The HIPC Initiative and China’s Emergence as a Lender – post hoc or propter hoc?
Author:
Tito Cordella
Search for other papers by Tito Cordella in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Maia Cufre
Search for other papers by Maia Cufre in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Andrea F Presbitero
Search for other papers by Andrea F Presbitero in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4622-941X

Twenty years after the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) debt relief initiative, debt levels in low-income countries are rising again, renewing sustainability concerns. The prevailing view suggests that China and other emerging lenders exploited the HIPC initiative to expand lending. Using a synthetic control method to generate a counterfactual, we find that, contrary to this narrative, China and other emerging lenders reduced net lending after debt relief; only multilateral creditors increased it. Furthermore, we find no support for the claim that debt relief encouraged lending to political allies. Overall, debt relief seems to have had limited influence on subsequent lending patterns.

More galling for other foreign lenders is what they see as China’s free-riding. Some African governments can afford fresh loans from China only because the AfDB, the IMF, and the World Bank recently forgave their sour ones.

The Economist, May 17, 2007

1 Introduction

Developing countries’ indebtedness increased significantly in the last decade. The ratio of external public debt to GDP rose from below 20 percent in the early 2010s to above 30 percent in 2022 (Figure 1, panel A). While the Armageddon the development finance (DF) community has been warning about (UNCTAD, 2019; Atingi-Ego et al., 2021) has not (yet?) materialized, the Covid crisis and the rise in global interest rates have aggravated an already dire situation. Developing countries are experiencing a prolonged period of debt accumulation (Kose et al., 2022) and a sharp increase in debt service, which went back (as a share of government revenue) to levels not seen since the late 1990s before the debt relief provided under the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) and the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiatives (MDRI, Figure 1, panel B).

True, a few short-term measures have been undertaken to create additional fiscal space in the developing world—think, for instance, at the Debt Service Suspension Initiative (DSSI), which contributed to easing financing constraints through additional liquidity provision (Lang et al., 2023), or the liberal use of IMF Rapid Credit Facilities (RCF) and Rapid Financing Instruments (RFI) as opposed to standard arrangements. However, as of September 2024, more than half of DSSI-eligible countries are either in or at high risk of debt distress,1 and developing countries’ advocates are calling on the international community to find solutions.2

To address this daunting task, the DF community developed a novel approach to debt restructuring, reflecting a new landscape where China and other non-traditional donors play an increasingly important role (Horn et al., 2021) (Figure 1, panel C). This new approach, codifed in the G20-based Common Framework, recognizes the need to overcome the Paris Club constructions.3

While the Common Framework is a good starting point, some obstacles may hold back the emergence of a new consensual approach to prevent debt crises. Among these are the blurry line between commercial and official Chinese lending, the balance of powers in the Bretton Woods Institutions, and the perception of international aid as a tool to control natural resources and exert geopolitical in-fuence (Alfaro and Kanczuk, 2022; Gelpern et al., 2022; Cormier, 2023; Ballard-Rosa et al., 2005; Ferry and Zeitz, 2024). Hence, any debt relief initiative can change the relationship between donors and aid recipients and the balance of powers between different donors competing for geopolitical influence.

According to the World Bank Senior Managing Director van Trotsenburg, this happened with the HIPC initiative, which forgave a large share of the poorest countries’ debt in early 2000. At the 2023 World Economic Forum, he claimed that “the countries that were hitherto in debt found new life following the relief they got from the HIPC. The [...] write-offs in the 1990s allowed them to restart their borrowing spree with a temptation to turn to non-traditional creditors as the Paris Club lenders had changed the rules, turned their backs on extensive lending operations, and opted for grants.”4 Bunte (2018) reports similar statements from former French President Sarkozy and German Finance Minister Steinbruck.5

The common wisdom within the DF community is that debt relief was plagued by new creditors taking advantage of debt relief from traditional ones. More precisely, after the HIPC Initiative, Paris Club and multilateral creditors reduced their financial assistance to HIPCs, consistent with the presence of “aid fatigue” (Erixon and Sally, 2006). Because of the new “debt space,” China became interested in lending to such countries. If this story holds, any new debt relief initiative should anticipate the free-rider problems associated with debt dilution (see, among others, Sachs, 1990; Hatchondo et al., 2016). Furthermore, if debt relief ends up being a geopolitical game (Hameiri and Jones, 2024), one should be skeptical about the emergence of consensual solutions.

To understand what one can expect from any new debt relief initiative, we look at the past to answer the following critical question: Has the HIPC/MDRI debt relief led to a change in the volume and the composition of external resources available to developing countries, reducing the share of traditional creditors and increasing that of non-traditional ones?

A first look at the data shows that multilateral creditors reduced their net flows to developing countries around the 1996 HIPC initiative announcement, hovered at about 1 percent of GDP after the MDRI, and started increasing again only in the mid-2010s. By contrast, Chinese net flows were small (around 0.1 percent of the borrower’s GDP) and constant until the MDRI’s announcement in 2005; since then, they accelerated sharply for about a decade, increasing to about 1 percent of GDP (Figure 2, panel A). Does this mean that because of the HIPC initiative IFIs such as the IMF, the World Bank, and other multilateral development banks withdrew from lending to developing countries, and China took their place?

As much as such a narrative sounds compelling, we get a different picture when contrasting the flows directed to HIPCs with those directed to a comparator LIC group. Throughout the paper, our comparator group includes those non-HIPC-eligible countries that qualified for the Debt Service Suspension Initiative (DSSI) launched by the G20 in May 2020 to assist with temporary debt moratoria during the COVID-19 pandemic. When we compare Chinese net flows to HIPC and non-HIPC DSSI-eligible countries, both groups experienced similar trends until 2005. After 2005, the increase in Chinese net flows was twice as large for non-HIPCs than for HIPCs, the opposite of what one would expect from the “free-riding” hypothesis (Figure 2, panel B). Multilateral lending, instead, did not differ much across HIPC and non-HIPCs (Figure 2, panel C). Also, from Figure 2, it is difficult to find evidence of the donors’ fatigue that, according to the common wisdom, should have affected multilateral lending in the aftermath of the HIPC/MDRI.

