An important aim of this paper is to take shifts in the long-term anchor in the empirical specifications. The study examines exchange-rate pass-through and external adjustment in the euro area. The impact on third-country trade and investment is also discussed. A better understanding of the economic behavior underlying limited pass-through is an important consideration for investigating the implications of currency fluctuations and the pattern of external adjustment. The impulse-response patterns suggest a high degree of local currency pricing in import prices and producer currency pricing in export prices.

Abstract

An important aim of this paper is to take shifts in the long-term anchor in the empirical specifications. The study examines exchange-rate pass-through and external adjustment in the euro area. The impact on third-country trade and investment is also discussed. A better understanding of the economic behavior underlying limited pass-through is an important consideration for investigating the implications of currency fluctuations and the pattern of external adjustment. The impulse-response patterns suggest a high degree of local currency pricing in import prices and producer currency pricing in export prices.

III. Exchange-Rate Pass-Through and External Adjustment in the Euro Area1

A. Introduction

1. Recent swings in exchange rates and persistent external imbalances, particularly in the United States, have once again focused attention on the global alignment of currencies and current accounts. Over the past two years, the euro has appreciated by 30 percent against the dollar and by 20 percent in effective terms (see Figure 1). Currency movements notwithstanding, the constellation of current account positions among the major economies still shows considerable imbalances. Namely, the large U.S. current account deficit appears unsustainable from a long-term viewpoint and leaves open the possibility of a further significant decline in the value of the dollar.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Euro Area Nominal Exchange Rates

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2003, 298; 10.5089/9781451812947.002.A003

1/ January 1995 = 100

2. From the euro area’s perspective, a possible global realignment along these lines is of central interest given its relative size in the world economy. In particular, with the prospect that the large U.S. deficit could eventually narrow substantially, the question remains as to what role currency and external adjustment in the euro area might play as part of that process.2 Note that despite the depreciation of the euro over the period 1995-2001 the euro area current account was not the counterpart to the widening U.S. deficit (Figure 1).

uA03fig01

Current Account Balances

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2003, 298; 10.5089/9781451812947.002.A003

1/ Including global current account discrepancy.

3. In terms of area-wide growth and inflation, the extent to which exchange rate changes associated with external realignments will be passed through to domestic prices and the “expenditure-switching” effects that may result is also of clear interest and importance. A further disinflationary shock imparted by a strengthening euro, for example, could hamper the contribution of net external demand to the area’s economic recovery in an environment where growth in consumption and investment spending are already weak.

4. The nature of external adjustment in the eurozone is a complex issue and likely depends on several factors. Some issues are fairly straightforward. The patterns of international trade and finance, for example, help determine the euro area’s economic “exposure” to exchange rate movements against key currencies.3 More difficult to assess, however, are the behavioral considerations that underlie the extent of exchange rate pass-through in prices as well as the responsiveness of trade flows to relative price signals. These issues are important in determining the strength of “expenditure-switching” effects from exchange rate movements.4 Incomplete pass-through, for example, could delay or diminish the response in external variables and produce a certain degree of “exchange rate disconnect.”5

5. Several economic explanations have been put forth to account for incomplete exchange rate pass-through—a feature that has strong empirical support for a larger number of economics, including the euro area.6 With nominal rigidity and local currency pricing, destination prices can change very little in the face of exchange rate fluctuations.7 With “pricing to market” behavior, segmented markets allow firms to stabilize their destination prices (via changing mark-ups) in response to fluctuating exchange rates to preserve foreign market share. In the presence of local distribution costs, firms may also face offsetting factors when the exchange rate changes, leading to international price discrimination and incomplete pass-through.8 These factors can also help account for differential responses between first stage pass-through (e.g., in import prices) and second stage pass-through (e.g., in consumer prices).

6. This paper further examines exchange-rate pass through and external adjustment in the euro area. The methodology proceeds in two parts. First, the empirical analysis follows a vector autoregression (VAR) approach, where the time-series behavior of the euro exchange rate and a system of euro area prices are jointly examined. Specifically, the empirical analysis investigates exchange rate pass-through in a set of prices along the pricing chain, Second, the impulse-response functions (IRFs) from the VAR estimates are used to help calibrate in a new open economy macroeconomics model those key behavioral parameters that underlie the pattern of exchange rate pass-through and external adjustment in the euro area. Repeating the exercise for the United States and the other major industrial countries, the framework can provide some insight into the likely pattern of external adjustment in a multilateral context.

7. The use of a VAR approach to examine exchange rate pass-through has several advantages compared to single-equation based methods. Previous studies typically focus on pass-through into a single price (e.g., import or consumer prices), without further distinguishing the types of underlying exchange rate shocks (e.g., permanent or transitory). By investigating exchange rate pass-through into a set of prices along the pricing chain, the VAR analysis characterizes not only absolute but relative pass-through in upstream and downstream prices. Second, the VAR methodology potentially allows one to identify specific “structural” shocks affecting the system. In this case, a structural exchange rate shock is identified through a Cholesky decomposition of innovations, where exchange rate fluctuations at higher frequencies are assumed to be largely driven by exogenous asset market disturbances.

8. Using this identification scheme, one can map the empirical results into a well-defined shock in an economic model of incomplete pass-through. Specifically, the estimated impulse-response functions from an exchange rate shock in the VAR are matched to the response patterns generated by the corresponding asset market disturbance in the pass-through model. Minimizing the distance between these sets of IRFs is used to identify key behavioral parameters that underlie the pattern of exchange rate pass-through. These parameters include the pricing behavior of firms (i.e., the extent of local currency pricing), the degree of nominal rigidity, and the extent of local distribution and trading costs generating international price discrimination.

9. Based on the empirical estimates, the analysis investigates the expected impact of the recent euro appreciation on area-wide prices and trade flows. Combined with the calibrated model, the scenario of a further decline in the value of the dollar and the resultant pattern of external adjustment is also examined. In particular, for a uniform decline in the dollar, the pattern of realignment in external positions between the euro area and the other major industrial economies is further analyzed.

