This paper examines monetary and exchange rate policies of the euro area. The paper reviews the European Central Bank’s definition of price stability, and examines the factors determining “the optimal rate of inflation” in the euro area. It reviews the benefits of price stability, including the reduction in the distortions of savings and investment behavior that stem from the interaction between nominal tax systems and inflation. It then goes on to evaluate arguments for maintaining a small positive inflation rate in the context of the euro area.

Abstract

This paper examines monetary and exchange rate policies of the euro area. The paper reviews the European Central Bank’s definition of price stability, and examines the factors determining “the optimal rate of inflation” in the euro area. It reviews the benefits of price stability, including the reduction in the distortions of savings and investment behavior that stem from the interaction between nominal tax systems and inflation. It then goes on to evaluate arguments for maintaining a small positive inflation rate in the context of the euro area.

III. Market Predictability of ECB Policy Decisions: A Comparative Analysis1

A. Introduction

1. Particularly during it’s early history, many surveys and reviews of the European Central Bank’s (ECB) monetary framework emphasized the inability of financial markets to fully understand and correctly predict monetary policy decisions.2 According to these reports, market participants questioned the ECB’s degree of policy transparency and had difficulty interpreting how the two-pillar monetary framework was linked to policy actions.3 At the same time, these surveys of financial market participants gave relatively high marks to the United States Federal Reserve (Fed) and the Bank of England (BoE) on their ability to be understood by financial markets.

2. In various communications the ECB has highlighted the important linkage between financial markets ability to understand and predict monetary policy decisions and the effective implementation of monetary policy.4 In an address to an ECB Watchers Conference, Issing (2001) noted that policy “should induce ‘rule like’ behavior on the behalf of market participants. This leads them to react to new developments in a manner consistent with the monetary policy strategy, thus aiding in the smooth conduct of monetary policy.” Similarly, Hämäläinen (2001) stressed that “a credible and predictable central bank can achieve price stability with more stable interest rate movements and at lower interest rate levels than a central bank with lower credibility”.

3. So far, empirical research by the ECB has indicated that financial markets have generally understood and predicted ECB policy decisions since the startup of Stage III of EMU (Box 1). Most of this work, however, has focused on a relatively small number of ECB policy decisions or during a period of generalized expectations of tightening. Research on the predictability of Federal Reserve and BoE’s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) policy actions has tended to support a view of an evolving process: as transparency and market understanding of policy have increased over the years, the accuracy of market forecast’s of central bank policy decisions has improved. For example, Haldane and Read (2001) found that the introduction of inflation targeting in the U.K. appears to have coincided with a marked dampening in yield curve responses, suggesting greater transparency and predictability as the BoE monetary framework changed. For the U.S., Poole and Rasche (2001) demonstrated that predictability of the Fed’s actions increased after the 1994 decision to announce changes in Fed policy rates immediately after Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meetings.

4. Against this background, this paper examines the predictability of the ECB, BoE and U.S. Fed’s monetary policy decisions over the last 3½ years. A comparison of policy actions during this period offers a number of advantages, including the ability to examine central bank predictability of two industrial countries and a currency union, each with distinctive monetary frameworks, during a number of large changes in policy rates, and over a period of relatively turbulent shifts in the macroeconomic environment.

5. The paper will rely on calculations that market participants employ in anticipating policy changes and on regressions that provide ex post evidence of market surprises. For a variety of reasons a direct comparison of market predictability of these three central banks’ policy actions is not feasible. Monetary policy operations and the market instruments available to ascertain expectations of future policy decisions are markedly different between the three central banks (Figure 1).5 Therefore, different degrees and types of liquidity, term and risk premia may be affecting the outcomes under the simple techniques employed in this study. Other factors, which prevent precise conclusions, are differences in macroeconomic environments and the short period of time under review—with a restricted number of policy decisions—that limit the power of the empirical work undertaken.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Policy Determined and Money Market Interest Rates

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2002, 236; 10.5089/9781451812985.002.A003

Source: Bloomberg.

6. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: section B briefly discusses the recent evolution in how these three central bank’s communicate their monetary policy stance. Sections C and D describe the policy decisions undertaken during the period under review and estimates the degree to which each central bank followed a pattern of interest rate smoothing. Section E presents the results of our predictability analysis of central bank policy decisions, while in section F, the outcomes of regressions that examine the movement of yield curves at the time of policy rate changes are discussed. Finally, some concluding observations are offered in section G.

B. The Movement Toward Greater Transparency of Central Bank Policy Actions

7. Monetary policy has it’s greatest impact on current economic conditions and the movement of financial market variables through the formulation of expectations. Indeed, the efficacy of the monetary transmission mechanism—the link between the real economy and policy—depends heavily on the ability of monetary policy to impact the course of interest rates through financial market expectations. With this in mind, many industrial country central banks in the 1990s embraced a greater emphasis on transparency and open communication in order to enhance credibility and improve the effectiveness of policy.

8. Historically, the conduct of U.S. monetary policy has been viewed as rather opaque. For example, before February 1994 changes in policy rates were not announced but rather left to be gradually discerned by financial markets. However, since then the U.S. Federal Reserve has started to publicly announced FOMC policy changes, with this policy officially enshrined in 1995. In a similar vein, before May 1999, press statements announcing policy decisions were relatively brief, cryptic, and undifferentiated between rate cuts and rate increases. Now, these statements offer greater detail on all policy decisions, and occur after every meeting. In addition, prior to May 1999, the Fed would announce its “policy bias” only after FOMC minutes were published (a few days after the next meeting) thus disabling it’s signaling function. Since then, the policy bias has been announced immediately after each FOMC meeting making it an effective forward-looking signal. In February 2000, the Fed moved away from the policy bias terminology and instead inserted a formulaic “balance of risks” sentence in order to clarify its asymmetric directives regarding inflationary pressures and economic weaknesses.6 Finally, in March 2002, the FOMC started to publish a roll call of the votes on the Federal Funds target, including the preferred policy choice of any dissenters.

