This Background Paper examines sources of net international reserve inflows for Poland. It shows that once estimate of unrecorded border trade is included, both the current and capital accounts are in surplus. The paper illustrates the methods through which estimates of unrecorded trade can be obtained. It offers a complementary view of Poland’s inflation problem from a medium-term perspective. Specifically, the paper shows that relative price adjustment, combined with indexation and inertia, has been part and parcel of Polish inflation.

Abstract

This Background Paper examines sources of net international reserve inflows for Poland. It shows that once estimate of unrecorded border trade is included, both the current and capital accounts are in surplus. The paper illustrates the methods through which estimates of unrecorded trade can be obtained. It offers a complementary view of Poland’s inflation problem from a medium-term perspective. Specifically, the paper shows that relative price adjustment, combined with indexation and inertia, has been part and parcel of Polish inflation.

II. Moderate Inflation in Poland: A Real Sector Story

1. Introduction

Inflation in Poland has proven resilient. Since stabilizing the economy in 1991-1992, policymakers have been unable to tame inflation and to bring it back to single-digit levels. Hyperinflation was overcome, but since then inflation has seemingly become stuck at moderate levels. Of particular interest is the fact that a marked slowdown of the currency depreciation, which began in 1994, appears to have contributed little, at least until recently.

Why is that? In a sense, this is the same question asked by Dornbusch and Fischer (1993). Why is it that the switch from moderate to low inflation is almost always slow or costly?

A first answer is that Poland was not willing to bear the high cost of this adjustment. Just over three years ago, when still in academia, Finance Minister Kolodko expressed this view succinctly: “It seems that curbing the inflation rate to about 2 percent monthly (i.e., 27 percent yearly), while keeping up the trend to form market-clearing prices, is sufficient at this phase of inflation fighting. Because otherwise, e.g., if a goal of the order of 1 percent monthly is laid down, the policy must be much more restrictive, thus sustaining the recessionary trends in the real economy sphere and threatening it with further destruction” (Kolodko et al. (1992)).

This assessment raises the issue of why the cost of reducing inflation in terms of lost output (the “sacrifice ratio”) is unusually high when inflation is moderate.

The general thrust of the analysis of this chapter is that persistent inflation is both caused by and reflects imbalances in the real economy. The main arguments are as follows:

First, a salient feature of Polish inflation is that it has been accompanied by marked changes in relative prices. In particular, utility and rental price inflation has vastly exceeded overall CPI inflation. The explanation for this is fairly intuitive: to improve profitability, these sectors, and loss-making firms in general, need to change their relative prices if they are to remain in business. In addition, prices in many sectors are still in the process of converging toward international levels.

Second, in a well-indexed economy, the effects of frequent sectoral price hikes will be magnified. A small wage-price model of the Polish economy shows that after four years the initial inflationary impact of a CPI shock is quadrupled, even if the exchange rate remains constant. In a sense, this validates Kolodko’s assertion: to combat inflation, sectoral inflationary pressure combined with high indexation would require very tight monetary policy.

Third, certain underlying structural problems, in particular on the labor market, undermine the efficiency of monetary and fiscal policies. Chief among them is the fact that some loss-making firms do not yet face a hard budget constraint. The threat of job losses gives large established firms political power against the imposition of such constraints. In addition, the sizable debts such firms have already accumulated makes default a powerful threat against banks. In this context, a policy of high real interest rates and exchange rate appreciation would place the brunt of adjustment on Poland’s emerging private sector. In short, tight monetary policy is not a substitute for structural reforms.

2. Sectoral aspects of Polish inflation

Price liberalization was a key element of reform programs in transitional economies. Hence, there was an outburst of inflation at the inception of the transition, also fueled by a monetary overhang. But, as the primary goal of this liberalization was to restore prices as a means for allocating resources in the economy, it is important to analyze how relative prices have evolved.

a. A brief history of inflation in Poland, (1989-1994) 1/

Chart II.1 illustrates the precipitous increase in inflation in Poland in 1989. By October 1989, CPI inflation had reached 55 percent per month and, in 1990, Poland was on the verge of hyperinflation (inflation averaged 585.8 percent). The stabilization program succeeded in bringing inflation down, but was accompanied by an unexpectedly high drop in output (see Ebrill et al. (1994)). That period also witnessed marked changes in the terms of trade and in real wages.

CHART II.1
CHART II.1

POLAND: INDICATORS OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, 1989–95

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

Sources: Polish authorities and staff estimates.

During these chaotic developments on the macroeconomic front, movements in the overall CPI masked considerable divergences in relative prices. Past repressed inflation in the service sector suddenly materialized through a marked increase in relative prices. In particular, the drift in services prices persisted in 1992, even though overall price inflation was tamed (see Chart II.2). By 1993, however, it seemed that the bulk of relative price adjustment between food, services and manufactured goods had already taken place.

CHART II.2
CHART II.2

POLAND: INDICATORS OF REAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, 1989–95

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

Sources: Polish authorities and staff estimates.

Relative price adjustment was, however, not over. At a more disaggregated level, relative price changes remain substantial although less visible. As shown below, between January 1992 and May 1995, the relative cost of water has tripled. Rental prices have also largely exceeded average inflation. Substantial relative price adjustment can therefore take place not only in the atmosphere of hyperinflation and stabilization, but also during moderate inflation spells.

The causation between these relative price changes and inflation remains open to question. On the one hand, at low levels of inflation, even small changes in relative prices may have a large proportionate effect on inflation. On the other hand, annual inflation in the range of, say, 20 percent to 40 percent can also create large relative price shifts if certain prices are sticky.

The remainder of this section fleshes out the argument linking relative prices to inflation. First, it is shown how changes in relative prices might cause inflation. Specifically, following Ball and Mankiw (1995), it is shown that there is a relation between inflation and the skewness of the distribution of sectoral price changes, and that the latter helps explain future price inflation. Second, we use a comparison of international price levels to show that, notwithstanding the dramatic relative price changes associated with the “big bang”, considerable scope remains for further Polish relative price adjustment. To the extent that relative price changes are a cause of inflation, this could fuel more inflation. Finally, the Polish energy sector is considered in some detail, to illustrate the extent of relative price adjustment that may still be needed.

b. Relative price adjustment, asymmetric price adjustment, and inflation in Poland

In recent years, economists have paid renewed attention to relative price adjustments. This interest has been fueled by consistent statistical evidence that these adjustments are asymmetric (prices are more flexible upward than downward) and that relative price adjustments are correlated with the level of inflation. Fischer (1981) stressed, for instance, that U.S. inflation is highly correlated with a higher variance of sectoral price inflation. Similarly, Gerhaeusser (1988) found instantaneous Granger-causation between inflation and relative price volatility in Germany. 1/

The empirical relationship between relative price changes and inflation has until recently been regarded as an analytical puzzle. Indeed, at first glance, there need be no relationship between relative price changes and the overall price level (for example, if money determines the overall level of prices). On this view, relative price increases in certain sectors would be offset by price decreases in other sectors, leaving the overall price level in the hands of monetary policy. Of course, if prices were sticky downward, relative price changes could only occur in an inflationary context. But downward price adjustment is difficult to justify on theoretical grounds (unless adjustment costs were, for some reason, asymmetric). A solution to this puzzle must therefore be based on different grounds.

Such a solution has recently been proposed by Ball and Mankiw (op. cit.) who argue that price stickiness (both upward and downward) arising from “menu costs” can cause higher inflation if the distribution of relative price changes is skewed. 2/ Their argument runs as follows.

In the presence of menu costs, firms will only change their prices if the costs of inaction exceed the menu costs associated with changing prices. Accordingly, small shocks to the economy will have little effect on the price level, since individual firms will be reluctant to change prices. Large shocks will have a disproportionate effect on individual prices--but not necessarily on the aggregate price level: if the distribution of shocks is symmetric, price increases and decreases at the firm level cancel each other out. Thus, contrary to what is sometimes argued, greater variance of shocks need not lead to overall price inflation.

Rather, Ball and Mankiw’s approach can justify a relation between the skewness of price changes and overall inflation. In a skewed distribution, most outliers are on one side of the distribution. Suppose that the distribution of relative price shocks is skewed positive (that is, there is a small number of large positive price increases, offset by a large number of small relative price reductions). Owing to menu costs, the large number of small price reductions does not materialize, while the small number of large price increases will, resulting in an increase in the average price level.

Empirical analysis of price dispersion in Poland for the 1990-1994 period yields the following results.