The evidence presented in Figure 2 is purely descriptive, as it compares two groups of countries that may differ substantially. To address this problem, we use the Synthetic Control (SC) methodology to construct a counterfactual (the synthetic control) for each HIPC (the treated unit), considering a “donor pool” made by countries at a similar level of development (non-HIPC DSSI-eligible). We then compare gross and net inflows to HIPCs before and after debt relief with those to their SCs.

Doing so, we find that while gross flows to HIPCs decline (relative to their SCs)—suggesting a break in defensive lending— net flows after debt relief are resilient and, on average, positive. This average result masks quite a large variation across countries, and it could hide different behaviors across creditors. As a second step, we study the evolution of net inflows coming from specific creditors (multilaterals, Paris Club, China, and other emerging donors, bondholders, and private creditors) and assess whether the HIPC initiative allowed countries to turn to non-traditional creditors. Our main finding is that, contrary to the popular narrative, the HIPC initiative led to increased multilateral (but not traditional bilateral creditors) flows to HIPCs and reduced net flow from China and other emerging lenders.

Thus, our main result points to a lack of free riding from China and an increase in multilateral lending post-HIPC/MDRI. To understand the drivers of the result, we look at whether such behavior could have reflected geopolitical motivations, that is, HIPCs being politically closer to the West and non-HIPCs to China. The data do not support such evidence and hint at the lack of relevance of excessive debt and debt relief as a driver of credit flows. This seems to hold for all creditors, except for multilaterals, whose lending, we argue, may be bounded by their own rules and debt sustainability analyses.

2 The HIPC Initiative and Developing Country Debt: a Brief Review

The concept of debt overhang and the idea that debt write-offs may increase efficiency gained limelight in the 1980s when Sachs (1989) and Krugman (1988) applied Myers (1977) corporate finance insights to sovereign lending showing that a heavy debt burden acts as an implicit tax on the resources generated by the country so that debt relief could boost investment, encourage better policies, and enhance efficiency.

The success of the Brady plan for resolving the 1980s emerging market crisis validated the debt overhang view. Hence, the international community followed a similar approach when faced with the 1990s low-income countries’ (LICs) debt crisis. In 1996, the IMF and World Bank launched the HIPC Initiative to reduce debt burdens to sustainable levels.

To be considered for HIPC debt relief, a country had to meet specific criteria: be eligible to borrow from the World Bank and IMF lending facilities for LICs; face an unsustainable debt burden after the application of traditional debt relief mechanisms; demonstrate a track record of sound policies supported by the IMF and World Bank; and develop a Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP). The Executive Boards of the World Bank and IMF assessed the fulfillment of such criteria, triggering the international community’s commitment to reducing debt to a sustainable level. This stage is called the “decision point” (DP). Once a country reaches it, it obtains interim debt relief.

To receive full debt relief, a country must establish a further track record of good performance under IMF- and World Bank-supported programs, implement key reforms agreed to at DP, and adopt and implement its PRSP for at least one year. A country that meets these criteria reaches its “completion point” (CP), which allows it to receive full debt relief. Of the 39 countries eligible or potentially eligible for HIPC Initiative assistance, 37 have reached their CP and received full debt relief.6

The HIPC initiative and the subsequent MDRI resulted from a robust civil society campaign under the Jubilee 2000 umbrella, including prominent figures like Bono, Muhammad Ali, and the Pope. If, under the HIPC initiative, bilateral and multilateral creditors were expected to provide debt relief in proportion to their exposure, the MDRI called for the cancellation of the entire claims of three multilateral institutions—the IMF, the International Development Association (IDA) of the World Bank, and the African Development Fund—on countries that had either already reached or were expected to reach the completion point.

If the HIPC and MDRI led to a substantial reduction in debt ratios (Ando et al., 2024) and were seen as a success by the Jubilee 2000 campaigners, the academic community had contrasting views on whether debt relief would work for the HIPCs the same way it did for Brady countries. Some observers questioned whether HIPCs’ debt servicing significantly impacted investment and reform incentives, while others were skeptical about the nexus between debt forgiveness and increased private capital flows.

Easterly (2002) notes that countries with high debts and repayment challenges may have higher discount rates and, thus a lower willingness to invest so that debt relief is granted to countries less inclined to make productive investments. Radelet (2005) warns that debt relief may trigger a harmful cycle of lending and forgiving and cautioned against the possibility of non-concessional lenders taking advantage of debt relief and aid hampering debt sustainability.

Arslanalp and Henry (2005) argue that the influence of debt relief on HIPCs is limited because they often lack the infrastructure and institutions needed to attract private foreign investment. Asiedu (2003) shows that only countries with suffciently high discount factors/institutional quality can commit to repayment and attract foreign investment. Although debt relief increases a country’s repayment capacity and eases access to global capital markets, more is needed for HIPCs to secure external financing. Cordella and Missale (2013) show that choosing debt relief (vis-à-vis aid) can offer donors helpful information on the creditworthiness of the aid recipients.

Ferry and Raffnot (2019) provide a comprehensive review of the economic literature on measuring the effect of debt relief and point out the lack of robust empirical evidence due to the “diffculty of identifying the causal effects of these programs.” Among the early studies, Depetris Chauvin and Kraay (2005), Presbitero (2009), and Johansson (2010) find no significant association between debt forgiveness and investment or growth in HIPCs.

While most of the recent literature looks at the effects of debt relief on growth and other development goals (Essers and Cassimon, 2022), it does so without answering the preliminary question of the impact of debt relief on credit flows. The few studies that address the issue directly (Dömeland and Kharas, 2009; Claessens et al., 2009) are too close to the HIPC initiative to catch its longer-term effect. More recently, Ferry et al. (2021) look at the impact of the debt relief initiative on private credit flows and show an increase in private lending in a standard difference-in-difference setting.

