82.1 percent and the latter at 63.1 percent in 2003.

21. Cyprus also fares well with respect to employment rates. Between 2000 and 2003, the overall employment rate in Cyprus rose by 3.5 percentage points to 69.2 percent while the employment rate for women rose by almost 7 percentage points to 60.4 percent. This measures well both compared with the Stockholm/Lisbon criteria for 2005 and 2010, and the EU15 and EU25 averages. In fact, within EU25, only three countries, Cyprus, Hungary, and Latvia, have seen increases in overall employment rates over the last five years, and by 2003, only Cyprus and the Czech Republic among the new EU members had employment rates above the EU15 average.

Cyprus and the Stockholm/Lisbon Employment Criteria 1/

(in percent)

article image
Sources: European Commission, Employment in Europe 2004 - Recent Trends and Prospects; and Republic of Cyprus, National Action Plan for Employment 2004-06.

The Lisbon European Council of 2000 set strategic goals for 2010 for the EU overall and female employment rates. The Stockholm Council of 2001 set intermediate targets for 2005 and added a new target for 2010 for the EU elderly employment rate. Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom had reached the Lisbon employment rate criteria by 2003.

uA01fig01

Cyprus: Employment by Sector, 1980-2003

(in percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Source: Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance; Planning Bureau.
uA01fig02

Cyprus: Participation Rate in Labour Force by Age Group and Gender, 2003

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Source: Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance; Planning Bureau.

Foreign Labor17

22. In 1991 working permits were issued for the first time to foreign workers and since 1992 there have been large-scale inflows. Foreign workers now constitute some 13 percent of the labor force. Foreign workers receive wages according to the collective agreements, just as comparable Cypriot workers, although apparently often at lower starting wages, and they are entitled to the same social benefits and health insurance.18

23. While foreign workers are active in most sectors of the Cypriot economy, most are found in the services sector. In 2003, half of all foreign workers were employed in private households (30 percent of foreign workers) and in restaurant and hotels (20 percent); another 42 percent were evenly distributed among the agriculture, manufacturing, construction, retail trade, and international business sectors. As shares of total employment in Cyprus, foreign workers constituted 15 percent of the employed population in the agriculture, forestry, and fishing sector in 2003, 13 percent in the trade, hotel and restaurant sector, 11 percent in the construction sector, and 10 percent in the manufacturing sector.

Cyprus: Foreign Workers by Sector, 1998-2003

article image
Source: Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance, and the Planning Bureau

24. Work permits are required for foreign workers. Until May 1, 2004, the issuance of work permits to foreign workers needed the agreement of the unions, and permits were only to be issued in case no eligible Cypriot workers were available. However, since EU accession on May 1, 2004, EU nationals are treated in the same manner as Cypriots as to employment and no work permits are needed for workers from EU countries. Instead, employers now need to “prove” that there are no EU workers available in order for working permits to be issued to non-EU workers. The unions have expressed some consternation over these developments, fearing the waning of their control over the Cypriot labor market. As a result, one union has been lobbying to legalize the existing voluntary collective agreements and fringe benefits. The unions are also supporting recent government proposals to limit the inflows of workers from non-EU countries, which currently constitute the majority of foreign workers in Cyprus. Meanwhile, the employer organizations have expressed deep concerns regarding any further restrictions on the inflow of foreign workers in light of the severe labor shortages characterizing the Cypriot economy.19

uA01fig03

Cyprus: Share of Foreign Workers in Total Employment by Sector, 2003

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Source: Cyprus Statistical Service.

