The Impact of Bailouts on the Probability of Sovereign Debt Crises
Evidence from IMF-Supported Programs
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: hbalima@imf.org, asy@imf.org

This paper studies the role of IMF-supported programs in mitigating the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults in borrowing countries. Using a panel of 106 developing countries from 1970 to 2016 and an entropy balancing methodology, we find that IMF-supported programs significantly reduce the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults. This finding is robust to different specifications of the entropy balancing and alternative identification strategies. Our results suggest that a country that signs a program with the IMF, typically experiences a slight improvement in its sovereign credit rating and a decrease in both government debt-to-GDP and fiscal deficit-to-GDP.

Abstract

This paper studies the role of IMF-supported programs in mitigating the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults in borrowing countries. Using a panel of 106 developing countries from 1970 to 2016 and an entropy balancing methodology, we find that IMF-supported programs significantly reduce the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults. This finding is robust to different specifications of the entropy balancing and alternative identification strategies. Our results suggest that a country that signs a program with the IMF, typically experiences a slight improvement in its sovereign credit rating and a decrease in both government debt-to-GDP and fiscal deficit-to-GDP.

I. Introduction

Rising debt to risky levels has been pointed as one of the major challenge for many countries, especially those in the developing world. According to IMF (2018), global debt reached a record pick of 225 percent of world GDP in 2016, an increase of 12 percentage points of GDP compared to the previous pick at the onset of the 2007 financial crisis. The report highlighted public debt as an important driver of the increased global debt. While high government debts expose countries to rollover risks and to a sudden tightening of international financial conditions—and therefore subsequent debt crises—an important policy question is whether, the Fund, in its mandate of providing financial support mechanisms to member countries that are experiencing actual or potential macroeconomic problems through bailout mechanisms, can help mitigate the occurrence of such subsequent crises. In this paper, we study the role of bailouts in mitigating the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults in developing countries, taking IMF-supported programs as an example.

In theory, the mechanisms through which IMF-supported programs can have an impact on sovereign debt crises is not obvious. IMF loans may affect sovereign defaults through a number of conflicting channels (Jorra, 2012). A first mechanism may arise from the consequences of liquidity provision, particularly in a context of an illiquid government. If a government is facing a temporary liquidity shortage, having a rescue from the Fund may have a direct impact on its liquidity constraint and help avoid a potential self-fulfilling crisis (Fischer, 1997). In addition to mitigating the liquidity constraint, the Fund support may also have a catalytic effect on other official and private investors through restoring confidence, thus helping to mobilize capital from other sources (Dhonte, 1997; Fisher, 1997; Bird and Rowlands, 2002; Tirole, 2002; Morris and Shin, 2006; Saravia, 2010). However, the catalytic effect on private lenders may come at a cost in the long-run if the government accumulates a higher level of private debt (Fink and Scholl, 2016). Second, IMF-supported programs may affect debt crises through the policy adjustment channel. If countries do not pay for the consequences of their policy actions because of an insurance provided by the Fund—through emergency loans that are somewhat cheaper than market conditions—this may create a moral hazard since countries may be more reluctant to undertake painful fiscal adjustments. A moral hazard may particularly arise if the Fund fails to differentiate between temporary and permanent liquidity crises (Vaubel, 1996; Dreher, 2004). Finally, a third mechanism, linked somewhat to the previous one, is the role of conditionalities in IMF programs that may help rebuild a stable and sustainable macroeconomic position, including an improved fiscal position. Consequently, the question of whether IMF-supported programs have a positive or a negative effect on the likelihood of occurrence of debt crises is an empirical question.

This paper analyzes the impact of bailouts on the probability of sovereign debt crises, taking IMF-supported programs as an example. The empirical assessment relies on a large and representative panel of 106 developing countries over the period 1970-2016. We address the common issue of identification in IMF program evaluation using different strategies. In our benchmark approach, we employ the entropy balancing methodology, a generalization of conventional matching methods proposed by Hainmueller (2012), and recently used by Neuenkirch and Neumeier (2016) to study the impact of U.S. sanctions on poverty, and by Balima (2017) to analyze the effect of domestic sovereign bond market participation on financial dollarization. While the relative performance of entropy balancing—compared to alternative methods—will be closely discussed in detail in the methodological section, this method allows to identify the impact of Fund-supported programs by comparing program and nonprogram countries that are as similar as possible in terms of observable characteristics, after purging for country- and time-specific factors. In robustness checks, we also employ an instrumental variable approach and conventional matchings. Our instrumental variable strategy uses two political variables—borrower’s ties with the Fund major shareholders at the United Nations General Assembly and previous executive elections—as external instruments for a country decision to sign a program with the Fund. The matching approaches employ propensity scores matching and bias-corrected matching to deal with the selection bias in Fund program adoption.

The main finding in this paper indicates that IMF-supported programs significantly reduce the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults by around 1.3 percentage points. This estimated coefficient is economically meaningful given that the unconditional probability of experiencing a sovereign default is 3.5 percentage points in our sample. We demonstrate that our finding is particularly robust to different specifications of the entropy balancing and the use of additional identification strategies including an instrumental variable approach and conventional matchings. Moreover, we find that a country that signed a program with the Fund experienced a slight improvement in its sovereign credit rating, and a decrease in both government debt-to-GDP and fiscal deficit-to-GDP during the program period compared to the period before. This suggests that (i) the liquidity provision channel and catalytic role, (ii) the role of government adjustment effort, and (iii) the conditionality channel may be at work. Our results are in line with the theoretical model of Corsetti et al. (2006) that shows that a lending support not only has an impact on the likelihood and the possible incidence of a crisis, but also prompts the borrowing government to implement desirable policies and reforms.

The rest of the paper is as follows. Section 2 discusses the existing literature. Section 3 presents our benchmark empirical methodology. Section 4 describes the data. Section 5 reports the baseline result while section 6 follows with the robustness checks. Section 7 provides some potential explanations of the result. Finally, a summary is presented in section 8.