Regarding the effects of the changes in the international finance landscape, Chuku et al. (2023) find that “debt vulnerabilities in LICs today remain substantially less alarming than in the mid-1990s” (p. 27). However, the change in debt composition—which has shifted away from traditional Paris Club creditors towards commercial and non-Paris Club creditors—may make it more difficult to take preemptive actions to avoid a new debt crisis. The emergence of China as the leading bilateral donor may have added to the contentiousness of any further debt relief initiative. However, Bunte (2018) find recipients of bilateral debt relief are not more likely to receive credit from non-Western donors. We contribute to this literature exploiting the HIPC initiative for identification and looking at the volumes of net flows after the HIPC initiative across creditor type.

3 Our Empirical Approach

To understand the implication of debt relief on aid flows, we should recognize that several country-specific factors affect the amount of resources a country may receive. In such circumstances, when the number of countries is limited, the traditional regression analysis, including its DiD variants, is not suited to evaluating the effect of an aggregate intervention such as debt relief. To address this kind of problem, where a ‘treatment’ (debt relief in our case) affects only a relatively small number of ‘units’ (countries) Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003) and Abadie et al. (2015) introduce the synthetic control method, which is widely used in the macroeconomic and public finance literature (Campos et al., 2019; Essers and Ide, 2019; Marchesi and Masi, 2020; Lang et al., 2023).

When using SCs to evaluate a policy intervention, the critical decision is selecting the donor pool, used to construct a SC for each treated country with a combination of untreated countries. SCs often match the characteristics of treated countries in the pre-intervention period better than single unaffected countries, thereby providing more appropriate counterfactuals. Compared to the DiD design, the SC method does not give all untreated units the same weight, but it generates a weighted average of the untreated countries in the donor pool (often including zero weights for many units). Then, the outcomes for the SCs are projected into the post-treatment period using the same weights.

In our case, countries unaffected by the policy intervention (debt relief) can be used to provide a synthetic comparison for each affected country. However, to limit the donor pool to a group of countries as homogeneous as possible, we exploit the DSSI launched by the G20 in May 2020 taking DSSI-eligible countries as our main sample and, within that group, the HIPCs as the treated sample and the DSSI-eligible non-HIPCs as the donor pool.

We construct the SCs for each treated HIPC country by looking at net flows over GDP, considering either new flows from all creditors and net flows from specific creditors (multilaterals, Paris Club, China, and other emerging donors, bondholders, and private creditors). Following the notation in Abadie (2021), the treated country is the first unit (c = 1); the donor pool is the set of potential comparisons, c = 2,...,C + 1. Yct is the outcome variable, in our case, net flows over GDP. The synthetic control estimator of τ1t, that is, the treatment effect on the treated country (c = 1) at time t, is then estimated by:

A001lev1sec03

Following Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003) and Abadie et al. (2010), the weights, W=(w2,...,wC+1), are restricted to sum to one and to be nonnegative. They are chosen to minimize:

A001lev1sec03

Minimizing this expression ensures that the synthetic control best resembles the pre-intervention values of the outcome predictors for the treated unit (X1). The matrix X0 = [X2 ...XC+1] collects the values of the predictors for the untreated units. X may include pre-intervention values of the outcome, Y. The positive constants, v1,...,vk, reflect the relative importance of the k predictors X11,...,Xk1 for predicting Y1t (see Abadie, 2021, for details).

We build a synthetic control for 31 (out of 37) countries that participated in HIPC initiative using the entire pool of DSSI-eligible non-HIPCs. The baseline treatment is the official country-specific DP under the HIPC Initiative.7 HIPCs and the donor pool are matched to have similar net debt flows and key macro characteristics in the ten years before the DP.

The primary matching is performed on smoothed (3-year average) overall net flow series (in years -8,-4,-2,-1). Key macro characteristics include current account and external debt to GDP, GDP per capita, and real GDP growth. Our analysis ensures that pre-decision point fts are strong and robust, both to the selection of countries in the donor pool and the macro-characteristics used for matching. We study the post-DP characteristics of net debt flows by comparing HIPCs with their counterparts on a 22-year horizon. Given the volatility of net debt flows, we analyze cumulative post-HIPC trends.

Data on (net and gross) flows by creditors are from the World Bank International Debt Statistics (IDS, December 2022 vintage), complemented with dataon IMF lending from the International Monetary Fund. Gross flows (or disbursements) are drawings by the borrower on loan commitments. Net flows (or net lending or net disbursements) are disbursements minus principal repayments. Both variables refer to public and publicly guaranteed (PPG) long-term external debt, and they do not include grants.8 Additional variables used to construct the SC—real per capita GDP, GDP growth, external debt (% GDP), and the current account balance (% GDP)—are taken from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators and the IMF WEO database.

Finally, we report the weights used to construct the SCs for each HIPC and the Fit Index (Ad-hikari and Alm, 2016)—a goodness-of-ft measure of the constructed counterfactual for each treated country—in Appendix Table A2. This index is computed as the ratio of the pre-treatment normalized root mean squared prediction error (RMSPE) and the variance of net flows over GDP in the pre-treatment period (e.g., the RMSPE of a zero-ft model). The index is close to zero across all countries, suggesting that our SCs perform well in approximating the pre-treatment dynamics of net flows.

4 Main Results

4.1 Net versus Gross Credit Flows

To understand whether the HIPC initiative did change the volume and composition of credit flows creating the space for the entrance of new donors/creditors, we start by looking at net inflows to HIPCs before and after the country-specific DP under the HIPC Initiative, and compare them with those of other DSSI-eligible non-HIPCs.