Turkish-Cypriot Workers

25. In the last few years, Turkish-Cypriot (T/C) workers have started to become an important source of labor for the Greek-Cypriot economy. In April 2003, restrictions on movement across the “green line” dividing the government controlled areas from the Turkish-Cypriot community in the north were partially removed, immediately leading to a large increase in the flow of T/C workers to the government controlled areas. While some 700 T/C workers were already commuting to work in the government controlled areas before the removal of restrictions, this number had increased to at least 2,300 as of August 2004, according to data from the Department of Social Insurance (based on social security contributions—as Cypriot citizens, T/C workers are entitled to the same social security and health benefits as residents in the government controlled areas20). In addition to the officially registered T/C workers, there is also a large number of T/C workers unofficially employed in the government controlled areas, possibly bringing the total number of T/C workers currently employed in the south to 10,000.

26. Most T/C workers are found in industry. More than half of the 2,300 T/C workers registered in August 2004 were employed in the construction sector while 12 percent were employed in the manufacturing sector; 5 percent were employed in the trade sector.21

27. While a further inflow of T/C workers could ease the problem of labor shortages in the south, there are also concerns that inflows will start to taper off. In particular, there are concerns that the current construction boom in the north, in part triggered by the Annan Plan of last spring and mainly financed by European (in particular British) vacationers and retirees, might reduce the number of T/C workers coming to the south.2223 There are also concerns that the lack of a solution to the Cyprus “problem” and the resulting political uncertainty may put a damper on the number of T/C workers willing to come to work on a more permanent basis in the government controlled areas.24

National Action Plan for Employment 2004–06

28. As a result of EU accession, Cyprus has prepared its first National Action Plan for Employment for 2004-06. This plan was submitted to the European Commission in September 2004.25 The plan aims at enhancing the supply of labor, mainly through increased use of part-time and temporary work, and at wage flexibility (while maintaining a “sufficient” degree of security). In addition to the EU guidelines, the plan also contains three country-specific policies:

  • Increase the adaptability of workers and enterprises to enhance innovation capacity and diversify the services sector;

  • Enhance the supply of labor through: increased female participation (in part through enhanced access to child and elderly care, and by raising the attractiveness of and opportunities for part-time work); active employment policies and services, enhanced by coordination through the European Employment Service; and encouragement of further employment of T/C workers (all while limiting the inflow of non-EU workers).

  • Investment in human capital and life-long learning.

C. Assessment of the Cypriot Labor Market’s Efficiency and Flexibility

29. In many aspects, the Cypriot labor market is significantly more flexible than those of other advanced countries. Legislation is reduced to a minimum, hiring procedures are simple, there a few constraints on dismissal compared with most other European countries, minimum wages are low enough not to be binding, and unemployment benefits are limited in their duration. Furthermore, the emphasis on consensus decision making among the social partners has contributed to maintaining labor peace and reduced the number of labor disputes and work days lost to disputes.

30. The centralized wage bargaining process also seems to have benefited the Cypriot economy. While centralization can imply rigidities, it has been argued in the literature, starting with Calmfors and Driffil (1988) and Calmfors (1993), that either a fully centralized or a fully decentralized bargaining system will produce better outcomes as to employment and inflation than a middle-ground solution. The main idea is that while the cooperative behavior of fully centralized bargaining creates incentives for moderate wage demands, market forces will restrain wage claims when bargaining takes place on the firm level.

31. Moreover, the economy is functioning at or near full employment. There is mostly frictional unemployment, and there are shortages of both unskilled and skilled labor. In October 2004, only 2.9 percent of the economically active population was unemployed. Furthermore, long-term unemployment remains limited, with more than two thirds of registered unemployed remaining unemployed for less than 6 months, and with less that 10 percent unemployed for more than a year.

32. Lastly, as a result of the 2002–04 tax reform, direct taxation remains very low in an international comparison. The tax reform shifted taxation from direct to indirect taxes and gradually increased the tax-free threshold, whish now is among the highest in the EU. The marginal effective rate is only 30 percent (compared with EU15, only Denmark has a lower rate).26 In addition, the 2 percent defense levy on employers’ and employees’ payroll and the professional tax on incomes of physical persons were abolished as a result of the tax reform, resulting in an overall significant reduction in taxation on labor.