9. Most of the changes in communication and transparency at the Bank of England can be linked to the granting of operational independence in May 1997. At that time, the setting of monetary policy was delegated to the MPC, with the power to set the inflation target remaining with the Chancellor. In addition, the BoE’s Inflation Report—christened in 1993—was retained as the main public communication vehicle that described current MPC thinking. While press statements on policy decisions have shied away from a precisely worded statement on the balance of risks to the inflation target—due in some part to the individualistic nature of the MPC—-the quarterly inflation report contains a rather detailed analysis of the balance of risks and highlights financial market’s views on these risks. Most of the MPC’s analysis is encapsulated in error bands or probability distributions contained in fan charts on the direction of prices and output some 2-years ahead. Also, these fan charts are published under constant as well as expected market interest rates. For MPC members, one gap in coverage may arise from the fact that these charts are only updated on a quarterly basis versus a monthly MPC meeting. Finally, the BoE publishes the minutes of each MPC meeting with a 2-week lag and has outlined in some detail, the models used by the Committee.

10. In many respects, the ECB has been able to draw upon this new emphasis on transparency and openness when it developed its communication and disclosure policies. Like many other central banks with a defined inflation objective, the ECB issues a Monthly Bulletin, which provides a relatively detailed analysis of monetary and economic developments throughout the area. The monthly editorial in the bulletin offers a guide to the Council’s assessment of the balance of risks to price stability and the suitability of its monetary policy stance.7 In addition, after the first meeting of the month, the President and Vice-President preside over a press conference, in which an introductory statement—that will be used as the outline of the editorial of the next bulletin—is read out and the floor opened to questions and answers.

11. At the same time, the ECB has augmented or modified some aspects of its communication strategy over the last 3½ years. First, since December 2000 the ECB has started to publish bi-annual staff forecasts on output growth and inflation, which are discussed in the monthly bulletin.8 However, the models and methods that underlie these forecasts are not explicitly presented in detail, and it is unclear how much weight the Governing Council actually places on them in formulating policy. Second, in November 2001 the ECB moved from bi-monthly meetings of the Governing Council, at which time interest rate decisions are undertaken, to monthly meetings.9 At the second meeting of the month, the Governing Council focuses on issues related to other tasks and responsibilities of the ECB and Eurosystem. Finally, since 1999 ECB’s Governing Council has actively supported and participated in a unique annual forum for ECB watchers that brings together academics, the media and financial market participants in a broad discussion on ECB policy.

C. ECB, Fed, and BoE Policy Decisions

12. Table 1 displays information on monetary policy decisions of the ECB, U.S. Fed and BoE over January 1999 to May 2002 period. All three central banks hold frequent, regularly scheduled monetary policy meetings. With bi-monthly policy meetings—until the move to monthly meetings in February 2002—the ECB Governing Council has met more often, some 77 times over the 41-month period versus 30 and 42 meetings respectively, of the U.S. Fed’s Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) and the BoE’s MPC. In general, it would appear that the ECB has been the least active central bank with only 16 percent of all meetings resulting in a decision to change policy rates. On the other hand, the U.S. Fed has been the most active, changing the targeted Federal Funds rate at about 60 percent of the FOMC decision dates, while the BoE’s policy activism lies in-between, moving repo rates at about 35 percent of all MPC meetings.

Table 1.

ECB, FED and BoE Policy Decisions, January 1999-May 2002

article image
Source: ECB, US Federal Reserve and the Bank of England; and staff estimates.

Data includes the decisions on September 11, 2001.

13. However, the more frequent ECB Governing Council meetings may provide a false sense of inactivity. Excluding the non-scheduled September 17, 2001 meeting, the ECB has tended to change rates at the very end or beginning of the month (9 of the 11 changes) when all available monthly information on activity and prices have been tabulated suggesting that mid-monthly meetings would not be expected to contain changes in policy stance. Similarly, there have been three U.S. Fed policy changes during unscheduled meetings (through telephone conference calls among the FOMC) that increase the percentage of Fed policy activism.10 Also, the Federal Reserve was much less active in the preceding 40 policy meetings from 1994-98, changing rates only 30 percent of the time, suggesting the last three years has been a particularly active period in US monetary policy.

D. Interest Rate Smoothing and Predictability

14. Generally, the three central banks appear to favor a form of interest rate smoothing, with small movements in interest rates without marked reversals in direction. In fact, including the path of rates in the pre-1999 period, each central bank changed direction of interest rates twice over the last 3½-4 years, with only two of the six directional changes applying rate changes of at least 50 basis points. In addition, the time lag between the last policy move and the new change in direction policy move has usually been about 9-11 months. Interest rate smoothing has typically been explained by uncertainty regarding the current state of the economy, with policymakers undertaking a rather muted reaction to new data since the true structure of the economy is unknown.11 Interest rate smoothing behavior under this scenario could be uncovered by looking at basic autocorrelations.