II. Literature Review

Existing theoretical literature on this issue, starting from Eaton and Gersovitz (1981), focuses more broadly on bailout programs by International Financial Institutions (IFIs) in models of strategic sovereign defaults (Zettelmeyer, 2000; Corsetti et al., 2006; Boz, 2011; Fink and Scholl, 2016). Zettelmeyer (2000) uses a static co-ordination game model and suggests that limited rescue packages can have counterproductive effects in the short run by providing investors the opportunity to exit. Corsetti et al. (2006) provide an opposite view. Using a model in which a crisis can be the outcome of fundamental shocks and self-fulfilling panics, they show that partial bailout conditional on policy adjustment by the debtor country can restore investors’ confidence and therefore reduce the incidence of crises. Their model also shows that liquidity support can tilt the government’s incentives to implement desirable but costly policies and reforms. Boz (2011) shows that sovereigns borrow more from private sector creditors compared to IFIs—even if the interest rates charged by the latter are significantly lower—because they can strategically default on private debt, whereas IFI’s debt contracts are enforceable. Fink and Scholl (2016) formalize a dynamic stochastic model of sovereign debt and default with endogenous participation rates in bailout programs, and calibrate the model to Argentina. They show that bailouts lower the likelihood of a sovereign default in the short run, and restore confidence of private lenders through increasing their willingness to provide new credit to the borrowing government. In their framework, the government then takes advantage of the catalytic effect induced by bailouts—lower interest rates, larger capital supply—and accumulates more private debt. As a result, the risk of default increases in the long run.

On the empirical side, the literature is however relatively sparse. A notable exception is Jorra (2012) who analyzes the effect of IMF bailouts on the probability of subsequent sovereign defaults. Using a sample of 57 developing economies, he finds that IMF-supported programs increase the probability of subsequent sovereign defaults by approximately 1.5-2 percentage points. The author stresses that his result cannot be attributed to an endogeneity bias or a lack of compliance with IMF conditionality, as his empirical specification explains simultaneously sovereign defaults and program participation. Apart from Jorra (2012), previous empirical studies analyzing the direct association between bailouts in the context of IMF lending programs and crises focus on three types of crises: sudden stops, currency crises, and banking crises (Eichengreen et al., 2008; Dreher and Walter, 2010; Papi et al., 2015). Eichengreen et al. (2008) examine the impact of IMF-supported programs on the incidence of sudden stops in capital flows. After corrected for the non-random assignments of IMF programs, they find that IMF credit reduces the likelihood of sudden stops—particularly for countries with strong fundamentals—through the stabilizing effect of liquidity insurance. Dreher and Walter (2010) employ a panel of 68 countries over the period 1970-2002. They show that IMF involvement decreases a country’s risk of experiencing a currency crisis through the presence of the Fund itself rather than money disbursements or compliance with conditionality. Finally, in a recent paper, Papi et al. (2015) focus on banking crises, using a large panel of 113 developing countries over the period 1970-2010. The empirical assessment concludes that, after correcting for endogeneity issues, countries which signed IMF-supported programs are less likely to experience a banking crisis.

However, the empirical assessment of IMF-supported programs and sovereign defaults—Jorra (2012)—is not immune of criticisms. First, since the paper focuses only on 57 developing countries, the finding, somewhat, may face criticism regarding its external validity. In fact, given that the Fund is an organization of 189 countries, a broader assessment of its impact in preventing (or not) debt crises may rely on a representative sample of its member States. Second, and in relation to the previous point, Jorra’s definition of a debt crisis is taken from Standard and Poor’s, and therefore excludes countries not rated by this rating agency. Third, while Jorra’s empirical identification uses a version of Heckman two step approach, such a strategy may be subject to inconsistent estimates if collinearity problems prevail (Puhani, 2002). Finally, given the above evidence from Eichengreen et al. (2008), Dreher and Walter (2010), and Papi et al. (2015), a natural question emerges. Why should IMF involvement lower the likelihood of sudden stops, currency crises and banking crises, while increasing the risk of sovereign defaults?

III. Methodology

The objective of this paper is to analyze the role of bailouts in mitigating the likelihood of subsequent sovereign debt crises (SDC) in borrowing countries, taking IMF-supported programs as an example. Our challenge is to establish a causal link running exclusively from a Fund program implementation to the occurrence of a SDC. As stressed by Bird (2001) and Dreher and Walter (2010), empirical studies of the impact of IMF programs commonly faced the problem of counterfactual and endogeneity. On the one hand, it is hard to properly predict the outcome that would have emerged without a program and therefore to quantify the impact induced by the program participation. On the other hand, countries tend to turn to the Fund during times of economic downturn—in particular when a crisis is looming down—due to the Fund’s mandate of international lender of last resort. A number of previous studies aimed at dealing with these issues usually employ a version of Heckman (1979) two-step estimator or an instrumental variable approach (Przeworski and Vreeland (2000), Hardoy (2003), Barro and Lee (2005), Conway (2006), Jorra (2012). Other studies also use conventional matching methodologies (Mumssen et al., 2013; Gunduz, 2016).

In this paper, we employ the entropy balancing methodology—a generalization of conventional matching methods proposed by Hainmueller (2012)—to overcome the counterfactual and endogeneity issues with regard to the adoption of an IMF program. This methodology has been recently used by Neuenkirch and Neumeier (2016) to assess the impact of U.S. sanctions on poverty, and by Balima (2017) to analyze the effect of domestic sovereign bond market participation on financial dollarization. Entropy balancing allows to identify the impact of IMF-supported programs by comparing program and nonprogram countries that are as similar as possible in terms of observable characteristics, after purging for country- and time-specific factors. In particular, entropy balancing has some advantages over other treatment effect estimators or regression analyses (Hainmueller, 2012). Its most important attractive feature is to allow obtaining a high degree of covariate balance between program and nonprogram groups by creating a synthetic control group that is as close as possible to the program group.1 A second advantage is that, compared for instance to simple regression-based approaches (namely difference-in-difference) or conventional matching methods (including propensity scores matching and bias-corrected matching), entropy balancing is fairly versatile in the sense that its use does not require specifying an empirical model for the adoption of an IMF program. This feature makes it possible to minimize potential problems of misspecification, multicollinearity, or wrong choice of the functional form. A third advantage is that, compared to conventional matching where the control units are either discarded or matched, entropy balancing uses a more flexible reweighting scheme. It reweights units with the goal of achieving balance while keeping at the same time the weights as close as possible to the base weights to avoid a loss of information. Finally, while conventional matching methods and pooled probit rely on the conditional independence assumption—that is, conditionally on the vector of observable covariates, the treatment is independent of unobservable factors—using the entropy balancing allows considering the panel dimension of the data by controlling for country and time specific factors in its second step of the regression analysis.2 While our preferred method is the entropy balancing, later in the paper, we also employ a battery of alternative identification strategies including instrumental variable approach and conventional matching methodologies, to validate our findings.