33. However, there are also sources of rigidity in the Cypriot labor market, in particular regarding the wage setting mechanism, and labor supply bottlenecks. Below, these issues are discussed more fully and suggestions for reforms are outlined. Before turning to these issues, however, productivity and real wage developments in Cyprus are compared with those for a number of selected European countries.

Productivity and Wage Developments

34. Since the mid-1990s, Cypriot labor productivity growth has been lagging behind increases in real wages and unit labor costs. This in turn suggests that Cypriot competitiveness is falling behind that of its competitors. Overall Cypriot labor productivity hovers around 70 percent of the EU average. However, different segments of the labor market perform differently: indeed, while the public and semi-public sectors may be overstaffed, showing low productivity growth, the private sector—with the exception of the banking sector-demonstrates much less rigidity.

uA01fig04

Cyprus: Productivity, Wages, and Unit Labor Costs, 1982-2003

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and ECB.

35. In comparison with other European countries, Cyprus fares reasonably well as to productivity growth but less so as to wage growth. In Figures 1-3, developments in labor productivity and nominal and real wages for selected European countries, including Cyprus, are displayed for 1979–2004.27 Cypriot labor productivity growth has lagged behind that of Finland, Greece, Ireland, and Sweden, but has exceeded productivity growth in Belgium, Denmark, and Spain. Meanwhile, real wage growth in Cyprus, deflated by private consumption, has exceeded real wage growth in almost of all of these comparator countries, the only exceptions being Norway (where the oil boom has spurred wage growth) and (in 2003) Greece, which until very recently also relied on wage indexation.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Cyprus and Selected European Countries: Labor Productivity, 1982-2004

(1995=100)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Cyprus and Selected European Countries: Nominal Wages, 1979-2003

(in percent of GDP)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Source: ECB.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Cyprus and Selected European Countries: Real Wages, 1979-2003

(deflated by private consumption; 1995=100)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2005, 106; 10.5089/9781451809848.002.A001

Source: ECB.

Wage Setting Mechanisms

Theoretical considerations

36 The use of wage indexation in Cyprus can be criticized on theoretical grounds. The seminal study by Modigliani and Padoa-Schioppa (1978) showed that when indexation is complete (after a lag), downward flexibility of real wages can be attained only at the cost of permanently raising the rate of inflation. After a one-off negative shock to productivity, labor market equilibrium cannot be restored by reducing the real wage through a one-off increase in prices as, with a lag, wages will catch up. Real wages can only be permanently lowered by preventing wages from catching up with prices, i.e., through an inflationary process. Also, full indexation may exacerbate the inflationary pressure from an increase in prices of imported inputs or from a hike in indirect taxes. Furthermore, in the case of a pegged exchange rate regime, an inflationary spiral caused by these factors may also lead to balance of payments difficulties. Indeed, as pointed out in Calmfors (2003), a country looking ahead to monetary union will require greater wage flexibility as a currency union implies a more rigid monetary policy.

Empirical considerations

37. Cyprus’s use of wage indexation can also be criticized on empirical grounds. Kontolemis (1994) argues that Cyprus’ low level of unemployment, which is a reflection of chronic labor shortages, in combination with the indexation mechanism and the strong union movement, have resulted in large increases in real wages and a deterioration in competitiveness of domestic firms.28 He shows through regression analysis that between 1970 and 1990, unemployment had a very limited role in the determination of wages, in contrast to prices, which was the biggest determinant of wage inflation. Furthermore, annual productivity growth (output per head in manufacturing) averaged 2.2 percent during 1981–90 compared with 4.1 percent during 1963–90, and did not explain the rapid growth in wages. Between 1977 and 1992, average real wages in a large number of sectors, including the finance, insurance, real estate, manufacturing, and government sectors, increased by some 150 percent, or just below 10 percent per annum. These increases could not be justified by economic fundamentals. While the unions had argued that real wage increases in excess of productivity had been necessary in order to improve the distribution of income in the economy, it was clear, according to Kontolemis, that wage increases of these magnitudes had considerably damaged the competitiveness of the domestic industry.