B. Empirical Estimates

10. The empirical analysis focuses on euro area prices and the exchange rate at a monthly frequency. The time span covers the period from 1990 through 2002. All series are expressed in logarithms. For the euro exchange rate s, the nominal effective series is defined for the ECB’s “narrow” group of partner countries.9 For factor prices or wage earnings w, the series derive from quarterly data on nominal compensation per employee, extrapolated to a monthly frequency.10 For trade prices, import prices pm and export prices px are based on unit values in extra-area manufacturing trade.11 Producer prices py are based on the producer price index for manufacturing, excluding construction and energy. Consumer prices pc are based on the core CPI—i.e., excluding energy and unprocessed foods—from the harmonized index of consumer prices (HICP).12 The exclusion of energy prices is motivated by the standard finding that its pass-through behavior differs from that of other goods.13

11. The use of extra-area trade data helps avoid potential pitfalls from ascertaining pass-through for the euro area from estimates for individual member countries. To the extent that intra-area trade systematically differs from extra-area trade with respect to pass-through behavior, aggregating individual country estimates to generate an area-wide measure could suffer from a “fallacy of composition.” Hufner and Schroder (2001), for example, construct pass-through estimates for euro area consumer prices by summing over individual country estimates, based on each country’s weight in the area-wide HICP. The analysis is then required to make some “correction” of the estimates due to the presence of intra-area trade.

12. Before turning to the VAR estimation of euro area pass-through, some preliminary tests of the data were first conducted. Namely, unit root and stationarity tests indicate that these nominal variables are non-stationary in levels but stationary in first differences, suggesting that they are integrated of order one or I(1) series.14 Furthermore, residual-based cointegration tests do not find evidence of cointegration among the variables; see appendix. Given potential non-stationarity and lack of cointegration in the levels data, estimating the VAR in first differences is appropriate.

VAR methodology

13. The VAR approach examines the joint historical time-series behavior of the euro exchange rate and a system of euro area prices. Specifically, the reduced-form YAR(p) can be written a follows:

Yt = c + A(L)Yt1 + μt;E(μtμt) = Ω,(1)

where Y = [Δs Δw Δpm Δpx Δpy Δpd]’, c is a vector of deterministic terms (i.e., monthly time dummies), A is a matrix polynomial of degree of p in the lag operator L, and μ is the (6x1) vector of reduced-form residuals with variance-co variance matrix Ω. The exchange rate is placed first in the order of variables, reflecting the presumption that exchange rate innovations at monthly frequency are primarily driven by exogenous asset market disturbances.15 For prices, the ordering after the exchange rate is motivated by the pricing chain, from factor input prices to trade prices to wholesale producer prices and retail consumer prices. The ordering among price variables after the exchange rate does not matter for the subsequent analysis of the exchange rate shock.

14. To recover the underlying exchange rate shock, the Cholesky decomposition of the matrix Ω is used to produce orthogonalized innovations 6. These disturbance terms are expressed in terms of the reduced-form VAR innovations as follows:

Cεt = μt,(2)

where C is the unique lower triangular Cholesky matrix with Is along its principal diagonal.16 Because the exchange rate appears first in the VAR, the recursive structure in (2) imposes the assumption that orthogonalized innovations to the exchange rate depend only on the residuals from the exchange rate equation and not the other variables. This identification thus allows for a simple correspondence between the VAR estimates and a well-defined shock in the model described later. For prices, the corresponding disturbance term will represent a mix of shocks, including the structural exchange rate shock.17

15. An alternative identification scheme would place the exchange rate last (or near last) in the VAR. This ordering is motivated by the view that prices (and quantities) are predetermined in the very short run and, thus, cannot respond to an exchange rate shock, whereas the exchange rate can respond to various shocks.18 While this restriction may indeed be valid for many prices, it may not be appropriate for others. More to point, this ordering imposes a specific pass-through pattern in the estimates, and, ultimately, certain behavioral features in the model, that the current analysis seeks to investigate.

16. The implications of the present identifying restriction can be further understood from the structural representation of the VAR:

F(L)Yt = k + εt,(3)

where F(L) is a matrix polynomial of degree p+1, k is a transformation of deterministic terms (i.e., Ck = c), and s is the vector of structural shocks. One can show that the identification scheme based on the Cholesky decomposition introduces the following restriction: in the first equation—i.e., for the exchange rate As, the coefficients on contemporaneous price changes Δw, Δpm, Δpx, Δpy, and Δpc are equal to zero.

17. The economic justification for this identifying assumption can be understood as follows. Exchange rates, particularly at high frequencies, are essentially driven by asset market rather than goods market disturbances. From the asset market view of exchange rate determination, the prevailing exchange rate as a forward-looking price should reflect not only current but expected future economic conditions affecting the supply and demand for foreign exchange. Changes in the exchange rate can then be expressed in terms of a predictable component (usually deemed to be small) and a potentially large unexpected component, reflecting the impact of new information on expectations of all future economic conditions.19 Short-run changes in the exchange rate, consequently, arc likely to be dominated by “news” and not be predictable based on lagged price data.20 The VAR identification scheme takes this view one step further, specifying that contemporaneous price innovations also do not help explain exchange rate innovations.21

18. Based on the reduced-form estimates of the VAR and the Cholesky decomposition to identify structural shocks, accumulated impulse-response functions to a unit structural exchange rate shock are shown in Figure 2.22 The horizontal axis measures the time horizon in terms of months after the shock; the vertical axis measures the percent deviation in prices from their baseline levels.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Effects of an Exchange Rale Shock on Euro Area Prices

(unit structural shock; estimation period: 1990-2002)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2003, 298; 10.5089/9781451812947.002.A003

19. Figure 2 shows that the short-run effects of an exchange rate shock on prices are very small in the euro area. Prices tend to be predetermined or very sticky (in local currency) initially in response to a unit depreciation in the euro effective exchange rate. Over time, the degree of exchange rate pass-through generally tends to rise, although the extent in factor and retail prices remains comparatively small. Wholesale producer prices tend to rise more than retail consumer prices, but the greatest response is in trade prices. A year to 18 months after the shock, export prices respond by almost half the response in import prices, which moves in proportion to the unit exchange rate shock, suggesting full pass-through. Consequently, the manufacturing terms of trade (tot) for the euro area tends to worsen or decline in response to an exchange rate depreciation.23

20. Normalizing the price responses in Figure 2 by the exchange rate response, Table 1 summarizes the time paths for pass-through elasticities in euro area prices. After 18 months, pass-through rates in export and import prices are about one-half and one, respectively. Wage pass-through is relatively very small at 5 percent. Pass-through in wholesale prices is nearly 20 percent, significantly exceeding the pass-through in retail prices.24 These results are robust to re-orderings of the VAR.25 Using headline rather than core inflation (or including longer lags), would raise the degree of pass-through in consumer prices to near 10 percent at 18 months, but the pattern of relative pass-through remains intact.

