An Imperfect Financial Union With Heterogeneous Regions*
Author:
Filippo Balestrieri https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Filippo Balestrieri in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Mr. Suman S Basu
Search for other papers by Mr. Suman S Basu in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

We analyze a union of financially-integrated yet politically-sovereign countries, where households in the Northern core of the union lend to those in the Southern periphery in a unified debt market subject to a borrowing constraint. This constraint generates sudden stops throughout the South, depresses the intra-union interest rate, and reduces Northern welfare below its unconstrained level, while having ambiguous effects on Southern welfare. During sudden stops, Pareto improvements can be achieved using North-to-South governmental loans if Southern governments have the capacity to commit to repay, or using a combination of Southern debt relief and budget-neutral taxes and subsidies if they do not. From the pre-crisis perspective, it is Pareto-improving to allow loans and debt relief to be negotiated in later sudden-stop periods as long as the regions in the union are sufficiently heterogeneous to begin with. We show that our results are robust to production and to limited financial openness of the union.

Abstract

We analyze a union of financially-integrated yet politically-sovereign countries, where households in the Northern core of the union lend to those in the Southern periphery in a unified debt market subject to a borrowing constraint. This constraint generates sudden stops throughout the South, depresses the intra-union interest rate, and reduces Northern welfare below its unconstrained level, while having ambiguous effects on Southern welfare. During sudden stops, Pareto improvements can be achieved using North-to-South governmental loans if Southern governments have the capacity to commit to repay, or using a combination of Southern debt relief and budget-neutral taxes and subsidies if they do not. From the pre-crisis perspective, it is Pareto-improving to allow loans and debt relief to be negotiated in later sudden-stop periods as long as the regions in the union are sufficiently heterogeneous to begin with. We show that our results are robust to production and to limited financial openness of the union.

1. Introduction

European integration in the post-WW2 era began with greater openness in goods markets and proceeded over time to the liberalization of markets in services, labor, and the particular focus of our paper, finance. Capital market integration in Europe in the early 2000s took the form of a Northern “core” of economies intermediating debt purchases, from their own savers and from the rest of the world, to help a Southern “periphery” of economies finance their large current account deficits with respect to the rest of the world (Chen et al., 2012).1

But financial integration came with financial frictions. As Europe slid into crisis from 2009 onwards, there was a substantial reversal in North-to-South lending, as the value of the collateral backing the lending was downgraded: firstly, as Giavazzi and Spaventa (2010) observed, tradable output in periphery economies had not kept pace with external debt repayment needs;2 and secondly, the price of collateralizable nontradable assets in the periphery, such as housing, also declined. As a result, the periphery’s current account deficits shrank and turned into surpluses. Using the Calvo et al. (2004) methodology, Merler and Pisani-Ferry (2012) established that the decline in private capital flows into the periphery was severe enough to be classified a “sudden stop.”3 Subsequent analyses using structural models by Martin and Philippon (2014) and Gourinchas et al. (2016) have supported this finding. The impact of financial constraints in the periphery was partially cushioned by low interest rates, the Target 2 mechanism, and new debt-repurchase facilities introduced by the European Central Bank, and by sovereign bailouts from the International Monetary Fund and European supranational institutions.

In this paper, we draw on Europe’s experience to build a model of an “imperfect financial union”—a group of politically-sovereign countries whose debt markets are integrated but suffer from a collateral-based repayment friction.4 These countries are divided into core and periphery regions, with the former lending to the latter because of heterogeneity: the periphery begins with higher inherited debt and/or lower initial endowments. We show that sudden stops in the periphery depress the intra-union interest rate in general equilibrium, and thereby affect the welfare of both core and periphery regions. The endogeneity of the interest rate creates the potential for supranational fiscal policies to generate welfare improvements in a novel manner. Given the politically sovereignty of countries, we restrict our attention to policies that are Pareto-improving, benefiting each country in both the core and the periphery. We eschew restrictions on intra-union capital flows because we take it as given that financial integration is a pre-existing economic imperative.

The basic mechanism is as follows. Inspired by the literature on sudden stops, we assume that all households in the union have a borrowing limit that is equal to a fraction of the value of their future tradable and nontradable outputs. When households in the periphery wish to issue a high level of debt to the core, and when the periphery’s nontradable goods price is low, the periphery’s borrowing constraint binds, which we interpret as a union-wide crisis: an entire region is suffering a sudden stop. If the intra-union interest rate is endogenous—for example, the union is financially closed, or households in the core intermediate funds from the rest of the world to the periphery and earn a premium on such lending—it must decline below the unconstrained level when sudden stops occur. Since the core is a lender region, a decline in the interest rate constitutes a decline in the core’s intertemporal terms of trade, and reduces the welfare of the core’s households relative to the unconstrained allocation. By contrast, periphery households benefit if the constraint is moderately binding, but are worse off if the constraint is severely binding.

Within this environment, there exist Pareto-improving interventions which reverse the constraint-induced declines in interest rates and core-to-periphery lending. We examine two interventions which both accomplish this objective but in rather different ways.

Firstly, a core-to-periphery governmental loan directly increases public capital flows but it also reduces private capital flows (by a smaller amount), because the private sector borrowing limit is tightened as a result of the fall in the nontradable goods price in the period when the loan is repaid. The core is willing to subsidize this governmental loan, because it increases the interest rate on private loans, which in turn benefits the core’s households. The implementation of such a loan requires the periphery’s governments to have fiscal space, i.e., an ability to commit to repay that gets around the private sector’s constraint.

Secondly, we consider an unconventional policy package of debt relief for the periphery today combined with a commitment by the periphery’s governments to tax tradable consumption and subsidize nontradable consumption in a budget-neutral manner in the future. The commitment raises the future nontradable goods price and perhaps also nontradable output, and thereby relaxes the private sector borrowing constraint immediately, boosting private core-to-periphery capital flows. The associated increase in the interest rate benefits the core because it is the lender region, and it can afford to share its welfare gains with the periphery by offering the latter debt relief. Such a policy requires no commitment to repay by the periphery’s governments, just a commitment to implement future fiscal policies.

In section 2, we construct the simplest possible framework that captures the mechanisms described above. Our financial union is endowment-based and has two periods. It features the two regions North and South, each containing a continuum of countries. A common riskless bond is freely traded within the union, but the union is financially closed to the rest of the world (while being open to goods trade). Households in the Southern periphery start off with some debt owed to the Northern core, and when the inherited debt is high, the borrowing constraint binds throughout the South. In this simple model, both governmental loans and the debt relief package can restore the first-best allocation. Bargaining via regional coalitions is able to exploit all Pareto improvements, since the coalitions internalize the effects of their actions on the interest rate in a way that individual countries do not.

Are crisis-time interventions also Pareto-improving from the perspective of earlier periods, when borrowing constraints have yet to bind? In section 3, we show that the answer to this question depends on the union’s degree of heterogeneity in pre-crisis times—i.e., how much more of an endowment the North starts off with relative to the South. If heterogeneity is low, the North rules out beforehand all interventions during crises, because interventions cause higher Southern borrowing and lower Northern consumption in pre-crisis periods. When heterogeneity is moderate or high, however, the ability of interventions to increase the interest rate during crises more than compensates the North for the higher pre-crisis Southern borrowing. Therefore, both regions agree beforehand to establish institutions that can then provide governmental loans and debt relief during regional sudden stops.

How do the optimal policy interventions change when households in the union can borrow from and lend to the rest of the world, and when output is produced instead of endowed? In section 4, we extend our model to address both of these issues.