38. Further distortions are created by the wage-setting process in the public sector. Wage increases that may be justified by higher productivity growth and profits in the semi-government organizations typically spill over to the public sector in the form of demands that are of equal cost to the government as an employer. Given the COLA and the additional seniority-based increments, total wage increases in the public sector routinely exceed productivity growth by a wide margin, leading to a drain of the best and brightest employees in the private sector to the public sector. In the language of some Cypriot observers, in Cyprus the private sector is the “poor cousin.”29

39. Even current “zero wage-increase” agreements in the public sector may turn out to be very costly and further widen the wage gap versus the private sector. Under the Convergence Program, the government and social partners have reached preliminary agreement on a zero percent increase in public sector salaries in 2004–05 and a 2 percent “negotiated” wage increase in 2006. Under this arrangement, the increase in total wage costs for the 50,000 public servants will still reach ₤C 80 million (around 1 percent of GDP) a year according to calculations by one employer organization, taking into account also the estimated 4 percent increase each year due to the automatic seniority-based “increments,” as well as the COLA. Such developments make for a widening wage differential between the public (including the semi-government organizations) and the private sectors, where there are no “increments” and where negotiated wage increases typically average productivity, i.e. around 1.5 percent.

40. The achieved labor peace may have proven too costly. Arguably, the COLA has contributed to long-term contracts and labor market peace. However, this can be contrasted with, say, Ireland, where the social partnerships have not only allowed for labor peace and fewer disputes but also a moderation in wage demands and a significant decline in wages as a share of GDP. This in turn has contributed to the steady increase in competitiveness experienced in Ireland during the 1990s. Meanwhile, it could be argued that labor peace in Cyprus has been has been mainly achieved through wage agreements that are too expensive. Box 1 outlines briefly the wage setting mechanisms in selected European countries.

41. The rigidity of the COLA may be exacerbated in a low-growth environment. It may be argued that the COLA worked better in a high-growth economy, where the downward stickiness in real wages did not constitute an effective constraint on the wage determination process, as real wages increased with productivity and workers released from industries unable to pay the rising wages were absorbed by other sectors in the expanding economy. However, in an environment characterized by less robust growth, this rigidity may become an impediment to the economy’s ability to weather negative shocks. In particular, in the presence of long-duration wage contracts in some industries, the COLA mechanism constrains the markets’ ability to correct an overshooting of wages that may result from too optimistic an outlook at the time of the contract’s inception.

Wage Setting in Selected European Countries

Belgium: Wages are indexed to CPI excluding energy items. The actual implementation of the indexation is negotiated and varies across years and sectors, i.e., forward or backward looking indexation, and the number of months to include. In its concluding statement following its most recent Article IV consultation, the Fund suggested that the system be abolished over the medium term.

Greece: For years, indexation of wages to the CPI has been the normal practice, although it has always been negotiated. However, in the wage negotiations of June 2004, wage indexation was excluded.

Ireland: Broad social partnerships that include some 18 umbrella organizations cover a wide array of issues ranging from the macroeconomic environment to income distribution and supply side measures such as tax changes. In the 2003–05 agreements, many volunteer organizations were also involved. Social partnerships have been a source of strength in times of crises, allowing for a more long-term view and helping to build consensus for difficult but necessary reforms. The resulting broadened perspective has not only allowed for labor peace and fewer disputes, but also for moderation in wage demands and a significant decline in wages as a share of GDP, hence contributing to the steady increase in competitiveness experienced during the 1990s. There is no wage indexation mechanism, although the 2000–2002 wage contract was opened for renegotiation due to an inflation adjustment. There are now concerns that the 3-year agreements do not allow for sufficient wage flexibility, that they may not have delivered the wage restraint they have been credited with, that they have become too broad in scope and in the number of partners involved, and, hence, that they place inappropriate constraints on public policy.

