The paper suggests that several factors, besides tight monetary policy, may well have contributed to the high real interest rates that have been observed in Israel. The paper examines the impact of unanticipated changes in nominal interest rate monetary policy shocks on a number of variables in Israel. The paper provides evidence that the inflation expectation measure derived from the capital markets tends to overstate the trend in actual inflation. The paper also provides statistical data on the economic indices of Israel.

Abstract

The paper suggests that several factors, besides tight monetary policy, may well have contributed to the high real interest rates that have been observed in Israel. The paper examines the impact of unanticipated changes in nominal interest rate monetary policy shocks on a number of variables in Israel. The paper provides evidence that the inflation expectation measure derived from the capital markets tends to overstate the trend in actual inflation. The paper also provides statistical data on the economic indices of Israel.

III. Monetary Policy Procedures in Israel1

1. This paper examines the procedures underlying the conduct of monetary policy in Israel by estimating a monetary policy reaction function. The period under examination is the era since 1991 which marked a significant reduction in inflation and an explicit inflation-targeting regime. This paper examines current monetary policy procedures in light of the literature on inflation targeting, especially the role of a capital-market-based measure of inflation expectations. In addition, the paper measures the volatility of the monetary policy instrument—the discount rate—under two policy reaction rules.

2. Section A of the paper describes the current procedure of inflation targeting in Israel and one important element in its implementation, a market measure of inflation expectations. Section B assesses the statistical property of this inflation expectations measure and discusses the implication of pure inflation-expectation targeting using a nonstructural method. Section C presents the estimates of a monetary policy reaction function and rolling regression forecasts of the monetary policy variable based on an alternative monetary policy rule. Section D concludes.

A. The Monetary Policy in Israel

3. Monetary policy in Israel was characterized by an excessively accommodative stance in the late 1970s and early 1980s which led to the triple digit inflation. The government launched a massive stabilization program in mid 80s, including a drastic reduction in the fiscal deficit, a significant tightening of monetary policy and the adoption of a nominal anchor. The move successfully brought inflation down to double-digit levels in the early 1990s. With the eruption of a series of exchange rate attacks in 1988—1991 mainly reflecting the still high inflation differential between Israel and other industrial economies that was inconsistent with the fixed exchange rate, the Bank of Israel (BoI) gradually relaxed the nominal exchange rate anchor by widening the trading band around a fixed exchange rate against a currency basket and adopted explicit inflation targeting following the example of several other industrial countries.2

4. The major policy change was initiated in December 1991 when Israel moved from an adjustable band to a preannounced crawling band. The band was widened in several steps to about ±18 percent around the midpoint rate in late 1999. The rate of crawl is asymmetric: 2 percent per year for the appreciated edge of the band and 4 percent per year for the depreciated edge. Even though inflation targeting is the main objective of the BoI, the interest rate that is consistent with the inflation objective may not be consistent with the crawling band of the exchange rate. Since 1991 tight monetary policy to achieve the inflation target had led to large capital inflows which in turn caused the exchange rate to appreciate. As adjusting interest rates downward would have jeopardized the inflation target, in order to maintain the band the BoI had to intervene in the foreign exchange market on several occasions since 1993 to keep the sheqel within the band and large-scale sterilization was taken to reverse the monetary impact (Leiderman and Bar-Or (1999), Bufman and Leiderman (1998)). However, with the current very wide band the exchange rate is essentially freely floating, the conflict of using one instrument supporting two nominal anchors is no longer an issue.3

5. Inflation targeting has a number of advantages relative to the traditional monetary aggregates targeting: it reduces the instability in the relationship between the target variable and the policy variable, it provides a more transparent guide to monetary policy, and it provides the commitment, discipline, and accountability which make it easier to judge whether policy actions were taken to ensure that the target is achieved. However, successful inflation targeting requires good inflation forecasting. In reality, inflation targeting is conducted by adjusting the monetary policy instruments whenever there is a deviation of the inflation forecast from the inflation target.4

6. In Israel, the discount rate is the most important tool used by the BoI to influence the inflation rate. According to the current BoI law, the governor makes the decision on the direction of the interest rate, based on the inputs from his staff concerning future movements in inflation. In the Inflation Report published by the BoI semiannually, the “inflation environment” is referred to as the important element in the interest rate decision. In the absence of an official or commonly used inflation forecast formulated by the BoI (see Bufman and Leiderman 1998), the inflation environment is the asset-market-based inflation expectation measure along with other macroeconomic variables such as GDP growth rates, the fiscal performance, and the capital market developments.