We show that if both North and South can issue debt to the rest of the world, but there are tight limits on such borrowing, then the equilibrium of the model looks like the environment described in Chen et al. (2012): the North intermediates funds from the rest of the world to the South. In our model, the North earns a riskless premium on such lending, and all of the above results continue to apply because the premium is endogenous.

In an environment where tradable and nontradable goods are produced instead of endowed, both the interventions described above now generate intratemporal distortions. The governmental loan requires a tax on the South’s tradable output in the period of repayment, which depresses tradable production, while the tax-and-subsidy portion of the debt relief package causes excessive Southern production of nontradable output. Therefore, the interventions do not restore any first-best allocation, but instead trace out a second-best frontier. Our general result is that both interventions are always used, each until the marginal reduction in the constraint-induced intertemporal distortion is equal to the marginal increase in the policy-induced intratemporal distortion. Deviating from the second-best combination of interventions reduces the welfare gains for both North and South. Excessive use of the governmental loan generates an excessively large union-wide current account surplus, while excessive use of the tax-subsidy intervention has the opposite effect.

Related Literature. This paper draws on an extensive literature on borrowing constraints and sudden stops in emerging markets.5 Closest to our paper are works by Jeanne and Korinek (2013) and Benigno et al. (2013, 2016), which have moved beyond pre-crisis interventions that reduce the risk of crises,6 to the kinds of policies that we focus on in this paper: crisis-time interventions that make crises less painful. However, our results diverge from those in the literature because of the change in setting: while most papers to date have focused on an individual country facing an exogenous interest rate, we examine a continuum of countries in a union with an endogenous interest rate. In Benigno et al. (2016), a contemporaneous tax on tradable consumption and subsidy on nontradable consumption improves welfare for a single borrower country facing an exogenous interest rate. In our model, instead, when a continuum of borrower countries commit to implement such taxes in the future, the interest rate increases, and as a result, it may be that lender countries benefit more than borrower countries. For this reason, debt relief must generally be added to the policy package in order to make sure that borrower countries are also better off.7

The way in which borrowing constraints depress the interest rate in our model is consistent with a growing body of research on debt deleveraging episodes, encompassing both closed-economy and open-economy frameworks.8,9 This literature often assumes that prices are sticky and that there is a zero lower bound on interest rates. In such an environment, fiscal transfers, debt relief, or simply higher fiscal spending in the core, can generate import and export demand spillovers between core and periphery and raise the interest rate above the zero lower bound. Relative to this literature, our use of a flexible-price framework sets aside the zero lower bound issue, and shifts focus from intra-union trade spillovers to intra-union financial spillovers. In our core-periphery model, the interest rate reflects the core’s intermediation return from financing consumption in the periphery—even if all of the periphery’s imports come from the rest of the world. Pareto improvements then involve raising the interest rate while providing some compensation to the periphery for this change.10

Our focus on the financial aspects of integration and our assumption of flexible prices separates our work from the literature on optimal currency areas. This substantial body of research, initiated by Mundell (1961) in an era of global trade integration and limited financial flows, focuses on asymmetric shocks to export demand within a currency union that has (implicitly or explicitly) sticky prices.11 While exchange rate flexibility is generally enough to restore post-shock Pareto efficiency in that literature, our results in this paper can be interpreted as showing that it is no longer such a powerful instrument when intra-union capital flows are large enough to trigger regional sudden stops.12 In this new environment, inter-regional lending and debt relief institutions need to be built.

Finally, this paper is informed by the literature on European capital flows that has emerged since the recent crisis.13 While some authors have proposed adding impediments to capital flows,14 our work falls instead within the strand of papers which have examined policies to stabilize economic activity while taking higher financial integration as given.15

2. A Simple Financial Union

The main contribution of this paper is the potential for Pareto-improving policies in a financially-integrated union of countries, when the union is composed of heterogeneous regions and one of those regions is experiencing a sudden stop. In this section, we build the intuition for this result by proving it in a simple two-period financially-closed union containing endowment economies. In later sections, we generalize the result to models with more periods, with financial openness of the union to the rest of the world, and with production. All proofs of lemmas and propositions are contained in the appendix.

2.1. The Environment

Our financial union F has two regions i ∈ {N, S}, where N is the Northern core and S is the Southern periphery. Each region is composed of a unit measure of countries j ∈ [0,1], and each country in turn contains a government and a unit measure of identical households who consume tradable and nontradable goods. There also exist unmodeled countries outside the financial union, in the rest of the world ROW. There are two periods, t ∈ {1, 2}.

Households. The representative household in country j of region i has log preferences:

U i , j = ( l o g c T 1 i , j + ν 1 o g c N T 1 i , j ) + ( l o g c T 2 i , j + ν l o g c N T 2 i , j ) , ( 1 )

where cTti,jandcNTti,j are respectively the consumption of tradable and nontradable goods in country j of region i in period t, and ν captures the taste for nontradable goods. Tradable goods can be transported costlessly within the union and outside it, while nontradable goods are country-specific. Households face the following budget and borrowing constraints:

c T 1 i , j + p 1 i , j c N T 1 i , j + ( 1 + τ i , j ) c T 2 i , j + ( 1 η i , j ) p 2 i , j c N T 2 i , j r 2 i , j b 1 i , j + y T 1 + p 1 i , j y N T 1 + x i , j + y T 2 + p 2 i , j y N T 2 + z i , j r 2 i , j ( 2 )
b 2 i , j r 2 i , j ( c T 1 i , j + p 1 i , j c N T 1 i , j + b 1 i , j y T 1 p 1 i , j y N T 1 x i , j ) ϕ ( y T 2 + p 2 i , j y N T 2 + z i , j ) , ( 3 )

where tradable goods are the numeraire, pti,j is the (flexible) relative price of nontradable goods in country j of region i in period t, yTt and yNTt are respectively the endowments of tradable and nontradable goods common to all countries in period t, bti,j is the inherited debt of each household in country j of region i at the beginning of period t, r2i,j is the interest rate on borrowing and lending faced by that household between periods 1 and 2, ϕ ∈ (0,1) is the fraction of period-2 endowments that is pledgable as collateral against borrowing in period 1, xi,j and zi,j are the lump-sum transfers or taxes (depending on the sign) provided by the government to each household under its authority in periods 1 and 2 respectively, and τi,j and ηi,j are respectively a tax on the consumption of tradable goods and a subsidy on the consumption of nontradable goods imposed by the government in period 2.

Households begin period 1 with inherited debt b1i,j. The borrowing constraint (3) on b2i,j, based on the value of future tradable and nontradable endowments, is inspired by the sudden stops literature.16 When this constraint is binding for a country in our model, we say that the country is experiencing a sudden stop. The potential for government policies to generate Pareto improvements depends on the form of this constraint.

The household’s first-order conditions are:

( 1 + τ i , j ) c T 2 i , j r 2 i , j c T 1 i , j ( 4 )
ν c T 1 i , j = p 1 i , j c N T 1 i , j ( 5 )
( 1 + τ i , j ) ν c T 2 i , j = ( 1 η i , j ) p 2 i , j c N T 2 i , j . ( 6 )

The intertemporal Euler condition (4) holds with equality when the borrowing constraint (3) is slack, but with inequality when the constraint is strictly binding. The intratemporal conditions (5) and (6) hold irrespective of whether the borrowing constraint is binding.

Government. Each government is benevolent. It can tax or subsidize the households in its own country and exchange goods with other countries’ governments.