15. An alternative explanation focuses on the use of a systematic and predictable monetary policy (with low nominal interest rate variability) in the context of a forward-looking private sector. In this view, the potency of monetary policy will be enhanced—through the formation of accurate expectations of future policy—if the private sector can expect interest rate changes to persist, allowing agents to better anticipate policy adjustments. This can be accomplished if the central bank commits itself to a rule.12

16. To quantify the extent to which each central bank has followed an interest rate smoothing policy (and therefore tended to improve the probability of accurate market predictions), we estimated the following regression on monthly data (1999.1-2001.12) for each area:

it=α+βπt+δgapt+λit1+t(1)

where i1 is the overnight interest rate series, πt is the CPI inflation rate, gapt is detrended industrial production, and it-1 is the one-period lagged overnight interest rate. This type of regression separates out an explicit smoothing coefficient (λ) from other factors that may have affected the behavior of the monetary authority. Larger values of (λ) imply a higher degree of smoothing.

17. Figure 2 shows the behavior of these overnight interest rates and the estimated smoothing coefficient. The smoothing coefficients for the euro area and the U.K. are very similar at around 0.8. For the U.S., the smoothing coefficient is greater than one, indicating that shocks affecting the setting of interest rates would not eventually fade away, i.e., interest rates would not revert to “trend”. Previous work by Amato and Laubach (1999) estimated an interest rate-smoothing coefficient of about 0.9 for the US using data from the late 1980s to 1997. Thus, our results imply that Federal Reserve’s view of the economy, perhaps related to the signals emanating from the equity markets, radically changed in 2001, forcing the Fed to abandon the small infrequent changes seen under interest rate smoothing in favor of repeated large reductions in the Fed Funds target13. This should make the predictability of U.S. policymakers more difficult in comparison to the U.K. and the euro area.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Behavior of Euro Area, U.s., and U.K. Overnight Interest Rates with Estimated Smoothing Coefficients

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2002, 236; 10.5089/9781451812985.002.A003

Source: Staff estimates.1/ Due to high volatility the Sterling Overnight Index Average (SONIA) is a 2 month average.

E. Predictability of Central Bank Interest Rate Decisions

18. Given the paper’s focus on the relative predictability of ECB policy decisions, benchmark calculations on how well financial markets anticipated U.S. Fed and BoE policy actions are undertaken first. The results on ECB policy decisions is then compared to the evidence for these two central banks.

The U.S. Federal Reserve FOMC

19. This section uses Fed Funds futures rates to predict changes in U.S. monetary policy. In doing so, we follow the heuristic method employed by Robertson and Thornton (1997). Variants of this method have been used by Poole and Rasche (2001) and Kuttner (2000) in studies of the expected and unexpected changes in Fed Funds targets.

20. We start by assuming that the one-month Fed Funds futures rate is a predictor of average Federal Funds rate, with the allowance for a non-zero risk premium αi that may vary with the forecast horizon. Specifically,

ffft,i=Etff¯t+i+αi(2)

where ffft, i. is the i-month ahead future rate calculated as the rate on the last day of the month, Et the expectations operator at time t and ff¯t+i is the average of the daily effective federal funds rate for each day of the month. The data are measured on a monthly frequency, and given that our data runs from January 1999 to May 2002, we have 41 observations. The forecast errors are serially correlated, and adjusted estimates reveal a significant positive bias of 8.3 basis points at the one-month horizon. This “hedging premium” results from the fact that banks use the Federal Funds market to finance their loan portfolios and will hedge their positions against any rate increases in the futures market. The desire to protect against possible spot increases will increase the yield in the futures market.

21. Using the one-month Fed funds futures rate at the end of the month as a barometer of expected changes in the Fed funds target over the following month runs into two problems. First, the Fed funds futures rate is a forecast of the average of Fed funds rates and not the Fed funds target. Second, the effect of a target change on the average depends on the timing and the magnitude of any target change.

22. Assume the market’s forecast of the average funds rate is the sum of the average Fed funds rate target and deviations of the average Fed funds from that average target:

Etff¯t+i=Etfftar¯t+i+Et(ff¯t+ifftar¯t+i)(3)

Substituting from equation 2, we get:

ffft,iαi=Etfftar¯t+i+Et(ff¯t+ifftar¯t+i)(4)

Thus, the bias adjusted futures rate would deviate from the market’s forecast for the average target rate when the market’s forecast for the average Fed funds rate differs from the average target rate. In order to identify the market’s expectation for the target rate, we could assume that the market’s expectation of the average Fed funds rate will coincide with the Fed Funds target rate. However, this is unlikely, so identification remains a problem.

23. Robertson and Thornton consider a “partial identifying assumption”, which allows identification on occasions when the market is expecting a change in the target rate. Specifically, assume that Et(ff¯t+ifftar¯t+i) falls within a certain interval. If the bias-adjusted / -month spread between the futures rate and current target rate is outside this interval then they conclude the market expected a change in the target. To see this better subtract fftart from both sides of equation 4 to get:

ffft,iαtffftart=Etfftar¯t+i+Et(ff¯t+ifftar¯t+i)(5)

24. If markets expected no change in the target, the bias adjusted spread between the Fed funds futures and the target is equal to the market’s expectation of the average Fed funds-Fed target spread, i.e., the historical average spread.

ffft,iαtfftart=Et(ff¯t+ifftart+i)(6)

This partial identifying assumption can be made operational by using the min/max bounds of (ff¯t+ifftar¯t+i) over the whole sample period. In our sample, this has ranged between -20.4 and +5.9 basis points. With the interval determined, we then plot the bias adjusted spread (ffft,iαifftar¯i), with points outside the interval signifying an expectation of a target change (Figure 3, top panel).

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Financial Market Predictions of Central Bank Policy Decisions

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2002, 236; 10.5089/9781451812985.002.A003

Source: Staff estimates.1/ Bars represent change in average Fed funds rate (one month ahead) over current target. Circles represent the bias adjusted futures spread. Dotted lines represent range of the historical difference between average effective Fed funds rate and average Fed funds target.2/ Dark (clear) circles represent incorrect (correct) market predictions.3/ Bars represent changes in the official rate.4/ Dotted lines are drawn at +/- 0.125 basis points, reflecting the 50 percent probability of at least a 25 basis point change.