First, the distribution of price changes is heavily skewed, and not only during the first months of the transition (Charts II.3a and II.3b). On average, once every two months there is some change in price more than two standard deviations away from the mean price increase. This fat-tailed distribution of price changes primarily reflects sizable price increases. It should also be noted that these increases are largely concentrated in particular sectors (e.g., utilities). Thus, there is considerable evidence of relative price adjustment within overall price level changes.

CHART II.3a.
CHART II.3a.

POLAND: MONTHLY PRICE CHANGES

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

CHART II.3b.
CHART II.3b.

POLAND: HISTOGRAM OF MONTHLY PRICE CHANGES

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

Second, inflation (CPI) and skewness (SK) are highly correlated. 1/ This suggests that relative price shocks are closely linked to aggregate inflation. Note, also that the introduction of the asymmetry variable renders lagged inflation not statistically significant.

ΔCPI=0.07(.45)ΔCPI(1)+1.18(6.1)SK0.22(.83)SK(1)+2.2(5.9)(1)R2=.91

However, causation is uncertain. Just as menu costs can explain why relative price increases can cause inflation, they can also explain why trend inflation owing to other causes can lead, in any given period, to a positively skewed distribution of price changes (Ball and Mankiw (1994)). First, in the presence of menu costs and trend inflation, those sectors facing relative price declines can simply avoid paying the menu cost, keep nominal prices unchanged, and allow overall inflation to generate the desired erosion in relative prices. On the other hand, those sectors needing to establish relative price increases must increase prices, over and above the inflation rate. With no change in certain sectors and increases in others, the result is a positively skewed distribution of price changes. Second, menu costs may differ across sectors. Assume that average long-term inflation does not differ between sectors. Sectors with small menu costs will change prices continuously, but those with large menu costs will change prices infrequently--but by large amounts when they do. The result is apparent skewness in the distribution of price changes, without implication for the long term inflation rate.

The question is whether skewness causes inflation, or whether inflation causes skewness. On the first interpretation, skewness--and relative prices--are part of the inflation process; on the latter they are simply an epiphenomenon. If the relative price explanation is correct, one should observe in the same sectors skewed price increases and a lasting improvement in their relative prices. If the second explanation is correct, the skewed price increases should be essentially random, without any lasting effect. To distinguish between these explanations, the change in a sector’s relative price (RCPIi) between December 1989 and June 1995 was regressed against the number of times that sector registered a skewed price increase (NSKi) 1/:

ΔRPIi=.211(5.52)NSKi+0.623(1.40)(2)R2=.50

The regression indicates a strong correlation between a sector’s ability to generate a sustained increase in relative prices, and the number of times its price changes are “outliers”, consistent with the claim that skewness captures genuine relative price changes, and that these relative price changes are linked to Polish inflation.

c. Incomplete convergence toward world prices

While the previous section argued for a link from relative price changes to inflation, for this linkage to have continuing empirical significance it needs to be shown that considerable relative price adjustment has still to take place. Two attempts at this are made. First, it is shown that, in general, prices of Polish goods are lower than their international counterparts. Second, this undervaluation varies enormously for different goods. The implication is that exchange rate adjustment alone would not solve the problem of relative price disparities.

Description of the method Since 1994, Business Eastern Europe (BEE) has collected prices for basic consumer goods and services in various Eastern European countries. 2/ In addition, the Polish statistical bulletin provides a breakdown of Polish households’ average expenditures (Table II.1 below) as well as some information on the volume of consumption of selected foodstuffs.

Table II.1.

Structure of Household Expenditures

(January-March 1994: in percent)

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuletyn Statystyczny.
Table II.2.

Indices of Relative Prices in Visegrad Countries and Slovenia

(In percent, March 1994)

article image
Sources: BEE (1994); and staff calculations.

By combining these sets of data, one can calculate a cost of living index, with weights corresponding to the consumption basket for Polish households. To facilitate comparison, we calculated a relative price index (I), dividing each country’s cost-of-living index by its Austrian equivalent, assumed to be prototypical for a Western European country. Thus, I provides some information on the relative cost of living in Eastern European countries or, under certain conditions, about the possible undervaluation of the exchange rate.

Formally, index I is calculated as: 1/

I=ΣωiPpol,iΣωiPAus,iwithΣωi=1(3)

It is also of interest to measure the extent to which product prices depart from the average cost of living index. This can be done by calculating a (weighted) standard deviation of individual prices, and then dividing by the mean to derive the coefficient of variation. Formally, this weighted coefficient of variation is given by: 1/

S=Σωi(Ppol,iIPAus,i)2ΣωiPpol,i(4)

Results The main findings for the Visegrad group of countries and Slovenia are as follows. First, the cost-of-living index is clearly much lower in these countries than in Austria. However, prices in Slovenia and, to a lesser extent, Hungary come closer to their Austrian counterparts. Not surprisingly, these two countries were also relatively open to international trade during the communist era. In comparison, a recent (and much more detailed) study of Russian prices, De Masi and Koen (1995), found that, in 1994, Russian prices were only a fifth of the level of their French equivalents. Thus, while considerable distance remains, the group of countries surveyed here has made more progress toward Western price levels.

Second, relative prices (captured by index S) fluctuate significantly around the average price level, more than would be predicted if Eastern European prices were a constant fraction of Austrian prices. In a sense, the variation in relative prices gives a better indication of the extent of price liberalization. For Poland, much of this variation reflects the significant undervaluation (in relative terms) of utility prices: subsidized household utility prices have remained an important component of the social safety net. Other prices, and in particular those of manufacturing goods, come closer to world (Austrian) prices. 2/

The low value of index I suggests that considerable currency undervaluation remains. However, currency appreciation would not eliminate the price dispersion and the need for corrective relative price adjustments.

d. The need to adjust relative prices: the case of energy

As a legacy of the communist safety net, certain goods are still highly subsidized in Poland. The comparison with Austrian price levels has underlined that the two single most important areas of subsidies are probably the housing and the energy sectors. This section focuses on the latter. 1/

It would be incorrect to suggest that utility prices have not adjusted since the beginning of the transition. Indeed, as Table II.3 reveals, utility price growth has significantly outpaced CPI growth since 1990. Compared to the average CPI, their relative price has been multiplied by two to fifteen times. It is noteworthy, however, that most of the relative price hike took place before 1992.

Table II.3.

The Relative Price of Polish Utilities 1/

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuletyn Statystyczny, various issues.

Before the transition, energy subsidies in Poland were pervasive and clearly favored over-consumption. As stressed by Meyers et al. (1994a and 1994b), energy-intensive industries in Poland in 1991 reached a share in GDP that, among industrialized countries, only Norway exceeded. These authors estimate that energy use in the steel industry or in household central heating is comparable to that of Western countries in the early 1970s. As a striking example of the role of price distortions, energy subsidies allowed Poland to largely ignore the restructuring implications of the oil shock.

So far, the relative price changes already incurred have caused only minor shifts in consumption patterns. In the long run, one would expect higher energy prices to result in better insulation for houses and in a preference for low-energy appliances. However, such behavioral adjustments take time and, so far, the reduction in household energy consumption has been only minimal. Indeed, between 1989 and 1994, the share of energy in total household expenditure increased sixfold (Table II.4), matching the pattern of relative price increases. Unfortunately, the short observation period makes it difficult to disentangle the respective impact of price and income effects.

Table II.4.

Share of Energy in Total Household Expenditure, 1989-94 1/

(In percentage points)

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuletyn Statystyczny, various issues.

Recent studies, however, suggest that past price increases, substantial as they were, fall short of the required adjustment (See Table II.5). Two different concerns have emerged. First, the cross-subsidization between firms and households is still worrisome. In Western countries, the high cost of energy distribution for households is used to justify lower energy prices for firms. Despite this, in most Eastern European countries, household energy prices are lower than those paid by firms, placing an undue burden on firms.

Table II.5.

Electricity and Natural Gas Pricing in 1994

(Absolute terms, and in percent of estimated LRMC)

article image
Source: Freund and Wallich (1995).

U.S. cents/kWh.

U.S. cents/cubic meter.

Second, it remains to be seen whether current energy prices provide utility companies with adequate rates of return. Standard pricing strategies usually refer to long run marginal cost (LRMC), including current costs of existing investment as well as potential replacement costs. This stands in stark contrast with well-established practices in Eastern European economies where (short-term) average cost pricing is favored. Because the debt levels of utility companies are unusually low by Western standards, low energy prices do not necessarily bring these companies into the red. However, leaving aside the insufficient return on capital, ignoring replacement costs will become a growing impediment as the need for modernizing existing equipment becomes more pressing.

