Government Spending Effects in a Policy Constrained Environment
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund
  • | 2 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: rmao@iu.edu; syang@imf.org

The theoretical literature generally finds that government spending multipliers are bigger than unity in a low interest rate environment. Using a fully nonlinear New Keynesian model, we show that such big multipliers can decrease when 1) an initial debt-to-GDP ratio is higher, 2) tax burden is higher, 3) debt maturity is longer, and 4) monetary policy is more responsive to inflation. When monetary and fiscal policy regimes can switch, policy uncertainty also reduces spending multipliers. In particular, when higher inflation induces a rising probability to switch to a regime in which monetary policy actively controls inflation and fiscal policy raises future taxes to stabilize government debt, the multipliers can fall much below unity, especially with an initial high debt ratio. Our findings help reconcile the mixed empirical evidence on government spending effects with low interest rates.

Abstract

The theoretical literature generally finds that government spending multipliers are bigger than unity in a low interest rate environment. Using a fully nonlinear New Keynesian model, we show that such big multipliers can decrease when 1) an initial debt-to-GDP ratio is higher, 2) tax burden is higher, 3) debt maturity is longer, and 4) monetary policy is more responsive to inflation. When monetary and fiscal policy regimes can switch, policy uncertainty also reduces spending multipliers. In particular, when higher inflation induces a rising probability to switch to a regime in which monetary policy actively controls inflation and fiscal policy raises future taxes to stabilize government debt, the multipliers can fall much below unity, especially with an initial high debt ratio. Our findings help reconcile the mixed empirical evidence on government spending effects with low interest rates.

1 Introduction

More than a decade after the global financial crisis in 2007–2008, most advanced economies have not returned to their pre-crisis macroeconomic policies. Government debt in advanced economies remains elevated, averaging 105 percent of GDP in 2019, compared to 72 percent in 2007 (International Monetary Fund (2019a)). Meanwhile, monetary policy in most advanced economies has been loose and accommodative. The constrained policy environment is illustrated in Figure 1. Economies like the euro area and Japan are trapped at the effective zero lower bound (ZLB), and the U.S. reversed the course on interest rate normalization as signs of weakness emerged since 2019 (International Monetary Fund (2019b)), and the federal funds rate hit the ZLB again in March 2020 as the coronavirus outbreak has posed a severe risk to the U.S. and the global economy.

Figure 1:
Figure 1:

Constrained policy environment.

The annual policy rates are monthly averages. The policy rate of the European Central Bank is the main refinancing rate of the ECB Key Interest Rates. The policy rate of Japan is the Call Money/Interbank Rate. Public debt is the gross public debt of general governments from the database of the World Economic Outlook (International Monetary Fund (2019a)).

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

With high government debt and low interest rates, should the government pursue expansionary fiscal policy to counteract economic downturns? The theoretical literature (e.g., Kim (2003), Davig and Leeper (2011), and Christiano et al. (2011)) generally predicts that government spending multiplier is much bigger than one when monetary policy does not actively respond to inflation or is at the ZLB. Among the few empirical studies available, the evidence, however, is divided on supporting more expansionary government spending effects with low interest rates. Miyamoto et al. (2018) estimate that in Japan, the impact output multiplier is 0.6 in the normal period (1980Q1–1995Q3) and 1.5 in the ZLB period (1995Q4–2014Q1). Also, Jacobson et al. (2019) estimate that the peak output multipliers of fiscal expansions are 3.6–4.5 during the 1933–1940 recovery period in the U.S. when the gold standard was abandoned. On the other hand, Almunia et al. (2010), Ramey (2011), and Ramey and Zubairy (2018) do not find clear support that government spending multipliers are bigger when interest rates are low.

To reconcile with the mixed empirical evidence, this paper studies the factors that can dampen the expansionary effects of government spending under passive monetary policy. Specifically, we focus on nonlinear government spending effects in policy regime F, in which monetary policy is passive and fiscal policy is active in Leeper’s (1991) terminology. The results are compared to government spending effects in the commonly analyzed regime M—active monetary policy and passive fiscal policy—in the literature (e.g., Forni et al. (2009), Cogan et al. (2010), and Traum and Yang (2015)). Confirming the findings in Leeper et al. (2017) with a linearized model, we also find that higher steady-state distorting labor income taxation and longer debt maturity decrease government spending multipliers in regime F. Using a fully nonlinear solution, we bring new insights on the role of initial government debt levels and policy regime uncertainty in affecting government spending effects in regime F.

We first compare government spending effects under the two fixed regimes: regime F vs. regime M.1 In regime M, the monetary authority stabilizes inflation and the fiscal authority raises taxes. In regime F, by contrast, the fiscal authority does not raise taxes (sufficiently) to debt increases and the monetary authority does not actively respond to inflation. Different from regime M, where government debt is stabilized through fiscal backing (raising taxes as modeled here), government debt in regime F is stabilized mainly through inflation. Consistent with Kim (2003), Davig and Leeper (2011), and Dupor and Li (2015), multipliers in regime F are generally bigger than one and those in regime M. Both the intertemporal substitution effect and wealth effect channels contribute to the very different multipliers. In regime F, weak responses in the nominal interest rate plus rising inflation from more government spending lower the real interest rate, reversing the crowding-out effect in regime M. Moreover, lack of fiscal backing in regime F eliminates the negative wealth effects of government spending that crowds out private demand in regime M.

The very expansionary government spending effects in regime F, however, can diminish by various factors, particularly relevant for advanced economies. The first one is high debt burden. Since government debt is stabilized through inflation, a higher initial debt stock provides a bigger “tax base” for “inflation taxes,” and hence inflation increases by less to stabilize debt. A smaller inflation increase leads to a smaller decline in the real interest rate, weakening the intertemporal substitution effect that crowds in consumption.

Other factors include higher tax burden (modeled by a higher steady-state labor income tax rate), longer average debt maturity, and more responsive monetary policy to inflation. All these factors work through the intertemporal substitution effect channel. Although the government does not increase the tax rate in response to more debt in regime F, part of the additional debt is financed by increased tax revenues because of an enlarged tax base. Thus, with a higher steady-state tax rate, a bigger proportion of a spending increase is financed by taxes, so the debt amount to be inflated away is smaller. As the inflation rate does not increase as much, the intertemporal substitution effect is weakened. Similarly, longer debt maturity implies that the required inflation adjustment can be spread over a longer horizon. When combined with a bigger response of the nominal interest rate to inflation (monetary policy remaining passive), the output multiplier can fall below one. Although a smaller inflation increase erodes the bond income by less, the overall consumption response can turn negative because of the rising real interest rate.

Next, we allow for regime switching to study how policy uncertainty can affect government spending effects and interact with other factors. Following Davig and Leeper (2011), we assume that the two policy regimes switch according to a two-state Markov chain. Instead of constant transition probabilities, we deviate from their setting by assuming that the switching probability from regime F to M is state-dependent and time-varying: households in regime F place a higher switching probability to regime M upon observing higher inflation. In regime F, expectations of switching to regime M lower expected inflation, leading current inflation to increase by less relative to the case without such expectations. Lower expected inflation then produces a smaller crowding-in effect. Also, expectations of switching to regime M imply rising expected future taxes, invoking negative wealth effects. This offsets some positive consumption responses from a negative real interest rate in regime F. When combining policy uncertainty with high initial debt, the output multipliers can fall substantially below one. Since high levels of inflation are uncommon in advanced economies in last three decades, inflation-dependent policy uncertainty in regime F can be empirically relevant.

In addition to regime F, policy uncertainty also has negative effects on output multipliers in regime M, although the negative impact is relatively small. In regime M, expectations of switching to regime F increase expected inflation and hence current inflation more relative to the case without such expectations. Since the Taylor rule still operates, the monetary authority raises the nominal interest rate more, exacerbating the crowding-out effects of government spending and produces smaller output multipliers in regime M relative to the case without policy uncertainty. The crowding-out effect, however, is somewhat offset by diminished negative wealth effects, because policy uncertainty makes households place some probability that future tax rates do not increase once switching to regime F.

Aside from government spending effects in normal times, we also examine them in recessions. We inject sufficiently negative structural shocks such that the economy is driven to a deep recession with the binding ZLB. Although several papers have studied theoretical government spending effects in recessions, they tend to focus on the ZLB in regime M (e.g., Michaillat (2014) and Canzoneri et al. (2016)). Unlike the typical results that a recession or the ZLB can generate much bigger output multipliers (e.g., Christiano et al. (2011), Woodford (2011), and Erceg and Lind´e (2014)), we find that a recession or the ZLB may not enhance government spending effects in regime F. In regime M, government spending at the ZLB generates higher inflation and reduces the real interest rate, producing a much bigger multiplier than in normal times—similar to the intertemporal substitution effect channel making the multiplier bigger in regime F than in M. In regime F, on the other hand, high inflation from a government spending increase makes the economy immediately exit the ZLB. Unless the monetary authority becomes less responsive to inflation (e.g., pegging the net interest rate at zero), the initial ZLB does not enhance government spending effects in recessions.