25. To compare against actual changes in the Fed Funds target, we plot as vertical bars the difference between the current Fed Funds target and the average of the following month14. The results show that futures markets did not emit false signals regarding rate increases and were able to predict most of the rate increases in 1999 and 2000. The two exceptions being the 25-basis point increases of November 1999 and February 2000. Most importantly, the markets were able to predict changes in direction (both the increase in rates in 1999 and the reversal in 2001) and anticipated the majority of the large changes in rates. However, the markets did not anticipate well the last round of sharp cuts starting in September of2001, perhaps due to the aforementioned deviation from interest rate smoothing. In fact, two-thirds of the errors in market anticipation of Fed policy action can be found in the fall of 2001.

26. The accuracy of the forecast results can be summarized in a basic tabulation, Table 2. The simple rule correctly predicted 10 out of the 16 (63 percent) Fed funds target changes and 100 percent of the no-change months.15 While the overall hit rate was about 85 percent, with 35 of the 41 months correctly predicted, the reliability of the model’s prediction of a policy change was 100 percent or 10 out of 10. However, it is important to remember that this analysis predicts monthly FOMC policy actions (over our 41-month sample), regardless if a meeting had been scheduled. In 11 months, no policy decision meetings occurred within the month. Although the model correctly predicted no target changes during these months, eliminating these dates would bring the overall hit rate to some 80 percent (24 out of 30 decisions).

Table 2.

United States: Contingency Table Using Federal Funds Futures Rates

article image
Source: Staff estimates.

Percentage of time model signals rate change and one actually happens.

Percentage of correct signals.

27. A second caveat is the use of the range of the prediction interval. We made the model operational by using the min/max bounds of (ff¯t+ifftar¯t+i) over the whole sample period. These bounds were influenced by rather large end-of-year values; adjusting for these values resulted in a min/max range of-9.8 to +5.9 basis points. Re-tabulating the contingency table under the adjusted bands resulted in very similar numbers. The model predicts 11 out of the 16 policy rate changes and 20 out of the 25 no-change months. The overall hit ratio falls to 31 out of 41, or 76 percent, while the reliability of a change prediction falls to 69 percent or11 out of 16. In sum, given that the accuracy of a no-change forecast was around 40 percent, it is clear that the markets, as embodied in the futures markets data, do a fair job of predicting policy decisions of the US Federal Reserve’s FOMC.

The BoE’s Monetary Policy Committee

28. Money market instruments available to extract expectations of future changes in the Bank of England’s (BoE) official two-week repo rate include: (i) generalized collateral (GC) repurchase agreements, (ii) interbank loans fixed at LIBOR rates, (iii) short-sterling futures contracts, (iv) forward rate agreements (FRAs), (v) the sterling swap market, and (vi) the sterling overnight interest average (SONIA) deposit rate. However, in each instrument the existence of term premia, and differences in credit quality, maturity, liquidity and other biases complicate the extraction of a “pure measure” of market expectations.16

29. Recognizing the inability of any one money market instrument to provide the best indication of Bank repo rate expectations, the BoE estimates two alternative forward curves from two alternative sets of instruments, each with common credit risk characteristics. One curve is fitted using mostly GC repos and gilt yields (known generically as the VRP17 curve), while the second (known as the Bank Liability Curve) is fitted using synthetic bond prices from interbank offer rates, short-sterling futures, FRAs and swaps. After adjusting for biases, these curves can be seen as the best measure of the market’s expectation of two-week forward rates. In what follows, we focus on market predictability taken from the short-end of VRP curve since it resulted in slightly better results.18

30. In order to determine the degree of predictability of BoE policy decisions, the interest rate from the fitted VRP curve is defined as a linear combination of two events:

it=βi25+(1β)i0(7)

where β is the probability of at least a 25 basis point change and (1 - β) is the probability of a no change decision. The interest rates are the present BoE official two-week repo rate with a 25 basis point change i25 added on and the current official rate i0. The assumption is that a β of 50 percent or greater implies the market expected the BoE to change interest rates during the upcoming MPC meeting. The observations are taken the day before the two-day meeting of the Bank’s MPC19. In the analysis, 42 meetings are used, 1 more than in Table 1 given the two meetings in September 2001.

31. Figure 3 (middle panel) reveals in graphical form the number of times financial markets correctly anticipated BoE decisions:

  • The graph shows that the two 50 basis point cuts in interest rates (February 1999, and November 2001) were anticipated by the market but the first change in direction (September 1999) caught the market off guard.

  • In contrast to the U.S. Federal Reserve results, about a third of the incorrect signals can be found in and around the fall of 2001.

  • The chart also demonstrates that the lull before the second change in direction—and the move toward loosening policy rates in early 2001—was also correctly viewed by markets as a “wait and see” period.

32. The contingency table results Table 3 reveals that the simple rule correctly predicted 9 out of the 15 (60 percent) changes in the BoE policy rate and 83 percent of the no-change months. While the overall hit rate was about 71 percent—with 30 of the 42 decisions correctly predicted—the reliability of the model’s prediction of a policy change was slightly lower at 60 percent or 9 out of 15.

Table 3.

United Kingdom: Contingency Table Using VRP Fitted Forward Curve

article image
Source: Staff estimates.

Percentage of time model signals rate change and one actually happens.

Percentage of correct signals.