Thus there is evidence that the relative price of utilities is still in need of significant overhaul. According to Freund and Wallich (1995), in 1993 the extent of desirable price adjustment ranged from 60 percent for district heat to 80 percent for gas and 90 percent for electricity.

Implementing such an energy price increase could create profound social tensions. However, since the income elasticity of energy consumption exceeds one, the welfare gains from the current system of energy price subsidies are greater for the rich than for the poor. Overall, the current system is regressive (Freund and Wallich (op. cit.)). To maintain the safety net, while encouraging more efficient energy usage, the one-time increase in energy prices could be accompanied by cash or voucher distribution to compensate households. It is clear that, for the reform to succeed and to be genuinely welfare-improving, considerable attention needs to be paid to the design of such a reform. The point is more that the case of energy prices shows that further relative price adjustment still has to be made in Poland, and that this is likely to have significant implications for inflation.

3. Price adjustment in a well-indexed economy

The previous section documented the role that relative price adjustment has played in the Polish inflation story. This section estimates the extent to which Polish inflation has become increasingly inertial, reflecting the widespread move toward indexation. The two elements, relative price adjustment and inertial inflation, are then put together to consider the likely inflationary consequences of future relative price adjustment.

a. The dynamics of wages, prices, and the exchange rate

To gauge the extent of wage and price indexation, we estimated a standard mark-up model of the Polish economy. Given that the estimation period is restricted to 1991:3-1995:5 1/, simple dynamic specifications were favored. This exercise sheds some light on the nature of the interplay between prices, wages and the exchange rate, as well as of the lags involved.

(i) The structure of the model

For the producer price index (PPI), the following mark-up pricing is assumed:

PPI=(1+μ)(PICIC+WLY)α(5)

Thus, producer prices are a mark-up on unit variable costs, defined as the sum of wage costs (WL) and the costs of intermediate inputs (PIC IC), divided by output (Y).

Output affects prices through at least two distinct channels. First, through the effect on marginal cost. Unless the production function has constant returns to scale, average and marginal productivity differ. For example, with increasing returns to scale and holding factor prices constant, marginal cost will decline as output increases. Second, through the effect on the mark-up. Some authors have argued that, in industrialized economies, price-competition fades somewhat during growth spurts. Therefore, the mark-up μ of prices on costs is a function of capacity utilization, simply proxied here by changes in output.

The impact of the exchange rate (exr) upon producer prices is also twofold. First, it directly affects the cost of imported intermediate inputs. Second, foreign competition may also influence the mark-up of domestic firms: when the currency appreciates, margins shrink in those sectors most exposed to foreign competition.

Overall, a reduced form equivalent of equation (5) can be expressed as

Log(PPI)=a1Log(W)+a2Log(exr)+a3Log(Y)+a4(6)

The CPI equation is largely an accounting identity. Most models simply assume that the CPI is a weighted average of producer price indices and import prices. This CPI equation also incorporates wages. This could be justified on the following grounds. First, consumer goods are often more labor intensive than typical industrial goods. Hence, simply using an aggregate PPI would underestimate the influence of wages. Second, wages also represent an important variable cost for retailers. Thus, for consumer prices, the following equation is assumed:

Log(CPI)=b1Log(PPI)+b2Log(exr)+b3Log(W)+b4(7)

For the labor market, a standard relation between unemployment and real wages is assumed:

Log(Wn)=Log(CPI)c1Log(UR)+c2(8)

where UR represents the unemployment rate, and wages are considered net of tax. 1/

To capture the dynamics associated with high frequency data, these equations were all estimated in an error-correction form. This involves estimating, first, a long-term (“cointegrating”) relation between the various variables and, second, a short-term dynamic equation which determines the speed of adjustment towards the long-term target. Econometric results are reported in Table II.6. 2/

Table II.6.

Poland: Long Run Wage and Price Equations

article image
Notation (all variables in logarithms):
lwnrreal wage (deflated by consumer price index)
lurunemployment rate
lppiproducer price index
lipindustrial production
lcuunit labor costs
lexrexchange rate
lcpiconsumer price index
lwggross wages
article image
Notation:Δ denotes first difference. Error-correction terms ecmw-1, ecmp-1, and ecmc-1, are, respectively, the lagged residuals from the long run wage, producer price, and consumer price equations of the previous table.
(ii) A highly indexed economy

Poland is a well-indexed economy, therefore prone to relatively high inflation. Such findings are not unexpected after a hyperinflation spell (see Commander and Coricelli (1991)). However, certain aspects of the econometric results deserve specific comment.

First, wages are much more indexed than prices. After a consumer price shock, the mean lag of wage adjustment amounts to about two months. Hence, an inflationary shock to the CPI or wages is likely to reduce enterprises’ mark-ups rather than real wages. This result may seem counter-factual since, at the beginning of the transition, average real wages declined strongly. There are various ways to reconcile these two facts. For one, Polish households may have learned from the hyperinflation period how to protect themselves against price changes. Also, in addition to the precipitous decline in productivity, the initial real wage decline was facilitated by centralized negotiations, quite independently from any inflationary surprise. 1/

Second, the producers’ mark-up reacts rapidly to changes in output, and is negatively affected by sudden changes in costs. The first feature may partly explain the PPI’s growth in early 1995 given the brisk pace of output growth. The magnitude of the effect of output on price is, however, surprising. It may have resulted from a shortage of capital in industry during the recent recovery and, subsequently, higher margins accompanying the boost in demand. As expected, exchange rate appreciation compresses producers’ margins. However, such an impact on inflation materializes only with a mean lag of 7-8 months. The pass-through from unit labor cost is somewhat more rapid.

Third, three factors drive CPI inflation: domestic PPI, the exchange rate--as a proxy for the cost of imported goods--and wages. Possible explanations for the strong direct impact of wages on the CPI have already been mentioned. The direct effect of the exchange rate appears to be relatively slow--the mean lag equals three to four months--and weak. A more disaggregated analysis shows that its impact is statistically significant only for manufactured consumption goods, but not for foodstuffs or services.

A casual Inspection of the structure of Polish imports provides an explanation for such findings (Table II.7). Before the transition, imports of consumer goods, as in other Eastern European countries, were constrained to fairly low levels in Poland. Since then, a strong appetite for Western products combined with a more liberal trade policy have boosted consumer goods imports. Their share in total imports has more than doubled since 1988 to reach approximately 20 percent. 1/ As such, since imports and consumption represent respectively, 25 percent and 70 percent of GDP in 1994, an appreciation of the currency by 10 percent mechanically reduces CPI by 0.7 percent. 2/

Table II.7.

The Structure of Polish Imports

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office.

This is in line with our econometric estimates. Overall, the stronger impact of the exchange rate on PPI than on CPI mainly reflects the large share of intermediate inputs in total imports (Table II.7).

It would be utterly misleading, however, to infer from this that the exchange rate is useless in controlling inflation. Indeed, the weak initial impact from the exchange rate on both CPI and PPI is magnified by the high indexation in the economy. To illustrate this point, this model was simulated in two different ways. The first simulation simply consists of a ten percent devaluation. Consumer prices increase by 2.5 percent after one year and by about 6 percent after three years. As shown in the second simulation, the effect could be even stronger if, after the initial shock, the exchange rate were to be depreciated in line with inflation. This would amount to adding to the previous three equations the following one:

ΔLog(exr)=d1ΔLog(CPI)(9)

which represents an accommodating policy reaction function. With this addition to the model and assuming that d¿ equals 0.5, the inflationary effect of the devaluation is severely compounded and exceeds 10 percent.

Finally, the wage-price model was used to gauge the inflationary impact of the energy price adjustment discussed earlier in this chapter. At first glance, if utility prices increase by 60 percent, the immediate impact on CPI would amount to approximately 6 percent, given the share of energy in the consumption basket. This effect would be stronger if one takes into consideration the effects of utility price increases on the prices of other public services (e.g., transportation) and on household rents.

In the well-indexed Polish economy captured in our wage-price model, any such energy price shock would also induce a considerable multiplier effect. As shown in Chart II.4, such a shock would increase the overall level of prices by approximately 20 percent after a four year period. The inflationary impact would be compounded by additional exchange rate depreciation. With a partly accommodating exchange rate rule (d1-0.5), consumer prices would increase by 40 percent after four years. 1/

CHART II.4
CHART II.4

POLAND EFFECT OF A 60 PERCENT ENERGY PRICE INCREASE ON THE POLISH CPI

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

Source: Staff estimates.