We assume that all households in each country are treated identically, so that governments do not make transfers between different households inside the same country. Then the implementation of lump-sum transfers and taxes requires coordinated domestic and foreign actions: if xi,j or zi,j are greater than zero, the government provides identical transfers to all domestic households using funds collected from foreign governments; while if xi,j or zi,j are less than zero, the government imposes domestic lump-sum taxes and uses the revenues to fund transfers to foreign governments.

By contrast, we assume that taxes and subsidies on consumption are budget-neutral within each country:

τ i , j c T 2 i , j = η i , j p 2 i , j c N T 2 i , j . ( 7 )

We can use the tools {xi,j,zi,j,τi,j,ηi,j}i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1], to design two policy packages—which we call “interventions”—requiring different degrees of commitment by the government.

  • Governmental loans: lump-sum taxes and transfers {xi,j,zi,j}i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1], whereby some governments provide funds to others in period 1 and get repaid in period 2. This intervention requires the recipient governments in period 1 to be able to commit to repay in period 2, getting around the private sector’s borrowing constraint (3).

  • Tax-subsidy with debt relief: lump-sum taxes and transfers in period 1 which are not repaid, but are followed by budget-neutral taxes and subsidies on consumption in period 2, {xi,j,τi,j,ηi,j}i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1]. This intervention requires governments in period 1 to be able to commit to undertake specific fiscal policy actions in period 2, but not to be able to commit to repay.

Imperfect financial union. The financial union F is defined such that within it, there is a common riskless bond and no government-imposed restrictions on capital flows. Therefore, households in all countries inside the union borrow and lend at the same interest rate:

r 2 i , j = r 2 f o r a l l i , j . ( 8 )

Nevertheless, as we have seen above, financial integration is not perfect because of the borrowing constraint (3), which reflects the limited pledgability of future endowments.

In this section, our financial union is both financially and politically closed to the rest of the world. Financial closure means that although households can exchange exports and imports with the rest of the world, they cannot borrow or lend outside the union. Political closure means that government transfers cannot be financed using resources from outside the union. These two notions of closure give rise respectively to the following two conditions:

Σ i { N , S } 0 1 b t i , j d j = 0 for all t ( 9 )
Σ i { N , S } 0 1 x i , j d j = Σ i { N , S } 0 1 z i , j d j = 0. ( 10 )

Now we can characterize the market-clearing conditions for the financial union. Firstly, by definition, the market for nontradable goods must clear within each country j:

c N T t i , j = y N T t for all i , j , t . ( 11 )

Secondly, combining equations (2) and (7)-(11), we establish that even if countries inside the union import and export tradable goods from and to the rest of the world ROW, it must be that the total tradable consumption equals the total tradable endowments within the union in each period t ∈ {1,2}:

Σ i { N , S } 0 1 c T t i , j d j = 2 y T t for all t . ( 12 )

Heterogeneous regions. A region i ∈ {N, S} is defined such that within each region i, the inherited debt levels are common across all countries j:

b 1 i , j = b 1 i for all i , j . ( 13 )

Therefore, at the beginning of period 1, one region owes all of its inherited debt to the other region. We assume that the Southern periphery is the borrower region:

b 1 S = b 1 N ( 0 , ( b 1 S ) max ) , ( 14 )

where (b1S)max is the highest value of inherited debt consistent with non-negative Southern consumption in period 1. Since all countries within the same region are identical, we focus on interventions such that all governments within the same region follow identical policies:

x i , j = x i , z i , j = z i , τ i , j = τ i , and η i , j = η i for all i , j . ( 15 )

We are interested in interventions such that the Northern core provides transfers to the Southern periphery in period 1, followed either by transfers in the reverse direction in period 2, or by taxes and subsidies on Southern consumption in period 2:

x S = x N > 0 , z S = z N 0 , a n d τ S , η S 0 , τ N = η N = 0. ( 16 )

Substituting conditions (8), (13), and (15) into the household’s optimization problem establishes that the equilibrium variables are identical for all countries j within each region i:

c T t i , j = c T t i c N T t i , j = c N T t i = y N T t , a n d p t i , j = p t i for all  i , j , t . ( 17 )

Therefore, we suppress country superscripts in favor of regional superscripts below. This notational choice keeps the focus on regional heterogeneity, while in the background we keep in mind that each region is composed of a continuum of countries who do not have any market power on their own.

Competitive equilibrium allocations. A rational expectations equilibrium is a set of prices and {r2i,j,{pti,j,cTti,j,cNTti,j}t{1,2}}i{N,S},j[0,1] which satisy the households constraints and first-order conditions, (2)-(6), the government’s budget constraint (7), the nontradable goods market clearing condition (11), and the financial-integration and market-clearing conditions for the union, (8) and (12), subject to the set of inherited debt levels and government policies {b1i,j,xi,j,zi,j,τi,j,ηi,j}i{N,S},j[0,1] defined by equations (13)-(16).

Our problem simplifies to characterizing the prices and allocations {r2,p2S,cT1S,cT2S,cT1N} as a function of {b1S,xS,zN,τS}, using the following equations:

2 c T 1 N = b 1 S + y T 1 x S + y T 2 + z N r 2 ( 18 )
c T 1 S + c T 2 S r 2 = b 1 S + y T 1 + x S + y T 2 z N r 2 ( 19 )
R 2 S c T 2 S c T 1 S r 2 1 + τ S ( 20 )
b 2 S r 2 ( c T 1 S + b 1 S y T 1 x S ) ϕ ( y T 2 + p 2 S y N T 2 z N ) ( 21 )
p 2 S y N T 2 = ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) c T 2 S ( 22 )
c T 1 S + c T 1 N = 2 y T 1 , ( 23 )

and then backing out the implicit variables {{p1i=νcT1iyNT1}i{N,S},p2N=νcT2NyNT2,cT2N=r2cT1NηS=τScT2Sp2SyNT2}. Equations (20) and (21) hold with complementary slackness, and Walras’ Law allows us to ignore the market-clearing condition for tradable goods in period 2.

R2S is the shadow interest rate on borrowing in the South. It will serve as an indicator of the distortion in equilibrium allocations arising from the borrowing constraint.

2.2. Pareto Efficiency of the Laissez-Faire Equilibrium

First best. The first-best allocation maximizes i{N,S}01λi,jUi,jdj subject to the market-clearing conditions (11) and (12) and the Pareto weights {λi,j}i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1], ignoring the borrowing constraint (3). We assume that the Pareto weights are identical for all countries j within each region i:

λ i , j = λ i f o r a l l i , j . ( 24 )

Lemma 1 (First-best allocation) Irrespective of {λi}i∈{N,S}, the first-best allocation features cT2icT1i=yT2yT1foralli.

As the Pareto weights change, the relative levels of tradable consumption in the North and South change, but for all countries in both regions, the ratio of consumption between the two periods remains fixed at yT2yT1 (which means in particular that the condition R2S=yT2yT1 is satisfied). Nontradable consumption is simply fixed by the endowments {yNTt}t∈{1,2}.

Laissez faire. The laissez-faire equilibrium follows equations (18)-(23), setting xS = zN = τS = 0. The resulting allocations are parameterized by the inherited debt level b1S, and are shown by the solid lines in figure 1. For comparison, the dashed lines in the figure represent the unconstrained equilibrium, i.e., the equilibrium calculated ignoring condition (21).