We want to strengthen the importance of looking at both gross and net flows. Indeed, it is easy to imagine that, after debt relief, gross flows will decrease, as defensive lending—the practice of extending new loans to enable borrowers to meet their debt service obligations and avoid default—will also decrease. However, if donors consider aid and debt relief as substitutes, debt relief may not increase the net flow of resources to eligible countries. After debt relief, a country may indeed not have to repay creditors (or repay them less), but, in return, it may receive smaller flows. Looking at net flows is thus essential to understand whether debt relief provided additional resources to a country or just ended the cycle of defensive lending. Notice that, unlike the emerging markets involved in the Brady initiative, virtually all HIPCs received positive net flow before debt relief (Easterly, 2002; Bird and Milne, 2003). Hence, by itself, debt relief does not imply an increase in the availability of resources.

When we compare gross flows before and after debt relief, we find that, as expected, gross flows decreased dramatically in the aftermath of HIPC debt relief: when we compare HIPCs with their SCs, we see an average reduction in gross lending to HIPCs (vis-à-vis their SCs) of about 1 percent of GDP per year (Figure 3, panel A). The decline in gross flows is common to most HIPCs, being somewhat larger for the median HIPC country and almost twice as large for the HIPC at the 25th percentile of the distribution. This drop likely reflects that debt forgiveness allowed donor countries to stop the practice of defensive lending.

But what happened to net flows? Against the standard narrative, we do not find evidence of donors’ fatigue towards HIPCs. Net flows as a share of recipient countries’ GDP declined during the 2000s; however, when we compare the behavior of net flows between HIPCs with their SCs (Figure 3, panel B), we find that post-DP net flows to HIPCs increased both on average and for the median country. However, there is substantial variation across countries, as shown by the interquartile range, which also goes into negative territory.9 In addition, as this chart pools net flows provided by all creditors, it could still be the case that this average result is consistent with China’s or other creditors’ free riding on HIPC/MDRI debt relief. To tackle this issue, we exploit the granularity of the IDS data to look at the evolution of net flows by creditor type.

4.2 Net Flows by Creditor Type

Let us now turn to our main question: Which creditors contributed the most to such a (relative) increase in new flows to HIPCs? Are China and/or the private lenders those who took advantage of the borrowing space created by debt relief, or are they instead multilateral and Paris Club creditors who followed on their pledge of post-HIPC additional support? From what we know, we are the first to answer such a question by looking at long-time trends with a rigorous identification strategy.

Our analysis—based on the comparison between HIPCs and their SCs around the HIPC DP— shows that multilateral donors followed their pledge to provide additional help (Figure 4, panel a). Still, the same is not true for Paris club donors that, on average, kept the net flow constant (Figure 4, panel b). Against the current common wisdom, China reduced its support for HIPCs post-debt relief compared to non-HIPCs (Figure 4, panel c). This does not mean that China withdrew from those countries; China increased its support, but debt relief negatively impacted its lending volumes.10 The same applies to other non-Paris club bilateral donors’ lending (Figure 4, panel d). Hence, if we aggregate China and other bilateral emerging creditors (mostly Gulf states not part of the Paris Club), we observe a sharp and persistent debt reduction in net flows to HIPCs, which gets close to 10 percent of GDP for the median country 20 years after decision point, and close to 15 percent of GDP on average (Figure 4, panel e).

Surprisingly, we also find that private creditors and bondholders did not take advantage of the new borrowing space created by the HIPC initiative (Figure 4, panel f). This, however, may reflect the non-concessional lending clause in the HIPC debt relief initiative that was imposed exactly to deal “with the free rider problem [which] involves both a collective action issue vis-à-vis creditors, and moral hazard risks vis-à-vis borrowers” (World Bank, 2016).

4.3 Methodological Considerations and Robustness Analysis

The SC method requires two assumptions to hold (Abadie, 2021). First, no anticipation. The variables chosen to construct the SCs should approximate the path of net inflows to HIPCs, but they should not anticipate the provision of debt relief. This means HIPC debt relief should be considered a plausibly exogenous shock concerning the provision of net flows. While this is not the case, we compare net flows from specific creditors, so that the violation of the no anticipation assumption requires that flows from a particular creditor are more likely to predict debt relief than those from others, which is quite unlikely given the extensive HIPC eligibility criteria.

Second, no interference. The treatment should not affect the countries in the donor pool used to estimate the synthetic controls. This implies no spillover effects from HIPC debt relief to non-HIPC DSSI-eligible countries. This assumption will likely hold as HIPC-eligible countries are among the poorest ones and are not systemic, even at the regional level. Moreover, by definition, spillovers within Africa mainly originate from the two largest economies—South Africa and Nigeria (Omoshoro-Jones and Bonga-Bonga, 2022), which were not HIPC-eligible. In addition, the no interference assumption requires no spillovers through the debt relief channel. As HIPC debt relief has no clear-cut effects on growth and investment in recipient countries (Depetris Chauvin and Kraay, 2005; Presbitero, 2009; Johansson, 2010), this bodes against cross-border spillovers due to the HIPC initiative.

We test the validity of our results running an in-space placebo test in which we assign the treatment to 16 DSSI-eligible countries which are not part of the HIPC Initiative. If the relative shift in net flows from emerging to multilateral creditors is the result of a common trend among LICs which is unrelated to debt relief, this falsification test should show results similar to the baseline. Instead, we see that the median and average gaps are very close to zero for the 20-year period post-treatment; while there is some variation across countries in net flows from China, countries are equally split between those with positive and negative gaps, suggesting no evident trends (Appendix Figure A1).

Finally, we test the robustness of our results running: i) a simple version of the SC method where we do not add any macroeconomic variable as additional control and match HIPCs and the donor pool only on lagged values of net flows; and ii) a version of the SC method in which we drop small island states from the donor pool to address the potential concerns that these countries could not be an appropriate counterfactual for HIPCs. The results—reported in Appendix Figures A2 and A3—-align well with our main findings.