This exercise in itself need not imply that inflation should be high if energy prices are liberalized. Indeed, one could argue that a tighter monetary policy would allow to keep overall inflation subdued. What is important, however, is that such an outcome would hinge on a severe price adjustment in other sectors. In the face of nominal price rigidity, changes in relative prices can only be achieved through higher inflation. In this case, the switch from moderate to low inflation would have to be postponed.

4. Monetary policy, delayed restructuring and inflation

Inflation is a monetary phenomenon and there is little doubt that tighter monetary policy would ultimately bring down inflation. The interesting question is how these premises apply in the Polish case. The issues tackled in this section are twofold. First, an attempt is made to gauge whether lax monetary policy has contributed to inflation, or whether monetary policy has accommodated inflationary shocks. Second, the effectiveness of monetary policy is discussed, in the Polish context.

To preview the results, there is statistical evidence linking financial variables, including money supply, to inflation. However, the results are quite sensitive to the sample period, and there is also evidence of reverse causation from inflation to monetary growth, suggesting that monetary policy has often accommodated inflationary shocks. An attempt is also made to model the effects of monetary policy in a dual economy consisting of a market-oriented sector and an inefficient nontraded sector. It is argued that, to succeed in reducing inflation, in such a model, tighter monetary policy must act with disproportionate effect on the restructured traded goods sector--leaving the unreformed sector largely intact. After presenting arguments for and against monetary tightening to reduce inflation in such a second-best world, it is concluded that--at least for the inefficient nontraded sector--both macroeconomic stabilization and structural reform should be part of any desirable strategy aimed at a sustained reduction in inflation.

a. Statistical evidence on money and inflation

Since 1990, inflation and broad money growth have been closely related (Chart II.5). The relationship is clearest for six-month or annual growth rates, where both broad money growth and inflation have declined. The relationship is much less discernible for monthly growth rates. However, even for the six month and annual growth rates, it is difficult to ascertain whether monetary growth leads or lags the inflation rate. Finally, over this period broad money growth has, on average, exceeded measured CPI inflation. The result is a sizable trend increase in real money balances. This remonetization is not surprising given the decline in Poland’s inflation rate.

CHART II.5
CHART II.5

POLAND MONEY GROWTH AND INFLATION June 1991 - September 1995

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

Source: Polish authorities.

Inspecting the data suggests some relationship between money growth and inflation, but cannot pronounce on its statistical significance. Also, it is difficult to judge the direction of causality: is money leading inflation or lagging inflation? To answer these questions, econometric “Granger-causality” tests of the relationship between inflation and money were conducted.

Granger “causality” tests do not test for causality, strictly speaking: they are tests of temporal precedence. More precisely, X is said to Granger-cause Y if past values of X help predict future values of Y, over and above the predictive information contained in past values of Y. This is more a test for predictive content, than for causality. Thus, while such tests may only hint at “true” causality, they may be more useful for finding leading indicators of inflation or output growth.

Ideally, such tests would be employed on long data series, to increase degrees of freedom. But for Poland as a transition economy, there are barely five years of observations. To increase our degrees of freedom, we are forced to use monthly data. However, monthly inflation is extremely volatile, reflecting the effects of one-off shocks (such as changes in administered prices) or seasonal factors. This makes monthly inflation rates difficult to predict. Adding monthly dummy variables should help capture seasonal patterns in so far as they are regular, but will not incorporate the effects of irregular shocks.

One way round this data problem is to test whether money growth helps predict inflation not 1 month, but on average over a 6 or 12-month period. Annual and six-month inflation rates are far less volatile than monthly rates. Their coefficient of variation is far lower than that for monthly inflation (Table II.8). Also, even if inflation is a monetary phenomenon, monetarists would hardly claim that money growth explained every monthly change in prices. Rather, monetarists would claim that the relation holds in the medium term, and is subject to long and variable lags. For Western economies, a time lag of 18 months to 2 years between money growth and inflation would be thought common place. Indeed, predicting inflation only 6 or 12 months ahead might also be too short, save that inflation in transition economies is much higher and, presumably, the frequency of price changes that much greater, and the transmission to inflation that much more rapid.

Table II.8.

Consumer Price Inflation Basic Descriptive Statistics (1990:1 to 1995:9)

article image

Table II.9 presents the results of various causality tests linking money growth to inflation. The table is divided into four sections, concerned with predicting inflation 12, 6, 3 and 1 month ahead, respectively. Each row of the table summarizes the results of a regression of future inflation on a constant and six lags of the first differences of the variables indicated in the first columns. Save for interest rates, all variables are in logarithms, so that the first differences measure growth rates.

Table II.9.

Predictive Content of Brood Honor and Interest Rates in Explaining Inflation, Inelading Six Legs of the Explanatory Variables

article image

The results suggest that broad money has considerable predictive power for future inflation. First, consider a simple autoregression of inflation on lagged monthly inflation rates (Row 1). Lagged monthly inflation explains only around a third of the variance of inflation over the next twelve months; the standard deviation of the forecast error is approximately 7 percentage points. Adding lagged broad money growth improves predictive power (Row 2). F-tests show statistical significance at even the 0.1 percent level, and the doubling of the R-squared and the near-halving of the standard error show that money has considerable explanatory power in economic terms. Results predicting inflation one, three and six months ahead were broadly similar.

However, proponents of alternative theories of inflation might argue that such tests of forecasting power reveal little about underlying economic causality. The arrival of seasonal greetings is usually a good predictor that the holiday season is about to arrive, but in no sense do Christmas cards “cause” Christmas. More moderate critics might accept that monetary growth leads to inflation, but would want to go one step further, and enquire what caused the monetary growth. Specifically, they would argue that monetary growth often accommodated inflationary impulses, such as the attempts of certain sectors to increase their relative prices, or of workers to raise their relative wages, to prevent a possible recession.

To test for this possibility, additional causality tests were conducted, this time from lagged inflation to future money growth. 1/ Except when forecasting money growth one month ahead, lagged inflation proved statistically significant in explaining future broad money growth.

Thus, in general, the results are open to interpretation. There is evidence that financial factors, including monetary growth, are linked to future inflation, consistent with conventional monetary explanations. At the same time, there is evidence linking inflation to future monetary growth, consistent with less orthodox and more structural explanations of inflation, or with a monetary policy reaction function that seeks to offset the output costs of adverse supply shocks. Thus, tighter monetary policy should succeed in lowering inflation, but perhaps at significant cost in terms of lost output.

b. Inflation and monetary policy in a restructuring economy

So far, two potential sources of entrenched inflation in Poland have been isolated: a drift of certain relative prices and some evidence of an accommodating monetary policy. In this section, it is argued that the nature of Polish firms’ restructuring process may be an ultimate underlying cause. Indeed, certain firms have restructured largely through attrition, accompanied by gradual output contraction and accumulated losses. It is argued that, due to this slow restructuring, firms are likely to increase their relative prices or to run deficits. As a result, they are less responsive to traditional macro-policy instruments. Therefore, to the extent that such firms represent a sizable proportion of output, we show that a “hard-currency” strategy to reduce inflation may be unexpectedly costly. 1/

The move to a market economy was accompanied by a relative price shock of unprecedented magnitude. This shock created a fault line between two groups of firms: those which benefitted from it and those for which it proved detrimental. 2/ In the face of this shock, restructuring in the sectors adversely affected can be expected to follow one of three paths:

  • (i) cutting wages to restore profitability;

  • (ii) boosting productivity by shedding labor or, in certain (rare) instances, by investing in new equipment;

  • (ill) a “wait-and-see” approach where firms merely shrink by attrition. In this situation they run losses, and possibly increase their prices.

In a sense (iii) is a slower version of (ii), leading through accumulated losses to a depletion of the firms’ assets.

The “wait-and-see” approach seems to capture certain traits of the restructuring process in some sectors of the Polish economy. Indeed, as argued in Chapter 4 of this background paper, Poland has adjusted employment rather than the structure of its relative (sectoral) wages. Relative wages have remained fairly stable, while employment has plunged most in loss-making sectors. So far, however, labor shedding has fallen short of restoring profits. In other words, for these sectors, the “hard” budget constraint has not been binding enough to force firms into sufficient adjustment.