Our analysis of government spending effects in regimes F and M is closely related to two recent papers that compare the conventional debt-financed and money-financed government spending effects. English et al. (2017) and Galí (forthcoming) find that a money-financed government spending increase crowds in private consumption and is more expansionary than a debt-financed one. The main mechanisms underlying these results are the same as those driving bigger multipliers in regime F.2 This implies that the factors we highlight which can weaken the expansionary effects of government spending in regime F are likely to be relevant for money-financed government spending effects.

2 The Model Setup

We adopt a New Keynesian (NK) model with nominal price rigidity as modeled in Rotemberg (1982).3 The key features deviating from a standard NK model include: 1) flexible government debt maturities, a la Woodford (2001)4 and 2) the possibility of switching between regimes F and M.

2.1 Households

The representative household chooses consumption (ct), labor (nt), and nominal government bonds (Bt) for each period t to maximize the lifetime utility by solving the following optimization problem:

maxE0t=0βtU(ct,nt),(2.1)

subject to

ct+QtBt(1κ)Bt1Pt=Bt1Pt+(1τt)wtnt+γt+zt+ξt,(2.2)

where ct[01ct(i)θ1θdi]θ1θ is a basket of goods aggregated by the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator, Pt is the price of the composite good, wt is the real wage rate, and τt is the labor income tax rate. The left hand side of (2.2) is the total expenditure, including consumption and the purchase of (net) newly issued government bond. The right hand side is households’ income, consisting of income from savings—bond payment from the government, after-tax labor income, dividends from owning the firms (ϒt), government transfers (zt), and the rebate of nominal price adjustment costs (ξt) to be explained in firms’ problem.

Following Woodford (2001), we assume that households have access to a portfolio of government bonds, Bt, which sells at a price of Qt at t and pays (1 – κ)t dollars t + 1 periods later for each t ≥ 0. The average bond maturity is (1 – β(1 – κ))-1 quarters. The usual setting of short-term government bonds is nested with κ = 1. The transversality condition for bond is

limTEt{qt,TDT}=0,(2.3)

where qt,T=RT1(PT/Pt)andDTBT1[1+(1κ)QT].

2.2 Firms

The production sector consists of a continuum of monotonically competitive firms. Each firm i chooses price (Pt(i)) and labor (nt(i)) to maximize the present value of future nominal profits, discounted by the household’s stochastic discounting factor:

 maxnt(i),Pt(i)Ets=0βsλt+sλt[Pt+s(i)yt+s(i)Wt+snt+s(i)ψ2(Pt+s(i)π*Pt+s1(i)1)2yt+sPt+s],(2.4)

subject to linear technology for each intermediate good i:

yt(i)=Ant(i),(2.5)

and the demand for each intermediate good i:

yt(i)=(Pt(i)Pt)θyt,(2.6)

where yt=[01yt(i)θ1θdi]θ1θ is the final goods, π* is the inflation target set by the monetary authority and A is technology assumed to be constant. The discounting factor between time t+s and t follows from the household’s Euler equation, βsλt+sλt, with λt = UCt, the marginal utility of consumption. Price adjustments are subject to a quadratic adjustment cost with an adjustment parameter ψ > 0 to govern nominal price rigidity. In aggregation, the price adjustment cost, ξtψ2(πtπ*1)2yt, is rebated back to households, as shown in (2.2).5

To solve for the optimality condition, rewrite (2.4) in real terms:

maxnt(i),Pt(i)Ets=0βt+sλt+sλt[(Pt+s(i)Pt+s)1θyt+swt+snt+s(i)ψ2(Pt+s(i)π*Pt+s1(i)1)2yt+s].(2.7)

Solving firms’ optimization problem and imposing the symmetric equilibrium conditions yield the Phillips curve:

ψ(πtπ*1)πtπ*=(1θ)+θmct+βψEt[λt+1λtyt+1ytπt+1π*(πt+1π*1)],(2.8)

where πtPtPt1 is gross inflation and mctwtA it the real marginal cost.

2.3 The Public Sector

The public sector consists of a fiscal authority and a monetary authority. The two policy regimes analyzed are defined in terms of different responses of fiscal adjustment to government indebtedness and monetary policy to inflation.

2.3.1 Fiscal Policy

Each period the government collects a proportional labor income tax and issues nominal bonds to finance its goods purchases (gt) and transfers to households (zt), subject to the following flow budget constraint:

QtBt(1κ)Bt1Pt+Ttwtnt=Bt1Pt+gt+zt.(2.9)

Since our focus is on expansionary fiscal policy through goods purchases, we assume that government purchases follow an exogenous AR(1) process:

 ln gtg=ρg ln gt1g+εtg,(2.10)

where the innovation εtgi.i.d.N(0,σg2) and g is steady-state government goods purchases. For simplicity, we assume that transfers are constant at the steady-state level: zt = z.

The labor income tax rate responds to debt and the coefficient, γ(st), is regime-dependent:

τt=τ+γ(st)(bt1b)RR(1κ),γ(st){γF, γM},(2.11)

where btBtPt is real government debt, b and R are the steady-state real debt and nominal interest rate, st indicates the state of the policy regime (F or M), and γM > γF ≥ 0. With long-term debt, government indebtedness is captured by the the face value of outstanding debt-defined as the sum of the present value of all future payments, discounted by the steady-state nominal interest rate.6

2.3.2 Monetary Policy

The monetary authority determines the short-term nominal bond return based on a nonlinear response to inflation deviation from the inflation target, π*:

Rt= max{1,R.(πtπ*)α(st)}α(st){αF, αW},(2.12)

where α(st) is the regime-dependent response to inflation deviation. When the unconstrained interest rate rule implies a gross nominal interest rate below 1, the economy is at the ZLB, Rt = 1.

We follow Leeper (1991) and Leeper et al. (2017) to define regime M, in which the monetary authority actively controls inflation and the fiscal authority raises taxes to stabilize debt, and regime F, in which the monetary authority does not stabilize inflation and the fiscal authority does not stabilize debt. We initially assume that the economy has fixed policy regimes. When studying policy uncertainty the fixed regime assumption is relaxed in Section 4.

2.4 Functional Forms, Parameterization, and the Solution Method

We assume the representative household’s utility function is:

U(ct, nt)=(ctνt)1σ1σχnt1+φ1+φ(2.13)

where νt affects consumption taste as in Erceg and Linde (2014) and Battistini et al. (2019). While most analysis does not involve shocking νt, we inject negative taste shocks to generate a recession when analyzing government spending effects in such a state. The taste shock follows a stationary AR(1) process:

νt=ρννt1+εtν,(2.14)

where νti.i.d.N(0,σν2).

Since our model setup is mostly a standard NK model, we adopt common values for the structural parameters of the baseline calibration. Table 2.4 summarizes the parameter and policy values in the steady state. We calibrate the model at a quarterly frequency. The discounting factor, β, is set to 0.992, implying an annualized real interest rate around 3%. The quarterly inflation target is set to 1.005, matching the annualized 2% inflation target adopted in most advanced economies. The risk aversion parameter in the utility function is set to σ = 2. The labor disutility parameter, X, is endogenously calculated to produce a steady-state labor of n = 0.25. The steady-state technology is set to A = 1, equivalent to having a normalized steady-state yearly output of 1. The inverse Frisch elasticity is set to ϕ = 2, to be consistent with the values from estimated NK models.7 We follow Davig and Leeper (2011) to set θ = 7.66. This implies a 15% of price markup in the steady state. The Rotemberg quadratic cost parameter is set to ψ = 78, implying the degree of nominal price rigidity to be about one year (as estimated in Smets and Wouters (2007) for the probability that firms can choose prices optimally).8

The baseline calibration sets κ = 1 to have the common setting of only short-term debt, so it can be compared to an alternative case of longer debt maturity—κ = 0.05. This implies the average debt maturity of about 20 quarters, matching the average maturity of total U.S. outstanding Treasury marketable debt from 2000 to 2018 of about five years (Office of Debt Management (2018)). We adopt other fiscal values in the steady states to follow Drautzburg and Uhlig (2015) with U.S. data. The steady-state debt-to-annual output ratio is 0.6, and the government goods purchase-to-output ratio is 0.15. The steady-state labor income tax rate is set to τ = 0.28, and transfers are endogenously computed to satisfy the government budget constraint in the steady state.