Table 1.

Euro-Area Pass-Through Elasticities

(Percent change in prices divided by percent change in exchange rate)

article image
Notes: Based on impulse-response functions from 6-variable VAR estimated on monthly data from 1990 through 2002.

21. Full pass-through in euro area import prices over time may be a somewhat surprising result.26 Alternative specifications—e.g., with coefficient restrictions or VAR re-orderings—tend to yield smaller but still high pass-through elasticities between 0.7 and 1. In a recent paper that also examines extra-area manufacturing trade prices, Anderton (2003) also finds generally high (albeit not full) pass-through between 0.5 to 0.7, based on a single equation approach.27 Given the identification of near-permanent exchange rate shocks from the VAR estimates here, it is not surprising that import price pass-through in this analysis lies somewhat above those single-equation based estimates.

Cross-country evidence

22. Before relating the empirical findings to the theoretical model, it is useful to compare the pass-through results for the euro area to the other major industrial economies. Repeating the VAR exercise for the United States, Japan, United Kingdom, and Canada produces the pass-through coefficients for trade prices shown in Table 2.

Table 2.

Pass-Through Elasticities in Trade Prices: International Comparisons

article image
Notes: Based on impulse-response functions from 6-variable VAR estimated from 1990 through 2002. For Euro area, import and export prices based on unit values in manufacturing trade. For others, import and export prices based on unit values in total trade.

23. As evident from the table, pass-through is incomplete, particularly in the short run. For the United States, pass-through in trade prices at the time of the shock is near zero, quite similar to the response of euro area. But while pass-through rises significantly over time in the euro area, the extent of the increase is much smaller for the United States. For the other countries, pass-through to import and export prices are higher on impact than for the U.S. and the euro area. For Canada and Japan, import prices pass-through estimates are about 60 to 70 percent initially and remain around those levels over time; for the United Kingdom import price pass-through eventually reaches 60 percent, but is initially half that. Pass-through in export prices is (eventually) around 50 percent for these three countries, similar to the euro area.

C. Model of Incomplete Pass-through

24. This section briefly describes the analytical framework used to interpret the VAR evidence in terms of underlying economic behavior. The stylized model generates incomplete pass-through based on many of the common themes found in the “new open economy macroeconomics” (NOEM) paradigm, following the seminal work of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995).28 A detailed derivation of the micro-founded model employed here can be found in Choudhri, Faruqee, and Hakura (2002). A descriptive summary of the model is as follows.

25. Imperfect competition characterizes the production and allocation of two differentiated goods—a traded intermediate good and a non-traded final (consumption) good. One differentiated primary factor (labor) enters the production of traded goods. A domestic retail sector also relying on labor services is then needed to transform intermediate goods into final consumption goods in each country. This structure gives rise to a pricing chain with five price indices: retail consumer prices, wholesale producer prices, import and export prices, and wages or factor prices.

26. Prices and wages arc not fully flexible. Instead, prices and wages are updated only infrequently based on Calvo-type adjustment.29 Specifically, the probability that a firm will revise its price in a given period is fixed equal to π. Correspondingly, the average interval over which prices remain fixed is (1 - π)/π.30 This framework generates staggered price setting behavior in the economy.

27. With nominal rigidity in an open economy, the question arises as to whether prices are sticky in terms of domestic or foreign currency. The two cases are referred to as local currency pricing (LCP), where prices are rigid in term of the destination or buyer’s currency, and producer currency pricing (PCP), where prices are rigid in terms of the originating or seller’s currency. Both types of pricing behavior are allowed for in the model. Specifically, the parameter ϕ and ϕ * denote the share of domestic and foreign firms following producer currency pricing behavior. If ϕ = 1, all domestic firms engage in PCP; If ϕ = 0, all domestic firms engage in LCP.

28. Finally, segmented goods markets allow firms to price discriminate internationally. Following Corsetti and Dedola (2002), firms face trading or distribution costs in the export market, providing an incentive for ‘pricing to market’ (PTM) given their ability to do so.31 Specifically, imports are assumed to go through local distribution channels before they can be used in the production of either intermediate or final goods. To sell one unit in the export market requires 5 units of local labor services.32 With this dependence on local currency wages, changes in the exchange rate lead to incomplete pass-through in trade prices and “pricing to market” behavior described by Krugman (1987) through a cost or supply mechanism.33 The introduction of “pricing to market” along these lines helps limit the effects of import price pass-through on retail prices and helps generate greater overall persistence in the degree of incomplete pass-through over time.

29. Benchmark parameters in the model follow the calibration in Choudhri, Faruqee and Hakura (2002) which are generally based on average estimated values for the major industrial countries—including euro area members Germany, France and Italy.34 Monetary policy, for example, is specified by an interest rate rule targeting expected inflation in consumer prices and allowing for interest rate smoothing, with the corresponding parameter weights based on the average estimates for the (non-U.S.) G-7 countries.

30. To match the empirical impulse-response patterns, an asset market shock ξ to uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) in the model is considered. The scale and persistence of ξ is calibrated to reproduce the VAR’s accumulated impulse-response path for the exchange rate from a structural exchange rate shock εs.35 Simulating the model’s price responses to the UIP shock then generates the analytical impulse-response functions. To find the “optimal” structural parameter values in the model consistent with the empirical evidence, the following loss function is minimized:36

min{0}[IR(P,ξ;θ)IRVAR(P,εs)][IR(P,ξ;θ)IRVAR(P,εs)](4)

where IR(P,ξ;θ) denotes the vector of simulated impulse-responses for the price vector P from an ξ shock in the model conditional on the set of structural parameters θ = (ϕ,ϕ*,;π,δ).37 IRVAR(P, εs) denotes the vector of accumulated impulse-responses to a structural exchange rate shock εs in the VAR. The time horizon for the impulse-response paths is 18 months.