However, it is important to bear in mind two things. First, this characterization only applies to sectors in need of restructuring and which have delayed it. Privatized or newly created firms have been less prone to procrastination and, in certain cases, have made giant strides toward Western productivity standards. In essence, the transition creates a dual economy. 1/ Second, a pure “wait-and-see” approach is unlikely since no firm is totally immune from restructuring pressure. As we discuss below, firms are better sheltered if they can get additional financing (e.g., from rolling over loans, tax arrears or interenterprise credits). What the above description emphasizes, however, is that the process is relatively slow because managers try to shelter workers from painful wage adjustment or labor shedding. A similar point is made by Berg and Blanchard (1993).

The coal mining sector provides an interesting illustration of this behavior. First, the coal industry has restructured as evidenced by sizable productivity gains (Table II.10). These gains have certainly exceeded what a pure “wait-and-see” approach would have delivered and have significantly contributed to the improvement in the sectors’ profitability. However, despite substantial losses, coal miners have improved their relative wages which still stand strikingly above the average for industry as a whole. In other words, a large fraction of productivity gains have been erased by additional wage costs. These developments have three main implications. First, the price of Polish coal has increased despite a 15 percent decline in international prices between 1991 and 1994. Second, the sectors’ assets have been severely eroded, threatening its long-term viability. Third, the completion of restructuring has been delayed. A recent report issued by the Polish Ministry of Mining now considers that restructuring might take another five years and involve the loss of another 90,000 jobs.

Table II.10.

Restructuring in the Coal Industry, 1991-94 1/

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuletyn Statystyczny, various issues.

How relevant is this example? One may certainly argue that the behavior of the mining industry is an extreme case, reflecting largely the historical and political clout of miners in the Polish society. In a sense, this is precisely the lesson drawn from this example: for whatever reasons, certain sectors have successfully circumvented the “hard-budget” constraint. And, because these sectors represented a substantial fraction of industrial employment before the transition (approximately 12 percent for the coal mining sector), they represent more than a statistical curiosity. Indeed, various studies have documented insiders’ resistance to painful restructuring. Aghion et al. (1994) have modeled how certain groups can impose the status quo to avoid mass layoffs. The companion study (Chapter 4 of the Background Papers) also documents various rigidities in the labor market, and the lack of reaction of relative wages to the financial situation of firms.

The slow adjustment to the new post-transition conditions is also illustrated by the financial results of Polish enterprises. Polish firms have restructured between 1992 and 1994, as evidenced by the recovery in profitability (Table II.11). However, during this period the proportion of loss making firms, as well as their losses as a percentage of total income, has remained sizable. 1/ This is consistent with the view that some firms adjusted by slowly reducing activity rather than by raising profitability. For the economy as a whole, losses have dwindled partly because some firms are profitable again but also because loss-making firms have shrunk.

Table 11.11.

Financial Results of Polish Enterprises, 1989-94

(In percent)

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuletyn Statystyczny, various issues.

As a percentage of total income.

What are the macroeconomic implications of sizable loss-making sectors undergoing only (relatively) slow transformation? To answer that fundamental question, a model is presented where relative price adjustment plays a key role. Such a model is useful--and somewhat unrealistic. However, it at least provides a useful way to synthesize certain stylized facts concerning the transition. 3/ Its main conclusion is that the sector undergoing restructuring will gradually increase its relative prices, as it reduces output and labor hoarding, adding to medium-term inflationary pressures. True, if the slowly restructuring sector faces a high price elasticity of demand, achieving such a relative price increase is unlikely, and the inflationary pressure correspondingly lower. However, in these circumstances, the slowly restructuring sector will make higher losses, for longer. For given money supply growth, the credits that it will require to longer. For given money supply growth, the credits that it will require to stay afloat will unduly crowd out lending to the expanding sector, prolonging the restructuring process. If these credits remain in place, the burden of tighter monetary policy to reduce inflation would then fall disproportionately on the expanding sector.

Starting with the model, it is assumed that the Polish economy comprises two distinct groups of firms, say distressed (sector 1) and profitable (sector 2). 1/ In sector 1, activity dwindles at a pace determined by the rate of attrition of the labor force. This rate of attrition includes an exogenous factor (say, retirement) and an endogenous one, linked to employment growth in sector 2. The intuition between such a linkage is as follows. Growing employment in the emerging sector is the main source of job creation. Therefore, separations from distressed firms are facilitated by an important pool of job creation. Conversely, quits tend to fall during a period of intense job destruction. As a result, during the transition in Poland, job-to-job movements have become increasingly important as a way to avoid unemployment spells (see Coricelli et al. (1994)). Also, for certain occupational groups, intense job creation has led to shortages and, in turn, to higher wages to lure workers away from sector 1. This equation may therefore capture this wage competition between the two sectors.

Consider supply. In sector 1, at any instant, employment is assumed to determine output:

Y1,t=F1(L1,t)withΔL1,t=δL1,tβΔL2,t(10)

Note that this implies that supply in sector 1 is exogenous: it does not respond to wage or price changes. For simplicity, it is assumed that this effect is minor (β=0).

In the profitable second sector, output is given by equating the real wage, w/P2, to the marginal product of labor:

F2´(L2,t)=WP2(11)

It is further assumed that nominal wages are given, so that increased prices of good 2 lower the real product wage, and increase employment and output in sector 2. 1/ In contrast, in sector 1 we assume employment is excessive, so that the real wage always exceeds the marginal product in sector 1. Moreover, it is assumed that labor shedding has only a limited impact upon output. One measure of progress toward restructuring is the extent to which the marginal product of labor and the real wage in sector 1 can be brought closer together. 2/ With fixed nominal wages, progress can only be achieved by reducing employment or by increasing output prices.

The demand side of the model is standard and simply assumes a certain substitution of domestic demand for the two goods depending upon their prices (see Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987)). It is assumed that the output of sector 1 is consumed entirely at home, whereas the output of good 2 is both exported and consumed domestically. The share of domestic consumption of goods 1 and 2 as a proportion of domestic income depends on the relative price of the two goods:

P1C1=g(q)IncomeP2C2=h(q)Incomewhere:(12)q=P2/P1Income=ΣPiYi

g(.) and h(.) are, respectively, increasing and decreasing functions of q: if the relative price of good 2 increases, consumption of good 1 Increases and consumption of good 2 declines. The sim of g(.) and h(.) is constant, and less than unity. Equivalently, households save a constant share of their nominal income. 3/

It is assumed that foreign demand for exports of the profitable firms of sector 2 declines as the ratio of the domestic producer price to the exchange rate increases, 1/

x=x(P¯2e)(13)

To determine equilibrium, we equate supply with demand in the two goods markets: 2/

Y¯1=c1(P+2P1,P2e)(sector1)(14)

and

Y2(P+2)=C2(P2P1P2e)+X2(P2e)(Sector2)(15)

The underlying mechanisms for the impact of prices on output can be summarized briefly. Demand for good 1 increases when the relative price of good 2 increases, by a pure substitution effect; it is reduced by higher prices in sector 2 relative to the exchange rate because exports, and hence household income, diminish (income effect). In sector 2, higher prices of good 2 relative to good 1 reduce domestic consumption, higher prices relative to foreign prices reduce export demand; in addition, the marginal product of labor condition determines total supply. Chart II.6 depicts these two equilibrium loci.

CHART II.6
CHART II.6

POLAND EQUILIBRIUM IN 2 SECTOR MODEL

Citation: IMF Staff Country Reports 1996, 019; 10.5089/9781451831788.002.A002

As time goes by, the exogenously defined labor shedding which takes place in sector 1 leads to lower supply of good 1. Barring any change in households’ demand, producers in this sector will gradually increase their relative price, restoring profitability but at the expense of a lower domestic market share. Conversely, sector 2 is faced with growing demand. Its firms react by increasing their prices slowly, leading to an increase in supply as well as a reduction in exports. 1/

Overall, this set-up does provides a potential explanation for the gradual increase in the relative price of sector 1 during the transition. As sector 1 contracts, supply falls and the relative price of good 1 increases. As sector 2 grows, income increases, raising the demand for and relative price of good 1. This relative price shift is facilitated if the elasticity of substitution between goods 1 and 2 is low.

One may draw the following parallel. Some authors have argued that inflation is required in transitional economies to eliminate the initial monetary overhang. In our set-up, labor hoarding in sector 1 plays a similar role. As labor is dishoarded, output in sector 1 declines, and its relative price increases. However, the size of the relative price increase will depend on the size of the price elasticity of the demand. Whether or not it leads to inflation will depend on the extent of monetary accommodation.