To calibrate γ(st) and α(st) in the tax and interest rate policy rules, (2.11) and (2.12), we set the values consistent with Leeper’s (1991) definitions for active/passive monetary and fiscal policies:

{st=F:α(st)=αF,γ(st)=γF;st=M:α(st)=αM,γ(st)=γM.(2.15)

To reflect the typical slow process of debt adjustment in reality, γM is set to the smallest value that meets the transversality condition for government debt, (2.3).9

For exogenous processes, we set the process of the taste shock to be ρν = 0.8 and σν = 0.0025. This process determines how often the economy hits and remains at the ZLB. Our calibration implies that the conditional probability of hitting the ZLB is about 5% in regime M, typical of NK models subject to the ZLB (e.g., see Miao and Ngo (forthcoming) for 5.6% in an NK model).10 The economy has a government spending persistence of ρg = 0.9 with a standard deviation of 0.01, based on Shen and Yang’s (2018) estimate. Sensitivity analysis explores different government spending persistence.

Table 1:

Baseline Calibration

article image

The model is solved fully non-linearly with Euler equation iteration, following Coleman (1991) and Davig (2004). Appendix A contains the equilibrium system, Appendix B calculates the deterministic steady state, and Appendix C describes the solution method.

3 Government Spending Effects: Regime F vs. Regime M

We begin our analysis by explaining the channels that drive the different government spending effects in the two regimes and identify relevant factors that diminish the expansionary effects of government spending in regime F in a hxed regime environment.

3.1 Simulations with the Baseline Calibration

Figure 2 compares the effects of an initial government spending increase of 1% of steady-state output in the two regimes with the parameters in Table 2.4. Unless specified in the figure notes, the plots show the differences between the paths with and without a spending shock in percentage deviations from the latter path.11 In fully non-linear models, the size of the government spending shock and the initial state of the economy both matter for government spending effects. Thus, for all experiments we fix the size of the government spending increase at one percent of the steady-state output and fix the initial debt level at its deterministic steady state—60% of the annualized steady-state output, unless specified otherwise.

Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Simulations with the baseline calibration: regime F vs. regime M.

Impulse responses to a government spending increase. Except for G/Y (the government spending-to-steady state output ratio), inflation, nominal rate, real interest rate, and expected inflation, the y-axis units are in percent deviation from a path without a government spending shock. For G/Y, the graph plots level differences in percent. For inflation, the nominal rate, the real interest rate, and expected inflation, the graphs plot annualized level differences. The x-axis unit is in quarters after the government spending shock.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

Consistent with the literature (Kim (2003), Davig and Leeper (2011), Dupor and Li (2015), and Dupor et al. (2018)), government spending in regime F is more expansionary and generates much higher inflation than in regime M. Two main forces driving the very different responses are via the wealth-effect channel and the intertemporal substitution effect channel. Households in regime M expect higher future tax burden, which discourages consumption and encourages saving, producing an output multiplier smaller than one. In regime F, this negative wealth effect does not operate because the future tax rate is not expected to rise in response to higher debt. The real wage rate rises because the stimulus increases firms’ labor demand, and more wage income supports higher consumption.12 On the intertemporal substitution effect, the monetary authority in regime M raises the nominal interest rate more than the inflation increase M > 1), hence an increase in the real interest rate. Instead, the monetary authority in regime F does not raise the nominal interest rate sufficiently to control inflation so the the real interest rate falls, reversing the typical crowding-out effect of government spending in regime M. Also, in regime F, the strong demand increases together with muted interest rate responses generate much higher inflation (4.2% in regime F vs. 0.5% in regime M on impact), as shown in Figure 2.

Table 2 summarizes the cumulative output multipliers in present value under different calibrations, computed as

Table 2:

Cumulative output multipliers: fixed policy regimes.

The multipliers are calculated as described in (3.1). b04y denotes the initial debt-to-annual output when the government spending takes place. The baseline case has b04y=0.6,τ=0.28,αF=0.5,andκ=1. For other cases, we hold all the parameters the same as the baseline values except for the one specified in parentheses.

article image
j=0k(Πi=0jrt+i1)Δyt+jj=0k(Πi=0jrt+i1)Δgt+j,(3.1)

where y and g are level changes relative to the paths without a government spending increase and is the gross real interest rate. When . Under the baseline calibration, the impact output multiplier is 1.27 in regime F, compared to 0.58 in regime M, and the differences remain large for longer horizons (0.90 in regime F vs. 0.45 in regime M five years after). Although consumption multipliers are not reported, its impact multiplier is 0.27 in regime F under the baseline calibration, compared to -0.42 in regime M, reflecting crowding-in vs. crowding-out effects in the two regime.13

The rest of this section explores each of the factors in Table 2 that can reduce the expansionary effect of government spending in regime F.

3.2 A Higher Stock of Initial Government Debt

A major concern associated with increasing government spending is elevated government debt in many advanced economies after the global financial crisis. Several empirical studies show that government spending is less expansionary in a high-debt state than in a low-debt state (e.g., Kirchner et al. (2010), Ilzetzki et al. (2013), and Nickel and Tudyka (2014)). One plausible explanation is that high debt may induce expectations of larger fiscal adjustment (Bi et al. (2016)). This mechanism cannot operate in regime F though, as the government does not raise tax rates or implement other fiscal adjustment measures to stabilize debt. By solving the model fully nonlinearly, we can explore the role of initial government indebtedness on government spending effects in regime F.14 We find that a high initial debt level also reduces the government multiplier in regime F, but the underlying mechanism is quite different from expecting bigger fiscal adjustments in regime M.

To examine debt dependence of government spending effects in regime F, we simulate government spending effects when an initial debt ratio is 100%. The first two rows in Table 2 show that the output multipliers are smaller across various horizons in regime F when an initial debt ratio is higher: the impact output multiplier is 1.19 with 100% of initial debt, compared to 1.27 with 60% of initial debt.15

Figure 3 compares the impulse responses for these two simulations. It shows that in regime F, an initial debt of 100% leads to a smaller increase in inflation and hence a smaller decline in the real interest rate than the case of 60%. For a given government spending increase, higher government debt provides a bigger base for inflation taxes; consequently, the inflation rate need not increase as much as with a smaller stock of debt. Lower inflation implies that the real interest rate does not fall as much, which generates a smaller intertemporal substitution effect and hence a smaller increase in consumption, leading to the smaller output multipliers.

Figure 3:
Figure 3:

The role of government indebtedness in government spending effects in regime F.

The axis units and the government spending path follow those in Figure 2.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

Note that rising inflation in regime F also reduces the real value of households’ holding of government bonds. As the top-right plot in Figure 3 shows, households’ real bond income, calculated as bt1πt, decreases in both cases because of higher inflation.16 With 100% of initial debt, inflation increases less and therefore the drop in household’s real bond income is smaller than the case of 60%. Despite a smaller reduction in bond income, consumption increases less with the 100% debt level, as the intertemporal substitution effect channel dominates the negative bond income effect on consumption.

The two opposite forces arising from higher initial debt in affecting consumption in regime F imply that the overall effect is relatively small. Later when we incorporate the factor of policy regime uncertainty, the intertemporal substitution effect channel gets amplified substantially, and government spending multipliers can drop much below one with a marginal increase in the initial debt ratio from 0.6 to 0.7.

Our closed-economy model assumes that government debt is held only by domestic households. If a large proportion of debt is held abroad (such as the case of the U.S.), the role of government indebtedness in driving the difference in the multipliers in regime F would be more pronounced. In the extreme case with all government debt held by foreigners, consumption would increase more with the initial debt ratio of 60% than 100%, because the avoided negative consumption effect from declined bond income is bigger with the former case.

3.3 A Higher Level of Taxation

Next, we explore the role of tax burden on government spending effects in regime F, a factor particularly relevant for the European countries. We compare the baseline economy (τ = 0.28) to two different levels of the steady-state distorting labor tax rate: τ = 0 and τ = 0.5. Figure 4 shows that a higher steady-state tax rate leads to a smaller increase in inflation and, hence, a smaller decrease in the real interest rate than with a lower tax rate.

Figure 4:
Figure 4:

The role of the steady-state labor income tax rate in regime F.