7. This inflation expectation measure is derived as the difference between the yields on a nonindexed bond (usually the Makam treasury bill) and that on inflation indexed bonds (usually the Gali or Sagi bond) of similar maturity. The BoI’s measure corrects for the inflation differential actually accrued during the life of an indexed bond and that was compensated for by employing detailed information on the bonds’ coupon and inflation payment and its maturity. However, the usually published measure simply takes the difference between the yield to maturity of the treasury bill and the real yield to maturity on an indexed bond of similar remaining maturity as a proxy for inflation expectations.

B. Measurement Errors in the Inflation Expectation Measure and the Implication of Pure Inflation Targeting Based on Nonstructural Inflation Expectations

8. There appear to be several measurement problems with this capital-market-based measure of inflation expectations.5 First, these two types of instruments are not perfect substitutes because of the differential tax treatment on the capital gains from them and because of the liquidity difference between the treasury bill and the bond markets.6 Second, the yield differential also embeds the risk premium for holding a nominal asset versus a real asset and it is likely that the risk premium itself is correlated with the inflation expectation. Given the high inflation history in Israel, the risk premium is likely positive and hence the inflation expectation measure would tend to overstate actual future inflation.7

9. In addition, the inflation expectation measure derived from the capital market is highly adaptive and does not appear to be a good predictor of ex post inflation. Figure 1 plots the inflation expectation at time t, the 12-month past inflation at time t and the actual ex post inflation at time t+12. It is clear from the figure that the 12-month inflation expectation measure is highly correlated with the past inflation at time t and thus follows the movement of the past inflation. It also appears evident that the ex post 12-month inflation does not have a close relation with the ex ante expected 12-month inflation. In short, the figure reveals that the current inflation expectation measure that is used as an input in the monetary policy decision process by the BoI is very adaptive and appears not to be a very reliable predictor of future inflation.8

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Inflation and the 12-month Inflation Expectation Measure

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2000, 062; 10.5089/9781451819502.002.A003

10. Simple regressions from the beginning of 1991 to mid-1999 confirm that the inflation expectation measure is significantly correlated with past inflation and with a coefficient larger than one (Table 1). This seems to suggest that the inflation expectation measure tends to react more than proportionately to the past inflation development; hence, a measure that tends to exaggerate expected inflation. Another regression of the inflation expectation measure on the ex post 12-month inflation indicates that the correlation between these two variables is significant at 5 percent confidence level but the magnitude of the correlation is small. In other words, a simple regression points out that the inflation expectation measure does not have much predictive power about the future inflation. The correlation coefficient between actual inflation and the inflation expectation measure is 0.88, while the correlation coefficient between the expectation measure and ex post 12-month inflation is only 0.22. These observations reinforce each other and indicate that the inflation expectation measure does not possess the required statistical properties for a good predictor for inflation. This is in addition to the measurement errors inherent in its construction as discussed in paragraph 8.

Table 1.

Correlation Between Actual Inflation and Inflation Expectation Measure

article image

t–ratio in parenthesis

11. Inflation targeting has gained momentum in recent years, led by several successful examples, such as Australia, Canada, Sweden and the United Kingdom. The two main advantages of inflation targeting compared to the traditional monetary aggregate is that it is more direct: it avoids the unstable relationship between the intermediate target like M2 and the policy target. Moreover, it is more transparent and easier for the public to understand. For example, the inflation report published by the Bank of England details its policy reaction function and how different inflation expectation measures are derived and related. However, as the path of future inflation is unobservable, inflation targeting in practice usually is conducted by targeting some form of inflation forecast.