The entropy balancing approach is based on the idea that the adoption of an IMF-supported program represents the treatment and the occurrence of a SDC represents the outcome variable. The units of observations are country-year observations; observations with (without) a program represent the treatment (control) group. The measure of interest we wish to estimate is the well-known average treatment effect on the treated, τ, defined as

τ=E[SDC(1)|P=1]E[SDC(0)|P=1](1)

where SDC(.) is the outcome variable measuring the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. P indicates if the unit of observation is subject to the treatment IMF-supported program (P = 1) or not (P = 0). Consequently, E[SDC(1)| P = 1] is the probability of experiencing a sovereign default during the program period and E[SDC(0)| P = 1] is the counterfactual outcome for countries that signed programs, that is, the likelihood of experiencing a sovereign default in program countries if they had not adopted programs. Given that we cannot observe the last one, we need to identify an appropriate proxy. If the adoption of a program was a random event, we can easily identify τ by comparing SDC in program and nonprogram countries. However, as discussed earlier, the decision to request a program from the Fund is rather endogenous to several macroeconomic variables. For this reason, we can compare—after purging for some specific factors—program and nonprogram units that are as close as possible with respect to observables characteristics that meet these two conditions: (i) they are correlated with a country decision to sign a program with the Fund and (ii) they are associated with the occurrence of a SDC. Under the condition that the nonprogram units are similar as possible to the program units, difference in SDC is caused by the adoption of an IMF-supported program. With these remarks, the above equation can then be rewritten as follows

τ=E[SDC(1)|P=1,X=x]E[SDC(0)|P=0,X=x](2)

where X = x is a vector of observables covariates that may affect both the decision to sign a program and the likelihood of experiencing a default, as described in the data section below. E[SDC(1)| P = 1, X = x] is the likelihood of a default occurrence for program units, and E[SDC(0)| P = 0, X = x] is the expected likelihood of experiencing a default for the synthetic control units.

Practically, to estimate τ with the entropy balancing, we follow the following two consecutive steps. A first step computes weights for nonprogram units. These weights may satisfy pre-specified balanced constraints involving sample moments of observable characteristics, X. Following Neuenkirch and Neumeier (2016), we choose the balance constraints that impose equal covariate means across program and nonprogram groups. By doing so, we want to ensure that the nonprogram group contains, on average, units not subject to a program that are as similar as possible to the program units. In the robustness exercises, we will also bring the 2nd and the 3rd moments into the list of the balanced constraints. A second step uses the weights from the first step in a regression analysis where SDC is the dependent variable and IMF-supported program dummy is the main explanatory variable. We then estimate the average treatment effect of IMF programs on SDC, τ. In the second step, we also control for the entropy balancing covariates as well as time and regional specific effects—as in a randomized experiment—to increase the efficiency of the estimates.

IV. Data

We use a large panel dataset covering 106 developing countries over the period 1970-2016. We focus exclusively on developing countries to reduce the scope for parameter instability owing to difference in structural and institutional conditions in program and nonprogram countries (Dicks-Mireaux et al., 2000). The dependent variable is a dummy indicating the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. This variable is taken from the database on government debt in default developed by the Credit Rating Assessment Group (CRAG) of the Bank of Canada, the latest version of the database is provided by Beers and Mavalwalla (2017). We do prefer to use this database due, on the one hand, to its relative comprehensiveness and, on the other hand, to the frequency of occurrence of sovereign defaults, compared to existing concurrent database including Laeven and Valencia (2013). The Bank of Canada’s CRAG database has been recently used by Eichengreen (2015), Reinhart and Trebesch (2016) and Reusens and Croux (2017). In a robustness check, we also use Laeven and Valencia database. CRAG database compiles a comprehensive global dataset of official government debt on defaults and the stock of arrears with official creditors using different sources including international and regional organizations (i.e., the Asian Development Bank, the IMF, the Paris Club, the World Bank, and the IBRD’s annual financial statements) and academic authors.3 In particular, CRAG database gathers previously published data sets compiled by various public and private sector sources together with new information, which makes it one of the most comprehensive dataset on sovereign defaults currently available. Consistent with previous literature on sovereign defaults (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2010; Cruces and Trebesch, 2013), a default is defined when a debt service is not paid on the due or within a specified grace period, or when payments are not made within the time frame specified under a guarantee or absent an outright payment default. However, given that the final resolution with creditors following a sovereign default can be very lengthy, we follow Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) and consider only the first year of default as a crisis year. By doing so, we identify 115 sovereign debt crises in our sample, the first event occurs in 1976 and the last in 2016. The average number of crises per year is about two events, with some picks occurring in 1980, 1985, 1998, 2008, and 2013.

Information on our treatment variable, IMF-supported programs, is drawn from a database maintained by the Fund’s Strategy, Policy and Review Department called “Fund Arrangements since 1952”. This database provides information on the years in which a program started and ended. Consistent with previous works on IMF programs (Dreher and Walter, 2010; Jorra, 2012; Papi et al., 2015), we define a dummy variable taking 1 if a country had any type of IMF-supported program during the previous five years, because reforms may take some time to be implemented under IMF-supported programs.4 Appendix 1 lists countries that have signed at least a program in our sample together with the number of programs, and Appendix 2 reports the list of countries in the present analysis.

Regarding the control variables, our baseline regressions include similar covariates as Jorra (2012). In the robustness check, we will introduce a battery of additional covariates to ensure that the result is not driven by a specific choice of covariates. Our baseline covariates consist of the following: the GDP growth rate, the ratio of reserves to imports, the ratio of debt service to exports, the external debt to GDP ratio, and a variable capturing parliamentary democracies. Contrary to Jorra (2012), we did not include the five-year US treasury constant maturity interest rate since our main regressions do include year dummies that capture more broadly time specific factors, including the US treasury interest rate. Consistent with previous findings, we expect the first two variables and the last one to be negatively correlated the probability of a sovereign default, while debt service and external debt may be positively correlated. [Appendix 3] presents the sources and definitions of data used in this paper.

A first insight of the relationship between IMF-supported programs and SDC can be gauged by comparing the unconditional and the conditional probabilities of a SDC occurrence in our sample of analysis. In Table 1, the unconditional probability of a sovereign default— that is the number of crises divided by the number of non-missing country-year observations— is 3.5 percentage points (pp), compared to a conditional probability—i.e. the probability of experiencing a debt crisis conditional on having signed an IMF program during the past five years—of 2.7 pp. This simple correlation suggests that countries that have signed programs with the Fund have, roughly speaking, 0.8 pp lower probability of experiencing a debt crisis compared to countries in our sample. Building on this first insight, we therefore dig deeper into the analysis in the next section.

Table 1:

Conditional and unconditional probabilities of a debt crisis in the sample of analysis.

article image
Note: This table presents the conditional and the unconditional probabilities of the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis in our sample. The conditional probability is defined as the probability of experiencing a default, conditional on having signed at least an IMF-supported program during the past five years. The unconditional probability is the number of crises divided by the number of non-missing country-year observations.