The increase of government spending follows the path in Figure 2. See Figure 2 for axis units.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

In regime F, the economy with a higher steady-state tax rate implies that a bigger proportion of a government spending increase is financed by tax revenues from output expansion, despite that the government does not raise the tax rate to finance debt (γF = 0). For a given government spending increase, this means that inflation does not increase as much and the real interest rate does not decrease as much, weakening the intertemporal substitution effect channel. As shown in Figure 4, consumption and the real wage rate rise the most with τ = 0. A strong increase in goods demand from consumption implies strong labor demand, driving the largest increase in the real wage rate with τ = 0. While the change in the labor income tax rate in response to a spending increase in regime F is zero across the three cases (γF = 0), labor responses are quite different because of different crowding-in effects, as shown in Figure 4.

Table 2 shows that a higher steady-state tax rate decreases the output multipliers in regime F, but has little effect in regime M. For a given government spending increase in regime M, it must be financed by a certain amount of debt and future taxes. In the economy with a low steady-state tax rate, for a given size of a government spending increase, the amount of debt that needs to be issued at time zero is bigger than in the case with a high steady-state tax rate. While the negative wealth effect is bigger with a low steady-state tax rate (because the government issues more debt), a lower current tax burden implies a bigger increase in the aftertax income. By the same reasoning, a higher steady-state tax rate has a smaller negative wealth effect and a smaller increase in the after-tax income. In either case, the combined effect (from the negative wealth effect and positive income effect) is about the same on current consumption, and thus produces very similar output multipliers with different steady-state tax rates. This result is consistent with the finding of Leeper et al. (2017) in a linearized model.

3.4 A Longer Debt Maturity wi th a More Responsive Monetary Policy

From Figure 3, we see that inflation and inflation expectations to a government spending increase in regime F rise much more than in regime M. The typical short-term debt specification overstates the inflation responses and, hence, the crowding-in effect of government spending. Consistent with Leeper et al. (2017), we find that longer average debt maturity lowers the consumption and output multipliers in regime F. Table 2 shows that the impact output multiplier with an average maturity of approximately five years is 1.11, compared to the baseline short-term debt multiplier of 1.27.17 With only short-term debt, the government must repay a relatively large amount of liabilities next period, requiring an immediate inflation adjustment to stabilize debt, whereas longer-term debt permits inflation to be spread to future periods. As the left plot of Figure 5 shows, longer average debt maturity lowers current and near future inflation (the dotted line), leading to smaller multipliers than those with only short-term debt.

Figure 5:
Figure 5:

The role of debt maturity and monetary policy’s response to inflation in regime F.

The left panel compares inflation responses to a government spending increase under short-term debt (κ = 1) and long-term debt (κ = 0.05). The right panel compares inflation responses to a government spending increase under different monetary policy responses, conditional on an average debt maturity of about five years (κ = 0.05). The increase of government spending follows the path in Figure 2.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

Another relevant factor that also reduces short-run inflation responses in regime F is the response of monetary policy to inflation. Although monetary policy in regime F does not actively respond to inflation, the responsiveness still shapes the paths of current inflation and inflation expectations. As the right plot of Figure 5 shows, with an average maturity of five years, a bigger response of the nominal interest rate (a bigger αF in (2.12) but still in Regime F) limits the increase in inflation in the short run and pushes inflation to the future. As the initial inflation rises less, again it leads to a smaller decline in the real interest rate and hence smaller output and consumption multipliers.

The last row of Table 2 presents the multipliers for an average five-year debt maturity (κ = 0.05) combined with a more responsive interest rate policy (α = 0.8). While still in regime F, output multipliers throughout the horizon drop below one and the consumption multipliers turn negative as in regime M. On impact, the output multiplier falls to 0.89 with five-year average debt maturity. Since the average government debt maturity in reality is much longer than one quarter, and the monetary authority may not refrain from responding to inflation completely, the combination of the two factors suggest that government spending multipliers can easily fall below one in regime F.

The analysis in this section focuses on the factors that can diminish the expansionary effects of government spending under passive monetary policy. Our cashless model cannot simulate the effects of a money-financed government increase. The results obtained here, however, are likely to be relevant for the expansionary effects of money-financed government spending in English et al. (2017) and Galí (forthcoming), because the main mechanisms underlying its big multipliers are similar to those in regime F.

4 Policy Regime Uncertainty

In the above fixed regime environment, households believe that the current regime will never change and there is no policy regime uncertainty. Over the past thirty years, central banks in advanced economies have been emphasizing their independence and many of them have announced inflation targets. With this historical experience, mounting inflation generated by government spending in regime F is likely to induce households to expect a switching to regime M. To see how this expectation can affect government spending effects, we follow Davig and Leeper (2006, 2007, 2011) to assume that the policymakers’ behavior is captured by a two-state Markov chain with the transition matrix below:

st+1=Mst+1=Fst=MρMM1ρMMst=F1ρFFρFF(4.1)

where st indicates the state of the policy regime. Deviating from their assumption of constant regime switching probabilities, we assume that households’ expectations about switching back to regime M depend on observed last-period inflation. Specifically, we assume that the transition probability from regime F to M is an increasing function of last-period inflation in the following logistic form:

ρFF={1,ifπt1π*;exp(Φ(πt1))1+exp(Φ(πt1))otherwise,(4.2)

where Φ(πt1)=α1(πt1/π*1) governs how much the probability of staying in regime F decreases as inflation rises. To mimic the inflation-targeting policy in reality we assume that households do not expect policy to switch to regime M until inflation rises above the targeted level, π*. Figure 6 plots the probability of staying in regime F as a function of last-period inflation (πt-1) under different values of α1. To make the model tractable, we assume that ρMM is constant over time. Specifically, for the simulation below, we set α1 = 0.05 and fix ρMM = 0.98, which implies an average duration of 50 quarters in regime M.18

Figure 6:
Figure 6:

Regime switching probability:

ρFF. The y-axis is the probability in regime F at t to stay at regime F at t + 1. See equation (4.2) for the functional form that links ρFF to last-period inflation.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

4.1 Policy Regime Uncertainty in Regime F

To see how regime switching expectations affect government spending multipliers in regime F, we simulate a scenario with an initial debt-to-annual output ratio at 70%.19 Relative to the baseline multiplier (Table 2), Table 3 shows that output multipliers are much smaller when households expect that future policy can switch to regime M. Also, the higher the initial debt ratio is, the higher the probability households place on switching, and the smaller are the output multipliers. The impact output multiplier with a debt ratio of 80% decreases to 0.76, compared to 1.27 in the baseline without policy regime uncertainty.

Table 3:

Cumulative output multiplier in regime F with expectations of switching to regime M.

The multipliers are calculated as described in (3.1).

article image

In regime F, when households expect that the monetary authority can switch back to actively controlling inflation, it lowers inflation expectations, and hence, current inflation. Lower expected inflation drives up the current real interest rate, induces households to consume less, and thus lowers current goods demand relative to the case without such expectations. Moreover, with some probability of switching to regime M, households expect that future tax rates may increase and start saving for a potential tax hike, even though they are still in regime F.

Section 3 shows that government indebtedness seems to only have small quantitative effects in reducing government spending multipliers, as the impact multiplier with an initial debt ratio of 100% in regime F only drops to 1.19 from 1.27 with a ratio of 60% (see Table 2). With regime switching possibility, the analysis shows that policy uncertainty can substantially amplify the negative effect of high debt burden in lowering government spending multipliers in regime F.

The above simulations with regime switching policies are conducted in an economy with short-term debt (κ = 1). We also repeat the simulations in an economy with an average debt maturity of about five years (κ = 0.05). The magnitude of multiplier reductions relative to a fixed regime F with longer debt maturity is similar to those in Table 3.

4.2 Policy Regime Uncertainty in Regime M

Given that policy uncertainty can significantly lower multipliers in regime F, a natural question to ask whether it plays a similar role in regime M. Different from the state-dependent switching probabilities, we assume the switching probability from regime M to F is constant.

Table 4 compares the output multipliers under different switching probabilities of ρMM. As the probability of switching to regime F increases, output multipliers also become smaller relative to the baseline case without uncertainty, but the difference is not as big as in regime F. In regime M, while the monetary authority actively raises the nominal interest rate in response to inflation, the expectation that government debt can be inflated away drives up expected inflation and, hence, current inflation.20 Since the current policy remains in regime M, higher inflation induces a bigger response in the nominal interest rate, aggravating the crowding-out effect of government spending in regime M. Meanwhile, expecting a switch to regime F reduces the expected future tax rates. This works to increase government spending multipliers relative to the case without such expectation. Thus, the overall effect of policy uncertainty in regime M is generally small because the negative effect from expecting higher inflation is offset to some extent by the positive effect from expecting lower future taxes.

Table 4:

Cumulative output multiplier in regime M with expectations of switching to regime F.