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Laissez-faire equilibrium

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

In the absence of the borrowing constraint (21), the interest rate is fixed at R2S=r2=yT2yT1, and the unconstrained tradable consumption levels in the North and South follow:

c T 1 N * = 1 2 ( b 1 S + 2 y T 1 ) , c T 1 S * = 1 2 ( b 1 S + 2 y T 1 ) , a n d c T 2 i * = y T 2 y T 1 c T 1 i * f o r a l l i . ( 25 )

So the higher the inherited debt level of the South b1S, the lower the consumption of the South in both periods. But the borrowing constraint (21), combined with equations (19) and (22), imposes a lower bound on Southern consumption in period 2:

c T 2 S c ¯ T 2 S = y T 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν .

As shown in panel I of the figure, the unconstrained level of cT2S violates this bound once the inherited debt b1S is high enough:

b 1 S > b ¯ 1 S = 2 y T 1 ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν .

For these levels of debt, there is a union-wide crisis, because the constraint triggers a sudden stop throughout the Southern periphery. Southern consumption follows instead the expression:

c T 1 S , C = 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν y T 1 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S a n d c T 2 S , C = c ¯ T 2 S , ( 26 )

which is defined for b1Supto(b1S)max=1+3ϕ+4ϕν1+2ϕ+3ϕνyT1. Panel II shows that the interest rate r2 dips below yT2yT1, while the shadow rate R2S rises above it. Such a result is consistent with the research on debt deleveraging episodes (e.g., Guerrieri and Lorenzoni, 2011, Eggertsson and Krugman, 2012, and Fornaro, 2015). In our model, the binding constraint in the Southern periphery of a financial union reduces North-to-South private capital flows (cT1S+b1SyT1) and the South’s eventual debt position b2S (as shown in panel III of the figure), below their unconstrained levels.

Panel IV shows that the effect of the borrowing constraint on welfares in the North and South {Ui,j = Ui}i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1], relative to the welfares in the absence of the constraint {Ui*}i∈{N,S}, is more complicated. The Southern constraint unambiguously reduces the welfare of Northern households. By contrast, Southern households benefit relative to the unconstrained allocation if the inherited debt is moderately above b¯1S (even though the entire South is experiencing a sudden stop!), but they are worse off if the inherited debt is very high. All the above results are summarized in the proposition below.

Proposition 1 (Laissez-faire equilibrium) The laissez-faire equilibrium is a first-best allocation for some Pareto weights {λi}i∈{N,S} when b1S[0,b¯1S], but lies in the interior of the first-best frontier when b1S>b¯1S. In the latter region, cT2S,C=c¯T2SandR2S>yT2yT1>r2. Defining b^1S=6yT1ϕ(1+ν)1+2ϕ+3ϕν(<(b1S)max) welfare levels follow:

U N { = U N * f o r b 1 S [ 0 , b ¯ 1 S ] < U N * f o r b 1 S > b ¯ 1 S a n d U S { = U S * f o r b 1 S [ 0 , b ¯ 1 S ] > U S * f o r b 1 S ( b ¯ 1 S , b ^ 1 S ) < U N * f o r b 1 S > b ^ 1 S .

This welfare result comes from the endogeneity of the interest rate. We can understand the conceptual mechanism in a graphical fashion using two steps: firstly, choose any fixed value of b1S>b¯1S from panel IV of figure 1 and show how varying the pledgability parameter ϕ can take us from the unconstrained to the constrained welfare level; and secondly, apply the lessons of the first step to a variety of levels of b1S.

Panel I of figure 2 illustrates the first step. For b1S>b¯1S, the constraint is strictly binding at the actual value of ϕ, but if we raise the parameter to the value ϕJB which makes the constraint just binding, we can recover the unconstrained regional welfare levels. Then we gradually reduce ϕ from ϕJB to its actual value and explore how constrained regional welfares change according to the equations (18)-(23). Regional welfares are affected by the associated change in r2:

d r 2 = r 2 y T 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) ( 1 + ν ) ( 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 d ϕ d U N = c T 2 N y T 2 r 2 2 c T 1 N d r 2 = y T 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) c T 2 N y T 2 c T 2 N ( 1 + ν ) ( 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 d ϕ d U S = 1 c T 1 S [ y T 2 c T 2 S r 2 2 d r 2 + y T 2 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) ( 1 + ν ) ( 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 d ϕ ] = y T 2 r 2 c T 1 S ( 1 2 y T 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) r 2 R 2 S ) ( 1 + ν ) ( 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 d ϕ .
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Laissez-faire welfare

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

The interest rate r2 declines below yT2yT1 when ϕ decreases and the constraint begins to bind. The welfare of Northern households is hurt because they are “exporters” of saving (cT2NyT2)>0, and the “intertemporal terms of trade” on this saving, r2, is now lower. Southern households benefit from the decline in the interest rate r2 because they are “importers” of saving (yT2cT2S)>0, but they are also hurt by the transfer of consumption from period 1 to period 2, because when R2S>r2, consumption is more valuable in period 1 than in period 2.

The constraint’s impact on Southern welfare depends on how low the actual value of ϕ really is. If the actual value of ϕ is just below ϕJB, the constraint improves Southern welfare, because the “intertemporal terms of trade” effect is the dominant one. Southern constrained welfare continues increasing as ϕ decreases to ϕ*, which occurs when:

R 2 S = r 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) 1 2 y T 2 . ( 27 )

Reducing ϕ further reduces Southern welfare from its peak, and the constrained welfare falls below the unconstrained level if the actual value of ϕ is below ϕL.

The second step is to apply the above reasoning to a variety of levels of b1S. For all b1S>b¯1S, Northern welfare is hurt by the constraint, but the impact on Southern welfare is more complicated. The higher is the level of b1S in panel IV of figure 1, the higher is ϕJB relative to the actual value of ϕ in panel I of figure 2. For b1S just above b¯1S, ϕJB is just above ϕ, so the South benefits from the constraint. For future use, we define b˜1S to be the debt level at which condition (27) is satisfied. When b1Sexceedsb^1S(>b¯1S), ϕJB is far above ϕ, so the South’s constrained welfare falls below its unconstrained level.

Finally, panel II of figure 2 uses the information in the above proposition to plot the unconstrained and constrained welfare frontiers. The higher is b1S, the further up and to the left that the final allocation is located within this panel. The unconstrained allocations (which lie along the dashed first-best frontier) diverge from the constrained allocations (which lie along the solid line) when b1S>b¯1S.

2.3. Pareto-improving Interventions

Although financial markets are integrated across country borders within the union, individual countries are politically sovereign. Accordingly, we assume that union-wide policy interventions must be approved through a bargaining process involving all the governments inside the union. Governments bargain as regional coalitions (to support this notion, we show below that coalitions can exhaust the Pareto gains). Each country and coalition is allowed to veto any interventions which make them worse off than the laissez-faire equilibrium, so this equilibrium is the outside option to the bargaining process.

Formally, we start with a debt level b1S>b¯1S to maximize the Nash product over indirect utility functions:

Π i { N , S } ( U i ( x S , z N , τ S ) U i ( 0 , 0 , 0 ) ) γ i , ( 28 )

subject to the equations (18)-(23), with the bargaining powers of each regional coalition i}i∈{N,S} satisfying γN = 1 — γS ∈ [0,1]. Only policies that make all countries better off relative to the laissez-faire equilibrium—i.e., Pareto-improving interventions—are implementable, and which final allocation is chosen depends on the bargaining powers.