V. Baseline Results

Table 4 presents the estimated impact of IMF-supported programs on SDC using the entropy balancing. Before getting into the estimate of the treatment effect, we focus on the performances of the entropy balancing in building a fairly close counterfactual of nonprogram units. Tables 2 and 3 present the sample means of matching covariates before and after weighting used to estimate the impact of IMF-supported programs on SDC. The evidence in Table 2 suggests that countries that adopted at least a program during the past five years (column [1]) differ from countries that did not (column [2]). Indeed, countries that signed a program have (i) lower real GDP growth—although the difference is not statistically significant, (ii) higher debt service-to-GDP, (iii) lower reserves-to-imports, (iv) higher external debt-to-GDP, and (v) lower parliamentary democracy, compared to countries that did not. However, the results in Table 3 clearly show that no significant difference appears between program and nonprogram countries after having created the balanced sample using the covariate moments. The non-statistically significant difference between the two groups strongly demonstrates the effectiveness of the entropy balancing method in building a perfect balance between the treated and the control groups for estimating the treatment impact of a program adoption.

Table 2:

Descriptive statistics before weighting.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the pre-weighting sample means of the matching covariates for country-year observations where IMF-supported programs where in place (the treatment group) in column [1] and country-year observations where no IMF-supported programs were in place (the potential control group) in column [2]. Column [3] reports the differences in means between treated and control group, and the corresponding t-test statistics and p-values.
Table 3:

Descriptive statistics after weighting.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the sample means matching covariates after weighting across the treated IMF-supported programs group in column [1] and the synthetic control group obtained from entropy balancing in column [4]. Column [5] shows the differences in means, the t-test statistics and the associated p-values.

Coming to the main finding in Table 4, column [1] reports the result excluding the matching covariates in the second step of the entropy balancing. Column [2] brings the covariates to the regression. Columns [3] and [4] control for year and regional fixed-effects, respectively. Finally, column [5] gathers the covariates, and year and regional fixed-effects into the second step regression. The result is strong and robust. Irrespective of the specification, the estimated effect of IMF-supported programs is negative and statistically significant. The magnitude of the coefficient varies between 1.3 pp and 1.5 pp, and is 1.3 pp in our preferred specification that controls for the covariates, as well as year and regional fixed-effects. Unlike Jorra (2012), our finding suggests that IMF lending programs significantly reduce the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults by 1.3 pp. This estimate is economically meaningful given that the unconditional probability of experiencing a sovereign default is 3.5 pp in our sample.

Table 4:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Baseline results.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the effect of IMF-supported programs on sovereign debt crises obtained by weighted least squares regressions. The treatment variable is the presence of IMF-supported programs. The outcome variable is the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. The control variables include one-year lagged values of real GDP growth, debt service-to-exports, reserves-to-imports, external debt-to-GDP, and parliamentary democracy. Column [1] reports the result without the matching covariates in the second step of the entropy balancing. Column [2] brings the covariates to the regression. Columns [3] and [4] control for year and regional fixed-effects, respectively. Finally, column [5] gathers the covariates, and year and regional fixed-effects into the second step regression. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

VI. Robustness Checks

Our previous finding shows that the presence of an IMF-supported program lowers the probability of subsequent sovereign defaults in program countries, compared to nonprogram countries. In the following, we perform a large set of robustness exercises to ensure that this finding is not sensitive to alternative specifications and alternative identification strategies. In performing these robustness checks, we focus our attention on the sign and the statistical significance of our principal variable of interest—IMF-supported programs.

6.1. Alternative specifications

We perform alternative specifications as follows. First, we want to know if the result is affected when we exclude domestic arrears from our baseline definition of SDC, given that such arrears may often reflect a strategic behavior between the governments and their local suppliers. The new regressions excluding domestic arrears are reported in columns [1]-[5] of Table 5. Consistent with the previous finding, the estimated coefficients remain negative and statistically significant.

Table 5:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, alternative specifications.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the effect of IMF-supported programs on sovereign debt crises obtained by weighted least squares regressions. The treatment variable is the presence of IMF-supported programs. The outcome variable is the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. The control variables include one-year lagged values of real GDP growth, debt service-to-exports, reserves-to-imports, external debt-to-GDP, and parliamentary democracy. Columns [1]-[5] define sovereign debt crises excluding domestic arrears. Columns [6]-[10] use Laeven and Valencia (2013) database. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

Our second robustness check consists of using an alternative database of sovereign defaults. Columns [6]-[10] of Table 5 report the regressions using the well-known Laeven and Valencia database. While the number of sovereign defaults is relatively low in Laeven and Valencia (38 events compared to 115 events in CRAG database), interestingly, we find that our conclusion does not change. The estimated effect of IMF-supported programs dummy is negative, statistically significant, and of comparable magnitude compared to the baseline estimate.

Third, the result remains robust to the use of alternative lag structures of IMF-supported programs. Columns [1] and [2] of Table 6 use more restrictive lag structures and define the treatment variable equal 1 if a country adopted at least a program in the previous 3 and 4 years, respectively.5 Columns [3] and [4] opt for more flexible definitions: the treatment variable equal 1 if the country signed a program in the previous 6 and 7 years, respectively. We find that using different lag structures does not affect our main conclusion, since the estimated treatment effect does not change significantly.

Table 6:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, alternative specifications.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the effect of IMF-supported programs on sovereign debt crises obtained by weighted least squares regressions. The treatment variable is the presence of IMF-supported programs. The outcome variable is the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. The control variables include one-year lagged values of real GDP growth, debt service-to-exports, reserves-to-imports, external debt-to-GDP, and parliamentary democracy. Columns [1]-[4] use alternative lag structures of IMF-supported programs. Column [5] excludes the period 2008-2010 from the analysis to isolate the impact of the recent financial crisis. Columns [6] and [7] use additional specified moment conditions of the reweighted data obtained from the entropy balancing. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

Fourth, we look for the potential role of the recent financial crisis. In column [5] of Table 6, we exclude the period 2008-2010 from the analysis to isolate the impact of the recent financial crisis. As show in column [5], excluding the period 2008-2010 does not affect our main conclusion: the estimated effect of IMF-supported programs is still negative and statistically significant.

Fifth, we want to know if the result holds for additional specified moment conditions of the reweighted data obtained from the entropy balancing. In column [6] of Table 6, we reweighted the control units to satisfy the balance constraints that the 1st and the 2nd moments— means and variances—match the corresponding moments of the treated units. Analogously, in column [7] of Table 6, the reweighting scheme considers the 1st, the 2nd, and the 3rd moments— means, variances, and skewness—of the control units. The estimated effects reported both columns remain negative and statistically significant suggesting that using additional moment conditions confirms the previous finding.