12. A large number of academic and policy studies have been done on the merits and appropriateness of inflation targeting (Taylor (1999)). One development warranting particular attention comes out of the studies done by Bernanke and Woodford (1997) and Svensson (1997). Bernanke and Woodford (1997) address the issue of existence and uniqueness of rational expectation equlibria when the central bank targets an inflation forecast that is based on asset market or private forecasts. Using a dynamic rational expectation models, they are able to demonstrate that if the central bank only targets an inflation forecast which is not derived from a structural model of the economy, then the equilibrium outcome may be undetermined or nonexistent. This implies that, the inflation forecast, whether it is an asset-market-based measure, a consensus forecast, or a naive forecast, may contain useful information for the monetary authority, but too much reliance on it could lead to possible excess volatility in the policy variable and excess volatility in the macroeconomic environment. The indeterminacy in the equilibrium outcome and excess volatility can be avoided by using a structural forecast of inflation derived from a structural model and adopting an appropriate monetary policy reaction function in which the inflation forecast is not the sole significant argument.

C. The Monetary Policy Reaction Function and an Alternative Rule

13. In this section, we estimate a monetary policy reaction for Israel and evaluate its appropriateness in light of the studies cited above. An in-sample rolling regression forecast of the BoI’s discount rate based on an alternative rule similar to the one proposed by Bernanke and Woodford (1997) is compared to the actual interest rate.

Policy reaction function

14. The study focuses on the period from the end of 1991 to the end of 1998 both because of data availability and because this is the period during which an explicit inflation targeting framework was adopted.9 Monthly data on 12-month inflation, 12-month inflation expectations, industrial production index, industrial employment index, money growth, and credit growth are used in the study.10 Trend industrial production and employment are estimated by the H-P filter; the deviation of actual production and employment from this trend is defined as the output gap and employment gap, respectively.11

15. Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests on all the variables with a constant and a trend term indicate that except for inflation, all other variables are stationary. Further tests of inflation without the trend term show that the unit root hypothesis can be rejected at the 10 percent significance level. Given the low power of the standard unit root test, the evidence supports the hypothesis of the stationarity of the data.

16. Following Clarida, Gali and Gertler (1998a, 1998b), a monetary policy reaction function is estimated for Israel using the following variables: inflation, inflation expectation, and GDP and employment gaps. Generalized Method of Moment (GMM) estimators are estimated.12 Specifically, the model is of the following form:

it*=α+β(E[πt+k|Ωt}πt*]+γE[yt+1|Ωt](1)

where i*t is the policy interest rate (discount rate) set by the BoI, πt+k denotes inflation in period t+k, yt+1 denotes the output gap or employment gap at time t+1. E is the expected value operator, and Ωt is the information set at time t. The equilibrium nominal interest rate is denoted by α.

The implied real interest rate rule is then:

rt*=α¯+(β1)(E[πt+k|Ωt]πt*)+γE[yt+1|Ωt](2)

where α¯=απ* is the equilibrium real interest rate. This real interest rule implies that the response of the real interest rate to changes in expected inflation depends on whether β is greater or less than one.

However, given that the interest rate is likely affected by factors other than those included in the monetary policy reaction function derived in (1), and as the central bankers want to keep a relatively smooth path of interest rate, the following is assumed to be the actual interest rate process:13

it=(1ρ)it*+ρit1+t(3)

which assumes a partial adjustment of the deviation of interest rate from its target level. The error term embeds other shocks and factors that influence the interest rate.