The ECB Governing Council

33. In this section, we follow the simple heuristic methodology of Gaspar, Pérez, and Sicilia (GPS), who examined the ability of euro-area overnight interbank to anticipate changes in ECB policy rates. Pérez and Rodríguez (2001) showed that without market frictions and with risk neutral participants, euro-area interbank funds within a reserve maintenance period (and with a reserve averaging provision) could be considered perfect substitutes. In this framework, any expected differences between current and future cost of funds would be arbitraged away. Thus, EONIA rates at the start of any reserve maintenance period theoretically should already incorporate expectations of changes in overnight rates until the end of the reserve maintenance period. At the same time, new information could influence rates between the start of the reserve maintenance period and the day of the Governing Council meeting. Thus, the analysis could also be run using EONIA rates the day before the Governing Council meets.20

34. With this in mind, EONIA overnight rate before ECB decisions on monetary policy can be viewed a linear combination of two events as in equation (7). However, here the interest rates involved are the present main refinancing operation (MRO) rate with a 25 basis point change i25 and the current MRO rate i0. Again, assuming that β of 50 percent or greater implies the market expected the ECB to change interest rates, we can evaluate the number of times financial markets anticipated ECB decisions.21

35. Figure 3 (bottom panel) presents the results in graphical form using thresholds of +/- 0.125 basis points to represent EONIA outcomes with at least a 50 percent probability of a change in the official MRO rate. Bars are used to show the size and direction of the change in interest rates. With 12 of the 77 meetings close to the end of the reserve maintenance period, we have 65 usable observations. The chart clearly highlights a number of conclusions:

  • Although the October decision to reverse the April 1999 50 basis point cut was anticipated by markets, the second change in direction in May 2001 caught the markets by surprise;

  • Financial markets were unable to anticipate any of the 5 ECB rate cuts over the last 3½ years;22

  • Two of the five large rate changes were expected, although in one case (June 2000), it would appear that financial market participants were looking for a smaller 25 basis point change;

  • About one-third of the market prediction errors in anticipating ECB policy actions appear in and around the fall of 2001.

36. The contingency table results Table 4 reveals that the market correctly predicted 7 out of the 12 (58 percent) changes in the ECB policy rate and 83 percent of the no-change months. While the overall hit rate was about 79 percent—with 51 of the 65 decisions correctly predicted—the reliability of the model’s prediction of a policy change was only 44 percent or 7 out of 16.

Table 4.

Euro Area: Contingency Table Using EONIA Rates

(Day-before-ECB Meetings)

article image
Source: Staff estimates.

Percentage of time model signals rate change and one actually happens.

Percentage of correct signals.

37. Finally, Table 5 provides a summary of the results across all three central banks. The overall result is that the number of correct signals regarding policy decisions were roughly equal across all three central banks. The majority—about four fifths—of the policy decisions of these three central banks have been correctly anticipated by financial markets. However, on the basis of the models used here, the ECB is less predictable as regards large changes in or decreases in rates.

Table 5.

Summary Results of Central Bank Predictability

article image
Sources: staff estimates.

Percentage of monetary policy meetings in which the decision not to change rates was undertaken.

Numbers in parentheses represent changes.

Percentage of large rate changes correctly anticipated by financial markets. Large rate changes are defined as 50 basis points or greater.

Percentage of changes in the direction of the interest rate policy cycle.

Numbers in parentheses represent total number of policy rate cuts.

Percentage of time model signals rate change and one actually happens.

Percentage of correct signals over all policy decision days.

F. Interest Rate Changes: A View from Shifts in Yield Curves

38. Evidence on the predictability of central bank policy decisions can also be discerned from movements in the term structure of interest rates. From an expectations perspective, each point on the yield curve represents private sector agents’ best guesses on the current and future path of official interest rates. In forming these expectations, two sources of policy reaction uncertainty can arise. The first is related to private information on the macroeconomic indicators used by monetary authorities reaction function or in the monetary transmission process itself. Surprises here would reveal themselves at the short-end of the yield curve, particularly since lags on superior statistical data or monetary transmission mechanism itself is short lived. The second source of uncertainty is current and future (expected) policy targets, which may stem from imperfect policy credibility. This uncertainty on policy credibility could be due to reputation building or to an ongoing discovery process of market participants uncovering the central bank’s true policy targets.

39. To extract a measure of interest rate surprises along the yield curve, the following equation was estimated for each area across various maturities:

itm=α+β(L)itm+θitp+γdtitp+t(8)

where itm is the change in interest rates of maturity length m; itp is the change in the central bank policy rate; dt is a multiplicative regime shift dummy variable; and εt is a random error term.

40. Each regression uses daily data23 and is based on a set maturity length. Regressions were first run for the pre-1999 period to set baseline reaction levels, and then run over the January 1999 to May 2002 period to see if the reaction of yields changed over the last 3½ years. Yields on changes in German securities and in Bundesbank policy rates are use for the euro area given the lack of a true euro-area benchmark security and the de facto Bundesbank setting of area-wide policy in the pre-ECB period. In the post-1998 period, changes in the ECB two-week repo rate are used to represent changes in the monetary authorities policy stance.

41. Table 6 presents coefficient estimates on the main variable of interest (θ) and Newey-West adjusted p-values for each of the three countries at each maturity. A comparison of the results between the two periods suggests that surprises at the short-end of the yield curve have diminished in the United States and the United Kingdom since 1998. However, the comparison of euro-area and German interest rate data indicates that the surprises at the short-end of the spectrum have increased—between 10 to 20 basis points—since the start of stage III of EMU. In all cases, there would appear to be very little change at the long-end of the yield curve. Financial markets continue to view all three of these central banks as credible institutions, with well know policy targets.

Table 6.

Estimates of Interest Rate Surprise Effects in the United States, United Kingdom, and Euro Area 1/

article image
Source: staff estimates.