The final alternative specification check consists of controlling for a large set of control variables that may affect both a country likelihood of signing an IMF program and experiencing a sovereign default. The additional covariates—borrow from previous literature on the IMF interventions and debt crises—cover different macroeconomic dimensions including the real economy state (real GDP per capita), the external sector (trade openness to GDP, current account balance to GDP), monetary condition (inflation rate), financial development (capital openness index, private credit to GDP, and sovereign CDS market dummy), and macroeconomic instability (GDP growth volatility, banking crisis dummy, and currency crisis dummy). All these covariates are lagged by a year to overcome the issue of reverse causality. As reported in Table 7, we find that after controlling for these additional covariates, the main conclusion does not change.

Table 7:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, additional control variables.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the effect of IMF-supported programs on sovereign debt crises obtained by weighted least squares regressions. The treatment variable is the presence of IMF-supported programs. The outcome variable is the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. The baseline control variables include one-year lagged values of real GDP growth, debt service-to-exports, reserves-to-imports, external debt-to-GDP, and parliamentary democracy. Additional control variables are included in the regressions, as indicated at the top of each column. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

6.2. Alternative identification strategies

Is the previous result robust to alternative identification strategies? In the following, we provide an answer to this question using an instrumental variable approach as well as conventional matchings.

6.2.1. Instrumental variable approach

The instrumental variable (IV) approach has been widely used in previous works on IMF-supported programs (Barro and Lee, 2005; Eichengreen et al., 2008; Dreher and Walter, 2010; Papi et al., 2015). The challenge with the IV approach obviously consists of identifying variables that affect the likelihood of program participation but do not affect sovereign default other than through the effect on signing or not a program. We instrument IMF lending programs using two political variables. First, previous studies on political influences on the Fund show that borrowers that have closer ties with the Fund major shareholders, as reflected by their voting behavior at the United Nations General Assembly (UNGA), are more likely to have successful negotiations and better terms with the IMF (Thacker, 1999; Barro and Lee, 2005; Dreher and Walter, 2010; Papi et al., 2015). We follow this literature and use the UNGA affinity index, that is the fraction of time a country vote in line with the Fund main shareholders, as a first instrument for signing a program with the Fund. To ensure that our IV result is not driven by the definition of the IMF main shareholders, we consider separately these three groups of shareholders: the USA, the G5, and the G7. We then compute the average affinity index for each group, using three categories of vote data (approval of an issue, abstention, and disapproval of an issue) and focusing exclusively on important UNGA votes, as declared by the U.S. State Department. In so doing, the UNGA affinity index is a good instrument if it is uncorrelated with a sovereign default. Of course, a potential violation of the above exclusion restriction may arise when a default occurs as the result of poor creditworthiness arising from cut of foreign aid. Such a violation may be more likely given that voting behavior at UNGA has been widely accepted in the related literature as a reliable indicator of the political motivation of aid (Alesina and Dollar, 2000; Alesina and Weber, 2002; Gates and Hoeffler, 2004; Fink and Redaelli, 2011; Dreher and Sturm, 2012; Dreher et al., 2015). To overcome this issue, we also provide estimates controlling for foreign aid.

The second instrument exploits the established fact that the likelihood of engaging in a program with the Fund is more likely following the introduction of a new administration (Przeworski and Vreeland, 2000; Vreeland, 2002; Harrigan et al, 2006; Papi et al, 2015). We use a dummy variable identifying executive election years as an instrument. The underlying philosophy is that governments are more willing to seek an agreement with the Fund at the beginning of their terms in office in order to reduce the potential negative effect of IMF’s conditionality, if a program is signed later, on their chances of getting reelected.

Finally, given that we are interested in the impact of IMF-supported programs in the previous five years (t − 1, t − 5), we follow Papi et al. (2015) and build our instrumental variable, UNGA affinity score, as the average over the five-year period (t − 6, t − 10) prior the five-year used to construct our program dummy. In the same vein, the second instrument— executive election—takes the value of 1 if the country experienced an executive election in the period (t − 6, t − 10).

The result of the IV approach estimated using a probit model is reported in Tables 8 and 9. Table 8 uses the UNGA affinity score and executive election as instruments. Columns [1]-[6] of Table 8 present the probit regression using the conditional maximum-likelihood estimator, while columns [7]-[12] of Table 8 use the Newey two-step estimator. For each estimator, we report two regressions for each group of shareholders (G7, G5, and USA): one excluding and one including regional fixed effects. In Table 9, we reproduce the regressions of Table 8 by controlling for total foreign aid received.6

Table 8:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, instrumental variable approach.

article image
Note: This table presents the impact of IMF-supported programs on the probability of subsequent sovereign debt crises using an instrumental variable approach. The instruments are UNGA affinity score and executive election. Columns [1]-[6] present the probit regression using the conditional maximum-likelihood estimator, while columns [7]-[12] use the Newey two-step estimator. For each estimator, we report two regressions for each group of shareholders (G7, G5, and USA): one excluding and one including regional fixed effects. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

Table 9:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, instrumental variable approach controlling for ODA-to-GDP.

article image
Note: This table presents the impact of IMF-supported programs on the probability of subsequent sovereign debt crises using an instrumental variable approach. The instruments are UNGA affinity score and executive election. Each regression controls for foreign aid. Columns [1]-[6] present the probit regression using the conditional maximum-likelihood estimator, while columns [7]-[12] use the Newey two-step estimator. For each estimator, we report two regressions for each group of shareholders (G7, G5, and USA): one excluding and one including regional fixed effects. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

Before we examine the result of our main variable of interest—IMF-supported program—let us focus on the relevance and the validity of the instruments used. In each column of Tables 8 and 9, we report the first stage IV results—that are the estimated parameters of the instruments and the F-tests. Two interesting points emerged. First, the coefficients of our instruments are statistically significant at the 1 percent level with the signs consistent with the theory. Consistent with the above discussion, countries that vote in line with the IMF main shareholders at the UNGA and those that had election in the previous years are more likely to sign a program with the Fund. Second, the F-tests of the first stage regressions are higher than 10, with respect to the golden rule of Staiger & Stock (1997). These two facts confirm that our instruments are relevant. In addition, each column reports the Hansen test for over-identification restrictions. Irrespective of the regression, the p-values of the Hansen test are larger than the conventional level, meaning that the over-identification restrictions are respected. Consequently, we can conclude that our instruments for IMF lending programs are relevant and valid. We then move to the main finding.