Combining the policy rule with the partial adjustment in interest rate, we obtain the following interest rate reaction function:

it=(1ρ)α+(1ρ)β(πt+kπt*)+(1ρ)γyt+1+ρit1+ωt(4)

where ωt=(1ρ)[β(πt+kE[πt+k|Ωt])+γ(yt+1E[yt+1|Ωt])]+t. It is a linear combination of the forecasting errors of inflation and output and the shock from equation 3. By construction, wt is orthogonal to any variable in the information set at time t, i.e., there is no correlation between the error term and variables in the information set. In equation 4, the inflation target π* is not included into the constant term because in Israel the inflation target changes from year to year. Therefore, the yearly target was subtracted from the inflation series as indicated by the model.14 A variant of equation (4) is obtained by replacing the expected inflation at time t+k with the inflation expectation measure π˜t+k derived from the capital markets:

it=(1ρ)α+(1ρ)β(π˜t+kπt*)+(1ρ)γyt+1+ρit1+ωt(5)

In equation(5), ωt=(1ρ)[β(π˜t+kE[πt+k|Ωt])+γ(yt+1E[yt+1|Ωt])]+t. Thus ωt is the linear combination of the forecasting error of the capital market based inflation expectation measure from the expected inflation based on rational expectation, the output forecasting error, and the error from equation (3). Assuming that the market is efficient in pricing in all information, the first term in cot should be close to zero. Thus, ωt should also be orthogonal to the information at time t.

17. We estimated the monetary policy reaction function in three different ways. First, we estimate a Taylor type of backward-looking rule based on current inflation and expected oneperiod-ahead output or employment. Second, a forward-looking reaction function of the form of equation (4) is estimated with the 12–month lead inflation and with the output or employment one period ahead. Third, the measure of inflation expectation is used as in equation (5). Implicitly we assume a shorter forecasting horizon for real variables. Here the forecasting horizon for inflation is 12 months ahead, while that for the output is one month ahead.15 According to the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test both the inflation and the inflation expectation measure are trend-stationary, so they are detrended before the estimation.16 The instrument sets include the lagged output or employment, lagged inflation or inflation expectation, lagged money growth and credit growth and lagged interest rates, up to 3 lags. As there are more instruments than the parameters, the over–identifying test is performed and none of the models is rejected at the conventional significance level.17 The following table presents the estimation results, t-statistics in parenthesis.

Table 2.

Estimates of Monetary Policy Reaction Function

article image

18. First, all the models suggest that the interest rate series is highly auto-regressive, the interest rate-smoothing coefficient p is highly significant in most cases and below one. Second, the coefficient γ has the wrong sign in most cases, when the expected output is above the trend then the interest rate will be raised, but when the future employment is strong then the interest rate will be cut. But γ is never significant at any conventional significance level, suggesting that the Central Bank of Israel has consistently adopted a pure inflation targeting strategy during the sample period. This finding would appear to be consistent with the stated objective of the BoI of bringing inflation down over this period to the level close to that in industrial countries. Lastly, coefficient α, which should proximate the average interest rate during the sample period, is highly significant. The highly significant policy reaction coefficient β warrants more discussion below.

19. We can see that β remains well below one when the current realized inflation is used in the reaction function and when the 12-month inflation expectation measure is used.18 This indicates that the central bank does not raise discount rate one to one to the deviations of inflation from its targeted level. So when there is a surge in past inflation or inflation expectation, the real interest rate based on these inflation measures will decline even after the interest rate increase. However, the picture is quite different when the reaction function was estimated with 12-month ahead actual inflation, which exploits the relation between the ex post 12-month inflation and ex ante policy action. In this case, the β coefficient is well above one and statistically significant.19 We interpret this result as indicating that even though ex ante the central bank did not appear to raise the interest rate more than proportionately to preempt inflation, the ex post inflation performance suggests that the increase was more than enough to compensate the inflation shock 12 months later. This is entirely consistent with the fact that the inflation expectation measure tends to overstate the actual inflation, as discussed in Section B. One implication of this finding would appear to be that a decision based on this overstated measure ex ante may lead to aggressive inflation reduction ex post.