The multipliers are calculated as described in (3.1). The initial debt-to-annual output is 0.6.

article image

5 Government Spending Effects in Recessions

Theoretical literature studying business cycle state-dependent multipliers at the binding ZLB mainly focuses on regime M (e.g., Christiano et al. (2011), Michaillat (2014), Canzoneri et al. (2016), and Shen and Yang (2018)), and not much is known about government spending effects in recessions with regime F. In this section, we study how government spending effects differ in recessions under the two policy regimes. We consider a recession that the ZLB can bind for a sustained period in regime M with a series of negative taste shocks, following the common practice in the literature (e.g., Eggertsson and Woodford (2003, 2006), Christiano et al. (2011), Erceg and Linde (2014), Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2015)). Since the economy responds to the same macroeconomic shocks quite differently in the two regimes, we first compare the macroeconomic responses before analyzing government spending effects.

5.1 Macroeconomic Dynamics in Recessions: Regime M vs. Regime F

In non-linear models, initial states can affect economic responses to shocks. Thus, we design simulations such that the two economies begin with the same state—both in regime M at t = 0— and are hit by the same negative taste shocks from t = 1 to t = 5. At t = 3, one economy stays in regime M and the other switches to regime F, with the policy parameters in Table 2.4.

Figure 7 plots the impulse responses to the taste shocks under the two regimes. In the economy that stays in regime M, negative taste shocks lower consumption. As expected, output falls and inflation decreases because of weaker demand, and government debt as a share of output rises. The monetary authority responds to falling inflation by lowering the nominal interest rate. As shown in Figure 7, the shocks generate the binding ZLB from t = 2 to t = 8.

Figure 7:
Figure 7:

Responses to adverse taste shocks: regime M vs. regime F.

Consumption and output are in percent changes compared to the paths without the adverse taste shocks. The other variables are in level differences in percentage points. The economy is injected with a series of negative taste shocks from t = 1 to 5. Both economies start from regime M at t = 1. One of them switches to regime F in t = 3 as indicated by the gray vertical line.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

Given the same series of taste shocks, a switch to regime F, on the other hand, brings the economy immediately out of the binding ZLB as shown by the solid black lines in Figure 7. When the economy switches to regime F, inflation adjusts to stabilize rising debt due to previous negative taste shocks. Since the monetary authority still responds to inflation in regime F, rising inflation drives up the nominal interest rate, making the economy exit the liquidity trap quickly. Our recession simulation in regime F is similar to Bianchi and Melosi (2017, 2019). They show that coordinated monetary and fiscal policy can avoid a liquidity trap after a large negative taste shock: When policy authorities announce entering regime F, inflation immediately increases to move away from a liquidity trap.

The very different macroeconomic responses to the same negative macroeconomic shocks are important to understand why the ZLB may not generate bigger multipliers in recessions in regime F.

5.2 Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions with the Binding ZLB

Table 5 compares the multipliers across various simulations in the two regimes. While the output multipliers are generally bigger in recessions in regime M than F, they are almost the same across different business cycle states in regime F, as shown in the middle column under regime F (αF = 0.5).

Table 5:

Cumulative output multipliers: recessions vs. normal times.

The multipliers are calculated by (3.1). The baseline simulation does not have negative taste shocks. In the recession scenarios, the economy is hit by a series of negative taste shocks from t = 1 to 5.

article image

In regime M, multipliers are much bigger in recessions than in normal times, mainly because of the binding ZLB. This result is consistent with those in Christiano et al. (2011) and Erceg and Linde (2014).21 With the constant nominal interest rate at the ZLB, government spending that raises inflation and inflation expectations lowers the real interest rate and crowds in current consumption—the same intertemporal substitution effect channel in regime F discussed in Section 3.1. The crowding-in effect in recessions, however, is only temporary—present when the ZLB binds. As the economy exits the ZLB at t = 7 because of higher government spending, the monetary authority in regime M resumes its responsibility to raise the nominal interest rate (and hence the real interest rate) to control inflation. As a result, the two-year cumulative output multiplier drops to 1.18 (under the column for 8Q in Table 5), compared to 1.3 when the ZLB binds.

In the economy that switches to regime F at t = 3, output multipliers in recessions are not bigger than those in normal times (the baseline scenario). As regime F allows the economy to escape the liquidity trap (see Figure 7), the nominal interest rate is no longer constrained by the recession. Consequently, the mechanism through which a government spending increase stimulates output is the same as in normal times. As the ZLB—driving the business-cycle dependent multipliers in our model in regime M—quickly dissipates in regime F, government spending effects in recessions are similar to those in normal times.

In our simulations with recessions, since the economy in regime F only stays in the ZLB briefly, some may argue that the exercise does not capture monetary policy responses in a deep recession that the ZLB binds. Since the nominal interest rate typically does not (or cannot) respond to economic conditions at the ZLB, we also simulate an alternative scenario in which the monetary authority pegs the nominal interest rate at a constant level by setting αF = 0 in recessions (compared to αF = 0.5 in the previous simulations).

The multipliers are shown in the last column in Table 5. We see that the output multipliers are bigger compared to those in the baseline regime F, with the impact output multiplier rising to 1.45 (compared to 1.27 in regime F without a recession). The bigger multiplier is attributed to the more passive monetary policy. Figure 8 compares the impulse responses of government spending effects in recessions in regime F under αF = 0.5 vs. 0. When the monetary authority refrains from responding to rising inflation in recessions in regime F, the real interest rate falls more, generating more positive consumption and hence bigger output multipliers.

Figure 8:
Figure 8:

The role of the binding ZLB: regime F vs. a pegged interest rate.

Impulse responses to a government spending increase at t = 3. See Figure 2 for axis units. The economy is injected with a series of negative taste shocks from t = 1 to 5. Both economies start from regime M at t = 1 and switch to regime F with αF = 0.5 and αF = 0 at t = 3 as indicated by the gray vertical line.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

Our analysis of government spending effects in recessions under regime F shows that whether spending multipliers are larger during recessions or under a binding ZLB depends on the policy experiment conducted. In our model without additional channel to generate bigger government spending effects (such as downward nominal wage rigidity in Shen and Yang (2018)), whether the monetary authority deviates from its typical response magnitude to inflation becomes a key factor to generate bigger government spending multiplier in recessions in regime F.

6 Sensitivity Analysis

This section performs sensitivity analysis on government spending multipliers in both policy regimes along four dimensions: 1) the degree of nominal rigidity; 2) persistence of government spending; 3) the steady-state debt-to-output ratio; and 4) the steady-state labor income tax rate.

6.1 Nominal price rigidity

The left panel of Figure 9 plots the impact multipliers for a government spending increase as a function of the Rotemberg (1982) adjustment cost coefficient (ψ). We see that the higher the degree of price rigidity, the bigger the impact multiplier is in both regimes. This effect is, however, quite nonlinear in regime F. When prices are sticky, government spending can be more effective in boosting real demand as prices do not increase quickly. The multiplier in regime F first increases rapidly as ψ rises from zero and then stays almost the same when ψ exceeds the baseline value of 78 (corresponding the price rigidity of roughly one year).

Figure 9:
Figure 9:

Sensitivity analysis: nominal price rigidity and government spending persistence.

The plots present the impact output multipliers. Except for the parameter in the x-axis, other parameters are held at the baseline values in each regime.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

Note that the impact output multiplier in regime F falls below one when ψ = 10 (a very low degree of price rigidity). Intuitively, less price stickiness makes inflation rise more for a given government spending increase than the case of more price stickiness. Much higher inflation, however, has a negative income effect as the income from bond holding declines more. When price stickiness is sufficiently low, the negative income effect can dominate the crowding-in effect of government spending in regime F, which lowers consumption and drives the output multiplier to below one.

6.2 Persistence in Government Spending Increases

The right panel of Figure 9 plots the impact output multipliers under different ρg’s. Government spending persistence has opposite effects on output multipliers across regimes: a more persistent government spending process increases the multipliers in regime F but decreases them in regime M. This difference reflects how government spending is financed differently in the two regimes.

For a given government spending shock, higher persistence means that the total amount of spending stimulus in present value is bigger. In regime M, where government spending is largely financed by debt and future taxes, more stimulus leads to higher tax burden in the future, inducing a bigger negative wealth effect and thus reducing the current output multipliers. This result is consistent with Shen and Yang (2018) where bigger government spending has smaller output multipliers for a spending increase in regime M. On the other hand, a more persistent spending increase leads to a higher jump in current inflation because households expect future inflation to rise more. A bigger rise in inflation lowers the interest rate more, augmenting the crowding-in effect and producing bigger output multipliers.