In Tables 8 and 9, the coefficient of IMF-supported programs is negative and statistically significant, even if the magnitude of the coefficient is smaller compared to the estimate from the entropy balancing. The IV results confirm the entropy balancing finding that IMF lending programs statistically and economically reduce the probability of subsequent sovereign defaults.

6.2.2. Conventional matchings

The negative impact of IMF lending programs on the probability of subsequent sovereign defaults is also validated using two different methods of conventional matching: propensity score matching (PSM) and bias corrected matching (BCM). Both approaches consist of comparing a program country observation with a counterfactual nonprogram country observation that have a similar probability of having a program. Under the PSM or the BCM approach, the probability to sign a program is estimated in a first step for each country-year observation based on a vector of observable variables. The treatment effect of IMF-supported programs is then computed in a second step based on the first step estimated probabilities and using different varieties of defining the perfect counterfactual—the matching algorithms. Following Lin and Ye (2007), and Balima et al. (2017), we implement the PSM using these varieties: the N-nearest-neighbor (with N=1, 2, 3), the radius matching (with a radius of 0.005, 0.01 and 0.05), the kernel matching, the local linear matching, and the stratification matching.7 The BCM differs from the PSM, in the way that it relies on estimating a regression function only on the nonprogram group to predict the missing potential outcomes (see Abadie and Imbens (2006) for more discussions). In implementing the BCM, we consider the number of matched, n varying between 1 and 10.

The results of the PSM and the BCM are reported in Tables 10 and 11, respectively. The results confirm the negative impact of IMF lending programs on the likelihood of subsequent defaults. Indeed, the estimated treatment effects are negative and statistically significant in both Tables.

Table 10:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, propensity scores matching.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the effect of IMF-supported programs on sovereign debt crises using propensity scores matching. The treatment variable is the presence of IMF-supported programs. The outcome variable is the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. The covariates include one-year lagged values of real GDP growth, debt service-to-exports, reserves-to-imports, external debt-to-GDP, and parliamentary democracy. Bootstrapped standard errors based one 500 replications are reported in brackets.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

Table 11:

IMF-supported programs and sovereign debt crises—Robustness checks, bias corrected matching.

article image
Notes: This Table presents the effect of IMF-supported programs on sovereign debt crises using bias corrected matching. The treatment variable is the presence of IMF-supported programs. The outcome variable is the occurrence of a sovereign debt crisis. The covariates include one-year lagged values of real GDP growth, debt service-to-exports, reserves-to-imports, external debt-to-GDP, and parliamentary democracy. The number of matched N varies between 1 and 10. Heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors are reported in brackets.

p<0.01,

p<0.05,

p<0.1.

VII. Potential explanations

This section aims at shedding some light on the mechanisms behind the results. In particular, we test the relevance of these three transmission channels discussed in the introduction of the paper: (i) the liquidity provision channel and catalytic role, (ii) the role of government adjustment effort, and (iii) the role of conditionality. The liquidity provision channel and catalytic role, largely discussed in the literature, is usual tested by looking at the behavior of government bond yields or private capital flows following IMF intervention (Brealey and Kaplanis, 2004; Mody and Saravia, 2006; Eichengreen et al., 2006). The adjustment effort is usually tested through the behavior of policy outcomes, before and during program times. Finally, the conditionality channel is accessed by comparing the differential impact for program countries where the proportion of IMF loans that were agreed but left undrawn at the end of the program is larger than 25 percent or not, assuming that having drawn at least 75 percent of the agreed loans reflects compliance with IMF’s conditionality (Killick, 1995; Dreher and Walter, 2010, Papi et al, 2015).

In this paper, we take another way to test the relevance of the above transmission channels. We access the liquidity provision channel and catalytic role through annual changes in sovereign credit rating provided by notations agencies, using data from the three international credit rating agencies (Standard and Poor’s, Moody’s, and Fitch).8 Existent Empirical evidence suggest that a country credit rating is an important determinant of its international capital market access and the terms of that access (Reinhart, 2002; Kaminsky and Schmukler, 2002; Gande and Parsley, 2005; Pukthuanthong-Le et al., 2007). If IMF-supported programs help solve liquidity shortage and restore confidence, this might also result in an improvement in the borrowing country credit rating.9 Finally, the government adjustment effort and the conditionality channels are conjointly tested by looking at the behavior of government debt-to-GDP and fiscal balance-to-GDP. We believe that government debt or fiscal balance may be a good proxy for measuring the borrowing government effort and the role of conditionalities because, on the one hand, they are the main fiscal policy variables in the short and the long run, and, on the other hand, changes in these two outcomes may directly capture IMF conditionalities on fiscal targets in particular given that the Fund programs usually include some fiscal measures.10

To test for the conditionality channel, several studies use the proportion of loans that were agreed but left undrawn (Killick, 1995 and Dreher, 2003). We do not follow the literature for three main reasons. First, completion—as measured by the proportion of loans undrawn—might not be a good proxy for policy implementation (Conway, 1994; Killick, 1995; Bird, 2001). For instance, it may be that a country meets all the quantitative criteria, indicative targets and structural benchmarks but decides not to draw all the loans agreed with the Fund. In that case, using the proportion undrawn may underestimated the degree of completion. It may be also that a country fails to implement the agreed criteria but still complete the program. This may be so when the failure results from unexpected developments outside of the government control that deviate slightly the program from its initial objectives. In such a scenario, the program may be readjusted, or simply canceled if a large deviation emerges. It may be also that noncompliance arises because the economic situation of the borrower has improved before the program expiration and he decided to put down the program. In this last case, the program status may remain uncompleted due to good news—that is the borrowing country economic success. Second, data availability on IMF loans agreed but left undrawn is very limited, making cautious the interpretation of any derived empirical analysis (Dreher, 2006). And last but not least, IMF-supported programs usually include a fiscal adjustment plan, in particular when a debt distress is looming down (Independent Evaluation Office, 2007; Fink and Scholl, 2016).11 Consequently, the borrower fiscal outcomes may change if the program criteria have been met, making fiscal outcome variables some reliable measures for the borrower’s compliance with conditionality.