Norway: The centralized bargaining system, which in part has been justified in recent years by allowing for a fairer sharing of Norway’s oil wealth, has been instrumental to the relatively tranquil labor market relations, strong employment growth, and record-low unemployment. However, the compressed wage scale, a nominal wage growth that has exceeded that of key trading partners, and anemic productivity growth have all contributed to the public sector increasingly becoming the source of net employment gain.

Spain: Collective wage bargaining covers the bulk of workers. Wages are typically indexed to the previous 12 months of headline CPI. Wage indexation remains a contentious issue during the collective bargaining process, but has become more frequent in recent years. Negotiated wage increases are based on both an inflation component (2 percent) and on productivity gains, while ex-post, wages are adjusted upward if actual inflation deviates (beyond a certain threshold for many contracts) from the initial inflation component. The IMF has advised the abolition of the system, arguing that the increasing recourse to wage indexation contract clauses contributes to the persistence of inflation shocks.

Sources: Horváth (2001); Hunt (2004); IMF (2004a and b).
Looking ahead

42. Now is the time to gradually reform the COLA. As argued above, while the COLA and the Cypriot wage-setting mechanism may have served the country well in the past, there are now concerns that the automaticity of the COLA implies total wage cost increases that are in excess of productivity growth, and that leave little room for performance-related rewards. Such wage developments will have negative implications for incentives and productivity. However, an abolition of the COLA system may not be politically feasible at the present time. In the last election campaign, the President reportedly promised that there would be no significant changes to the COLA system, and even the employer organizations accept the system as a “political reality.” Still, there may be room for revisions at the margin, which would reduce overall wage costs and leave some room for performance-related rewards, and which in turn could enhance productivity. Such first-stage reforms could consist of:

  • Less automaticity and more room for negotiation regarding the implementation of the COLA each year, which would make the system better able to take into account the actual situation of the entire economy, and not just the lagged rate of inflation;

  • Excluding the impact of domestic and external shocks, such as changes in indirect taxes (including VAT), spikes in food prices due to droughts, energy price hikes, etc.; and

  • Abolishing universal compensation and letting the COLA compensation depend on income levels/tax brackets, which would be in line with the original idea of the COLA to cover increased cost of consumption. As it stands today, the COLA actually contributes to widening the salary gap between low- and high-income workers.30

43. Other reforms of the wage-setting mechanism are also important. In addition to reforming the COLA, the Cypriot wage-negotiation process would also benefit from:

  • Enhancing wage flexibility and wage dispersion by allowing firms to deviate from the centrally negotiated collective agreements and to a larger degree negotiate their own wage agreements;31 and

  • Reducing the seniority-related increments in the public sector and, preferably, making them less automatic and more dependent on actual performance. This would help reduce the current imbalance in wage developments between the public and the private sectors and enhance incentives for private sector employees not to leave their more productive occupations for safer employment in the public sector.

Enhancing Labor Utilization

Background

44. One of the major challenges currently facing the Cypriot labor market is the severe shortage of both skilled and unskilled labor. Lacking other policies, this problem is expected to gradually aggravate over the next decades with the aging of the population.32 The recent tentative agreement to increase the retirement age in the public sector from 60 years to 63, and the proposal to increase the retirement age in the private sector from 63 years to 65 and subsequently to 67, would help alleviate this problem.33 However, raising the retirement age is unlikely to be enough to solve the problem of labor shortages. Furthermore, there is only limited room for further enhancing domestic labor supply, with female participation rates already at 60 percent—in fact, in the new generation, most women work, in part aided by the relatively short working hours mentioned earlier.

Looking ahead

45. A number of measures could be considered to enhance labor supply and labor utilization. Such measures could include, but are not limited to:

  • Creating more incentives for part-time and temporary work;

  • Enhancing access to subsidized day care;

  • Increasing the work week back to 40 hours from the current 38 hours;

  • Allowing more flexibility regarding when during the day work can take place;

  • Facilitating the inflow of foreign workers; and

  • Working toward more green line crossing-points to enhance inflow of T/C workers.