Numbers in parentheses are p-values, calculated using Newcy-West adjusted standard errors.

Number of observations.

Number of policy rate changes.

G. Concluding Observations

42. Together with the general public, media and academic community, financial markets are an important constituency group of any central bank. In particular, although central banks can control short-term interest rates through monetary policy, their control on longer-term yields and asset prices (and therefore the transmission of monetary policy) is somewhat more tenuous, being enacted mainly through the formulation of expectations. In this regard, the stability of expectations—and therefore the effectiveness of monetary policy—can be greatly enhanced if markets are able to anticipate correctly central bank policy decisions.

43. To some market participants, the early record of the ECB has created the impression that financial markets are less able to predict ECB policy decisions, particularly when compared to other central banks. To evaluate the validity of these impressions, this paper has examined the predictability of ECB, BoE, and U.S. Fed policy decisions over the last 3½ years.

44. Any comparison on the predictability of these three particular central banks should acknowledge the rather unique circumstances of the ECB. The ECB is a relatively young institution with a track record of only a few years, which has needed to be mindful of establishing its independence from political influences. In addition, unlike the Fed or the BoE, it must communicate its strategy and decisions to a very diverse constituency covering a variety of countries with distinctive political backgrounds and views on the role of monetary policy. For example, some of the ECB’s communication appears to be directed toward price and wage setters, in line with an European tradition that focuses on ensuring wage moderation. An added complexity arises from communicating central bank views on fiscal policy actions, particularly given the rather distinct nature of the Stability Pact framework. These factors, plus the two pillar monetary framework suggests that the ECB may be, a priori, somewhat less predictable than the other two older institutions.

45. The empirical results provide support for a number of conclusions:

  • All three central banks are relatively predictable institutions with a high degree of credibility. Through prudent policy management, each institution has helped to achieve low inflation environments, and markets appear to generally understand the policy objectives and frameworks of each central bank with few marked surprises in policy decisions.

  • The U.S. Federal Reserve—the most active central bank among the three with over 55 percent of meetings resulting in a decision to change rates—appears to be the most predictable central bank. Broadly speaking, the results on the predictability of the BoE fall in-between those of the U.S. Fed and the ECB. This outcome may be linked to the small size of the U.K. economy, which is subject to a sizable number of shocks. In such circumstances, the potential for disparate interpretations between the central bank and financial markets on the implications of these shocks maybe frequent, the result of which would be reflected in “unanticipated” policy decisions.

  • In the case of the ECB, the market has had difficulty anticipating—at least in our calculations—large changes and cuts in policy interest rates. To some extent, this may be due to the large number of Governing Council meetings with no policy changes and the debate about the ECB’s monetary framework. A second factor may have been that rate cuts (4 out of the 5) have taken place during periods when the monthly bulletin was indicating a neutral bias in policy rates for the medium-term. The market’s mediocre record in predicting cuts in ECB policy rates, however, may be related to a specific characteristic of the euro-area inter-bank market. For example, inter-bank yields may not be able to respond quickly to rate cut signals given the well-known tendency of banks to be short reserves preceding the end of the reserve maintenance period. Thus, additional work on the predictability of ECB policy decisions will need to examine other markets.

  • Finally, the finding of a high degree of overall policy predictability among these three central banks during a relatively turbulent period demonstrates that a variety of monetary policy frameworks, be it inflation targeting, a uniquely continental European two-pillar system, or a more discretionary U.S. model can be successfully understood by financial markets.

Research on Predicting ECB Policy Decisions

Two research studies (Gaspar, Pérez, and Sicilia (2001) (GPS) and Hartmann, Manna and Manzanares (2001) (HMM) have considered the market’s ability to predict ECB policy moves./1 GPS examined the daily overnight EONIA market using interest rate data from January 1999 to March 2001. HMM examined intra-day tick data. (bid-ask spreads and mid-rates) on overnight interbank quotes from 6 voice brokers in four euro-area countries as well as tick data from the Italian electronic trading system (e-MID) from November 1999 to March 2000. Both papers viewed their results as providing positive evidence on the ability of markets to predict ECB policy decisions.

GPS (2001)

GPS estimated an EGARCH model of the daily change in EONIA overnight interest rates with calendar, reserve maintenance period and ECB meeting day dummy variables in the mean and variance equations. Meeting dummies were not found to be significant in the mean equation suggesting that monetary policy announcements did not affect overnight rates, i.e., the market did not make systematic errors with respect to monetary decisions. Similarly, the meeting dummies did not have a significant impact on the variance of returns, especially in relation to other fundamental determinates of market volatility (macroeconomic news, liquidity shocks). In addition, GPS used a heuristic approach to show that markets were able to predict a majority (around 80 to 85 percent) of the ECB’s interest rate decisions.

HMM (2001)

This paper considered the functioning of the overnight market for funds through a study of quoting activity (as well as trading volume where available), overnight rate volatility (defined as the average absolute overnight rate change during an intra-day period), and bid-ask spreads from broker data.

HMM first examined the intra-week and intra-day behavior of the data, focusing on “normal” days (all business days less the two-reserve maintenance period days and Y2K days). Given the infrequent and irregular pattern of the voice broker data, it is broken up into 3 intervals (8 a.m. to 11 a.m.), (11 a.m. to 2 p.m.) and (2 p.m. to 5 p.m.). The average absolute 3-hour interval change in the overnight rate is about 3-4 basis points. Thursdays are the most volatile (and active) at about 4-7 basis points—but as a whole the market is not very volatile. The main microstructure features are: (i) Mondays—low post-weekend trading and volatility, (ii) Tuesdays—high market activity related to MROs, (iii) Wednesdays—large MID trading volumes related to MRO settlement obligations, and (iv) Thursdays—high volatility potentially related to ECB meeting days. Trading activity took on the usual U-shape—except for Thursdays where the mid-day interval was very high—with lots of activity at the start and end of the day. Volatility and spreads were rather U-shaped as well. Friday was relatively active, as managers tended to close out positions before the long weekend break.