We assess these transmission channels following Neuenkirch and Neumeier (2016). In particular, we compute the mean of the above transmission channel variables for (a) the program group for observations where at least a program has been in place during the past five years, (b) the program group focusing exclusively on observations for which no program has been implemented during the past five years, and (c) the synthetic control group obtained via entropy balancing. The results reported in Table 12 indicate on the one hand that the synthetic control group computed from our entropy balancing differs from the program group before program implementation. Indeed, the former is characterized by a rating downgrade as shown by the negative variation in credit rating (-0.06 notch vs. -0.01 notch), a higher debt-to-GDP ratio (63.9 percent vs. 59.8 percent), and a lower fiscal balance-to-GDP (-3.0 percent vs. -2.7 percent). On the other hand, the implementation of IMF-supported programs has been accompanied by a significant decrease of the above outcomes. The change in sovereign credit rating turns form a downgrade (-0.06 notch) to an upgrade (0.04 notch), and the difference is statistically significant (t = -1.78; p-value = 0.07). Regarding debt-to-GDP, the program group moves from 63.9 percent prior to the program implementation, to 58.4 percent during the treatment period, and the difference is also statistically significant (t = 1.99; p-value = 0.04). Finally, a similar picture emerges from the fiscal balance, which improves from -2.96 percent before the program to -2.45 percent during the program, the difference being statistically significant (t = -1.87, p-value = 0.06). In addition, Table 12 also points out that the treatment group experiences a more favorable change in sovereign credit rating and a lower debt and fiscal deficit ratios during the treatment period compared to the synthetic control group. These findings lead us to conclude that the improvements in sovereign credit rating, debt, and fiscal deficit are some channels through which IMF-supported programs decrease the probability of subsequent debt crises in program countries, compared to nonprogram countries.

Table 12:

Transmission channels

article image
Notes: This Table presents the transmission channels of the effect of IMF-supported programs on the probability of subsequent sovereign debt crises.

VIII. Conclusion

In this paper, we analyze the role of bailouts in mitigating the likelihood of subsequent sovereign defaults in developing countries, taking IMF-supported programs as an example. We contribute to the literature on the impacts of bailouts in several grounds, including (i) drawing upon a large sample of 106 developing countries, (ii) using a comprehensive database on defaulted government debt, and (iii) properly taking into account the endogeneity of the IMF’s presence in a country.

Our result indicates that IMF-supported programs significantly reduce the likelihood of subsequent sovereign debt crises by about 1.3 percentage points. We provide evidence that this finding is particularly robust to different specifications as well as the use of alternative identification strategies including an instrumental variable approach and conventional matchings. Moreover, we provide suggestive evidence that (i) the catalytic role and the liquidity provision channel, (ii) the role of government adjustment effort, and (iii) the conditionality channel may be at work. In particular, we find that a country that signed a program with the Fund experienced a slight improvement in its sovereign credit rating, and a decrease in both government debt-to-GDP and fiscal deficit-to-GDP during the program period compared to the period before. Our results are in line with the theoretical model of Corsetti et al. (2006) that shows that a lending support not only has an impact on the likelihood and the possible incidence of a crisis, but also prompts the borrowing government to implement desirable policies and reforms.

Our results have some policy implications. Although the adoption of an IMF-supported program can be perceived as having a short term political cost related to fiscal consolidation, the empirical results of this paper show that IMF interventions yield long term benefits by helping avoid the costs of sovereign default—such as reputational costs, international trade exclusion costs, costs to the domestic economy through the financial system, and political costs to the authorities—mentioned in the literature (Borensztein and Panizza, 2009).

To conclude, while our paper provides suggestive transmission channels, future research could further disentangle the effects of these different channels. For instance, it would be interesting to assess how different types of IMF-supported programs compare in their stabilization role and also study how programs that involve IMF disbursements compare to those that require only IMF advice.

IX. Reference

  • -

    Abadie, A., Imbens, G.W. 2006. Large sample properties of matching estimators for average treatment effects, Econometrica, 74, 235-267.

  • -

    Alesina, A., Dollar, D. 2000. Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5, 33-63.

  • -

    Alesina, A., Weber, B. 2002. Do corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid? American Economic Review, 92, 1126-1137.

  • -

    Balima, W.H. 2017. Do domestic bond markets participation help reduce financial dollarization in developing countries? Economic Modelling, 66, 146-155.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Balima, W.H., Combes, J-L., Minea, A. 2017. Sovereign debt risk in emerging market economies: Does inflation targeting adoption make any difference? Journal of International Money and Finance, 70, 360-377.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Barro, R. J., Lee, J. W. 2005. IMF-programs: Who is chosen and what are the effects? Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1245-1269.

  • -

    Beers, D., Mavalwalla, J. 2017. Database of Sovereign Defaults, Bank of Canada Technical Report, 101, 1-35.

  • -

    Bird, G. 2001. IMF Programs: Do They Work? Can They be Made to Work Better? World Development, 29, 011, 1849-1865.

  • -

    Bird, G., Rowlands, D. 2002. Do IMF programmes have a catalytic effect on other international capital flows? Oxford Development Studies, 20, 003, 229-249.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Borensztein, E., Panizza, U. 2009. The Costs of Sovereign Default, IMF Staff Papers, 56, 004, 683-741.

  • -

    Boz, E. 2011. Sovereign default, private sector creditors, and the IFIs, Journal of International Economics, 83, 70-82.

  • -

    Brealey, R.A., Kaplanis, E. 2004. The impact of IMF programs on asset values, Journal of International Money and Finance, 23, 253-270.

  • -

    Caliendo, M., Kopeinig, S., 2008. Some practical guidance for the implementation of propensity score matching, Journal of Economic Surveys, 22, 3172-->.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Conway, P. 1994. IMF Lending programs: Participation and impact, Journal of Development Economics, 45, 365-391.

  • -

    Conway, P. 2006. The International Monetary Fund in a time of crisis: a review of Stanley Fischer’s IMF essays from a time of crisis: the international financial system, stabilization, and development, Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 115-144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Corsetti, G., Guimaraes, B., Roubini, N. 2006. International lending of last resort and moral hazard: A model of IMF’s catalytic finance, Journal of Monetary Economics, 53, 441-471.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Cruces, J.J., Trebesch, C. 2013. Sovereign Defaults: The Price of Haircuts, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5, 003, 85-117.

  • -

    Das, U.S., Papaioannou, M.G., Trebesch, C. 2012. Sovereign Debt Restructurings 1950-2010: Literature Survey, Data, and Stylized Facts, IMF wp, 12, 203, 1-127.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Dhonte, P. 1997. Conditionality as an instrument of borrower credibility, IMF paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment, 2, 1-18.

  • -

    Dicks-Mireaux, L., Mecagni, M., Schadler, S. 2000. Evaluating the effect of IMF lending to low-income countries, Journal of Development Economics, 61, 495-526.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Dreher, A. 2004. Does the IMF cause moral hazard? A critical review of the evidence, Unpublished paper, 1-25.

  • -

    Dreher, A., Nunnenkamp, P., Schmaljohann, M. 2015. The Allocation of German Aid: Self-Interest and Government Ideology, Economics & Politics, 27, 160-184.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Dreher, A., Sturm, J-E. 2012. Do the IMF and the World Bank influence voting in the UN General Assembly? Public Choice, 151, 363-397.