To combat this inflationary pressure, one may envisage letting the currency appreciate. A “hard currency” option will deliver lower domestic prices. The real cost, however, might be substantial: real appreciation combined with imperfectly indexed wages entails lower output growth in sector 2, and subsequently, in the economy as a whole. Moreover, owing to subdued demand, sector 1’s firms have to postpone their relative price increase and their profitability deteriorates. As a corollary, the end of the restructuring--when the marginal product and real wage equate in sector l--is postponed. Obviously, this conclusion is reinforced the larger is β: the greater the spillover from growth in sector 2 to labor attrition in sector 1. However, much depends on the condition of firms in sector 2. If this sector is already at capacity, enjoying the benefits of an undervalued exchange rate and buoyant foreign demand, more pressure may be needed to promote genuine restructuring. In these circumstances, real appreciation would still be appropriate.

As mentioned above, the conclusion that relative prices in the slowly restructuring sector will increase must be Qualified. As presented, the model is well-equipped only to describe the impact of slow restructuring when competition, possibly through foreign imports, is weak. This could well be the case, for instance, in the energy sector, in nontradables or when protection is strong. But there are other possibilities. First, in sectors where the price-elasticity of demand is high or in sectors exposed to foreign competition, a marked relative price increase is not a viable option. Various segments of Polish industry seem to be in this alternative situation (e.g., shipyards, tractors, etc.). Second, certain sectors maybe producing goods that no one wants. In other words, the equilibrium price is zero, and the product real wage infinity. In such a case, there will be no trend increase in relative prices, and there will be no demand spillover from growth in sector 2. Ultimately, there is no alternative to closure. In both of these two possibilities, firms have to seek outside financing to cover their losses. In the next section, it is argued that financing losses in these sectors may render the conduct of monetary policy more difficult, hence indirectly hampering the fight against inflation.

Loss-making firms have mainly relied upon three different sources of external financing: short-term loans, the accumulation of tax arrears and interenterprise credits. A World Bank survey (Belka et al. (1994)) indicated that, in state-owned firms, the payment of taxes and social security obligations had a much higher priority than obligations to banks or other firms. However, these authors also found that severely distressed firms tend to share the burden more equally between creditors; ultimately, they end up accumulating substantial debt against the government. As a result, in addition to additional stress on the fiscal front, the Polish banking industry has many problem loans and a potential crowding out of “good” borrowers has developed.

There is well-documented evidence that poorly performing loans represent a substantial fraction of Polish banks’ assets. Moreover, these loans are highly concentrated in approximately ten percent of Polish firms (Gomulka (1994)). Baer and Gray (1995) offer an interesting account of how Polish banks have handled these nonperforming borrowers. Overall, banks seem to have only limited leverage to push these firms into restructuring. For instance, these authors mention that only 50 percent of nonperforming borrowers in December 1991 had signed conciliation agreements with banks by April 1994, to avoid lengthy legal procedures. An even smaller fraction, 19 percent, had resumed debt service. In fact, banks are unlikely to force companies into bankruptcy, because they come far down in priority as creditors (after employees and social security related liabilities). Therefore, to keep themselves and the distressed sector afloat, banks will tend to roll over past loans. 1/

Therefore, an immediate undesirable outcome of slow restructuring is that it increases the exposure of the banking system to nonperforming loans. 2/ Against this background, how do banks rebalance their portfolios or alter their lending rates? They could obviously charge higher premia to distressed firms. Such a move, however, will be largely cosmetic if the book value of these loans is already low. In fact, banks may pursue a quite different strategy to reduce the risk of their portfolio while increasing their margins. It involves:

• increasing their holdings of government paper to reduce their overall credit-risk exposure; and, 1/

• reducing loans or increasing the premia charged to sector 2 firms.

An additional perverse feature of this behavior is readily apparent. Good enterprises, in particular start-up firms, may be those most penalized. This crowding-out effect, and the ensuing higher interest rates, hamper capital accumulation in the emerging sector.

Other factors may well undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy. One may think that this undue premium cannot be imposed indefinitely upon good borrowers. Indeed, since the premium charged to these firms is not economically justified by the borrowers’ credit risk but instead by the situation of lenders, other sources of financing may become available. The crowding out could be circumvented, in particular, through the formation of new financial intermediaries, by borrowing abroad or through long-term capital inflows. The problem in the banking sector will rematerialize as a capital inflow problem. Of course, this could be offset by a steep appreciation of the currency to make zloty-denominated investments riskier, but such a move would again exacerbate the pressure imposed on restructuring firms.

Against this background, a tight monetary policy or a “hard currency” option may prove “costlier” than in more standard conditions. The underlying cause is that they are both rather indiscriminate instruments. As a result, whatever the transmission channel (competitiveness-effect or financial crowding out), most of the burden of appreciation is shouldered by the “wrong” sector. Indeed, instead of fostering a more intense restructuring in sector 1 along with a desirable reallocation of resources into sector 2, it simply slows down the emergence of the latter. 2/

How to avoid these costs of tighter monetary policy? Under present circumstances, tighter monetary policy, be it in the form of exchange rate appreciation or reduced money supply growth, cannot be a complete substitute for restructuring. Indeed, if it unduly forces the burden of adjustment onto the emerging private sector, tighter monetary policy, unaccompanied by structural reform, might actually delay the restructuring on which the future growth of the Polish economy will depend. The first-best solution is to extend the discipline of “hard” budget constraints to all sectors of the economy, to promote restructuring and to ensure that the burdens of tighter monetary policy are borne proportionately.

5. Conclusion

This paper offers an alternative explanation of Poland’s persistent inflation, one that perhaps might be usefully applied to other economies in transition: the need for relative price adjustment. Specifically, for the price mechanism to replace central planning as the means of resource allocation, significant relative price adjustment are required. In centrally planned economies, divergences between supply and demand were not eliminated by relative price adjustment. As a result, the structure of prices (and wages) in these economies was vastly different from their Western counterparts. Therefore, relative price changes are pivotal during the move towards a market economy. These changes will affect the allocation of resources and the sectors’ relative size. Profits rise In those sectors whose relative prices increase, and output increases as a result. Where relative prices decrease, output will tend to contract. This is how restructuring takes place.

The paper argues that this process of relative price adjustment has contributed to high inflation. This argument Is not novel, and has been applied to many types of economies. It goes back at least to the 1920s, in the arguments of Graham and Mills, and has been investigated comprehensively by Fischer (op. cit.) after the oil-price shock. Most recently, the relationship has been revisited by Ball and Mankiw (op. cit.), this time as evidence supporting the implications of theories of price adjustment based on menu costs. We think that this argument may be of particular relevance to transition economies.

This paper’s contribution has been to document the role that relative price adjustment has played in Poland, both during hyperinflation, and in the more moderate inflation that followed. Much relative price adjustment has already taken place, and this has been part and parcel of Poland’s inflation process. However, it is also shown that much relative price adjustment still needs to be made, and this will inevitably contribute to inflationary pressure in the future. This initial pressure Is also magnified by high indexation in Poland. Combined with nominal rigidities, relative price adjustment in a relatively small number of sectors can help generate moderate inflation.

Since inflation is a monetary phenomenon, relative price adjustment cannot be the sole explanation of Poland’s persistent inflation. At best it explains why monetary growth has been allowed to increase. This paper is also an attempt to explain the hurdles facing monetary policy, suggesting that tight monetary policy (either through exchange rate appreciation or lower money supply growth) cannot be a substitute for restructuring. Indeed, without active restructuring, the burden of tight monetary policy may be placed on Poland’s emerging private sector. Likewise, appreciating the exchange rate places the burden of adjustment on Poland’s traded goods sector. Tighter monetary policy is most effective when all firms face hard budget constraints.

What are the policy implications? In this paper’s view, the first best strategy for reducing inflation would be to speed up the restructuring process through some combination of tighter monetary policy and active restructuring. Restructuring does not imply the need for centralized industrial policies and strategies: rather, it can be achieved at the micro-level through the imposition of “hard” budget constraints. Inevitably, this restructuring will entail lower relative wages and employment in loss-making sectors.

But reality is unlikely to be as transparent as the economic model of this paper would suggest. In practice, there may be political or resource constraints to adjustment. Almost by necessity, restructuring takes time. In such a second-best world, tighter monetary policy by itself may well prove a useful tool for reducing inflation. In particular, the threat of tighter monetary policy by an independent central bank may allow a better control of public finances and, ultimately, enforce a tighter budget constraint on loss-making firms.