Focusing on monetary policy related events, HMM investigated the intra-day patterns of Governing Council Thursdays versus non-Governing Council Thursdays. Activity was (substantially) higher on Council days than on non-Council days. In fact, non-Council days look like post-weekend Mondays. A U-shape trading pattern emerged for the non-Council days, but for the Council days, trading activity picked up in the mid-day period. HMM also look more closely at 45-minute intervals from the Italian MID market. Activity (volume and quoting) increased dramatically after the 1:45 p.m. ECB policy announcement; in fact, average volume in the post-announcement period on Council days was 2.5 times larger than on non-Council Thursdays and tick frequency was 4.5 times larger. HMM state that the volumes, however, were not particularly low before the ECB policy announcement—as compared to the non-Council Thursdays. They cited this as evidence that upcoming ECB interest rate decisions were not preceded by substantial asymmetric information, which would have led to adverse select and hence ceasing volumes.

Volatility in both the voice broker and electronic trading system increased on Council days around the 1:45 p.m. announcement period. The finer MID data reveal that most of the increase in volatility was right after the ECB policy announcement. Volatility (mean rate changes) on Council days was on average 3 times higher than the mean 45-minute rate change over a non-Council day, and 10 times larger than the average change on a non-Council Thursday during the same interval. Upon a closer examination of the Italian MID data, the authors concluded that the higher volatility after ECB policy announcements was not a mechanical adjustment to the three ECB rate changes in the data, and that the market was better at anticipating an unchanged ECB policy rate than in anticipating changes in policy rates. In particular, only in one rate increase did the overnight rate move close to the future or post-announcement rate. However, the authors noted that the average 4.6 basis point increase right after the announcement on Council days was relatively small given policy changes. On the other hand, mean returns were probably a lot higher right after the announcement; thus the average basis point change would tend to hide this outcome.

Bid-ask spreads were higher on Council Thursdays, especially during the mid-day interval. This could be interpreted as asymmetric information increasing trading costs before ECB announcements, however, the authors pointed to the large market activity and volumes, which suggested continuous informational flows. MID spreads were higher—as compared to non-Council Thursdays—both before and after ECB announcements. When compared to all other days (non-Council, non-MRO settlement days) the authors state that the spreads (during pre and post announcement periods) on Council Thursdays were similar. Together with the information on volumes, trading activity, volatility and spreads, the authors stated that overnight market participants were not subject to large uncertainty regarding ECB interest rate decisions, since they could by and large anticipate the decisions.

1/See Gaspar, Vitor, Perez Quiros, Gabriel, and Jorge Sicilia, 2001, “The ECB Monetary Strategy and the Money Market,” ECB Working Paper No. 69; and Hartmann, P, M. Manna, and A. Manzanares, 2001, “The microstructure of the Euro Money Market,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 20, pp. 895-948.

References

  • Begg, D., and others, 2002, “Surviving the Slowdown: Monitoring the European Central Bank 4,Center for Economic Policy Research.

  • Bini-Smaghi, L., and D. Gros, 2001, “Is the ECB Sufficiently Accountable and Transparent?,CEPS Working Document No. 169.

  • Blenck, D., H. Hasko, S. Hilton, and K. Masaki, 2001, “The Main Features of the Monetary Policy Frameworks of the Bank of Japan, the Federal Reserve and the Eurosystem,Bank for International Settlements Papers, No. 9.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blinder, and others, 2001, “How do Central Banks Talk?,International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies (ICMBS), and the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borio, C.E.V., 2001, “A Hundred Ways to Skin A Cat: Comparing the Monetary Policy Operating Procedures in the United States, Japan and the Euro Area,Bank for International Settlements Papers, No. 9.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brainard, W., 1967, “Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Policy,American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings.

  • Brooke, Cooper, and Scholtes 1999, “Inferring Market Interest Rate Expectations from Money Market Rates”, Bank of England, Quarterly Bulletin.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Callow, J., 2001, “Euro Area Special,Credit Suisse First Boston, Economics Research, November.

  • European Central Bank, 2001, “ECB Monetary Policy Press Conference,November 8.

  • Gaspar, Vitor, Gabriel Pérez Quirós, and Jorge Sicilia, 2001, “The ECB Monetary Strategy and the Money Market,ECB Working Paper No. 69.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gros, Daniel, et. al., 2002, “Fiscal and Monetary Policy for a Low-Speed Europe,Centre for European Policy Studies.

  • Haldane, Andrew, and Vicky Read, 2000, “Monetary Policy Surprises and the Yield Curve,Bank of England Working Paper.

  • Haldane, Andrew, and Vicky Read, 2001, “Monetary Policy and the Yield Curve,Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin.

  • Hämäläinen, S., 2001, “The ECB’s Monetary Policy—Accountability, Transparency, and Communication,Speech delivered to Old Age, New Economy and Central Banking Conference, Helsinki.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hartmann, P., M. Manna, and A. Manzanares, 2001, “The Microstructure of the Euro Money Market,Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 20, pp. 895948.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Issing, O. 2001, “Monetary Policy and Financial Markets,Speech at ECB Watchers Conference, Frankfurt, June.