20. To summarize, our estimates seem to confirm the view of the BoI itself (Leiderman (1999, 2000), BoI (1999)) that the BoI is pursuing a pure inflation targeting regime. Moreover, to the extent that there is reliance on the inflation expectation measure derived from the capital markets, the findings by Bernanke and Woodford (1998) would apply. They showed that a central bank policy reaction rule with pure inflation targeting on a non–structural inflation expectation measure could lead to indeterminacy in the rational expectation equilibrium outcomes and very likely, to excess volatility in the policy variable and macroeconomic outcome. However, as Leiderman (2000) notes, the monetary policy reaction of the BoI at times has been quite rapid to departure of inflation from targeted levels. He argues that in an economy where there is uncertainty about the persistence of inflation shocks and only partial credibility of monetary policy, aggressive policy responses to deviation of inflation can be more effective than gradual policy actions in bringing inflation back to target. Hence, what appears to be “excess volatility” can in fact be an appropriate policy response.20

In-sample forecast based on an alternative policy rule

21. This section follows Bernanke and Woodford (1998) to develop an alternative policy rule which is derived from a dynamic structural model. In their paper, they showed that a policy rule based on the past value of the interest rate itself, its expectation, observed values of output or unemployment and other macroeconomic variables, and the inflation measure will lead to an efficient equilibrium outcome. If we adopt a version of the sticky-price dynamic model used by many others in the literature, e.g., Taylor (1999) and Clarida, Gali and Gertler (1998), and linearize the equilibrium conditions along the steady state, we obtain the following interest rate policy rule which is very similar to the one proposed by Bernanke and Woodford (1998).

ir=α+β(πtπ*)+γyt1+ρit1+λmt1+ηlt1+ωt(6)

where mt−1 and lt−1 are the observed money growth and credit growth in last period, with other variables defined as above.

22. The alternative rule along with the estimated monetary policy rule as in equation (5) are also estimated using GMM with four lags of each of the variables in the model. The baseline estimation was done with data from the first month of 1992 to November 1995. This sub-sample was chosen to ensure sufficient observations in the estimation for accurate estimates, and at the same time to leave enough data for in-sample forecasts. Rolling regression is used to continuously update the estimation of the model whenever there is “new” information. One step ahead forecasts of the interest rate are obtained from the estimates of the model. Two measures of inflation are used in the forecasting, one is the current observed past 12–month inflation, the other is the current 12–month inflation expectation measure derived from the capital markets. The comparisons between the actual interest rate and the forecasted interest rates based on the alternative models is tabulated in Table 3, where:

article image

The four in-sample forecasts and the actual interest rate series are also plotted together in Figure 2.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Forecasts of Interest Rate and Actual Interest Rate

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 2000, 062; 10.5089/9781451819502.002.A003

Table 3.

In-Sample Forecasts of Interest Rate vs. the Actual Interest Rate

article image

23. The statistics in table 2 indicate that the four forecasted interest rates all have lower standard deviations than the actual interest rate. Some statistical tests are performed to check if the differences are statistically significant. We cannot reject the null that the variances of the five series are equal, neither can we reject the null of equal variance among predictions based on the estimated monetary reaction function as in equation (5) and the interest rate. But the hypothesis of equal variance between the alternative model described by equation (6) and the actual interest rate is strongly rejected.21 The test results are reported in Table 3.

24. The results seem to suggest that the alternative model does produce smoother interest rate reactions to shocks in the economy, and the difference is statistically significant. While the estimated monetary policy rule as in equation (5) generates a smaller variance in interest rate forecasts than that of the actual interest rate, the difference is not significant. Using the actual observed inflation in the two forecasting models also generates statistically different interest rate forecasts. These results provide evidence in favor of the view that an alternative policy rule as specified in equation (6) does produce a smoother interest rate outcome than a pure inflation targeting rule, especially if the targeted inflation forecast is not generated from a structural model.