6.3 Government Debt in the Steady State

The left panel of Figure 10 plots the impact output multipliers as a function of the steady-state debt-to-output ratio. To keep the economic structure as close as possible across the economies under comparison, we only allow non-distorting steady-state transfers to vary to satisfy the government budget constraint; all other parameters and steady-state values are set to those in the baseline calibration (Table 2.4).

Figure 10:
Figure 10:

Sensitivity analysis: steady-state indebtedness vs.

labor income tax rates. The plots present the impact output multipliers. Except for the steady-state values in the x-axes, other parameters are held at the values of the baseline calibration.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2020, 091; 10.5089/9781513546797.001.A001

In regime M, we find almost no change in the impact output multipliers. Regardless of the steady-state debt ratio, the crowding-out effect in regime M depends mainly on the amount of additional debt and thus the amount of taxes eventually need to be raised to financing government spending, determining the strength of negative wealth effects. As a result, the stock of existing steady-state debt does not matter much for government spending effects in regime M.

In regime F, instead, the multiplier decreases as the steady-state debt-to-output ratio increases. Similar to an initial high-debt state (as analyzed in Section 3.2), given a fixed amount of government spending to be financed by inflation, a higher steady-state debt ratio (which is also the initial debt in the current simulation) provides a higher nominal base, so inflation increases by less than in the case of low steady-state debt. As a result, the intertemporal substitution effect is smaller and so is the output multiplier.

Our result in regime F differs from Leeper et al. (2017), who find that the steady-state debt ratio affects output multipliers only when government debt has longer maturity. We show that with a fully nonlinear model, the steady-state debt-to-output ratio matters in regime F even with only short-term debt.

6.4 The Labor Income Tax Rate in the Steady State

The right plot of Figure 10 complements the analysis in Section 3.3, and presents the impact output multipliers as a function of the steady-state labor income tax rate in the two regimes. When τ = 0, it amounts to the case of only lump-sum taxes, as studied in Davig and Leeper (2011), and the impact output multiplier is the highest—around 1.8. In this case, an increase in government spending must be completely financed by inflation, leading to the biggest inflation response and crowding-in effect. When the steady-state tax rate increases, the multipliers decrease at a relatively large rate. Also, the flat line for regime M confirms that the steady-state labor income tax rate does not play a role in the spending multipliers, as shown in Table 2. (See Section 3.3 for the underlying reasons.)

7 Conclusion

In this paper, we study government spending effects under different monetary-fiscal policy regimes in a nonlinear model that features regime switching and the potentially binding ZLB. We find that government spending multipliers under passive monetary policy can be lower because of higher debt levels, longer debt maturity, higher distorting tax rates, more responsive monetary policy to inflation, and the existence of policy regime uncertainty. These results provide plausible explanations why empirical evidence does not always support big government spending multipliers under passive monetary policy or when nominal interest rates are low.

Among the various factors, policy regime uncertainty is particularly important in reducing the expansionary effects of government spending in regime F. With expectations of switching to regime M, multipliers in regime F decrease because the negative wealth effect in regime M spills over into regime F. In particular, when agents expect that future policy regimes can switch to regime M with an initial high debt ratio, government spending multipliers can fall much below one. Also, policy uncertainty matters in regime M, because higher inflation expectations in regime F spill overs into regime M, leading to higher real interest rates in regime M.

From the policy perspective, our analysis points out that government spending in regime F may not always be a very effective stimulus in regime F. The result is relevant to the recent discussion on the very different effects between money- and debt-financed government spending in the literature. Although our framework prevents us from modeling money-financed spending, the main mechanisms driving the different spending effects between the two regimes are very similar to those driving different effects between money- and debt-financed government spending. This implies that big government spending multipliers for money-financed spending can be subject to the same factors that lower the multipliers in regime F, as analyzed in this paper.

References

  • Almunia, M., Bénétrix, A., Eichengreen, B., O’Rourke, K. H., Rua, G., 2010. From Great Repression to Great Credit Crisis: Similarities, differences and lessons. Economic Policy 25 (62), 219265.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Battistini, N., Callegari, G., Zavalloni, L., 2019. Dynamic fiscal limits and monetary-fiscal policy interactions. Working Paper Series 2268, European Central Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck-Friis, P., Willems, T., 2017. Dissecting fiscal multipliers under the fiscal theory of the price level. European Economic Review 95, 6283.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bi, H., Shen, W., Yang, S.-C. S., 2016. Debt-dependent effects of fiscal expansions. European Economic Review 88, 142157.

  • Bianchi, F., Melosi, L., 2017. Escaping the Great Recession. American Economic Review 107 (4), 10301058.

  • Bianchi, F., Melosi, L., 2019. The dire effects of the lack of monetary and fiscal coordination. Journal of Monetary Economics 104, 122.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Broner, F., Clancy, D., Martin, A., Erce, A., 2018. Fiscal multipliers and foreign holdings of public debt. European Stability Mechanism Working Paper 30,.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, G. A., 1983. Staggered prices in a utility maxmimizing model. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (3), 383398.

  • Canzoneri, M., Collard, F., Dellas, H., Diba, B., 2016. Fiscal multipliers in recessions. The Economic Journal 590 (February), 75108.

  • Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M., Rebelo, S., 2011. When is the government spending multiplier large? Journal of Political Economy 119 (1), 78121.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cogan, J. F., Cwik, T., Taylor, J. B., Wieland, V., 2010. New Keynesian versus old Keynesian government spending multipliers. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (3), 281295.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coleman, II, W. J., 1991. Equilibrium in a production economy with an income tax. Econometrica 59 (4), 10911104.

  • Davig, T., 2004. Regime-switching debt and taxation. Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (4), 837859.

  • Davig, T., Leeper, E. M., 2006. Fluctuating Macro Policies and the Fiscal Theory. In NBER Macroeconomic Annual 2006, edited by D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford,. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Davig, T., Leeper, E. M., 2007. Generalizing the Taylor principle. American Economic Review 97 (3), 607635.

  • Davig, T., Leeper, E. M., 2011. Monetary-fiscal policy interactions and fiscal stimulus. European Economic Review 55 (2), 211227.

  • Drautzburg, T., Uhlig, H., 2015. Fiscal stimulus and distortionary taxation. Review of Economic Dynamics 18 (4), 894920.

  • Dupor, B., Li, R., 2015. The expected inflation channel of government spending in the postwar U.S. European Economic Review 74 (February), 3656.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dupor, W., Li, J., Li, R., 2018. Sticky wages, monetary policy and fiscal policy multipliers. Working Paper 2017–007A, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eggertsson, G., Woodford, M., 2003. The zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 139211.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eggertsson, G., Woodford, M., 2006. Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Liquidity Trap.

  • Eggertsson, G. B., Singh, S. R., 2019. Log-linear approxiation versus an exact solution at the ZLB in the New Keyesian model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 105 (August), 2143.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • English, W., Erceg, C. J., Lopez-Salido, D., 2017. Money-financed fiscal programs: a cautionary tale. Hutchins Center Working Paper 31, Brookings, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Erceg, C. J., Lind´e, J., 2014. Is there a fiscal free lunch in a liquidity trap? Journal of the European Economic Association 12 (1), 73107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fernández-Villaverde, J., Gordon, G., Guerrón-Quintana, P., Rubio-Ramirez, J. F., 2015. Nonlinear adventures at the zero lower bound. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 57, 182204.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Forni, L., Monteforte, L., Sessa, L., 2009. The general equilibrium effects of fiscal policy: Estimates for the e uro area. Journal of Public Economics 93 (3–4), 559585.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galí, J., forthcoming. The effects of a money-financed fiscal stimulus. Journal of Monetary Economics.

  • Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., Huffman, G. W., 1988. Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle. American Economic Review 78 (3), 402417.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. G., Végh, C. A., 2013. How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2), 239254.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2019a. Fiscal monitor. Chapter 1. Fiscal Policy for a Changing Global Economy, April, Washington, D.C.

  • International Monetary Fund, 2019b. World Economic Outlook, April. Chapter 1: Global Prospects and Policies, Washington, D.C.

  • Jacobson, M. M., Leeper, E. M., Preston, B., 2019. Recovery of 1933. NBER Working Paper 25629, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Kim, S., 2003. Structural shocks and the fiscal theory of the price level in the sitcky price model. Macroeconomic Dynamics 7 (5), 759782.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kirchner, M., Cimadomo, J., Hauptmeier, S., 2010. Transmission of government spending shocks in the euro area time variation and driving forces. Working Paper Series No. 1219, European Central Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leeper, E. M., 1991. Equilibria under ‘active’ and ‘passive’ monetary and fiscal policies. Journal of Monetary Economics 27 (1), 129147.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leeper, E. M., Traum, N., Walker, T. B., 2017. Clearing up the fiscal multiplier morass: Prior and posterior analysis. American Economic Review 107 (8), 24092454.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miao, J., Ngo, P. V., forthcoming. Does Calvo meet Rotemberg at the zero lower bound? Macroeconomic Dynamics.