The risk is, however, that tighter monetary policy will become increasingly difficult to enforce. For more than a year, the growth in money supply has been largely unintended, the result of unforeseen increases in international reserves. For monetary policy to remain effective, some appreciation of the currency will become increasingly hard to avoid. This simply illustrates the growing conflict between an export-led strategy and a fight against inflation by monetary means.

Of course, Poland should not abandon its tight financial policies. The challenge facing the authorities is to ensure that those sectors in need of restructuring do bear the brunt of the adjustment. Orthodox monetary policy succeeded in defeating the hydra of hyperinflation. However, at moderate inflation levels, the rise in unemployment makes stabilization less attractive than it once was. Our paper sheds some light on why further progress on the inflation front has been slow, and possibly suggests some avenues for reducing the cost of disinflation in the future.

References

  • Aghion, Philippe, Olivier Jean Blanchard and Robin Burgess, “The Behavior of State Firms in Eastern Europe Pre-Privatization,” European Economic Review, No. 38, pp. 1327-349, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baer, Herbert L. and Cheryl W. Gray, “Debt as a Control Device in Transitional Economies: the Experience of Hungary and Poland”, World Bank Working Paper No. 1480, (1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Lawrence. and N. Gregory Mankiw, “Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic Fluctuations,” The Economic Journal, pp. 247-62, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Lawrence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, “Relative-Price Changes as Aggregate Supply Shocks”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. CX, Issue 1, pp. 247-62, (1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Belka, Marek, Mark Schaffer, Saul Estrin and Inderjit Singh, “Evidence from a Survey of State-Owned, Privatized and Emerging Private Firms,” Paper presented at the workshop on Enterprise Adjustment in Eastern Europe, World Bank, Washington DC, September 1994.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, and Olivier Jean Blanchard, “Stabilization and Transition: Poland, 1990-91”, in The Transition in Eastern Europe, Vol. I, edited by Olivier Jean Blanchard, Kenneth A. Froot and Jeffrey Sachs, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1993.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, “Monopolistic Competition and the Effect of Aggregate Demand,” American Economic Review, Vol. 77(4), pp. 647-66, (1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Richard Layard, “Post-Stabilization in Poland”, M.I.T., mimeo (1993).

  • Bonin, John and Mark Schaffer, “Banks, Firms, Bad Debts and Bankruptcy in Hungary: 1991-1994,” presented at the Workshop on Enterprise Adjustment in Eastern Europe, Washington D.C., (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryan, Michael F., and Stephen G. Cecchetti, “The Seasonality of Consumer Prices,” NBER Working Paper, No. 5173, (1995).

  • Business in Eastern Europe (1994), “East European Consumer Basket,” parts I and II, April 15 and May 2, 1994.

  • Commander, Simon, and Fabrizio Coricelli, “Price-Wage Dynamics and the Transmission of Inflation in Socialist Economies”, World Bank Working Paper, No. 613, (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coricelli, Fabrizio, Krzysztof Hagemejer, and Krzysztof Rybinski, “Poland,” in Unemployment, Restructuring and the Liter Market in Eastern Europe and Russia, edited by Simon Commander and Fabrizio Coricelli, The World Bank, Washington D.C., 1994.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Masi, Paula and Vincent Koen, “Relative Price Convergence in Russia,” IMF Working Paper No. 95/54, (1995).

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger and Stanley Fischer, “Moderate Inflation,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 1-44 (1993).

  • Ebrill, Liam P., Ajai Chopra, Charalambos Christofides, Paul Mylonas, Inci Otker, and Gerd Schwartz, Poland: The Path to a Market Economy, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 113, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, “Relative Shocks, Relative Price Variability and Inflation”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1981:2), pp. 381-431.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freund, Caroline L. and Christine Wallich, “Raising Household Energy Prices in Poland: Who Gains? Who Loses?,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1495, The World Bank, (1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gacs, Janos, “Trade policy in the Czech and Slovak Republics, Hungary and Poland in 1989-1993. A Comparison,” Studies & Analyses No. 11, Center for Economic and Social Research, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerhaeusser, Klaus, “Price Dispersion and Inflation: A Test of Causality,” Applied Economics, Vol. 20, pp. 701-09, (1988).

  • Gomulka, Stanislaw, “The Financial Situation of Enterprises and its Impact on Monetary and Fiscal Policies, Poland 1992-1993,” Economics of Transition, Vol. 2(2) pp. 189-208, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kolodko, Grzegorz W., Danuta Gotz-Kozierkiewicz and Elzbieta Skrzeszewska-Paczek, Hyperinflation and Stabilization in Post Socialist Economies. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, (1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lach, Saul, and Daniel Tsiddon, “The Behavior of Prices and Inflation: An Empirical Analysis of Disaggregated Price Data,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No. 2, pp. 349-89, (1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meyers, Stephen, Jurgen Salay and Lee Schipper, “Energy Use in a Transitional Economy: The Case of Poland,” Energy Policy, Vol. 22(8), pp. 699-713 (1994a).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meyers, Stephen, Lee Schipper and Jurgen Salay, “Energy use in Poland, an International Comparison,” Energy Policy, Vol. 19(6), pp. 601-17, (1994b).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • National Bank of Poland, “Sources of Inflationary Threats,” Mimeo, (1995).

  • Reinsdorf, Marshall, “New Evidence on the Relation between Inflation and Price Dispersion,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 3, pp. 720-31, (1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rotemberg, Julio, “The New Keynesian Microfoundations,” MBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 69-104, (1987).

  • Schaffer, Mark, “The Enterprise Sector and Emergence of Polish Fiscal Crisis, 1990-91,” World Bank Working Paper No. 1195, (1993).

Appendix II.1. Definition of a Skewness Indicator 1/

The definition of an asymmetry indicator amounts to defining a cut-off point above which price increases are deemed unusually large. Any choice is subjective but some sensitivity analysis show that the econometric results are fairly robust to definitional changes. Ball and Mankiw (1995) simply calculate the weighted sum of industry inflation rate minus total inflation for sectors where inflation exceeds the cut-off point.

We have applied the same method to monthly CPI inflation in Poland. The CSO data provide a breakdown of CPI into 35 components. Information on weights, however, is scant with only one weigh available for each year.

Given the monthly frequency as well as the hyperinflation spell, two minor modifications were required:

a. We used monthly dummies to cancel out (partly) the seasonal component in sectoral prices. The seasonality adjustment is important since seasonality is much stronger at a disaggregated level than for the overall index (see Bryan and Cecchetti (1995));

b. The cutoff point is itself a function of CPI inflation. Our method can be described as follows. We define two groups. For each of these groups, one can calculate the inflation standard deviation. By construction, in the first group, all price changes are within two standard deviations. The second group includes all the outliers. The groups are defined iteratively. For a given group, we calculate the standard deviation and eliminate the most significant outlier, i.e., with the largest distance to the mean. Initially, the first group corresponds to all sectors. One can easily check that this procedure is convergent.

Appendix II.2. The Changing Causes of Polish Inflation

Blanchard and Layard (1992) used a similar framework to analyze the causes of inflation. In essence, their approach can be summarized as follows. Using our notation, their model can be written as:

ΔCPI=ΔPPI+CPIΔW=αΔCPI+W(16)ΔPPI=ΔW+PPI

with E(εi) = 0, i=W, CPI, PPI

Blanchard and Layard used this system of equations to determine the relative importance of wage, PPI and CPI shocks (εW, εPPI, and εCPI respectively) in the behavior of consumer price inflation. To do this, they used simple accounting to calculate each equation’s residual, month by month. They then calculated the impact of each of these residuals on CPI inflation. For example, if εCPI, t is the residual for the CPI equation at time t, its inflationary impact is (1+α) times εCPI, t, because of the feedback onto wages, costs and PPI.

We too wish to understand the relative importance of wage, producer price and consumer price shocks in the determination of consumer price inflation. Blanchard and Layard’s method works for a simple system of simultaneous equations, where all of the interactions are contemporaneous. However, our estimated wage-price system includes more complicated dynamics. In our system, a shock to wages may have little immediate impact on consumer prices, but may have considerable impact later as its effects propagate through increased labor costs and producer prices.