  • -

    Dreher, A., Walter, S. 2010. Does the IMF Help or Hurt? The effect of IMF Programs on the Likelihood and Outcome of Currency Crises, World Development, 38, 001, 1-18.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Eaton, J., Gersovitz, M. 1981. Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, Review of Economic Studies, 48, 002, 289-309.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Eichengreen, B. 2015. Coping with Global Volatility: Editor’s Introduction, International Economic Journal, 30:003, 313-321.

  • -

    Eichengreen, B., Gupta, P., Mody, A. 2006. Sudden Stops and IMF-Supported Programs, IMF wp, 06, 101, 1-51.

  • -

    Fink, G., Redaelli, S. 2011. Determinants of international emergency—humanitarian need only? World Development, 35, 741-757.

  • -

    Fink, F., Scholl, A. 2016. A quantitative model of sovereign debt, bailouts and conditionality, Journal of International Economics, 98, 176-190.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Fisher, S. 1997. Applied economics in action: IMF programs, American Economic Review, 87, 002, 23-27.

  • -

    Gande, A., Parsley, D.C. 2005. News spillovers in the sovereign debt market, Journal of Financial Economics, 75, 691-734.

  • -

    Gates, S., Hoeffler, A. 2004. Global Aid Allocation: Are Nordic Donors Different? CSAE wp, 34, 1-34.

  • -

    Gündüz, Y.B. 2016. The Economic Impact of Short-term IMF Engagement in Low-Income Countries, World Development, 87, 30-49.

  • -

    Hainmueller, J. 2012. Entropy balancing for causal effects: A multivariate reweighting method to produce balanced samples in observational studies, Political Analysis, 20, 25-46.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Hardoy, I. 2003. Effect of IMF programmes on growth: A reappraisal using the method of matching. Paper presented at the European Economic Association, Stockholm, 20-24 08 2003.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Harrigan, J., Wang, C., El-Said, H. 2006. The Economic and Political Determinants of IMF and World Bank Lending in the Middle East and North Africa, World Development, 34, 002, 247-270.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Heckman, J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error, Econometrica, 47, 001, 153-161.

  • -

    Independent Evaluation Office. 2007. Structural conditionality in IMF supported programs, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

  • -

    IMF. 2018. Fiscal Monitor: Capitalizing on Good Times, 04 2018, Washington, D.C.

  • -

    Jorra, M. 2012. The effect of IMF Lending on the Probability of Sovereign Debt Crises, Journal of International Money and Finance, 31, 004, 709-725.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Kaminsky, G., Schmukler, S.L. 2002. Emerging Market Instability: Do Sovereign Ratings Affect Country Risk and Stock Returns? World Bank Economic Review, 16, 002, 171-195.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Killick, T. 1995. IMF Programmes in Developing Countries—Design and Impact (London: Routledge).

  • -

    Laeven, L., Valencia, F. 2013. Systemic banking crises database, IMF Economic Review, 61, 002, 225-270.

  • -

    Lin, S., Ye, H. 2007. Does inflation targeting really make a difference? Evaluating the treatment effect of inflation targeting in seven industrial countries, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 2521-2533.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Mody, A., Saravia, D. 2006. Catalysing private capital flows: do IMF programmes work as commitment devices? Economic Journal, 116, 513, 843-867.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Morris, S., Shin, H.S. 2006. Catalytic finance: when does it work? Journal of International Economics, 70, 001, 161-177.

  • -

    Mumssen, C., Gündüz, Y.B., Ebeke, C., Kaltani, L. 2013. IMF-Supported Programs in Low Income Countries: Economic Impact over the Short and Longer Term, IMF wp, 13, 273, 1-63.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Neuenkirch, M., Neumeier, F. 2016. The impact of US sanctions on poverty, Journal of Development Economics, 121, 110-119.

  • -

    Papi, L., Presbitero, A.F., Zazzaro, A. 2015. IMF Lending and Banking Crises, IMF Economic Review, 63, 644-691.

  • -

    Przeworski, A., Vreeland, J.R. 2000. The effect of IMF programs on economic growth, Journal of Development Economics, 62, 002, 385-421.

  • -

    Puhani, P.A. 2002. The Heckman correction for sample selection and its critique, Journal of Economic Surveys, 14, 001, 53-68.

  • -

    Pukthuanthong-Le, K., Elayan, F.A., Rose, L.C. 2007. Equity and debt market responses to sovereign credit ratings announcement, Global Financial Journal, 18, 47-83.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Reinhart, C.M. 2002. Credit ratings, default, and financial crises? Evidence from emerging markets, World Bank Economic Review, 16, 151-170.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Reinhart, C.M., Trebesch, C. 2016. The International Monetary Fund: 70 Years of Reinvention, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30, 001, 3-28.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Reusens, P., Croux, C. 2017. Sovereign credit rating determinants: A comparison before and after the European debt crisis, Journal of Banking and Finance, 77, 108-121.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Saravia, D. 2010. On the role and effects of IMF seniority, Journal of International Money and Finance, 29, 006, 1024-1044.

  • -

    Staiger, D., Stock, J.H. 1997. Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments, Econometrica, 65, 557-586.

  • -

    Suter, C. 1992. Debt Cycles in the World-Economy: Foreign Loans, Financial Crises, and Debt Settlements, Westview Press, 1820-1990.

  • -

    Sy, A.N. 2002. Emerging market bond spreads and sovereign credit ratings: reconciling market views with economic fundamentals, Emerging Market Review, 3, 380-408.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Thacker, S.C. 1999. The High Politics of IMF Lending, World Politics, 52, 010, 177-213.

  • -

    Tirole, J. 2002. Financial Crises, Liquidity, and the International Monetary System, Princeton University Press.

  • -

    Tudela, M., Duggar, E., Metz, A., Oosterveld, B. 2011. Sovereign Default and Recovery Rates, 1983-2010, Moody’s Investors Service, 05 10, 1-44.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Tweedie, A., Hagan, S., Tiwari, S. 2012. Review of the Fund’s Strategy on Overdue Financial Obligations, IMF Policy Papers, 08 20, 1-24.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • -

    Vaubel, R. 1996. Bureaucracy at the IMF and the World Bank: A Comparison of the Evidence, World Economy, 19, 185-210.

  • -

    Vreeland, J.R. 2002. The Effect of IMF Programs on Labor, World Development, 30, 001, 121-139.

  • -

    Zettelmeyer, J. 2000. Can official crisis lending be counterproductive in the short run? Economic Notes, 29, 13-29.

Appendix 1: List of countries having signed at least an IMF-supported program during the sample period.

article image