5 Discussion

Our main takeaway is that net flows’ response to HIPC debt relief has been highly heterogeneous, with total net flows showing some moderate pickup (on average and for the median country) compared to those to similar non-HIPCs. The main driver of this trend is net flows from multilateral lenders, which increased substantially after the HIPC initiative. By contrast, new flows from China and other non-Paris Club creditors to HIPCs have declined compared to non-HIPCs. This means the IFIs’ exposure to HIPCs has increased relative to China’s and private borrowers’. It also means that, contrary to the current narrative, the HIPC/MDRI did not induce new creditors to “jump in” and “free ride.” If anything, the opposite is likely to be the case. Why did this happen? At the moment, we can only offer educated guesses. The first is that net flows reflect geopolitical considerations. The second is that indebtedness or lack thereof is not a significant pull factor for bilateral developmental assistance.

To discuss the geopolitical educated guess, which received much attention in the recent literature,11 we start with the somehow trivial consideration that HIPCs should have received substantial developmental assistance to qualify for debt relief (otherwise, they would not have accumulated such a debt). And they may have received it because of post-colonial or geopolitical ties that donors find particularly valuable. Once such ties could not be maintained through the debt and defensive lending cycle, new assistance was needed to keep them in the orbits or to attract them into a new orbit. If this is what happened, then one should find that debt relief should have increased geopolitically-motivated lending.

To assess whether this was indeed the case, we look at a measure of geopolitical proximity—the ideal point distance computed by Bailey et al. (2017)—in the five years before the decision point, and split the sample of HIPCs along the median of the ideal point distance from China (when looking at Chinese net flows) and from the US (when looking at net flows from multilaterals). We then define as “geopolitically close countries” to China and multilaterals those above the respective median, and “geopolitically distant countries” those below, and look at whether debt relief led to increased aid flows to geopolitical close countries relative to geopolitical distant ones. Our findings are illustrated in Figure 5, which depicts the gap in net flows between HIPCs and their SCs, as in our main analysis reported in Figure 4, but splitting the sample between countries which are geopolitically close or distant to China and the US. Even from a cursory observation of Figure 5, it is evident that neither Chinese nor multilateral net flows to HIPCs after debt relief are associated with geopolitical proximity. Hence, data seem to reject the geopolitical narrative.

The second, more speculative, educated guess is that indebtedness or lack thereof is not a significant pull factor for bilateral developmental assistance. In other words, bilateral donors may not place much weight on the existing level of debt in deciding where to provide aid/credit. This may happen for two reasons. The first is that net flows are almost usually positive, so aid-recipient countries tend to receive more than they have to repay every single year. The incentive of getting more is thus a strong enough incentive to repay and, when not, donors can use other levers to be repaid and/or to keep recipient countries in their sphere of influence (e.g., military assistance). Second, there is evidence that debt levels are irrelevant in LICs with poor governance (Cordella et al., 2010). If a high level of debt does not curtail investment and growth, then debt relief does not make a country more creditworthy either.

The story is a bit different for multilaterals. The amount they can lend is influenced by the Debt Sustainability Analyses (DSAs) that the World Bank and the IMF started conducting in 2005—when the MDRI was adopted—as part of their joint Debt Sustainability Framework for LICs. Though the DSA does not impose strict limits on the amount multilateral institutions can lend, it does influence lending decisions and the conditions under which funds are disbursed. In particular, debt distress levels affect the mix of grants and loans, with more indebted countries receiving more grants and, thus, a lower volume of net flows for any given level of assistance (Cordella and Ulku, 2007). Furthermore, in multilateral organizations, incentives tend to favor high lending volumes (Ravallion, 2016). Hence, when the HIPC/MDRI created space for increasing lending volumes (net flows), multilateral organizations did not miss such an opportunity and increased their lending independently of any geopolitical consideration. In doing so, they also fulfilled their additionality pledge (IDA, 2006), that is, their commitment to ensuring that the debt relief provided under the MDRI would not reduce the overall level of financial assistance to eligible LICs.

6 Conclusions

Whether reasonable people may disagree on how severe the current developing world debt crisis is, there are no doubts that dealing with it presents new challenges. If agreeing on how to split the burden of debt relief has always been difficult, the current international financial architecture is becoming a daunting challenge because of geopolitical rivalries between the major creditors. If the HPIC/MDRI was negotiated between Washington-based institutions and the Paris Club, any new debt restructuring initiative would have to pass through Beijing, adding a layer of complexity.

Aside from the increasing East/West distrust, traditional donors may be reluctant to forgive part of their debt because they fear that China will free-ride, as it allegedly did in the aftermath of the HIPC/MDRI. But did that happen? Sure, China’s lending to developing countries increased when these initiatives were implemented, but did it grow because of that?

To answer this critical question, one needs to create a credible counterfactual to assess the effect of debt relief on credit flows. This is what we do in this paper, using the SC method, which allows us to compare the credit flows that each country received after the HIPC/MDRI with the ones that it would have received had debt relief not happened. Contrary to the common wisdom, we find no evidence of China’s free riding. Conversely, the debt relief seems to have decreased China’s and other emerging lenders’ net flows.

This does not mean that history will repeat itself and that Western donors should ignore China. Today’s situation is very different from the one in the early 2000s. China’s exposure is much larger, and the world is much more polarized. However, our analysis suggests that net flows, not debt stocks, should matter the most in the aid game. The latter appear quite irrelevant regarding geopolitical competition, and thus, they should not be overemphasized.

Of course, one may disagree with these more speculative considerations, which should not be be the main takeaway from this paper. Our main contribution is a positive one, and it belongs to the realm of (recent) economic history. Indeed, we provide a rigorous framework to assess the impact of the HIPC/MDRI on the composition of credit flows, and we let the reader decide whether there is any lesson from the past that may be relevant to the present and the future.

References

  • ABADIE, A. (2021). Using Synthetic Controls: Feasibility, Data Requirements, and Methodological Aspects. Journal of Economic Literture, 59 (2), 391–425.

  • ABADIE, A., DIAMOND, A. and HAINMUELLER, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of California’s Tobacco control program. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105 (490), 493–505.

  • ABADIE, A., — and — (2015). Comparative Politics and the Synthetic Control Method. American Journal of Political Science, 59 (2), 495–510.

  • ABADIE, A. and GARDEAZABAL, J. (2003). The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country. American Economic Review, 93 (1), 113–132.