31. Figure 3 displays the combinations of LCP and PCP behavior in domestic and foreign firms that best replicate the price responses—particularly, for trade prices—derived from the VAR estimates for each of the major industrial economies. The vertical axis measures the extent of PCP behavior ϕ* in foreign firms (i.e., producing home imports) and the horizontal axis measures the extent of PCP behavior ϕ in domestic firms (i.e., producing home exports).

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Pricing Behavior of Domestic and Foreign Firms

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2003, 298; 10.5089/9781451812947.002.A003

32. In the figure, the origin represents local currency pricing at home and abroad, while the opposing corner represents the case of universal producer currency pricing. The 45-degree line connecting them reflects symmetric combinations of local and producer currency pricing. In terms of symmetric outcomes, the mid-point along the 45-degree line tends to outperform either extreme empirically as shown by Choudhri, Faruqee and Hakura (2002). The intuition is as follows. Exclusive reliance on LCP behavior in both countries produces stable import prices at the destination which generally squares well with the data at the expense of unstable export prices at the point of origin which does not. The reverse is true in the case of PCP. As is evident from the VAR results in Table 2, both export and import prices in a given currency show incomplete pass-through. Consequently, a mix of the two behaviors fares better.

33. Figure 3 indicates, though, that the opposing diagonal is more relevant empirically in describing the pricing behavior of traded goods in an international setting. Specifically, asymmetric pricing behavior between domestic and foreign firms appears more consistent with the data. Allowing for LCP to a greater degree in certain trade prices and PCP to a greater extent in other trade prices tends to be more consistent than equal degrees of each. Specifically, the smaller, more open economies and Japan gravitate toward pricing in foreign currencies—i.e., LCP in exports and PCP in imports, while the larger, more insular economies of the United States and the euro area gravitate toward pricing in domestic currencies—i.e., LCP in imports and PCP in exports. As further supporting evidence, the implicit currency pricing behavior suggested by Figure 3 appear very consistent with the data on invoice currencies for these countries.38

34. For the United Kingdom, pricing behavior is consistent with an “outward orientation.” Domestic firms exporting to foreign markets tend toward LCP and set and stabilize prices in terms of foreign or destination currencies, safeguarding export market share. Import prices also tend to be rigid in terms of foreign currencies, as foreign exporting firms are less sensitive to fluctuations in their destination currency prices. Canada is similar to the United Kingdom with foreign currencies playing a large role in price-setting behavior of traded goods, albeit closer to the symmetric or equal weighting case.

35. Despite its relative economic size, Japan also exhibits considerable outward orientation. From Table 2, recall that both Japanese import and export prices show considerable pass-through on impact akin to the smaller, more open economics considered here. These results suggest that Japanese exporting firms predominantly engage in local currency pricing, while foreign firms largely engage in producer currency pricing. This finding accords with the conventional wisdom regarding the behavior of Japanese and foreign (predominantly U.S.) exporting firms described in Giovannini (1988), Marston (1990) and others.39

36. For the larger, more insular economies excluding Japan, both domestic and foreign firms tend to price in the ‘dominant’ currency associated with the large economy. For foreign firms exporting to the United States and to the euro area, this translates into destination currency pricing in dollars and euros, respectively. For U.S. and eurozone firms exporting abroad, this translates into producer or domestic currency pricing. For the United States, this result is well-established.

37. The similarity between the United States and the euro area is somewhat striking. While it is generally accepted that U.S. firms exporting to the euro area (and elsewhere) primarily invoice in dollars and engage in dollar-currency pricing, less is known about the pricing behavior of euro-area firms.40 The results here suggest that the euro area behaves in some measure like the United States with respect to the predominant role of domestic currency pricing for international transactions. The finding is largely driven by the similar lack of pass-through on impact of U.S. and area-wide import and export prices shown in Table 2. The use of manufacturing trade prices for the euro area accentuates this similarity; although using total extra-area trade prices (which show higher pass-through) would only slightly alter the relative placements shown in Figure 3.

38. There are also some important differences worth highlighting between the United States and the euro area. Specifically, the dynamic response of prices suggests significantly higher pass-through (particularly in import prices) for the euro area over time. Interestingly, this translates into a higher estimate for the Calvo parameter π -i.e., reflecting greater nominal flexibility.41 Imposing a similar n value would shift the euro area in Figure 3 toward the other countries and away from the United States in terms of the mix of LCP versus PCP firms, although it would remain more closely aligned with United States.

39. In all countries, exchange rate pass-through in consumer prices is significantly lower than in trade prices. In the model, this “wedge” between intermediate and final goods is represented by local distribution, marketing or trading costs. Consequently, implicit estimates of local distribution costs limiting the pass-through into final goods prices are fairly substantial. Distribution costs 5, measured as a share of the final goods price, are estimated at roughly 38 percent for the United States, 40 percent for the United Kingdom and Canada, 50 percent for the euro area, and 60 percent for Japan.42 Estimates in Burstein, Neves and Rebelo (2001) suggest a 40 percent share for the United States.

D. Implications for Euro Area Adjustment

40. Based on the empirical estimates from the VAR, several inferences can be made regarding the likely effects of the recent appreciation of the euro. To the extent that recent currency movements have been led by asset market developments, the following inferences could be drawn:

  • The immediate effects of the recent exchange rate appreciation on area-wide prices are likely to be quite small in the near term. In response to the 15 percent effective appreciation in the euro over the past 12 months, manufacturing import prices could decline over time in proportion to the euro’s advance, and manufacturing export prices could decline by half that amount, ceteris paribus. Area-wide consumer prices could decline by ½ percent and 1 percent in terms of the core and headline CPI, respectively.

  • Assuming no further exchange rate movements, the dynamic response patterns suggest that the full effects of the recent currency appreciation on euro area trade prices should largely manifest by end-2004.

  • In terms of the trade balance, the calibrated model generates trade elasticities around ½ for euro area export and import volumes.43 Including pass-through or price effects, the model suggests that nominal exports will decline by 9-10 percent, while nominal imports will remain broadly unchanged (due to offsetting volume and price effects) next year in response to the euro’s appreciation. This indicates a prospective deterioration in the euro area trade balance of around 1 percent of GDP.