  • Krueger, Joel T., and Ken N. Kuttner, 1996, “The Federal Funds Rate As A Predictor of Federal Reserve Policy,”, Journal of Futures Markets, December 1996, pp. 86579.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kuttner, Kenneth N., 1999, “Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence from the Federal Funds Futures Market,Federal Reserve Bank of New York, November.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pérez Quirós, Gabriel, and Hugo Rodríguez-Mendizábal, 2001, “The Daily Market for Funds in Europe: Has Something Changed with the EMU?,ECB Working Paper No. 67.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poole, William, and Robert Rasche, 2000, “Perfecting the Market’s Knowledge of Monetary Policy,Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 18, No. 2/3, pp. 255298.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rasche, Robert, and Daniel L. Thornton, 2002, “The FOMC’s Balance-of-Risk Statement and Market Expectations of Policy Actions,Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October, Vol. 84, Number 5.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robertson, John C., and Daniel L. Thornton, 1997, “Using Federal Funds Futures Rates to Predict Federal Reserve Actions,Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December, pp: 4553.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • St. Louis Federal Reserve, 2002, “The Balance of Risks,Monetary Trends, May.

  • Thornton, Daniel L. 2000, “The Relationship Between the Federal Funds Rate and the Fed’s Federal Funds Target: Is it Open Market Operation or Open Mouth Operations?,Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Working Paper 1999-022B.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thornton, Daniel L. 1998, “Tests of the Market’s Reaction to Federal Funds Rate Target Changes,Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December, pp.2536

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

Prepared by Kevin Ross (krossfgiimf.org).

3

Gros, et.al, (2002) indicate that predictability may have improved since the second half of 2001.

4

However, there may be instances of justifiable monetary policy surprises, e.g., during periods of asymmetric information.

5

For example, a futures contract on Federal Funds—the main policy rate of the U.S. central bank—is available while futures contracts on the euro-area’s two-week official repo instrument are non-existent. See Borio (1997, 2001), and Blenck, et al. (2001) for a comparison of monetary policy operating procedures and frameworks.

6

In August 1999, the FOMC established the Working Group on the Directive and Disclosure Policy to assess the FOMC’s approach to disclosing its view about prospective policy adjustments and to propose procedural modifications. The working group’s January 2000 report recommended that the FOMC statement issue a “balance-of-risks” statement that chose between a set of bracketed words to reflect the Committee’s view about prospective developments. Now risks are explicitly categorized as either: (i) balanced with respect for both goals; (ii) weighted mainly toward conditions that may generate heightened inflation pressures; or (iii) weighted mainly toward conditions that may generate economic weakness.

7

While the language used in the press statement (and editorial) has generally referenced the “balance of risks to price stability over the medium-term”, the presentation of this assessment has not been uniform since the start of stage III of EMU. For example, in the Fall of 1999 President Duisenberg talked about “creeping biases” during press conferences; beginning in May 2001 editorial statements regarding the “appropriateness” of policy rates over the medium-term were used; in May 2002 the editorial compared the balance of risks to those projected in December 2001; and in June 2002 the editorial noted that there was too much uncertainty to fully assess the balance of risks.

8

These staff forecasts, however, have been criticized for their lack of precision. The width of forecast error bands have been set at twice the historical mean absolute forecast errors made by euro-area central banks.

9

President Duisenberg noted that bi-monthly meetings had led to higher volatility in exchange rates and interest rates, and the move to assess monetary policy only at the first meeting of the month may have the effect of calming markets, (ECB Press Conference, November 8, 2001).

10

Eliminating the three change decisions during these non-scheduled meeting days would decease Fed activism to some 50 percent of all FOMC meetings over this period. The Fed meets 8 times a year with the first and fourth meeting held over two days in order to cover the longer-term economic outlook and current state of open market operations. There does not appear to be any pattern regarding the decision to change rates. The BoE’s MPC generally meets on the Wednesday and Thursday after the first Monday of the month.

12

Given that policy moves are expected to last well into the future, consumers and firms should react more forcefully today to any change in policy rates.

13

Approximately 53 percent of the U.S. Federal Reserve changes in interest rates in this VA- year period were at least as large as 50 basis points. For the ECB and the BoE, these figures are 42 and 13 percent, respectively.

14

In order to allow rate hikes to be shown as positive changes, we take the negative of the spreads. Similarly we reverse the min/max range in what follows.

15

Two rate moves were undertaken in January 2001, which are considered as one monthly move in the analysis. Thus the 17 policy moves tabulated in Table 1 must be considered as 16 policy moves.

16

See Brooke, Cooper, and Scholtes (1999), “Inferring Market Interest Rate Expectations from Money Market Rates”, Bank of England, Quarterly Bulletin.

17

The BoE uses a variable roughness penalty (VRP) technique to fit various types of forward curves.

18

Near-term 3-month short sterling futures contracts were used. This method relied on more judgmental calculations of the time-varying term premia between the 3-month interbank deposit rate and the official repo rate, and resulted in somewhat less satisfactory outcomes. These results are available from the author upon request.

19

The BoE supplied the data for both curves.

20

As in GPS, we eliminate meetings that fall within 4 days of the end of the reserve maintenance period to avoid liquidity effects.

21

The average spread between EONIA and MRO rates will vary based upon a (time-varying) risk premia associated with the cyclical expectations of interest rates. Thus, as in GPS, we undertook the analysis with a “structural” spread of 3, 5, and 7 basis points. The outcomes were broadly similar, and here we report results using the 3 basis points spread.

22

This result also holds when the analysis used EONIA rates at the beginning of the reserve maintenance period.

23

All data was taken from Bloomberg. Libor rates were used at short maturities. U.K. gilt, U.S. treasury bond, and German bund rates were used at longer maturities.

Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies of the Euro Area: Selected Issues
Author: International Monetary Fund