  • Michaillat, P., 2014. A theory of countercylical government multiplier. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6 (1), 190217.

  • Miyamoto, W., Nguyen, T. L., Sergeyev, D., 2018. Government spending multipliers under the zero lower bound: Evidence from japan. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10 (3), 247277.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nickel, C., Tudyka, A., 2014. Fiscal stimulus in times of high debt: Reconsidering multipliers and twin deficits. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46 (7), 13131344.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Office of Debt Management, 2018. Treasury presentation to treasury borrowing advisory committee. U.S. Treasury Department.

  • Ramey, V. A., 2011. Identifying government spending shocks: It’s all in the timing. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1), 150.

  • Ramey, V. A., Zubairy, S., 2018. Government spending multipliers in good times and in bad: Evidence from U.S. historical data. Journal of Political Economy 126 (2), 850901.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rotemberg, J. J., 1982. Sticky prices in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 90 (December), 11871211.

  • Shen, W., Yang, S.-C. S., 2018. Downward nominal wage rigidity and state-dependent government spending multipliers. Journal of Monetary Economics 98 (October), 1126.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shen, W., Yang, S.-C. S., Zanna, L.-F., 2018. Government spending effects in low-income countries. Journal of Development Economics 133 (July), 201219.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2007. Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97 (3), 586606.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tauchen, 1986. Finite state Markov-chain approximations to univariate and vector autoregressions. Economics Letters 20 (2), 177181.

  • Traum, N., Yang, S.-C. S., 2011. Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in the post-war. U.S. European Economic Review 55 (1), 140164.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Traum, N., Yang, S.-C. S., 2015. When does government debt crowd out investment? Journal of Applied Econometrics 30, 2445.

  • Wieland, J., 2018. State-dependence of the zero lower bound government spending multiplier. Manuscript, University of California, San Diego.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Woodford, M., 2001. Fiscal requirements for price stability. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33 (3), 669728.

  • Woodford, M., 2011. Simple analytics of the government expenditure multiplier. JAmerican Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3 (1), 135.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

Appendices

A Equilibrium System

Households’ optimality conditions:

λt=Uct(A.1)
(1τtl)wtλt=Unt(A.2)
Qt=Et[βλt+1λt1+Qt+1(1κ)πt+1](A.3)
1Rιf=Et[βλt+11λtπt1](A.4)
ct+Qt(bt(1κ)bt1πt)=bt1πt+(1 τtl)wtnt+ϒt+ξt+zt(A.5)

Firms’ optimality conditions:

ψ(πtπ*1)πtπ*=(1θ)+θmct+βψEt[λt+1λtyt+1ytπt+1π*(πt+1π*1)](A.6)
mct=wtAt(A.7)
yt=Atnt(A.8)
ϒt=[1mctψ2(πtπ*1)2]yt(A.9)

Government budget constraint and policy rules:

Qt(bt(1κ)bt1πt)+τtlwtnt=bt1πt+gt+zt(A.10)
τt=τ+γ(bt1b)RR+(1κ)(A.11)
Rt= max{1,R(πtπ*)απ}(A.12)

Aggregate resource constraint:

yt=ct+gt(A.13)

Exogenous variables:

consumption taste:νt=ρννtl+εtν,εtνN(0, σν2)(A.14)
government spending:ln gtg=ρg ln gt1g+εtg,εtgN(0, σg2)(A.15)

The policy regime indicator, st, follows a Markov process with the following transition probabilities: ℙ(st = M|st-1 =M) = ρMM and ℙ(st = F|st-1 = F) = ρFF.

B Deterministic Steady State

The deterministic steady state is characterized by the following equations:

1R=βπ*(B.1)
Q=βπ*β(1κ)(B.2)
mc=θ1θ(B.3)
θ1θτgyzy=1βπ*β(1κ)by(B.4)
c+g=y=n(B.5)
cσ(1τ)mc=χyφ=χnφ(B.6)

The average duration of the government bonds is

RR+(1κ)=π*π*β(1κ)(B.7)

The government debt-to-annual output ratio is

b+Q(1k)b4y=Rκ+(R1)b4y(B.8)

The left hand side of (B.8) is the market value of outstanding debt, and the right hand side is the face value of outstanding debt. The market value of debt is the same as the face value of debt at the steady state.22 The steady-state market value of debt with decaying coupons is sometimes defined as Qb4y in the literature. If we adopt this definition, the short-term debt case cannot be nested, because b is not exactly outstanding liabilities of a long-term debt. Quantitatively, the difference in the two definitions of the debt market value is negligible. Here we make the modification to nest the short-term debt case within a general expression.

C Computational Algorithm

The model is solved with Euler equation iteration as described in Coleman (1991), which finds the fixed point of the Euler equations directly. Specifically, it makes initial guesses for future policy functions and iterates backwards to solve for the true policy functions. In this paper, the method is implemented in Fortran 90 and paralleled with OpenMP.23

Given the equilibrium system in Appendix A for the baseline economy, the set of the policy functions to be solved is {λ(bt-1; St), Q(bt-1; St),π(bt-i; St)}, where bt-1 is the endogenous state,24 and the exogenous state vector, St, consists of the exogenous variables, t,gt}, and the policy regime indicator, st.

The equilibrium conditions used to solve the model consist of

Rtf= max {1,(Rt1f)prf(Rf(πtπ*)απ)1ρrfeεtrf}(C.1)
(ct νt)σ=λt(C.2)
nt=ct+gt(C.3)
τt=τ+γ(bt1b)1+rκ+r(C.4)
(1τtl)wtλt=χntφ(C.5)
mct=wt(C.6)
bt=bt1πt+gt+ztτtlwtntQt+(1κ)bt1πt(C.7)

The equations used for updating the policy functions consist of

λtRtf=β𝔼t[λt+1πt+1](C.8)
λtQt=β𝔼t[λt+1((1+Qt+1(1κ))πt+1](C.9)
ψ(πtπ*1)πtπ*=(1θ)+θmct+βψ𝔼t[λt+1λtnt+1ntπt+1π*(πt+1π*1)].(C.10)

The solution algorithm is described below.

  • 1. Discretize the state space using Tauchen (1986).

  • 2. Guess the form of the policy functions: λ(1) (bt-1; St), Q(1) (bt-1; St), and π(1)(bt-1; St).

  • 3. For each state, plug the initial guesses to the system of optimality conditions, (C.1)- (C.7), to calculate Rtf,ct,nt,wt,mct,andbt.

  • 4. With bt from the last step, evaluate the expectations on the right hand side of (C.8)-(C.10) by calculating next period’s policy values with the guessed policy functional forms: λ(1) (bt; St+1), Q(1) (bt; St+1), and π(1)(bt; St+1).

  • 5. Solve for the policy functions—λ(2), Q(2), and π(2)—by solving a three-dimensional root-finding problem with (C.8)-(C.10).

  • 6. Check convergence. If max {‖λ(1)(2) ‖,‖Q(1)-Q(2) ‖,‖π(1)(2) ‖} < 10-6, then {λ(2),Q(2)(2)} is the final solution; else update λ(1),Q(1), and π(1) with λ(2),Q(2), and π(2), and repeat steps 2–4 until the conversion criterion is satisfied.

When solving the model, we use linear interpolation for policy function approximations. Since the state space is discretized with Tauchen (1986), numerical expectations are calculated accordingly. We also use quadrature to evaluate numerical integration as a robustness check, and the differences are small for this model. The root-finding routine we use is a Fortran translation from csolve.m by Sims.25

Lastly, there are a few remarks on model convergence. Regime M usually converges to the equilibrium faster than Regime F. One can start with the steady-state values or the solution from the log-linearized model as the initial guesses. When solving the model in regime F with no tax response to debt (γF = 0), we first solve the model under a small but non-zero value of γF and then use the solution as the initial guess for the case for γF = 0. Similarly, when solving for the equilibrium with regime switching or a highly persistent government spending process, we use the solutions of the fixed regime case or a less persistent spending process as initial guesses.