41. Combined with the VAR estimates for the other major industrial economies, the analytical framework can shed some light on the implications of a multilateral dollar depreciation and the resultant pattern of external adjustment.44 First, Table 3 show the currency weights on the U.S. dollar in each partner country’s effective exchange rate basket, which shows some country variation. In particular, the weights for Japan and for the euro area are one-quarter, while the weight for Canada—the United States’ largest trading partner—is more than twice that size.

Table 3.

U.S. Dollar Weights

(In percent)

article image
Notes: Dollar weight for the euro area based on ECB calculations, derived from average trade in manufactures (1995-97) with double weighting on exports to account for “third market” effects. Other dollar weights based on IMF Information Notice System (INS) methodology; see Zanello & Desruelle (1997).

42. The experiment considered here is a uniform 20 percent decline in the nominal value of the dollar against all other currencies. To the extent that a further decline in the dollar is led by asset market developments (e.g., changes in market sentiment), the model’s simulated response to a shock to uncovered interest parity should broadly reflect the effects of this disturbance. Table 4 summarizes the impact of the dollar depreciation on the trade positions of the major industrial economies.

Table 4.

Effects of a Dollar Depreciation

(Change in trade balance)

article image
Notes: Effects after 6 months derived from calibrated model based on country VAR estimates. Effects reflect both pass-through and volume effects, as well as output effects from the exchange rate adjustment. Initial trade balance and GDP based on 2002 estimates.

43. In response to the dollar decline, the U.S. trade position improves by $125 billion or more than 1 percent of GDP. Forty percent of this adjustment (in dollar terms) is reflected in lower trade balances for the euro area and Japan, given their economic size and reflecting their dollar weights. The effects relative to GDP for the euro area and Japan are fairly modest though, given the relatively closed nature of these economies. Japan has larger expenditure-switching effects (i.e., more responsive nominal trade flows) partly offset by being a more closed economy than the euro area. Expenditure-switching effects (in percent of GDP) are also generally larger in the U.K. and Canada, but the effects are much larger in the Canadian case, reflecting the difference in the respective dollar weights. Overall, $80 billion of the $125 billion adjustment in the U.S. is accounted for by the other major industrial economies including the euro area, with another $45 billion required from the rest of the world (for a given global discrepancy in trade).

44. Alternative scenarios wherein the euro experienced a larger multilateral appreciation as a result of weakening market sentiment in the dollar would magnify the external impact on the euro area. To date, it is worth noting that the “dollar area” has been sizeable with respect to recent currency movements, limiting the effective decline in the dollar. A narrow decline in the dollar against the euro (but not other currencies) translates into a wider appreciation of the euro. A plausible scenario would have this pattern continue, with some currencies following the dollar down—either due to market concerns or policy actions. For example, nagging concerns over Japan’s economic outlook and the value of its currency suggests that the degree of yen appreciation against the dollar could be mild. In that case, the potential impact on the euro area’s external position would be much larger, as the dollar and the yen (and the currencies pegged to them) account for over half of the euro area’s effective exchange rate basket. From the perspective of prevailing current account positions, however, a narrow decline in the dollar and a broad advance in the euro would not be particularly helpful in realigning major external imbalances.

E. Conclusions

45. Incomplete exchange rate pass-through in prices is a well-documented empirical regularity for many economies, including the euro area. A better understanding of the economic behavior underlying limited pass-through is an important consideration for investigating the implications of currency fluctuations and the pattern of external adjustment. The analysis here has sought to examine pass-through in a set of euro area prices along the pricing chain by using a VAR approach to identify the effects of an exogenous exchange rate shock. Mapping the effects of this structural shock into an analytical framework helps identify behavioral features that could help account for the nature of incomplete pass-through in the euro area. On the basis of the analysis, the following broad conclusions can be drawn:

  • Short-run pass-though is very low in the euro area for a wide range of prices. Similar to the United States, the impact effect of an exchange rate shock on factor and trade prices, and on wholesale and retail prices, is near zero.

  • Pass-through tends to rise over time in the euro area, although the extent of wage and consumer price pass-through remains comparatively small. Pass-through in producer and export prices is somewhat higher, but the highest degree of pass-though (near unity) is in euro area import prices. The differences in relative pass-through in import prices and consumer prices, for example, suggest that the roles of the retail sector and local distribution costs are important for price determination.

  • The pattern of pass-through in trade prices suggests a fair degree of asymmetry with respect to the pricing behavior of domestic and foreign firms operating in the eurozone (and the U.S.). Specifically, the impulse-response patterns suggest a high degree of local currency pricing in import prices and producer currency pricing in export prices. For the United States and the euro area, this suggests that firms are pricing in dollars and euros, respectively. For Japan and smaller, more open economies, the behavior of pass-through is more consistent with firms operating significantly in foreign currencies.

  • Local currency pricing and “pricing to market” behavior notwithstanding, expenditure switching effects still operate in these economies, although short-run trade elasticities can be small. Nevertheless, an exchange rate depreciation improves the trade balance overall, once both volume and pass-through effects are factored in. Given its generally small effects on the trade balance, however, the exchange rate adjustment required to achieve a moderate degree of external adjustment may be substantial in the absence of adjustment in other variables.

  • Illustrative calculations of a generalized dollar decline suggest modest external adjustment implications for the euro area, given the size of expenditure-switching effects, dollar exposure, and the degree of trade openness. Effects of a dollar decline can be significant, as the Canadian case suggests, in economics with more trade openness and pass-through, and closer ties to the U.S. economy. But if the dollar were to weaken narrowly against the euro—i.e., if the “dollar area” remained large, the external implications for the euro area could also be more significant with a broader euro appreciation. Given prevailing current account imbalances, however, an unwinding of the large U.S. deficit would be better facilitated by a broader decline in the dollar rather than a further multilateral appreciation of the euro.

Appendix I: Unit Root and Stationarity Tests

Test statistics based on Phillip-Perron’s non-parametric unit root test and Kwiatowski, ct al (KPSS) stationarity test are shown in Table 5. The alternative hypothesis with the Phillips-Perron test and the null hypothesis with the KPSS test is trend stationarity. The tests suggest that the levels (first-differences) of these variables are non-stationary (stationary). The borderline cases where the tests give conflicting answers are CPI inflation—where the tests reject a unit root and stationarity, respectively—and import price inflation—where tests fail to reject a unit root and stationarity, respectively.

Table 5.