Governmental loan. The first intervention involves {xS > 0, zN > 0, τS = 0} and assumes that the governments of the South have the ability to commit in period 1 to repay in period 2 despite the private sector borrowing constraint (21) being binding. Because of the constraint, the intervention cannot be completely undone by the private sector, and it does affect the allocation. When the constraint binds, Southern variables in period 2 satisfy:

c T 2 S = ( y T 2 z N ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν a n d p 2 S y N T 2 = ν c T 2 S .

To see how the competitive equilibrium alters in response to a governmental loan, first consider small changes in the intervention, dxS > 0 and dzN > 0. Since Northern households are unconstrained while the Southern borrowing constraint is binding, the change in the total consumption of tradable goods in the union in period 2 is:

d ( c T 2 N + c T 2 S ) = 1 2 r 2 d x S + ( 1 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) d z N + 1 2 ( y T 2 + z N ) + ( y T 2 z N c T 2 S ) r 2 d r 2 .

In period 2, the consumption of the North decreases by half the interest-compounded value of the extra transfer dxS and increases by half the extra repayment dzN, while the consumption of the South decreases by the fraction 1ϕ1+ϕν of the extra repayment dzN. Absent a change in the interest rate r2 on private sector loans, the change in total consumption may be positive or negative. To restore market clearing, r2 must adjust so that Northern households optimally tilt their consumption schedule in a manner consistent with the constrained consumption of Southern households:

d r 2 = r 2 1 2 ( y T 2 + z N ) + ( y T 2 z N c T 2 S ) [ 1 2 r 2 d x S ( 1 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) d z N ] .

Welfares in the North and South are affected directly by the transfers and indirectly by the associated change in the interest rate r2:

d U N ( x S , z N , 0 ) = 1 c T 1 N [ d x S + 1 r 2 d z N + y T 2 z N c T 2 S r 2 2 d r 2 ] d U S ( x S , z N , 0 ) = 1 c T 1 S [ d x S + { 1 r 2 + 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν } d z N y T 2 z N c T 2 S r 2 2 d r 2 ] ,

where yT2zNcT2S>0. Northern households are hurt by the higher transfer dxS, but they benefit from the higher repayment dzN and any increase in the interest rate dr2. Southern households experience changes in welfare in the opposite direction. But crucially, the South’s pain from the repayment is mitigated because dzN occurs in period 2, when consumption is less valuable at the margin than it is in period 1.

Because R2S>r2 in the constrained equilibrium, Pareto improvements are possible. Any increase in the private market interest rate, dr2 > 0, generated by a governmental loan benefits the North and hurts the South by shifting consumption in period 2 from the South to the North. The North can compensate the South by transferring extra tradable goods to the South in period 1. R2S>r2 means that the South values each extra unit of consumption more than the North does in period 1, so the North finds it possible to raise the welfare of the South through period 1 transfers, while remaining better off itself.

Formally, combining the above equations:

d U i ( x S , z N , 0 ) | d U i ( x S , z N , 0 ) = 0 = 1 c T 1 i 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν d z N f o r a l l i ,

which establishes that Pareto-improving governmental loans are possible for R2S>r2. Within the set of such interventions:

d r 2 = ρ x z ( γ N ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν r 2 1 2 ( y T 2 + z N ) + 1 2 ( y T 2 z N c T 2 S ) d Z N ,

where ρxz(γN)[12(1+r2R2S),1]>0anddρxzdγN<0. Therefore, the intervention is designed so that the interest rate r2 increases—although the less so the higher is the North’s bargaining power. Figure 3 shows the effects of a Pareto-improving loan, indexing the loan size by zN. As zN increases, the South’s consumption in period 1 increases and its consumption in period 2 decreases. The interest rate r2 increases, and the shadow rate R2S decreases, toward yT2yT1.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Impact of intervention

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

Panel III shows that the North-to-South governmental loan causes a contraction in the South’s private debt position b2S with respect to the North. The repayment zN reduces the South’s available tradable goods and depresses the price of its nontradable goods in period 2. Both of these effects tighten the private sector borrowing constraint (21) in period 1:

d p 2 S < 0 a n d d b 2 S < 0.

We can now illustrate how a Pareto-improving intervention begins and ends. The intervention begins as a small loan from the starting point b1S>b¯1S and xs = zN = 0. Defining the interest rate on the governmental loan as rNSzNxS (which for a small intervention is equal to dzNdxS, we can show in panel I of figure 4 the minimum interest rate the North is willing to accept, rminNS, and the maximum interest rate the South is willing to pay, rmaxNS:

r min N S = r 2 1 2 y T 2 + 1 2 ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) 1 2 y T 2 + ( 1 2 + 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) < r max N S = r 2 1 2 y T 2 + 1 2 ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) ( 1 2 1 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) y T 2 + ( 1 2 + r 2 R 2 S 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) .
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

How intervention begins

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

rminNS is downward-sloping and lower than r2: the Northern coalition is willing to subsidize the governmental loan because it increases the private market interest rate r2, which benefits the North’s (saver) households. The upward-sloping dashed line representing rmaxNS is lower than r2 for b1S(b¯1S,b˜1S) (when R2S is below the value required for condition (27)) and higher than r2 for b1S(b¯1S,b˜1S) (when R2S is above the required value).

In this panel, we can see why we assumed that governments bargain via regional coalitions. Coalitions internalize the effects of their actions on the union-wide interest rate r2, which individual countries do not. If the coalitions were to ignore their effects on the union-wide interest rate r2, then the Northern coalition would only accept interest rates above r2, while the Southern coalition would accept any interest rate below R2S. If such loans are agreed, they would not in general lead to Pareto improvements, because the resulting increase in r2 itself would shift too much of the welfare gains to the North at the expense of the South. Only in the blue region of the graph would Pareto improvements be achieved. On the other hand, when coalitions internalize the effects of their actions on r2, they can achieve Pareto improvements in both the pink and blue regions.

Panels I and II of figure 5 illustrate in shaded gray the zone of Pareto-improving actions in the (xS, zN) space for any b1S>b¯1S. The values of rNS derived above for the beginning of the intervention determine the upper slope (rmaxNS, representing γN = 1) and lower slope (rminNS, representing γN = 0) of the gray zone at the origin (0,0). Pareto-improving interventions are possible as long as R2S>r2, and the intervention continues until all Pareto gains are exhausted. The blue line represents the final interventions that solve (28) subject to (18)-(23), indexed by γN ∈ [0,1]:

x S = b 1 S 2 y T 1 ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν z N y T 1 y T 2 ( 1 ϕ ) ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν . ( 29 )
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

How intervention ends

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

Panel I assumes that ϕ<12+ν(1ϕ)ϕ(1+ν)>0, while panel II assumes the opposite sign for the inequality.17 Along the blue line, the intertemporal ratio of consumption is fixed at cT2icT1i=R2S=r2=yT2yT1 for all i, i.e., the allocations are along the first-best frontier. The bargaining power of the North γN determines which point on the line is chosen, and thereby the levels of consumption in each region. For both panels, the higher is γN, the larger the period-2 repayment to the North, zN, the higher is the interest rate rNSzNxS on the governmental loan, and the more that the South’s private debt position b2S declines relative to the laissez-faire equilibrium. The upper and lower ends of the blue line represent respectively the allocations for γN = 1 and γN = 0:

c T 1 S , γ N = 1 = y T 1 ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν a n d c T 2 S , γ N = 1 = y T 2 y T 1 c T 1 S , γ N = 1 ( 30 )
c T 1 S , γ N = 0 = 2 y T 1 y T 1 ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 ϕ + 2 φ ν 1 + ϕ ν a n d c T 2 S , γ N = 0 = y T 2 y T 1 c T 1 S , γ N = 0 . ( 31 )

If Northern governments have a limited ability to tax in period 1, i.e., xS ≤ (xS)max, or if Southern governments have a limited ability to repay in period 2, i.e., zN(zN)max, then Pareto gains may not be exhausted for some values of γN, and the final intervention lies instead along the dashed red line.18 The proposition below summarizes the above results.