*

Mao: Department of Economics, Indiana University; Yang: Fiscal Affairs Department, International Monetary Fund. We thank Philip Barrett, Jean-Berard Chatelain, Christopher Erceg, Vitor Gaspar, Eric Leeper, Siming Liu, Marialuz Moreno Badia, Adrian Paralta Alva, Catherine Pattillo, Babacar Sarr, David Savitski, Hewei Shen, Todd Walker, and participants of the seminar at the Fiscal Affairs Department of the IMF, 2019 Midwest Macro Meetings, and the UCA-CNRS-IRD-CERDI International Workshop on Policy Mix for helpful comments and discussion.

1

In Bianchi and Melosi (2017, 2019), they refer to regime M as a monetary-led regime and regime F as a fiscal-led regime.

2

Beck-Friis and Willems (2017) analytically show that in regime F with lump-sum taxes, government spending financed by nominal debt is equivalent to money-financed spending.

3

We choose Rotemberg’s (1982) mechanism instead of Calvo’s (1983) to reduce the number of state variables required in solving the model nonlinearly.

4

Traum and Yang (2011) show that when only a short-term debt is included, regime F requires an unusually high degree of price stickiness to reconcile inflation dynamics in data and in an NK model.

5

As shown in Eggertsson and Singh (2019) and Miao and Ngo (forthcoming), when the adjustment cost is rebated back to households, the results under Calvo (1983) and Rotemberg (1982) are closer when inflation changes are large than without the rebate. This is relevant for our analysis government spending in regime F tends to generate a big jump in inflation.

6

At the steady state, the face value of government bonds is the same as the market value.

7

For instance, the posterior estimate is 1.96 in Smets and Wouters (2007) and 2.16 in Drautzburg and Uhlig (2015). In Leeper et al. (2017), the estimated value is 1.77 in regime M and 2.34 in regime F.

8

Under first-order approximation and a zero net inflation target, Rotemberg (1982) is equivalent to Calvo (1983), and ψ=(θ1)ω(1ω)(1ωβ), where ω is the fraction of the firms that cannot reset prices in Calvo’s setting. Since the model here is fully nonlinear and the net inflation target is not zero, we cannot back up a precise ψ to match a certain price adjustment frequency in Calvo (1983). The sensitivity analysis explores the role of nominal price rigidity in output multipliers under different policy regimes.

9

Since we cannot solve the model analytically, the precise parameter ranges that distinguish regimes M and F cannot be obtained. The policy functions show that debt is stabilized differently across the two regimes. In particular, government debt is an important state in regime F but not so in regime M.

10

The persistent parameter, ρν, is set to 0.85 in Battistini et al. (2019) and 0.9 in Erceg and Linde (2014). We choose a slightly lower persistence ρν = 0.8; otherwise, it would imply a much higher probability of hitting the ZLB in the simulations allowing for switching to regime F.

11

To calculate one-year ahead inflation expectations, we simulate the impulse response sequences 10,000 times for both paths with and without a government spending increase, by drawing from the taste shock distribution each period. The one-year ahead inflation expectation at time t is the average of the inflation differences at t + 4 between the two paths in each simulation. Although our calculation is the ex-post average of inflation, under rational expectations, the average inflation for t + 4 (based on 10,000 simulations) should be very close to Ett+4).

12

Note that in regime M, the wage rate also increases but by a much smaller magnitude than that in regime F. A higher wage rate (together with higher labor) also increases labor income in regime M, but households save additional income for future taxes.

13

In our closed-economy model without investment, yt = ct + gt; the consumption multiplier is equal to the output multiplier minus one. Our analysis does not account for the possibility in an open-economy environment that capital inflows can help finance a fiscal expansion (such as aid), which can mitigate the crowding-in effects of a government spending increase. See Broner et al. (2018) and Shen et al. (2018).

14

Most papers that study government spending effects in regime F solve for a log-linearized equilibrium around the steady state, and the analysis is typically conducted from the steady-state debt level. We carry out this experiment in Section 6.

15

In our simulation, the initial debt level has almost no influence on multipliers in regime M. This is different from the finding in Bi et al. (2016), where the baseline economy assumes a GHH (Greenwood et al. (1988)) preference and no negative wealth effect on labor. We use a constant-relative-risk-aversion utility instead. Also, their income taxes include capital income taxes and we only have labor income taxes here. With a high initial debt level, expecting higher capital income tax rates discourages current investment and offsets some of the expansionary effect of government spending.

16

The simulation here assumes only short-term debt (κ = 1), so the nominal value of savings income from bond holding at t is Bt1Pt.

17

The average maturity of total U.S. outstanding Treasury marketable debt from 2000 to 2018 is five years (Office of Debt Management (2018)).

18

We also experiment with ρMM from 0.95–0.99, and its value does not affect the results as long as regime M is sufficiently persistent.

19

The deterministic steady-state debt ratio of 0.6 is lower than the stochastic steady-state ratio defined by the mean of the ergodic distribution. Therefore, the corresponding inflation is below the target even with a government spending increase of 1% of steady-state output. Since we assume that the probability of switching to regime M is zero unless inflation of last period exceeds the targeted inflation rate, we need a higher initial government debt to induce households to place a positive regime switching probability.

20

Bianchi and Melosi (2017) use this mechanism to explain why there was no deflationary spiral in the 2008 recession as predicted by standard NK models.

21

Wieland (2018), however, attributes to larger multipliers at the ZLB in the literature to the change in government spending persistence, not the ZLB itself.

22

This can be easily shown by plugging in the steady-state price bond price, Q.

23

Replication files can be downloaded from https://sites.google.com/view/rmao/research?authuser=0.

24

For the regime switching case with time-varying switching probability, πt-1 is also a state variable. The algorithm is similar; the only difference is that when calculating expectation, the switching probability is calculated by equation (4.2).

25

The code can be downloaded from http://sims.princeton.edu/yftp/optimize/.

Government Spending Effects in a Policy Constrained Environment
Author: Ruoyun Mao and Susan Yang Shu-Chun
  • View in gallery

    Constrained policy environment.

    The annual policy rates are monthly averages. The policy rate of the European Central Bank is the main refinancing rate of the ECB Key Interest Rates. The policy rate of Japan is the Call Money/Interbank Rate. Public debt is the gross public debt of general governments from the database of the World Economic Outlook (International Monetary Fund (2019a)).

  • View in gallery

    Simulations with the baseline calibration: regime F vs. regime M.

    Impulse responses to a government spending increase. Except for G/Y (the government spending-to-steady state output ratio), inflation, nominal rate, real interest rate, and expected inflation, the y-axis units are in percent deviation from a path without a government spending shock. For G/Y, the graph plots level differences in percent. For inflation, the nominal rate, the real interest rate, and expected inflation, the graphs plot annualized level differences. The x-axis unit is in quarters after the government spending shock.

  • View in gallery

    The role of government indebtedness in government spending effects in regime F.

    The axis units and the government spending path follow those in Figure 2.

  • View in gallery

    The role of the steady-state labor income tax rate in regime F.

    The increase of government spending follows the path in Figure 2. See Figure 2 for axis units.

  • View in gallery

    The role of debt maturity and monetary policy’s response to inflation in regime F.

    The left panel compares inflation responses to a government spending increase under short-term debt (κ = 1) and long-term debt (κ = 0.05). The right panel compares inflation responses to a government spending increase under different monetary policy responses, conditional on an average debt maturity of about five years (κ = 0.05). The increase of government spending follows the path in Figure 2.

  • View in gallery

    Regime switching probability:

    ρFF. The y-axis is the probability in regime F at t to stay at regime F at t + 1. See equation (4.2) for the functional form that links ρFF to last-period inflation.

  • View in gallery

    Responses to adverse taste shocks: regime M vs. regime F.

    Consumption and output are in percent changes compared to the paths without the adverse taste shocks. The other variables are in level differences in percentage points. The economy is injected with a series of negative taste shocks from t = 1 to 5. Both economies start from regime M at t = 1. One of them switches to regime F in t = 3 as indicated by the gray vertical line.

  • View in gallery

    The role of the binding ZLB: regime F vs. a pegged interest rate.

    Impulse responses to a government spending increase at t = 3. See Figure 2 for axis units. The economy is injected with a series of negative taste shocks from t = 1 to 5. Both economies start from regime M at t = 1 and switch to regime F with αF = 0.5 and αF = 0 at t = 3 as indicated by the gray vertical line.

  • View in gallery

    Sensitivity analysis: nominal price rigidity and government spending persistence.

    The plots present the impact output multipliers. Except for the parameter in the x-axis, other parameters are held at the baseline values in each regime.

  • View in gallery

    Sensitivity analysis: steady-state indebtedness vs.

    labor income tax rates. The plots present the impact output multipliers. Except for the steady-state values in the x-axes, other parameters are held at the values of the baseline calibration.