Unit Root and Stationarity Tests

(Euro Area monthly data, 1990-2002)

article image
An *(**) indicates significance at the 10 (5) percent level.Phillips-Perron unit root test includes deterministic time trend under the alternative.Kwiatowski, et al (1992) stationarity test includes deterministic time trend under the null.

Cointegration Tests

Given that the unit root and stationarity tests suggest that the log levels of the exchange rate and various price measures are non-stationary, cointegration tests are conducted to examine whether a linear combination of these variables is stationary. Table 6 reports the results of Phillip s-OuIiar is residual-based test for cointegration with window size = 2. Other window sizes produce similar results. The tests fail to reject the null of no cointegration.

Table 6.

Cointegration Tests

(Euro Area monthly data, 1990-2002)

article image
Notes: Multivariate trace statistic based on Phillips & Ouliaris (1990); 10 percent critical value given in parentheses.

Granger Causality Tests

Granger causality tests were conducted to examine if (changes in) euro area exchange rates and prices have predictive content for each other. Simple bivariate tests indicate that the nominal effective exchange rate Granger-causes (i.e., helps predict) several price measures, but prices fail to Granger-cause exchange rates. The exchange rate is found to be a significant predictor for trade prices and has predictive content for wages at shorter lag length.

Table 7.

Bivariate Granger Causality Tests

(Euro Area monthly data, 1990-2002)

article image
Note: Reported numbers arep-values on the relevant exclusion restriction (F-test). Lag length selection based on Akaike Information Criterion.

At one lag, the exchange rate Granger-causes wages (p = 0.04).

Block Exogeneity Tests

To generalize Granger causality tests to a multivariate context, consider the following partitioned VAR(p) system:

Δst = c1+A1X1t+A2X2t+ε1t,ΔPt = c2+B1X1t+B2X2t+ε2t

where c1 and c2 represent a constant term and monthly time dummies, P represents the (5x1) vector of price variables, X1 and X2 are (px1) and (5pxl) vectors of lagged changes in exchange rates and prices, respectively, with conformable matrices of autoregressive coefficients A1, A2, B1 and B2. Block exogeneity test results are shown in Table 8 below.

Table 8.

Block Exogeneity Tests

(Euro Area monthly data, 1990-2002)

article image
Notes: Test statistic is based on likelihood ratio test with degrees of freedom correction and is distributed as χ2(5p). Significance levels given in parentheses.

Sensitivity Analysis

In general, when the residuals from the VAR do not display high cross correlations, the order of factorization makes little difference.45 Otherwise, the results can be sensitive to the choice of ordering.

Changing the order of the exchange rate, however, can be shown to have little impact on the results. Placing the exchange rate last in the VAR, for example, leaves the impact of an exchange rate shock less permanent, as the innovation becomes a mix of shocks. Moreover, the exchange rate shock has no contemporaneous effect on any prices (i.e., prices are predetermined) by construction. However, the implied pass-through elasticities remain similar to the case where the exchange rate appears first in the VAR. See Table 9.

Table 9.

Euro-Area Pass-Through Elasticities Across VAR Re-orderings

article image
Notes: Entries report percent change in price measure divided by percent change in exchange rate in response to unit exchange rate shock from Cholesky decomposition of innovations.

As seen in the table, the implied pass-through elasticities from the two VARs are fairly similar. On impact, euro area prices are essentially predetermined in response to the exchange rate shock. However, it should be stressed that this response is imposed in the second VAR, rather than estimated, based on the ordering of variables. In the case of the euro area (and the United States) this restriction appears valid, although for other industrial countries this generally not be the case for certain prices as shown by Table 2 in the text.

References

  • Anderlon, Bob, 2003, “Extra-Euro Area Manufacturing Import Prices and Exchange Rate Pass-through,” ECB Working Paper No. 219, March (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergin, Paul, and Robert C. Feenstra, 2001, “Pricing-to-Market, Staggered Contracts, and Real Exchange Rate Persistence,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 54, pp. 333359.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bekx, Peter, 1998, “The Implications of the Introduction of the Euro for non-EU Countries,” Euro Papers 26, European Commission, July (Brussels: European Commission).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Belts, Caroline, and Michael B. Dcvereux, 1996, “The Exchange Rate in a Model of Pricing-to-Market,European Economic Review, Vol. 40, pp. 10071021.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Belts, Caroline, and Michael B. Dcvereux, 2000, “Exchange Rate Dynamics in a Model of Pricing-to-Market,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 215244.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burstein, Ariel T., Joao C. Neves, and Sergio Rebelo, 2001, “Distribution Costs and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics During Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilizations,Journal of Monetary Economics, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillcrmo A. and Carmen M. Rheinhart, 2002, “Fear of Floating,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, pp. 379408.

  • Calvo, Guillermo, A., 1983, “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 38398.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campa, Jose M., and Linda S. Goldberg, 2001, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through into Import Prices: A Macro or Micro Phenomenon?,” manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York (revised March 2002).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choudhri, Ehsan U., and Dalia S. Hakura, 2001, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through to CPI: Does the Inflationary Environment Matter?,” IMF Working Paper 01/194 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choudhri, Ehsan U., Hamid Faruqee, and Dalia S. Hakura, 2002, “Explaining the Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Different Prices,” IMF Working Paper 02/224 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, and Luca Dedola, 2002, “Macroeconomics of International Price Discrimination,” ECB Working Paper No. 176, September (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael, Charles Engel, and Cedric Tille, 1999, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through and the Welfare Effects of the Euro,” forthcoming, International Economic Review and NBER Working Paper No. 7382.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael, and Charles Engel, 2002, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Exchange Rate Volatility, and Exchange Rate Disconnect,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, pp. 913940.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael, and Charles Engel, 2000, “Monetary Policy in the Open Economy Revisited: Price Setting and Exchange Rate Flexibility,” NBER Working Paper 7665.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dominguez, Kathryn, 1999, “The Role of the Yen,” in International Capital Flows, ed. by Martin Feldstein, pp. 133171, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the NBER).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flath, David, January, “Regulation, Distribution Efficiency, and Retail Density,NBER Working Paper 9450, January.

  • Friedman, Milton, 1953, “The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates,in Essays in Positive Economics, pp. 157203, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engel, Charles, 2002, “Expenditure Switching and Exchange Rate Policy,NBER Macroeconomics Annual Report.