Proposition 2 (Governmental loan) When b1S>b¯1S, a governmental loan achieves a Pareto improvement relative to the laissez-faire equilibrium. When the loan size is unlimited, bargaining between North and South achieves an allocation on the first-best frontier satisfying (29) and zN ∈ [zN,γN=0,zN,γN=1], where zN=0 < zN=1 and dzNdγN>0.b1S is lower than in the laissez-faire equilibrium. When the loan size is limited, the frontier of achievable allocations is a piecewise combination of the first-best frontier and the relevant constraint.

Taking stock, we have shown how an intervention of any size (whether unlimited or not) achieves a Pareto improvement, by tracing out the intervention’s effect on the endogenous union-wide interest rate r2, the consumption levels in North and South {cTti}i{N,S}, and the Southern debt position b2S accumulated via North-to-South private debt flows. We have also rationalized region-based coalitional bargaining. If the size of North-to-South governmental loans is unlimited, the financial union is restored to the first-best frontier. These lessons will prove valuable as we consider alternative interventions, and as we extend the model to allow for financial openness of the union and for production.

Tax-subsidy with debt relief. The second intervention involves {xS > 0,zN = 0,τS > 0} and assumes that the government of the South has the ability to commit in period 1 to undertake budget-neutral fiscal actions in period 2, but is unable to commit to repay foreigners in period 2. Since the North-to-South transfer xs is never repaid, we label it as debt relief. When the constraint binds, Southern variables in period 2 satisfy:

c T 2 S = y T 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) a n d p 2 S y N T 2 = ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) c T 2 S .

Again, we first consider small changes in the intervention, {dxS > 0 and S > 0. The total consumption of tradable goods in the union in period 2 is altered as follows:

d ( c T 2 N + c T 2 S ) = 1 2 r 2 d x S c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S + 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) r 2 d r 2 .

The tax on the consumption of tradable goods and subsidy on the consumption of nontradable goods in the South in period 2 generates an increase in the price of nontradable goods p2S in that period, which relaxes the private sector borrowing constraint. Southern households are able to borrow more in period 1 and need to repay more in period 2, so the consumption of the South in the latter period falls, as captured by the second term in the above equation. The consumption of the North in period 2 decreases by half the interest-compounded value of the debt relief dxS. To restore market clearing, the interest rate r2 must rise, which affects welfares in the North and South:

d r 2 = r 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) [ 1 2 r 2 d x S + c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S ] . d U N ( x S , 0 , τ S ) = 1 c T 1 N [ d x S + y T 2 c T 2 S r 2 2 d r 2 ] d U S ( x S , 0 , τ S ) = 1 c T 1 S [ d x S + 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S y T 2 c T 2 S r 2 2 d r 2 ] ,

where yT2cT2S>0. Northern households are hurt by the higher transfer dxS, but they benefit from the higher interest rate dr2. Southern households experience changes in welfare in the opposite direction. Crucially, they also benefit from the relaxation of the constraint: S > 0 allows consumption to be moved from period 2 to period 1, when it is more valuable.

Again, because R2S>r2 in the constrained equilibrium, Pareto improvements are possible. The increase in the interest rate, dr2 > 0, generated by the tax-subsidy policy shifts consumption in period 2 from the South to the North and raises period-1 consumption in the South. If the South is worse off after this change, the North can compensate the South by transferring tradable goods as debt relief to the South in period 1, while remaining better off itself. Combining the above equations, we formally confirm this result and we derive the bounds for the increase in the interest rate:

d U i ( x S 0 , τ S ) | d U i ( x S , 0 , τ S ) = 0 = 1 c T 1 i 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S f o r a l l i . d r 2 = ρ x τ ( γ N ) r 2 1 2 y T 2 + 1 2 ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d T S ,

where ρxτ(γN)[12(1+γ2R2S),1]>0anddρxτdγN<0. Figure 3 shows the effects of a Pareto-improving tax-subsidy policy with debt relief, indexing the size of the intervention by τS. As the intervention size increases, Southern consumption in period 1 increases at the expense of its consumption in period 2, the interest rate r2 increases, and the shadow rate R2S decreases. Panel III shows that in contrast to the governmental loan intervention, a tax-subsidy policy with debt relief causes an expansion in the South’s private debt position b2S with respect to the North:

d p 2 S > 0 and d p 2 S > 0.

Next, we illustrate how a Pareto-improving intervention begins and ends. The intervention begins with b1S>b¯1S and xS = τS = 0. Defining the debt relief coefficient gNSxSτS as the debt relief per unit of promised tax (which for a small intervention is equal to dxSdτS, we show in panel II of figure 4 the minimum debt relief coefficient the South is willing to accept, gminNS, and the maximum coefficient the North is willing to offer, gmaxNS:

g min N S = 1 r 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) 1 2 y T 2 + 1 2 ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) ( r 2 R 2 S 1 2 y T 2 1 2 y T 2 + ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) ) c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν < g max N S = 1 r 2 ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) 1 2 y T 2 + 1 2 ( y T 2 c T 2 S ) c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν .

gmaxNS is higher than 0: the North is willing to provide debt relief to the South in period 1, because the South’s commitment to a budget-neutral tax-subsidy policy in period 2 increases the market interest rate r2, which benefits the North’s households. The downward-sloping dashed gminNS is above 0 for b1S(b¯1S,b˜1S) but below 0 for b1S>b˜1S. In other words, for very high debt levels, the South is willing to undertake the tax-subsidy policy even in the absence of debt relief, because the movement of consumption from period 2 to period 1 owing to the relaxation of the borrowing constraint (21) is very valuable.

Again, region-based coalitional bargaining is helpful to exploit all the Pareto gains. If the coalitions were to ignore their effects on the union-wide interest rate r2, then the Northern coalition would be unwilling to provide any debt relief at all, and only the Pareto improvements in the blue region of the graph would be achieved. By contrast, coalitional bargaining that correctly treats r2 as endogenous is able to achieve Pareto improvements in both the pink and blue regions.

Panels III, IV, and V of figure 5 illustrate in shaded gray the zone of Pareto-improving actions in (xS, zN) space, for three different levels of b1Saboveb˜1S.19 The values of gNS derived above for the beginning of the intervention determine the upper slope (gminNS, representing γN = 1) and lower slope (gmaxNS, representing γN = 0) of the gray zone at the origin (0,0).20 For b1S>b˜1S,gminNS<0, so the upper slope is negative. The blue line represents the final interventions that solve (28) subject to (18)-(23), indexed by γN ∈ [0,1]:

x S = b 1 S 2 y T 1 ϕ ( 1 + ν + τ S + ν τ S ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) . ( 32 )

Along this line, cT2icT1i=R2S=r2=yT2yT1 for all i, so the allocations are again along the first-best frontier—just like for the governmental loan. And the left and right ends of the blue line achieve the same consumption levels as the governmental loan does: equations (30) and (31). The higher the bargaining power of the North γN, the smaller the period-1 debt relief for the South, xS, and the larger the period-2 tax and subsidy combination imposed by the South, τS, so the lower is the debt relief coefficient gNSxSτS. The North uses its bargaining power to push the South to implement budget-neutral policies that improve the pledgability of the South’s future endowments, so that Northern households can exploit the correspondingly higher interest rate. In fact, the higher is γN, the more that the South’s private debt position b1S increases relative to the laissez-faire equilibrium.