25. The finding that the alternative monetary policy rule produces a smoother policy reaction is consistent with the result from Bernanke and Woodford (1998). When a structural model is used in formulating inflation forecast and based on which policy response is then generated, the additional information contained in the structural forecast helps to smooth the policy reaction. However, a smoother policy reaction to shocks may not coincide with an optimal policy reaction to shocks. Given the inherent tradeoff between the variability in output and in inflation, the conduct of monetary policy must balance the costs and benefits of departure of inflation and output from their target levels. To evaluate whether the alternative policy reaction rule in equation (6) is “better” than the estimated one as in equation (5), one has to compare the tradeoff between the variability of output and inflation implied by these two rules, termed the efficiency frontier of policy reaction functions. For any given level of inflation variability, the reaction function that leads to the lowest output variability on the efficiency frontier is considered a “better” policy reaction function. There is a body of research in this area, as demonstrated by the work of Clark, Laxton and Rose (1997) and more comprehensively, Black, Macklem and Rose (1998), Drew and Hunt (1999) and Taylor (1999). This line of work is beyond the scope of this paper, but provides an interesting line of investigation for future analysis of alternative reaction functions.

Table 4.

Test of Equal Variance Among the Interest Rate Predictions From the Alternative Model and the Actual Interest Rater22

article image

D. Conclusion

26. The study has provided evidence that the inflation expectation measure derived from the capital markets tends to overstate the trend in actual inflation, is a highly adaptive measure of inflation, and does not appear to be a very reliable predictor of future inflation.

27. The estimated monetary reaction function seems to indicate that the BoI was actively pursuing a “pure” inflation targeting policy. Bernanke and Woodford (1998) demonstrated that a monetary reaction function targeting only the inflation expectation measure that is not derived from a structural model could lead to volatile policy reactions. We showed that the interest rate response based on an alternative rule is smoother than the actual interest rate. Because the inflation expectation measure tends to overstate actual inflation, the policy response based on the inflation expectation measure, which appears accommodative, becomes preemptive ex post.

28. However, caution needs to be exercised when interpreting these results. A smoother interest rate response does not necessarily imply a better policy outcome in terms of the tradeoff between the output and inflation. To address the issues of the optimal policy response, one has to simulate the efficiency frontier between the variance of output and inflation (see Clark, Laxton and Rose (1997), Black, Marklem and Rose (1998), Drew and Hunt (1999)). This could be a natural next step from this study.

INFORMATION NOTE Israel: Developments in Exchange Restrictions

1. Since 1987, the extensive system of foreign exchange controls in Israel has been gradually eased. Before that time, all foreign currency transactions were forbidden unless explicitly permitted. Current account restrictions focused, inter alia, on limiting foreign currency travel allowances (including through use of credit cards) and wage payments and unilateral transfers abroad. Capital account restrictions focused on both inflows and outflows, but later the emphasis was more on restricting outflows due to a concern that, if left unrestricted, resident portfolio diversification would greatly outweigh the magnitude of foreign inflows. There were also multiple currency practices, such as the 4 percent tax on imports of tourism services levied at the time of the exchange transaction and the exchange rate insurance scheme for exporters.

2. The gradual easing of these restrictions over time–including elimination of the multiple currency practices—led to the acceptance by Israel of the International Monetary Fund’s Article VIII, Sections 2, 3, and 4 in September 1993. Further, by 1994 all restrictions on capital inflows had been eliminated, including foreign borrowing by Israeli residents.

3. During 1998, three further steps were taken in the liberalization program. The first went into effect on January 1, 1998 and included:

  • Israeli residents were permitted to purchase freely foreign currency with local currency and to deposit it in foreign currency deposits in Israeli banks.

  • Israeli residents were permitted to transfer money and foreign securities held in custody deposit between foreign currency deposits within the domestic banking system.

  • All restrictions on mutual funds’ investments in foreign securities were abolished.

  • The limit of 5 percent of turnover or 10 percent of capital on holdings of foreign securities and foreign currency abroad by Israeli companies was abolished.

  • Israeli residents, except insurers and pension funds, were permitted to freely engage in NIS/foreign currency derivatives, and provident funds could engage in such derivatives within the limit on foreign currency financial investments.

  • All restrictions on forward transactions between foreign currencies, cross rates, interest rates on foreign-currency assets or liabilities, commodity and securities prices, were removed.