To adapt their method, we first took the residuals from the econometric estimates of each of the dynamic wage and price equations. We then simulated the model four times: (i) a baseline simulation between January 91 and May 95, (ii) a simulation where the residuals of the wage equation were added over the same period, (iii) a simulation adding the residuals for the PPI as well as the wage equation, and (iv) a simulation adding the residuals for all three equations. To interpret the results, differences in CPI between simulation (iii) and (iv), for example, can be ascribed to random shocks on the CPI equation. 1/ Finally, as a useful check, the results of the final simulation match exactly the historical values for wages and prices.

The main results are presented in Figure 4, and can be interpreted as follows. The single most important conclusion is that, for the period as a whole, these residuals have fairly limited explanatory power. One may note, however, that, in 1992 and 1993, the cumulative effect of wage residuals on the CPI was on average quite negative, and therefore exerted considerable disinflationary pressure. The following years witnessed a stark reversal of that tendency. In 1994 alone, according to our simulations, wage shocks added almost 4 percentage points to CPI inflation. This worrying development was offset by a favorable trend on the CPI side.

It is also interesting to note that, over the last four years, producer price shocks have had only minimal influence on inflation. In other words, fluctuations in producer margins are reasonably well explained by changes in production costs. This is consistent with Blanchard and Layards’ findings and suggests that mark-ups in the industry have not drifted too much because of, say, a lack of competition.

1/

A more detailed analysis can be found in National Bank of Poland (1995).

1/

See also Lach and Tsiddon (1992) for similar results during the Israeli hyperinflation. A discordant note, however, and a case for a negative correlation between price dispersion and inflation, can be found in Reinsdorf (1994).

2/

“Menu-costs” here are shorthand for all of the costs associated with changing prices, from the physical costs of reprinting menus, to the costs of lost sales from reduced customer satisfaction. See Rotemberg (1987).

1/

SK is, for a given month, the skewness of the distribution of price changes for 34 goods (included in the basket which defines the CPI) (see Appendix II.1 for details). For the sake of brevity, seasonal dummies are not reported. As in most econometric equations in this chapter, t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

1/

A regression over the June 1991-1995 period leads to similar results.

2/

The basket, which includes 61 items, is in itself a useful source of information. It should be noted, however, that little is known about the sampling procedures and that prices are collected only in capital cities.

1/

Ppol, i and PAus, i represent the price of good i in Poland and Austria, converted to a common currency; wi is the weight of good i in Polish household expenditure.

1/

The numerator measures the sum of the squares of the deviations of Polish sectoral prices from the levels that would prevail if Polish sectoral prices were a constant proportion I of Austrian prices. Alternatively, it represents the sum of squares of the residuals from a regression of Polish prices on Austrian prices, omitting any intercept and forcing the regression line through the origin. Thus, if all Polish prices were a constant proportion of Austrian prices, the numerator would be zero: the standard deviation of Polish prices would be a scaled-up version of Austrian prices. Finally, to scale the measure of relative price dispersion, we divide by the average level of Polish prices.

2/

This concentration of differences in a few of the service sectors suggests that productivity differentials are not the main explanation of the different relative price structures.

1/

Subsidies in the housing sector also have far reaching implications. In particular, to retain their subsidized housing, households are often reluctant to move to other regions, if they then have to pay market rents. As a result, unemployment rates vary widely between regions and geographical mismatches are high. However, these important issues are beyond the scope of the present study.

1/

Ratio of sectoral price index to CPI (in percent).

1/

Hot water, central heating, electricity and gas for employees’ households.

1/

It is usually accepted that, before the transition, inflation was artificially repressed in Poland--as evidenced by rationing and the significant role of the parallel (black) market. Thus, it would not make sense to use data prior to 1990. Similarly, the hyperinflation spell was also accompanied by significant behavioral changes, that may not have persisted into more recent years.

1/

In the simulations that follow, the tax wedge is held constant.

2/

The short sample prohibits any serious attempt to test for cointegration. It also makes our estimates fragile. By the same token, the short period did not allow the inclusion of long-term correcting mechanisms in certain equations (e.g., productivity in the wage equation).

1/

Growing unemployment is the usual explanation offered for the real wage decline in Poland. However, it is interesting to note that the tax ratio on wages implicit in our calculations is highly correlated with unemployment, perhaps suggesting an alternative interpretation. As unemployment crept up, the financing of existing government spending (including social outlays) required higher taxes and social security contributions. Either willingly or because of myopic wage negotiation, wage earners have borne part of the resulting burden. Hence, the negative correlation between unemployment and net wages.

1/

See Gacs (1994) for a description. Note also that this increasing trend makes our econometric estimates potentially unstable. A time-varying coefficient, however, is a luxury our small sample does not allow.

2/

Assuming that importers do not alter their margins.

1/

Moreover, by ignoring the indirect effects of energy price increases on production costs, these estimates probably err on the low side. However, to some extent this effect should be mitigated by more efficient use of energy.

1/

To save space, the results are unreported, but are available on request.

1/

The simple model presented in this section supports these conclusions but, of course, there are many alternative models. The most difficult question is to what extent the model in the text provides a relevant description of the Polish economy. The lack of microeconomic data concerning how firms restructure makes this question particularly difficult to answer.

2/

The price shock may happen under different guises, e.g., a slash in governmental subsidies.

1/

Because of this dual nature of transitional economies, average data (e.g., on wage costs or productivity) can be misleading.

1/

Definitions: “Employment” is the change in average employment over the year. The coverage of the series changes in 1992. “Relative wage” is the ratio of gross wages in the “Coal” sector to average gross wages in industry. “Relative price index” represents the change in the relative price of sold production. “Profitability” is the ratio of net losses to total income. “Asset/liabilities” is the ratio of short assets to short term liabilities.

1/

As shown by Schaffer (1993), data on profitability between 1989 and 1991 are considerably affected by the changes in inflation. Indeed, Polish accounting methods based upon historical costs generate lower profits when inflation recedes. The 1991-1994 period is less exposed to this bias.

2/

In percent of total income.

3/

By the same token, by delineating which factors impinge upon inflation, it could suggest certain avenues for empirical research. This could in turn strengthen the relevance of the model.

1/

As discussed later, this is a drastic simplification. By assumption, we assert that the pace of restructuring in sector 1 is exogenous, impervious to the impact of financial or exchange rate policy. We also neglect the possibility that there is really a continuum of sectors, with all firms having the possibility of graduating from unreformed to fully restructured, perhaps encouraged in this process by tighter financial policy. These important topics await further research.

1/

Given the econometric findings on wage indexation, this assumption may seem counter-intuitive. In fact, this assumption simply captures the fact that when the exchange rate depreciates, wages and CPI are less affected than producer prices. Hence, there is a reduction in wage cost.

2/

Although this takes the level of capital stock as given when, in reality, we would expect significant reallocation of capital as part of the transition. We would also need to ensure that the marginal product of capital equalled the real rate of interest. However, the real wage condition is at least a first attempt to measure the degree of successful restructuring in the short run.

3/

One could derive such demand functions from a nested Cobb-Douglas cum CES utility function.

1/

The exchange rate (e) is defined as the domestic price of foreign currency; an increase in e represents a depreciation. Implicitly, we are holding the foreign price of good 2 constant, or using it as numeraire.

2/

The labor market does not clear because of excess labor supply combined with wage rigidity.

1/

The supply-side effect is possibly magnified by exogenous productivity gains in sector 2. If these gains materialize--and, it seems they do currently in Poland--one may observe in fact a growth in exports. Productivity gains in sector 2 must be sizable enough to generate growth in sector 2 and offset the contractionary impact of labor shedding in sector 1.

1/

A similar point is made for Hungary by Bonin and Schaffer (1994).

2/

An alternative solution for these distressed firms is to obtain additional nonbank financing, most frequently through tax or social security contributions arrears or interenterprise credits. To the extent these means are available, “hard” budget constraints are more difficult to enforce.

1/

The percentage of government and NBP securities amounted to 13 percent of the commercial banks’ balance sheet in December 1991 and more than 20 percent in May 1995.

2/

Again, this conclusion needs to be qualified if the export sector is already growing too rapidly and reaching capacity constraints, when tighter policy would be helpful. Also, it reflects our assertion that the sheltered sector 1 can wholly resist the effects of tighter economic policy, which may not be true in practice.

1/

Skewness is defined as the square root of the (centered) third-order moment, divided by the standard deviation.

1/

This is not completely correct since the residuals in the various equations could be correlated, making it problematic to identify these with the “true” underlying shocks. Since we are only trying to gain general insights concerning the wage and price dynamics, we did not correct for this; in practice, the correlations between the residuals turned out to be quite small.

Republic of Poland: Background Paper
Author: International Monetary Fund