Notice that for b1S>b^1S, γN = 1 is associated with negative debt relief: xS < 0. As described above, for very high debt levels, the South is willing to undertake the tax-subsidy policy even without debt relief. Then, for the North to extract all the welfare gains, the South needs to provide a transfer to the North instead.

If Northern governments have a limited ability to provide debt relief in period 1, i.e., xS ≤ (xS)max, or if Southern governments face a maximum politically-acceptable tax rate, i.e., τS ≤ (τS)max, then Pareto gains are not exhausted, and the final intervention lies instead along the dashed red line. The proposition below summarizes the above results.

Proposition 3 (Tax-subsidy with debt relief) When b1S>b¯1S, a tax-subsidy policy with debt relief achieves a Pareto improvement relative to the laissez-faire equilibrium. When the debt relief and tax rate are unlimited, bargaining between North and South achieves an allocation on the first-best frontier satisfying (32) and τS ∈ [τS,γN=0, τS,γN=1], where τS,γN=0 <, τS,γN=1 and dτSdγN>0.b2S is higher than in the laissez-faire equilibrium. When the debt relief or tax rate are unlimited, the frontier of achievable allocations is a piecewise combination of the first-best frontier and the relevant constraint.

Propositions 2 and 3 are closely related: they establish that each intervention on its own can achieve all the Pareto-improving allocations on the first-best frontier, provided that there are no limits on the intervention sizes. The sets [xS,γN=0, xS,γN=1] generated by the propositions 2 and 3 are not identical: the debt relief necessary to achieve any given allocation is smaller than the size of the necessary period-1 governmental loan, because the latter’s effect on Southern consumption is partially undone by the period-2 repayment zN.

Combining the interventions. In this endowment-based financial union, the two interventions described above are substitutes: the analytic work underlying propositions 2 and 3 can be easily combined to establish that in the absence of limits on the tools {xs,zNs}, every Pareto-improving allocation on the first-best frontier can be achieved by using many different combinations of the two interventions. The more that the governmental loan is used relative to the debt relief package within the combination, the higher are public capital flows and the lower are private capital flows within the union.

Therefore, if there are limits on one of the policy tools, then any Pareto gains which remain unexploited by using one intervention alone should be achieved by utilizing the other intervention as well.

2.4. Discussion

North-to-South capital flows. The heterogeneous structure of our financial union means that there are capital flows from the lender households of the North to the borrower households of the South. Our Pareto improvements are based on reversing the decline in these capital flows during crisis periods.

Unlike the monetary union literature, where sticky prices typically underlie the rationale for intervention (e.g., Galí and Monacelli, 2008, and Farhi and Werning, 2013a), our results are strengthened in an environment where prices—specifically, collateral prices p2S —are flexible: sudden stops become more severe when they strike, and Pareto improvements become possible even when fiscal space is lacking. In addition, in contrast to many papers emphasizing the zero lower bound on interest rates (e.g., Dogra, 2014, and Blanchard et al, 2015), our welfare gains do not come from the North and South spending more on each other’s goods. Our results hold when all countries in the union only export to and import from the rest of the world; what we need is that the North finances the external deficits of the South, so that the North gains from improvements in the terms of its financing.

Endogeneity of the interest rate is key. When Benigno et al. (2016) consider a contemporaneous tax-subsidy policy by a single borrower country facing an exogenous interest rate, they find that the borrower country is unambiguously better off. By contrast, in our financial union, a promise of future taxes and subsidies in the South raises the interest rate today, which generates welfare gains for the North—so much so that debt relief may need to be added to the policy package in order to make sure that the South is also better off.

Pledgability interpretation. The interventions work by making Southern period-2 endowments more pledgable as collateral against borrowing in period 1. The governmental loan works because in the repayment period, the government transforms the partially pledgable tradable endowments yT2 of Southern households into fully pledgable revenues from lump-sum taxation zN. The tax-subsidy intervention works by raising the price of the pledgable nontradable endowments yNT2 of Southern households, while keeping the pledgable value of tradable endowments unchanged.

More precisely, the tax-subsidy intervention works because it raises the price of collateralizable nontradable goods and/or assets. In practice, this should not be interpreted as a generalized real exchange rate support that subsidizes all nontradable goods. To underline this point, let us extend the above model to include an additional non-collateralizable nontradable sector with endowments, consumption levels, and prices {yMt,cMti,j,qti,j}i{N,S},j[0,1],t{1,2}. Then the nontradable goods {yNTt}t∈{1,2} can be interpreted as representing housing, which is collateralizable, while {yMt}t∈{1,2} represents haircuts, which are not.

Suppose that a subsidy θi,j can be provided on the consumption of these new goods, amending each government’s budget constraint:

τ i , j c τ j 2 i , j = η i , j p 2 i , j c N T 2 i , j + θ i , j q 2 i , j c M 2 i , j .

The upper bound on b2i,j for each household continues to be tied to {yT2, yNT2} only, but the utility function is amended with the additional terms t{1,2}γ1ogcMti,j, which results in an additional intra-temporal first-order condition for consumption:

( 1 + τ i , j ) γ c T 2 i , j = ( 1 θ i , j ) q 2 i , j c M 2 i , j .

Assuming as before that all variables are identical within regions, the system of equations (18)-(23) remains the same, except that equation (22) changes to:

p 2 S c N T 2 S = [ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) θ S 1 θ S ( γ + γ τ S ) ] c T 2 S .

We can show that in this amended setup, a small tax-subsidy intervention with debt relief, beginning at b1S>b¯1S and xS = rS = θS = 0, generates:

d U i | d U i = 0 = 1 c T 1 i 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S ) c T 2 S 1 + ϕ ν { ϕ ( 1 + ν ) d τ S γ ϕ d θ S } f o r a l l i .

Therefore, the government should tax non-collateralizable nontradable goods, and use the revenues to subsidize collateralizable nontradable goods. The following lemma holds.

Lemma 2 (Non-collateralizable nontradable goods) When the policy tools (xS, τS) are unlimited, an additional subsidy θS > 0 does not change the result in proposition 3 that bargaining between North and South achieves an allocation on the first-best frontier. However, when either tool is limited, bargaining will result in θS < 0.

Transfer effect. How does the effect of a pure transfer dxs > 0 in our model relate to the “transfer effect” highlighted in Keynes (1929) and Ohlin (1929)? They find that the country providing the transfer loses both from the goods no longer in the country and also from a decline in the country’s intratemporal terms of trade. Since our model does not have differentiated tradable goods and home bias, we cannot replicate their finding. Instead, our model adds a new countervailing finding into the mix: we demonstrate that in the presence of binding borrowing constraints, a transfer to the set of countries facing such constraints changes the intertemporal terms of trade in a direction that benefits the saver countries providing the transfer—namely, it increases the interest rate r2. Therefore, the countries providing the transfer actually recoup some, but not all, of the cost of providing the transfer. This result is summarized in the lemma below, which draws on the previous subsection.

Lemma 3 (Transfer effect) When b1S>b¯1S, a pure transfer dxS > 0 generates dr2 > 0 and dUN(xS,0,0)=1cT1N[dxS+yT2cT2Sr22dr2](1cT1NdxS,0).