The National Action Plan for Employment includes some of the measures listed above, such as enhancing opportunities for part-time work, and promoting female labor market participation by supporting child and elderly care programs. For example, the National Action Plan sets a target of providing day care for at least 80 percent of all children between the age of 3 and the mandatory school age by 2010.34

D. Summary and Conclusions

46. The purpose of this paper has been twofold, to give an overview of the legal and institutional framework of the Cypriot labor market, and to point to the room and need for reform. The Cypriot labor market is characterized by a number of specific features. A number of these features are arguably very positive, such as the consensus decision-making approach and the resulting labor peace, the low level of unemployment, flexible hiring and firing rules, and the voluntary nature of agreements. At the same time, there are a number of rigidities, in particular the wage-setting mechanism and the persistent shortage of labor, that have contributed to a decline in Cyprus’ international competitiveness. Several potential reforms would enhance the efficiency of the wage-negotiation process and improve labor utilization. However, such reforms are only likely to become more important as the full impact of accession to the European Union gradually makes itself felt.

References

  • Calmfors, Lars (1993), “Centralization of Wage Bargaining and Macroeconomic Performance,” Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Economic Studies No. 21 Winter, http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/18/2/33945244.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calmfors, Lars (2003), “Wages and Wage Bargaining Institutions in the EMU – A Survey of the Issues,” in R. Franzese, P. Mooslechner, and M. Schurz (eds.), Institutional Conflicts and Complementarities: Monetary Policy and Wage Bargaining Institutions in EMU, Kluwer Academic Publishers, the Netherlands.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calmfors, Lars and J. Driffil (1988), “Bargaining Structure, Corporatism, and Macroeconomic Performance,” in Economic Policy, April, pp. 1461.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Checchi, Daniele and Claudio Lucifora (2002), “Union Density—The Role of Unions and Institutions,in Economic Policy, No. 35, October, 363408.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (2004), “Employment in Europe 2004—Recent Trends and Prospects,” Directorate-General for Employment and Social Affairs, http://europa.eu.int/comm/employment_social/employment_analysis/employ_2004_en.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Horváth, Balázs (2001), “Emerging Challenges to the Norwegian Labor Market Framework,IMF Country Report 01/34, pp. 3858, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2001/cr0134.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hunt, Ben (2004), “The Role of Social Partnership Agreements in Ireland: Contributing to the Boom and Facilitating Adjustment to Sustainable Growth,in Ireland: Selected Issues, IMF Country Report 04/349, pp. 4358, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2004/cr04349.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (2004a), “Belgium—2004 Article IV Consultation, Preliminary Conclusions,” November 22, http://www.imf.org/external/np/ms/2004/112204.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (2004b), “Spain: 2003 Article IV Consultation—Staff Report,Country Report No. 04/89, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.cfm?sk=17294.0.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kontolemis, Zenon G. (1994), “The Labour Market in Cyprus: Institutional Characteristics and Empirical Evidence,in Cyprus Journal of Economics, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 14484.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Messios, Orestis (2004), “Social Dialogue and Conflict Resolution in Cyprus,” European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, http://www.eurofound.eu.int/publications/files/EF0446EN.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Modigliani, Franco and Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa (1978), “The Management of an Open Economy with ‘100% plus’ Wage Indexation,in Essays in International Finance, No. 130, December, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development (2004), “Social Expenditure Database,” www.oecd.org/els/social/expenditure.

  • Republic of Cyprus (1977), “Industrial Relations Code,” Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance.

  • Republic of Cyprus (2004a), “Convergence Program 2004–08,” Ministry of Finance, http://www.mof.gov.cy/mof/mof.nsf/Main?OpenFrameSet.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Republic of Cyprus (2004b) “National Action Plan for Employment 2004–06,” Ministry of Labour and Social Insurance, http://europa.eu.int/comm/employment_social/employment_strategy/nap_2004/nap2004cy_en.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Republic of Ireland (2004), Department of Enterprise, Trade, and Employment, http://www.entemp.ie/labour/workpermits/.