  • ADHIKARI, B. and ALM, J. (2016). Evaluating the Economic Effects of Flat Tax Reforms Using Synthetic Control Methods. Southern Economic Journal, 83 (2), 437–463.

  • ALFARO, L. and KANCZUK, F. (2022). Undisclosed debt sustainability. AEA Papers and Proceedings, 112, 521–25.

  • ANDO, S., ASONUMA, T., MISHRA, P. and SOLLACI, A. (2024). Sovereign Debt Restructuring and Reduction in Debt-to-GDP Ratio. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4605287.

  • ARNONE, M. and PRESBITERO, A. F. (2011). Debt Relief Initiatives—Policy Design and Outcomes. London: Routledge.

  • ARSLANALP, S. and HENRY, P. B. (2005). Is Debt Relief Efficient? Journal of Finance, 60 (2), 1017–1051.

  • ASIEDU, E. (2003). Debt relief and institutional reform: a focus on heavily indebted poor countries. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43 (4), 614–626.

  • ATINGI-EGO, M., TIMUNO, S. and MAKUVE, T. (2021). Public Debt Accumulation in SSA: A Looming Debt Crisis. Journal of African Economies, 30 (Supplement 1), i103–i139.

  • BAILEY, M. A., STREZHNEV, A. and VOETEN, E. (2017). Estimating Dynamic State Preferences from United Nations Voting Data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 61 (2), 430–456.

  • BALLARD-ROSA, C., MOSLEY, L. and ROSENDORFF, P. (2005). Paris Club Sovereign Debt Restructuring and the Rise of China. PSFL Working Paper 24–1, Princeton Sovereign Finance Lab.

  • BIRD, G. and MILNE, A. (2003). Debt Relief for Low Income Countries: Is it Effective and Efficient? The World Economy, 26 (1), 43–59.

  • BODE, E. (2024). The motives for Chinese and Western countries’ sovereign lending to Africa. Kiel Working Papers 2269, Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW Kiel).

  • BUNTE, J. B. (2018). Sovereign lending after debt relief. Review of International Political Economy, 25 (3), 317–339.

  • CAMPOS, N. F., CORICELLI, F. and MORETTI, L. (2019). Institutional integration and economic growth in Europe. Journal of Monetary Economics, 103, 88–104.

  • CASSIMON, D., ESSERS, D. and PRESBITERO, A. F. (2024). Debtor (Non-)Participation in Sovereign Debt Relief: A Real Option Approach. The World Bank Economic Review, forthcoming, 1–32.

  • CHUKU, C., SAMAL, P., SAITO, J., HAKURA, M. D. S., D CHAMON, M. M., CERISOLA, M. M. D., CHABERT, G. and ZETTELMEYER, M. J. (2023). Are We Heading for Another Debt Crisis in Low-Income Countries? Debt Vulnerabilities: Today vs the pre-HIPC Era. IMF Working Papers 2023/079, International Monetary Fund.

  • CLAESSENS, S., CASSIMON, D. and VAN CAMPENHOUT, B. (2009). Evidence on Changes in Aid Allocation Criteria. The World Bank Economic Review, 23 (2), 185–208.

  • CORDELLA, T. and MISSALE, A. (2013). To give or to forgive? aid versus debt relief. Journal of International Money and Finance, 37, 504–528.

  • CORDELLA, T. and MISSALE, A., RICCI, L. A. and RUIZ-ARRANZ, M. (2010). Debt Overhang or Debt Irrelevance?. IMF Staff Papers, 57 (1), 1–24.

  • CORDELLA, T. and MISSALE, A. and ULKU, H. (2007). Grants vs. Loans. IMF Staff Papers, 54 (1), 139–162.

  • CORMIER, B. (2023). Chinese or western finance? Transparency, official credit flows, and the international political economy of development. The Review of International Organizations, 18 (2), 297–328.

  • DEPETRIS CHAUVIN, N. and KRAAY, A. (2005). What Has 100 Billion Dollars Worth of Debt Relief Done for Low-Income Countries?, the World Bank, available at: ssrn.com/abstract=818504.

  • DREHER, A., FUCHS, A., PARKS, B., STRANGE, A. M. and TIERNEY, M. J. (2018). Apples and Dragon Fruits: The Determinants of Aid and Other Forms of State Financing from China to Africa. International Studies Quarterly, 62 (1), 182–194.

  • DöMELAND, D. and KHARAS, H. (2009). Debt Relief and Sustainable Financing to Meet the MDGs. In C. A. P. Braga and D. Dömeland (eds.), Debt relief and beyond: Lessons learned and challenges ahead, Washington DC: The World Bank, pp. 117–140.

  • EASTERLY, W. (2002). How Did Heavily Indebted Poor Countries Become Heavily Indebted? Reviewing Two Decades of Debt Relief. World Development, 30 (10), 1677–1696.

  • ERIXON, F. and SALLY, R. (2006). Trade and Aid: Countering New Millennium Collectivism. Australian Economic Review, 39, 69–77.

  • ESSERS, D. and CASSIMON, D. (2022). Towards HIPC 2.0? Lessons from Past Debt Relief Initiatives for Addressing Current Debt Problems. Journal of Globalization and Development, 13 (2), 187–231.

  • — and IDE, S. (2019). The IMF and precautionary lending: An empirical evaluation of the selectivity and effectiveness of the Flexible Credit Line. Journal of International Money and Finance, 92, 25–61.

  • FERRY, L. L. and ZEITZ, A. O. (2024). China, the IMF, and Sovereign Debt Crises. International Studies Quarterly, 68 (3), sqae119.

  • FERRY, M. and RAFFINOT, M. (2019). Curse or Blessing? Has the Impact of Debt Relief Lived up to Expectations? A Review of the Effects of the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiatives for Low-Income Countries. The Journal of Development Studies, 55 (9), 1867–1891.