4. Additional changes went into effect on February 12, 1998, namely:

  • Israeli residents and nonresidents traveling abroad were permitted to purchase US$1,000 on leaving the country without having to produce documents or personal identification.

  • Israeli residents living abroad were permitted to open bank accounts there regardless of the length of stay.

  • Israeli residents was permitted to freely engage in selling foreign securities short, while a foreign resident was permitted to sell Israeli securities short.

  • All time limits regarding payments for imports and submittance of receipts for exports were abolished.

5. Finally, on May 14, 1998, all activities and transactions in foreign currency and between Israeli residents and nonresidents were permitted (instead of the previous negative list). Following this declaration, the sheqel is now fully convertible. Individuals are allowed to invest freely abroad (including in real estate and land), to manage bank accounts abroad, to hold, make payments, or receive foreign exchange, to undertake any kind of unilateral transfer, and to make transactions directly with foreign financial intermediaries as well as authorized domestic dealers (there is an obligation by these parties to report on the nature of the transaction). The remaining restrictions are on institutional investors and derivatives made with nonresidents, as follows (and the government has committed to remove them over time):

  • A provident fund may not: (i) hold foreign exchange or foreign securities and make forward transactions involving payment or receipts in foreign exchange in an amount of more than 5 percent of the provident fund’s total assets; (ii) hold 5 percent or more of a given security issued by a nonresident corporation; or (iii) buy or hold other kinds of foreign assets.

  • A pension fund or insurance company may not: (i) buy foreign currency and hold it in cash or deposit; (ii) accept foreign currency from another resident; (iii) engage in forward transactions involving payment or receipt of foreign exchange; (iv) buy or hold foreign securities unless issued by the State of Israel or by an Israeli resident company registered for trading on a foreign stock exchange or over the counter; and (v) buy or hold other kinds of foreign assets.

  • A resident may not undertake with a nonresident a derivatives transaction of any kind in which one of the underlying assets is local currency and which involves payment or receipt of foreign currency, unless the transaction is a forward transaction at a pre–set price for a period of no more than 30 days.

6. In addition to the above, various other changes were implemented during 1998 and the beginning of 1999:

  • On June 22, 1998, in accordance with the regulations of the Ministry of Finance, the definition of a nonresident was extended to include: residents of the Palestinian Autonomy who are not Israeli residents; diplomats; UN personnel; foreign air crews; and diplomatic and consular representatives of foreign countries.

  • As of October 1, 1998, insurers were permitted to purchase foreign currency to hold in cash or in a bank account in Israel (not a bank account abroad), and to receive foreign currency from an Israeli resident.

  • On November 10, 1998, the Currency Control Law was amended, so that the authority of the Controller of Foreign Exchange to require reports as a condition of granting permits was stated specifically in the Law. The purpose was to ensure the proper flow of information that would enable the Bank of Israel to respond promptly to exceptional capital flows. The Law also included an article to ensure the preservation of secrecy regarding information received as a result of the Law.

  • Until November 9, 1998, an Israeli resident was defined as someone who was not a nonresident. As of November 10, 1998, a resident was defined as someone satisfying one of a list of specific alternatives, and a nonresident was defined as someone who is not a resident. The change also determined that an Israeli citizen permanently residing abroad is a nonresident.

  • On January 1, 1999, the requirements regarding reporting on transactions with residents of the Palestinian Autonomy were changed. As a result, banks are required to classify local- and foreign-currency accounts of residents of the Autonomy as a separate group, and report transactions between Israeli residents and residents of the Autonomy—in local and in foreign currency—along the same principles that apply to reporting of transactions with nonresidents.

  • On April 15, 1999, the list of those obliged to report to the Controller of Foreign Exchange was extended to include individuals and non-profit organizations, in addition to companies.

Table 1.

Israel: GDP by Expenditure Components in Current Prices, 1994–99

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; and 1998 Statistical Abstract of Israel.

Estimate by the Central Bureau of Statistics.