  • United Nations (2004), “The Annan Plan for Cyprus,” www.AnnanPlan.org.

1

Prepared by Ann-Margret Westin.

2

This section draws mainly on Kontolemis (1994) and Messios (2004).

3

In contrast to this tradition of voluntary agreements, since EU accession the trade unions have been lobbying for legalizing the existing collective agreements as well as fringe benefits, hours worked etc., possibly fearing waning influence given the expected inflow of workers from other EU countries. The employer organizations, meanwhile, have so far successfully opposed any changes to the current voluntary framework.

4

The code was signed by the Cyprus Employers’ Federation and the two largest trade union confederations, and countersigned by the Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance (Republic of Cyprus, 1977).

5

The proven ability of the Cypriot economy to weather storms and act in a unified manner when faced by adverse circumstances may be linked to the strong relationships among the social partners and the sense of consensus achieved during more peaceful times.

7

Still, the social partners have raised concerns that the Convergence Program was prepared without adequate consultation.

8

Given the limited scope of labor market legislation, the range of topics covered in collective agreements is wide, including—in addition to wages—overtime pay, distribution of working hours during the week, holidays, sickness pay, and retirement benefits.

9

The COLA was first introduced as a war bonus to civil servants in 1941 but its use was gradually extended and since 1951 it has been a regular part of the remuneration of almost all employees.

10

The COLA does not only enjoy the support of the unions. Also various government officials, including the president, have expressed their support of the system. Only in times of real crisis, such as after the military conflict in 1974, have a temporary suspension of the COLA been accepted by the unions.

11

The Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance, and the Planning Bureau; and the European Commission (2004).

12

In 2003, unemployment benefits for a skilled industrial worker with three dependants amounted to 69.2 percent of gross earning prior to unemployment.

13

Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance and the Planning Bureau.

15

This section draws mainly on information provided by the Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance and the Planning Bureau, unless otherwise indicated.

17

This section draws in large part on information provided by the Ministry of Labor and Social Insurance and the Planning Bureau.

18

The Social Insurance Scheme is financed by equal contributions by employers and employees of 6.3 percent, respectively, of earnings, and by the state of 4 percent.

19

Ireland recently introduced similar rules in light of the latest EU expansion, now only issuing working permits to non-EU workers that constitute highly qualified or highly specific personnel for which there is also a demonstrable and verified shortage in the Irish labor market (Republic of Ireland, 2004).

20

E.g., from January 2003 to August 2004, ₤C 5.8 million was paid out in the form of pensions to some 4,400 Turkish Cypriots, of which about 900 reside abroad. Also, in August 2004, some 1,400 Turkish Cypriots were treated at medical institutions in the government controlled areas, compared with about 200 in April 2003. (Department of Social Insurance Services)

21

Department of Social Insurance Services.

22

According to the Annan V Plan that was voted on in April 2004, improvements of 100 percent of properties in the T/C areas, which may well have belonged to someone else before the 1974 conflict, would lead to legal ownership. Although the plan was rejected by the Greek-Cypriot voters, there may be a belief that this will still hold in the future. See www.AnnanPlan.org.

23

According to news reports, construction increased by 600 percent in 2004 in the T/C community in the northern part of Cyprus. Also, over half of the land in the T/C-controlled ghost town of Famagusta was reportedly sold to foreigners in the last eight months (Alithia Newspaper, January 19, 2005).

24

At the same time, the lack of a permanent solution to the Cyprus problem implies that property rights remain obscure, which in turn may put a damper on the current construction boom. There have already been instances where Greek Cypriots have legally challenged new construction in the north, claiming ownership of the land under the construction and ordering its demolition. The Greek-Cypriot government has recently announced plans to take such actions on behalf of its citizens. So far, there has been one legal verdict in favor of a Greek Cypriot property owner; however, this verdict is currently being challenged by the defendants.