  • FERRY, M., RAFFINOT, M. and VENET, B. (2021). Does debt relief “irresistibly attract banks as honey attracts bees”? Evidence from low-income countries’ debt relief programs. International Review of Law and Economics, 66, 105978.

  • GELPERN, A., HORN, S., MORRIS, S., PARKS, B. and TREBESCH, C. (2022). How China lends: a rare look into 100 debt contracts with foreign governments. Economic Policy, 38 (114), 345–416.

  • HAMEIRI, S. and JONES, L. (2024). China, international competition and the stalemate in sovereign

  • debt restructuring: beyond geopolitics. International Affairs, 100 (2), 691–710. HATCHONDO, J. C., MARTINEZ, L. and SOSA-PADILLA, C. (2016). Debt dilution and sovereign default risk. Journal of Political Economy, 124 (5), 1383–1422.

  • HORN, S., REINHART, C. M. and TREBESCH, C. (2021). China’s overseas lending. Journal of International Economics, 133, 103539.

  • IDA (2006). Additions to IDA Resources: Financing the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative. The World Bank, available at: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/304381468313733304/Additions-to-IDA-resources-financing-the-Multilateral-Debt-Relief-Initiative.

  • JOHANSSON, P. (2010). Debt Relief, Investment and Growth. World Development, 38 (9), 1204–1216.

  • KOSE, M. A., OHNSORGE, F. and SUGAWARA, N. (2022). A Mountain of Debt: Navigating the Legacy of the Pandemic. Journal of Globalization and Development, 13 (2), 233–268.

  • KRUGMAN, P. (1988). Financing vs. forgiving a debt overhang. Journal of Development Economics, 29 (3), 253–268.

  • LANG, V., MIHALYI, D. and PRESBITERO, A. F. (2023). Borrowing costs after sovereign debt relief. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 15 (2), 331–58.

  • MARCHESI, S. and MASI, T. (2020). Sovereign rating after private and official restructuring. Economics Letters, 192, 109178.

  • MYERS, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5 (2), 147– 175.

  • OMOSHORO-JONES, O. S. and BONGA-BONGA, L. (2022). Intra-regional spillovers from nigeria and south africa to the rest of africa: New evidence from a favar model. The World Economy, 45 (1), 251–275.

  • PRESBITERO, A. F. (2009). Debt-Relief Effectiveness and Institution-Building. Development Policy Review, 27 (5), 529–559.

  • RADELET, S. (2005). Grants for the World’s Poorest: How the World Bank Should Distribute Its Funds. CGD Notes, Center for Global Development.

  • RAVALLION, M. (2016). The world bank: Why it is still needed and why it still disappoints. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30 (1), 77–94.

  • SACHS, J. D. (1989). The debt overhang of developing countries. In G. A. Calvo, R. Findlay, P. Kouri and J. B. de Macedo (eds.), Debt, Stabilization and Development, Oxford: Blackwell.

  • SACHS, J. D. (1990). A strategy for effcient debt reduction. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4 (1), 19–29.

  • UNCTAD (2019). Trade and Development Report 2019—Financing A Global Green New Deal. Geneva: United Nations.

  • WORLD BANK (2016). IDA countries and non-concessional debt: dealing with the free-rider problem in IDA 14 grant-recipient and post-MDRI countries. Report 2006/06/19.

  • WORLD BANK (2019). Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative and Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative (MDRI) : Statistical Update. Available at: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/419661565316083523/Heavily-Indebted-Poor-Countries-HIPC-Initiative-and-Multilateral-Debt-Relief-Initiative-MDRI-Statistical-Update.

Figures

Figure 1:
Figure 1:

The big picture: Rising debt and change in creditor composition

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Panel A plots the median and interquartile range of the public and publicly guaranteed external debt over GDP ratio. Panel B plots the amount of public and publicly guaranteed external debt (in constant 2017 USD) by creditor type. Panel C plots the distribution of the average of the ratio of debt service on public and publicly guaranteed external debt over revenues (winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles) over three periods of time (1995 – 2000; 2010 – 2015; 2020 – 2023) and across the 68 DSSI-eligible countries. Panels A and C are based on a slightly unbalanced sample of 68 DSSI-eligible countries (only three countries—Afghanistan, Kosovo, and Timor-Leste—are not observed for the entire time series of 23 years). The sample for panel B is balanced starting in 2013 and slightly unbalanced earlier.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); World Economic Outlook database (International Monetary Fund); and authors’ calculations.
Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Chinese and multilateral net flows around debt relief initiatives

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Each panel plots the net flows by a specific creditor (China and multilaterals) for the average country, for the whole sample of DSSI-eligible countries (panel A), and separately for HIPC and non-HIPCs (panels B and C). The sample includes all 68 DSSI-eligible countries. Net flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); and authors’ calculations.
Figure 3:
Figure 3:

Gross vs net flows

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Panel A(B) plots the difference between the actual gross (net) flows and those of the respective synthetic control (gap). The synthetic controls are built matching treated countries with those in the donor pool on past net flow and key macro characteristics; see Section 3. The solid line is the median value of the gaps in the sample of HIPCs; the dashed line is the average. The shaded area indicates the interquartile range. The vertical line indicates the country-specific HIPC decision point. Net and gross flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); and authors’ calculations.
Figure 4:
Figure 4:

Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Each panel plot the difference between the actual net flows by a specific creditor and those of the respective synthetic control (gap). The synthetic controls are built matching treated countries with those in the donor pool on past net flow and key macro characteristics, see Section 3. The solid line is the median value of the gaps in the sample of HIPCs; the dashed line is the average. The shaded area indicates the interquartile range. The vertical line indicates the country-specific HIPC decision point. Net flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); and authors’ calculations.
Figure 5:
Figure 5:

Geopolitical Lending

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Each panel plots the difference between the actual net flows by a specific creditor (multilaterals in panel A and China in panel B) and those of the respective synthetic control (gap), separately for geopolitically close and distant countries. Countries geopolitically close (distant) to China and and to multilaterals are those above (below) the median of the Ideal Point Distance from China and the U.S. (computed as average over the five years before the decision point), respectively. The synthetic controls are built matching treated countries with those in the donor pool on past net flow and key macro characteristics, see Section 3. The solid line is the median value of the gaps in the sample of HIPCs; the dashed line is the average. The shaded areas indicate the interquartile range. The vertical line indicates the country-specific HIPC decision point. Net flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); Bailey et al. (2017); and authors’ calculations.