Table 2.

Israel: GDP by Expenditure Components in Constant Prices, 1994-99 1/

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; and 1998 Statistical Abstract of Israel.

Estimates in 1995 prices derived by chaining each categories growth rate computed at different base year prices; hence totals do not reflect the sum of their components.

Estimate of the Central Bureau of Statistics.

Table 3.

Israel: Investment, 1994–99

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistic; and 1998 Statistical Abstract of Israel.

Estimate of the Central Bureau of Statistics.

Table 4.

Israel: Consumption, 1994–99

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; and 1998 Statistical Abstract of Israel.

Estimate of the Central Burean of Statistics.

Table 5.

Israel: Gross Private Income and Savings, 1994–99

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Current Briefings in Statistics; and data provided by the Bank of Israel.

Estimate of the Central Bureau of Statistics.

Including contribution to National Insurance Institute.

Table 6.

Israel: National Savings, Foreign Savings, and Investment, 1994–98

article image
Source: Data provided by the Bank of Israel.

Total income defined as GNP plus unilateral transfers from abroad.

Table 7.

Israel: Industrial Production Indices, 1994–99

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; and data provided by the Bank of Israel.
Table 8.

Israel: Labor Market Indicators, 1994–99 1/

article image
Sources: Bank of Israel, 1998 Annual Report; Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; and data provided by the Bank of Israel.

Based on 1995 census estimates and on new inflation system.

Semi-annual average of 1999 relative to same period in 1998.

Aged 15 and above.

Includes unreported foreign workers.

Table 9.

Israel: Employment and Labor Input by Industry, 1994–99 1/

article image
Sources: Central Bureau of Statistics, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics; and data provided by the Bank of Israel.

Employment figures are annual averages; labor input figures are weekly averages.

The Central Bureau of Statistics definitions and sample changed in 1994. The rows from 1996 on follow the new classification.

Semi-annual average of 1999 relative to same period in 1998.

Israeli employees.

Data do not sum to total due to an “unknown” category.

Table 10.

Israel: Real Wages, Labor Costs, and Productivity, 1994–99

article image
Sources: Bank of Israel, 1998 Annual Report; and data provided by the Bank of Israel.

Monthly average January to August of 1999 relative to same period in 1998.

Real wages in the public sector and real consumption wages in the business sector are deflated by the consumer price index.

Business sector net domestic product per man-hour estimated from the expenditure side.

Ratio of labor cost per man-hour to labor productivity.

Table 11.

Israel: Real Wage Indices, 1994–99 1/

article image
Source: Data provided by the Bank of Israel.

Average monthly wage per employee post at constant prices, based on employers’ contributions to the National Insurance Institute, deflated by the consumer price index. Data from 1994 are based on a new sample and a new definition of “public services;” data from earlier years were connected via linking indices.

Montly average January to August 1999; seasonally adjusted data.

Table 12.

Israel: Consumer Price Index and its Main Components, 1994-99

(Percentage change, unless indicated otherwise, as of November 1999)

article image
Source: Central Bureau of Statistics data, as prepared and compiled by the Bank of Israel.

In tables from previous years this component was calculated as “General Index excluding fruits and vegetables”.

Table 13.

Israel: Selected Price Indices, 1994-99

(Percent increase during the period, at annual rates, as of November 1999)

article image
Source: Central Bureau of Statistics data, as prepared and compiled by the Bank of Israel.

The weights of the components in the Consumer Price Index were changed in 1999.

The weights of the Controlled and Uncontrolled price indices and of the Tradable and Non-tradable product indices add up to 966.0. The difference represents health tax (as of 1995) which necessitated the exclusion of Sick Fund services from the CPI.

Public transport, communication services, education, medical services, municiple taxes, electricity, fuel, water, and meat.

Table 14.

Israel: Regulated Prices in the Consumer Price Index, 1998-99

(as of November 1999)

article image
Source: Data provided by the Bank of Israel.

The composition and weights of the regulated prices in the Consumer Price Index were changed in 1999.