25

The National Action Plan for Employment 2004–08 can be found at http://europa.eu.int/comm/employment_social/employment_strategy/nap_2004/nap2004cy_en.pdf.

26

As of January 1, 2004, the tax-free threshold is ₤C 10,000 (US$23,000), after which incomes are taxed by 20 percent up to ₤C 15,000 (US$34,500); by 25 percent up to ₤C 20,000 (US$46,000); and by 30 percent above ₤C 20,000.

27

Cypriot wage data are only available from 1994.

28

While the COLA in Cyprus is intrinsically linked to the strong union movement, some analysts would argue that institutions such as wage indexation generally reduces incentives for unionization (see Checchi and Lucifora, 2002).

29

The 2002–04 tax reform also contributed to further widening the gap between the public and private sectors, as it included a 7.5 percent retrospective public sector wage increase, which subsequently became part of the salary structure.

30

Apparently, union officials have generally not been in favor of letting the COLA depend on income.

31

This has, e.g., been argued by the Cypriot Chamber of Commerce and Industry.

32

The share of the population over 60 years of age is estimated to reach 23 percent by 2028 compared with 16 percent today (Republic of Cyprus, 2004b).

33

Convergence Program 2004–08 (Republic of Cyprus, 2004a).

References

  • De Broeck, Mark, and Torsten Sløk (2001), “Interpreting Real Exchange Rate Movements in Transition Countries,” Bank of Finland Institute for Economies in Transition Discussion Papers, No. 7.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (1998), “External Competitiveness in Cyprus,Chapter II of Cyprus: Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report No. 98/98.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (2003), “The International Investment Position: An International Perspective,” Chapter I of Cyprus: Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix, IMF Country Report No. 03/31.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pattichis, Charalambos, Marios Maratheftis, and Stavros A. Zenios (2003), “Economic Fundamentals and the Behaviour of the Real Effective Exchange Rate of the Cyprus Pound,Hermes Center of Excellence on Computational Finance & Economics, University of Cyprus, Working Paper 03-2.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Economic Forum (2004), Global Competitiveness Report 2004-2005, www.weforum.org.

STATISTICAL APPENDIX

Table 1.

Cyprus: Aggregate Demand, 1998–2003

(At current prices)

article image
Source: Statistical Service.
Table 2.

Cyprus: Aggregate Demand, 1998–2003

(At constant 1995 prices)

article image
Source: Statistical Service.
Table 3.

Cyprus: Origin of Gross Domestic Product, 1998–2003

(At constant 1995 prices)

article image
Source: Statistical Service.
Table 4.

Cyprus: Origin of Gross Domestic Product, 1998–2003

(At current prices)

article image
Source: Statistical Service.
Table 5.

Cyprus: Gross Manufacturing Output by Major Industries, 1998–2003

article image
Source: Statistical Service.
Table 6.

Cyprus: Tourist Arrivals and Receipts, 1998–2003

article image
Source: Statistical Service.
Table 7.

Cyprus: Labor Force and Employment by Sector, 1998–2003

article image
Source: Statistical Service.

Includes business services.

Includes employees of British military authorities and the national guard.

Table 8.

Cyprus: Guest Worker Employment, 1998–2003

article image
Source: Statistical Service.

including business services.

Table 9.

Cyprus: Wage and Productivity Indicators, 1998–2003

(Percentage change over previous year)

article image
Source: Statistical Service.

Including basic wages or salaries, cost of living and other allowances, bonuses, gratuities, and payments in kind. Data exclude overtime payments and are gross of income tax and social security deductions.

Based on average earnings.

Deflated by the GDP deflator.

Table 10.

Cyprus: Price Indices, 2002–04

article image
Source: Statistical Service.

Refers to Jan-Nov 2004

Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.