  • Faruqee, Hamid, 1995, “Pricing to Market and the Real Exchange Rate,” IMF Staff Papers, December (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flood, Robert A., and Andrew K. Rose, 1995, “Fixing Exchange Rates, A Virtual Quest for Fundamentals,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 36, pp. 337.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gagnon, Joseph and Jane Ihrig,Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Pass-Through,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers No. 704 (July); (revised March 2002).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giovannini, Alberto, 1988, “Exchange Rates and Traded Goods Prices,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 24, No. 1-2, pp. 4568.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, P., and M. Knetter, 1997, “Goods Prices and Exchange Rates: What Have We Learned?,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV, pp. 12431272, September.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hahn, Elke, 2003, “Pass-through of External Shocks to Euro Area Inflation,” ECB Working Paper No. 243, March (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hamilton, James D., 1994 Time Series Analysis (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press).

  • Herzberg, Valerie, George Kapetanios, and Simon Price, 2003, “Import Prices and Exchange Rate Pass-through: Theory and Evidence from the United Kingdom,” Bank of England Working Paper No. 182.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hufner, Felix P., and Michael Schroder, 2001, “ Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Consumer Prices: A European Perspective,” Discussion Paper 02-20, Center for European Research.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaeger, Albert, 2002, “Euro Area Trade Flows and the Exchange Rate: How Much Disconnect?,” International Monetary Fund, mimeo.

  • Jeanne, Olivier, and Andrew K. Rose, 2002, “Noise Trading and Exchange Rate Regimes,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, pp. 53769.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kasa, Kenneth, 1992, “Adjustment Costs and Pricing-to-Market: Theory and Evidence,Journal of International Economics, Vo. 32, No. 1-2, pp. 130, February.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kieler, Mads, 2001, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through for the Euro Area,” International Monetary Fund, mimeo.

  • Kwiatowski, Phillips, Schmidt & Shin, 1992, “Testing the Null Hypothesis of Stationarity Against the Alternative of A Unit Root: How Sure Are We That Economic Time Series Have A Unit Root?,Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 54, pp. 159178.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kollmann, Robert, 2001, “The Exchange Rate in a Dynamic-Optimizing Business Cycle Model With Nominal Rigidities: A Quantitative Investigation,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 55, pp. 243262.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1987, “Pricing to Market When the Exchange Rate Changes,” in Real-Financial Linkages Among Open Economics, ed. by Sven W. Arndt and J. David Richardson, pp. 4970 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1989, Exchange Rate Instability (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Lane, Philip, 2001, “The New Open Economy Macroeconomics: A Survey,Journal of International Economics, August.

  • Marston, Richard, 1990, “Pricing to Market in Japanese Manufacturing,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 29, pp. 217236.

  • McCarthy, Jonathan, 2000, “Pass-Through of Exchange Rates and Import Prices to Domestic Inflation in Some Industrialized Economies,” manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, August.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, Michael, 1984, “The Theory of Exchange Rate Determination,” in Exchange Rate Theory and Practice, ed. by John F.O. Bilson and Richard C. Marston, pp. 1378 (Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 2002, “Exchange Rates and Adjustment: Perspectives from the New Open Economy Macroeconomics,” NBER Working Paper No. 9118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 1995, “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, pp. 624660.

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2000a, “New Directions for Stochastic Open Economy Models,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 117153.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2000b, “The Six Major Puzzles in International Macroeconomics: Is There A Common Cause?” NBER Working Paper No. 7777.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Peersman, Gert, and Frank Smets, 2002, “The Monetary Transmission Mechanism in the Euro Area: More Evidence from VAR Analysis,ECB Working Paper No. 91, December (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Phillips, Peter, and Sam Ouliaris, 1990, “Asymptotic Properties of Residual Based Tests for Cointegration,Econometrica, Vol. 58, pp. 165193.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Slavov, Slavi Tr., 2002, “Should Small Open Economies Keep All Their Eggs in One Basket: The Role of Balance Sheet Effects,” Stanford University, mimeo, December.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smets, Frank, and Raf Wouters, 2002, “Openness, Imperfect Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Monetary Policy,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, pp. 94781.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Yang, J. 1997, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through in US Manufacturing Industries,Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. LXXIX, No. 1, February.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zanello, Alessandro, and Dominique Desruelle, 1997, “A Primer on the IMF’s Information Notice System,” IMF Working Paper 97/71 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

Prepared by Hamid Faruqee.

3

Measurement of currency weights, however, may not be as straightforward. Issues such as indirect competition in third-country markets complicate these matters in practice. See Zanello & Desruelle (1997). The role of financial linkages and balance-sheet effects—e.g., the currency composition of debt—is another complicating factor. See Slavov (2002).

4

See Obstfeld (2002) and Engel (2002) for a recent review of these issues.

6

See Goldberg and Knetter (1997) for a survey. See Kieler (2001), Hufner and Schroder (2001), Anderton (2003), and Hahn (2003) for euro area estimates.

7

See Betts and Devereux (1996, 2000) and Devereux and Engel (2002).

9

Parlners countries consist of the United States, Japan, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, Sweden, Denmark, Norway, Canada, Australia, Hong Kong, South Korea and Singapore.

10

Price and wage data are from Eurostat and not seasonally adjusted. The area-wide measures reflect aggregates of the 11 participating countries through December 2000. Thereafter, the chained series include Greece as the 12th member country.

11

Manufactured goods include Sections 5 to 8 of the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC).

12

For the United States, Japan, United Kingdom and Canada, all corresponding monthly series were drawn from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics, except wages which were obtained from the OECD’s Analytical Database.

13

See, for example, Campa and Goldberg (2001).

14

The differenced series for euro area consumer and import prices were borderline non- stationary; see appendix. But as is well-known, unit root and stationarity tests have low power, making it difficult to distinguish between stationary and unit root processes in finite samples.

15

The identification scheme largely follows Choudhri, Faruqee, and Hakura (2002). That analysis also includes the interest rate in the VAR in order to farther distinguish between the effects of interest rate and exchange rate shocks on prices. McCarthy (2001) and Hahn (2003) also uses a Cholesky decomposition to examine pass-through based on a somewhat different model.