Appendix: Additional Tables and Figures

Table A1:

HIPC and MDRI debt relief: timing and value

article image
Notes: The table reports the list of 36 HIPCs that qualified for HIPC and MDRI debt relief, together with the date of completion and decision points and the amount of debt relief granted, as of September 2019. Countries in italics are not included in our sample because of data availability or the poor ft of our synthetic controls (Nicaragua). DP: decision point; CP: completion point. Figures are in million USD. Source: World Bank (2019).
Table A2:

Synthetic controls

article image
Notes: The table lists the composition of the synthetic control for each HIPC country. The last two columns report the root mean square prediction error (RMSPE) of the outcome variable in the pre-treatment period (before the country-specific decision point) and the Fit Index, i.e., the ratio between the normalized RMSPE and the variance of the outcome variable in the pre-treatment period. The synthetic control estimates refer to those plotted in Figures 3 and 4.
Figure A1:
Figure A1:

Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type: In-space placebo

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Each panel plots the difference between the actual net flows by a specific creditor and those of the respective synthetic control (gap). The in-space placebo considers as treated the 16 DSSI-eligible countries that are not eligible for the HIPC Initiative: Angola, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Cabo Verde, Fiji, Kenya, Lao PDR, Lesotho, Nepal, Nigeria, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Samoa, Solomon Islands, Tonga, and Vanuatu. The synthetic controls are built matching these treated countries with those in the donor pool (i.e. the original donor pool excluding the country which is treated) on past net flow and key macro characteristics, see Section 3. The solid line is the median value of the gaps in the sample; the dashed line is the average. The shaded area indicates the interquartile range. The vertical line corresponds to year 2000, the decision point for most HIPCs. Net flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); and authors’ calculations.
Figure A2:
Figure A2:

Robustness: Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type, dropping macroeconomic controls

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Each panel plots the difference between the actual net flows by a specific creditor and those of the respective synthetic control (gap). The synthetic controls are built matching treated countries with those in the donor pool only on past net flow, see Section 3. The solid line is the median value of the gaps in the sample of HIPCs; the dashed line is the average. The shaded area indicates the interquartile range. The vertical line indicates the country-specific HIPC decision point. Net flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); and authors’ calculations.
Figure A3:
Figure A3:

Robustness: Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type, dropping small island states from the donor pool

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2025, 033; 10.5089/9798229001366.001.A001

Notes: Each panel plots the difference between the actual net flows by a specific creditor and those of the respective synthetic control (gap). The synthetic controls are built matching treated countries with those in the donor pool on past net flow and key macro characteristics, see Section 3. The donor pool excludes small island states. The sample of treated countries is made by 29 HIPCs, as the SCs for Burundi and Guinea-Bissau are not available with this sample. The solid line is the median value of the gaps in the sample of HIPCs; the dashed line is the average. The shaded area indicates the interquartile range. The vertical line indicates the country-specific HIPC decision point. Net flows are 3-year moving averages scaled by the recipient country’s GDP.Sources: International Debt Statistics (The World Bank); World Development Indicators (The World Bank); and authors’ calculations.
1

According to the debt sustainability analysis carried out jointly by the IMF and the World Bank

2

Pope Francis in his June 5, 2024, speech, argued that “To break the debt-financing cycle, it is necessary to create a multinational mechanism, based on solidarity and harmony among peoples.”

3

See the Club De Paris note on the G20 Common Framework and the discussion in Cassimon et al. (2024).

4

This quote is reported in Business Today. The full panel is available at the World Economic Forum website.

5

“During a visit to the Democratic Republic of Congo in 2009, French President Sarkozy stated that it would be unacceptable for China to extend new loans to Congo, which had just received debt relief from France. Similarly, former German Finance Minister Peer Steinbruck argued that Chinese loans undermine Western creditors’ efforts to help developing countries achieve a sustainable level of debt.”(Bunte, 2018, p. 318).

6

See the IMF and World Bank websites and Arnone and Presbitero (2011) for details.

7

The 31 HIPCs in our sample reached their decision point between 2000 and 2010, the majority by December 2000. We drop Afghanistan, Liberia, Mozambique, and São Tomé and Príncipe because of data availability, and Nicaragua because of a poor ft of the synthetic control. Somalia, the 37th country to reach the HIPC decision point, is also excluded as it reached this milestone in March 2020. See Appendix Table A1 for details.

8

Adding grants, which are mostly given by multilateral creditors, should, if anything, strengthen our results.

9

The trend in cumulative flows is positive for the first ten years, but then we witness a partial reversal, stronger for the mean than the median country.

10

We do not look at the drivers of Western and Chinese lending volumes. Bode (2024) finds evidence that China and the West’s motives for lending to African countries differ, with economic interest being a primary driver for China but not for Western countries.

11

See, for instance, Dreher et al. (2018), who find that foreign policy objectives largely influence Chinese official development assistance, and economic interests less concessional financial flows.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
The HIPC Initiative and China’s Emergence as a Lender: post hoc or propter hoc?
Author:
Tito Cordella
,
Maia Cufre
, and
Andrea F Presbitero
  • Figure 1:

    The big picture: Rising debt and change in creditor composition

  • Figure 2:

    Chinese and multilateral net flows around debt relief initiatives

  • Figure 3:

    Gross vs net flows

  • Figure 4:

    Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type

  • Figure 5:

    Geopolitical Lending

  • Figure A1:

    Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type: In-space placebo

  • Figure A2:

    Robustness: Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type, dropping macroeconomic controls

  • Figure A3:

    Robustness: Net flows post HIPC initiative, by creditor type, dropping small island states from the donor pool