16

The symmetric positive definite matrix Ω can be decomposed into unique lower triangular and diagonal matrices such that Ω = CDC′. Using equation (2), this decomposition then produces innovation terms that are uncorrelated by construction—i.e., E[εtε′t] = D.

17

For the first variable—i.e., the exchange rate, the orthogonalized disturbance term is given by ε1t = μ1t. For thejth variable (J > 1) in the VAR, the corresponding shock term is given by ε1t = μ1t - Cj, 1 εjt…- Cj,j-1 εjt where cj,t correspond to the entries of the Cholesky matrix; See Hamilton (1994).

18

Sec, for example, Peersman and Smets (2001).

20

Granger causality and block exogeneity tests find that (lagged) euro area prices have no predictive value for the euro exchange rate. The exchange rate, however, helps predict (at least) trade prices. See appendix. Restricted VAR estimates (not reported) excluding lagged prices from the exchange rate equation yield very similar results to those reported in the paper.

21

Reporting lags in prices may be one motivating factor. The presence of noise traders may be another consideration. See, for example, Jeanne and Rose (2002) and Devereux and Engel (2002).

22

Given the large number of parameters in the VAR, a parsimonious lag structure is sought to conserve degrees of freedom. The lag length/? is chosen by starting with given maximum lag length and sequentially testing the incremental significance of dropping an additional lag based on the likelihood ratio test.

23

Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000a) provide extensive evidence that the terms of trade declines with a currency depreciation—an observation that appears at odds with the implications of strict LCP models. See also Lane (2001) for a review.

24

Gagnon and Ihrig (2002) find very low degrees of pass-through in consumer prices for twenty industrial countries and argue that pass-through has been declining. Their average estimate for long-run CPI pass-through is around 5 percent.

25

As shown in the appendix, placing the exchange rate last among the variables does not materially alter the pass-through effects in the specific case of the euro area. With the exchange rate last, the initial or impact effects on prices are restricted to be exactly zero, but that is closely in line with the “unrestricted” estimates shown in the table. The interpretation of the exchange rate shock, however, becomes more difficult in this case as it incorporates a mix of innovation terms from all the price equations.

26

These estimates should be taken as indicative, given the standard errors of the impulse- response functions. Based on boot-strapped standard errors, the 90 percent confidence interval for import prices is the widest, suggesting pass-through at 18 months in the range (0.6,1.4). The median value of this band suggest a slightly lower degree of import price pass- through (i.e., 0.95 at 18 months); otherwise, the median and estimated impulse-responses responses closely coincide.

27

The time pattern is similar, though, with most of the price adjustment transpiring by 5 quarters. Based on a quarterly VAR, Hahn (2003) reports similar findings on the degree and time-pattern of pass-through in the euro area non-oil import deflator.

28

See Lane (2001) for a survey of this literature.

29

See Calvo (1983). See Kollman (2001) for a NOEM analysis with sticky wages and prices but without distribution costs.

30

Choudhri, Faruqee, and Hakura (2002) also examine the cases of wage and/or price flexibility in the model (i.e., π =1) and find that these model variants generally fall short in explaining the estimated IRFs.

31

Investigating extra-area import prices, Anderton (2003) finds that foreign suppliers attach a significant weight on the PTM strategy in efforts to maintain market share. Herzberg, et al (2003) find PTM to be the dominant consideration for U.K. import prices. Kieler (2001) provides comparative estimates for several industrial countries.

32

Burstein, Neves and Rebelo (2001) find that distribution costs account for roughly 40 percent of final consumer prices in the United States. For comparison purposes in what follows, the distribution cost parameter 5 is recast in similar units.

33

See also Kasa (1992), Faruqee (1995) for analyses that introduce market-specific costs as a way to generate incomplete pass-through and pricing-to-market behavior. An alternative approach that focuses more directly on the demand mechanism through translog (i.e., non-CES) preferences can be found in Bergin and Feenstra (1999).

34

The elasticity of labor supply was optimized in Choudhri, Faruqee, and Hakura (2002), In this analysis, it is preset in line with the optimal values previously obtained to replicate the low degree of wage pass-through evident in the data.

35

The exchange rate shocks from the VAR have permanent or highly persistent effects on the (log) level of the exchange rate. Consequently, the UIP shocks are permanent or highly persistent as well.

36

The standard errors for the accumulated impulse-response trajectories are fairly similar, suggesting that minimizing the (unweighted) least squares should yield similar parameters as the weighted least squares calculation following Smets and Wouters (2002). The weighted approach would give less weight to import prices in favor of consumer prices.

37

The elasticity of substitution o between traded goods was also chosen to minimize the distance between IRFs and found to be fairly low (σ = 2), in line with Smets and Wouters (2002) and the references cited therein.

38

Bekx (1998) reports the following 1995 percentages of import and export prices that are respectively invoiced in domestic currency: United States (81,92), Japan (23,36), United Kingdom (43,62), and Germany (52,75). Note that the percentages for Germany refer to deutschemarks rather than euro-area currencies.

39

See Dominguez (1999) for a related discussion of the limited role of the yen as an international currency, particularly as an invoicing currency. In principle, the choice of invoice currency is distinct from the issues of local versus producer currency pricing, but these issues share considerable overlap in practice.

40

With the advent of the euro, some have suggested that the international role of euro will expand. Sec Bekx (1998) and Devereux, Engel and Tille (1999).

41

The estimate for π equals 0.1 for the euro area, suggesting an average time interval of about 9 months between price changes. The π estimates suggest an average duration exceeding one year for the other countries.

42

High estimates of implicit distribution costs in Japan may reflect aspects of its unique distribution system. See Flath (2003).

43

The classic Marshall-Lerner-Robinson condition requires that the sum of trade elasticities exceed unity for a depreciation to improve the trade balance under traditional pass-through assumptions (i.e., zero and full pass-through in export and import prices, respectively). For example, Isard et al (2001) use elasticity benchmarks of 0.7 and 0.9 for export and import volumes.

44

Subsequent calculations are partial and should only be taken as illustrative as the model is a two-country or bilateral framework, whereas the question of a global external realignment is a inherently a multilateral issue.

45

From the variance-covariance matrix, the correlations between residuals are less than 0.2 with the notable exceptions of the exchange rate and trade prices and between trade prices themselves.

Euro Area Policies: Selected Issues
Author: International Monetary Fund