Coalitional bargaining. We have used the assumption of a continuum of countries inside each region, rather than a single country in each region, for two purposes. Firstly, we wished to illustrate that even in a union of many small countries, regional bargaining may be beneficial: regional coalitions internalize the effects of their actions on the interest rate r2, and as a result, they are able to exhaust the Pareto gains. Secondly, we wanted to give a sense that the process for approval of interventions in a union containing many countries may not be straightforward. Indeed, it may be desirable to set up union-wide institutions before a crisis occurs. In this light, we turn next to pre-crisis institutional design.

3. Pre-crisis Heterogeneity and Institutional Design

Our analysis so far suggests that for Pareto gains to be effectively exploited during crises, the financial union requires institutions which implement governmental loans and debt relief packages, and which help individual countries gather into regional bargaining coalitions. But will such institutions have been set up and made functional by the time that crises arrive? In pre-crisis times, before borrowing constraints bind, all the countries inside the financial union should decide whether to set up these institutions and which values of the bargaining power parameter, γN = 1 —γS ∈ [0,1], are acceptable. The institutions are brought into existence if and only if for some values of γN, regional bargaining during crises is also Pareto-improving from the pre-crisis perspective.

To tackle this issue, we endogenize b1S, the inherited debt of the South in the model of the previous section, as the outcome of a deterministic environment with pre-crisis endowments and consumption decisions. Specifically, we add one pre-crisis period onto the model of section 2, and assume that the North starts off with a higher endowment than the South.

3.1. The Pre-crisis Environment

There is one additional period, t = 0, just before the model in section 2.1. Correspondingly, we need to define some new variables and impose some additional constraints.

Households. The representative household in country j of region i has the amended log preferences:

V i , j = ( l o g c T , 1 i , j + ν l o g c N T , 1 i , j ) + ( l o g c T 0 i , j + ν l o g c N T 0 i , j ) + U i , j , ( 33 )

where cTti,jandcNTti,j are respectively the consumption of tradable and nontradable goods in country j of region i in period t, and Ui,j follows equation (1). The debt of the household in country j of region i at the beginning of period 1 is pinned down by the household’s budget constraint:

b 1 i , j r 1 i , j ( c T 0 i , j + p 0 i , j c N T 0 i , j e i , j p 0 i , j y N T 0 ) , ( 34 )

where ei,j is the tradable endowment of each household in country j of region i in period 0, yNTt is the nontradable endowment common to all countries in period t, r1i,j is the interest rate on borrowing and lending faced by the household between periods 0 and 1, and p0i,j is the price of nontradable goods in country j of region i in period 0. The equations (2) and (3) also continue to apply.

In addition to the first-order conditions (4)-(6), the household’s consumption choices now also satisfy the following conditions for period 0:

c T 1 i , j = r 1 i , j c T 0 i , j ( 35 )
ν c T 0 i , j = p 0 i , j c N T 0 i , j . ( 36 )

Imperfect financial union. The interest rates are equalized within the financial union F, which means the following additional condition:

r 1 i , j = r 1 for all i , j . ( 37 )

There are no imperfections from borrowing constraints in period 0. Our financial union is still assumed to be financially closed to the rest of world, so the additional market-clearing conditions are:

c N T 0 i , j = y N T 0 for all i , j . ( 38 )
Σ i { N , S } 0 1 c T 0 i , j d j = e T . ( 39 )

where eTΣi{N,S}01ei,jdj is the total tradable endowment within the union in period 0.

Heterogeneous regions. A region i{N, S} is defined such that within each region i, the tradable endowment levels are common across all countries j:

e i , j = e i f o r a l l i , j . ( 40 )

We assume that the North starts with a higher tradable endowment than the South, and we define the degree of pre-crisis heterogeneity of the union, H, accordingly:

e S = e T e N [ 0 , e T 2 ] ( 41 )
H e N e S e T = 1 2 e S e T [ 0 , 1 ] . ( 42 )

Equilibrium variables are again identical for all countries j of each region i: condition (17) holds for all periods. Therefore, as in the previous section, we suppress country superscripts in favor of regional superscripts. Equations (13)-(14) will be continue to apply in our extended model, but this time generated endogenously.

Competitive equilibrium allocations. The rational expectations equilibrium of the model follows a definition similar to that in subsection 2.1. The set of prices and allocations, now expanded to include {r0i,j,p0i,j,cT0i,j,cNT0i,j}i{N,S},j[0,1], satisfies the previous equilibrium conditions as well as equations (34)-(42), subject to the degree of heterogeneity H and the government policies {xi,j zi,j, τi,j, ηi,ji∈{N,S},i∈[0,1] defined by equations (15)-(16).

Institutional design. At the beginning of period 0, regional coalitions of Northern and Southern governments must decide whether to set up institutions that make crisis-time bargaining possible:

I = { 1 i f i n S t i t u t i o n S a r e S e t u p 0 i f n o i n S t i t u t i o n S a r e S e t u p . ( 43 )

If I = 0, no crisis-time interventions are allowed: xS = zN = τS = 0. For I = 1, unlimited interventions using all policy tools xS,zNS are allowed during crisis periods t ∈ {1,2}, so the North and South must additionally decide in period 0 the value of γN ∈ [0,1] to be used later on. Then crisis-time bargaining follows the procedure described in subsection 2.3: interventions are negotiated in period 1 taking b1S and the bargaining power γN as given.

3.2. Endogenizing the Debt Level b1S

Panel I of figure 6 illustrates the endogenous determination of the South’s inherited debt level b1S. The gray lines summarize the previous section’s findings regarding the Southern tradable consumption level as a function of b1ScT1S*andcT1S,C(cT1S,I=0) represent the unconstrained and constrained consumption levels, described respectively by equations (25) and (26). The constrained consumption level falls below the unconstrained value for b1S>b¯1S. When interventions are allowed, i.e., I = 1, the consumption of the South in period 1 increases above its constrained level, with the precise magnitude of the increase depending on the North’s bargaining power γN. The post-intervention consumption levels are represented by the lines cT1S,γN=1andcT1S,γN=0(>cT1S,γN=1), based on equations (30)-(31).

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Endogenizing the debt level b1S

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

To this configuration of graphs we need to add information regarding optimal household decisions and market-clearing in period 0. It turns out that irrespective of {I,γN}, the interest rate r1 takes a constant value, and households throughout the union optimally choose {cT0i}i{N,S} in line with {cT1i}i{N,S}:

r 1 = 2 y T 1 e T a n d c T 0 i = e T 2 y T 1 c T 1 i for all i .

Combining with the household budget constraint (34), we derive the new condition:

b 1 S = 2 c T 1 S 2 y T 1 ( 1 H ) . ( 44 )

This condition is shown as the black upward-sloping line in panel I. Along the line, households’ consumption-smoothing decisions cause the debt levels {b1i}i{N,S} to move in the same direction as {cT1i}i{N,S}. An increase in H, i.e., a reduction in the initial endowments of Southern households, shifts the black line to the right.

The union-wide equilibrium reduces to the set of prices and allocations {r2,p2S,cT1S,cT2S,cT1N} as a function of {H, xS, zN, τS}, subject to the equations (18)-(23) and (44). In graphical terms, the equilibrium is given by the intersection of the black line (indexed by H) and the appropriate gray line (indexed by {I,γN) in panel I of figure 6.

From the graphs and equations, the borrowing constraint (21) becomes binding, and a regional sudden stop occurs in the South, when the degree of pre-crisis heterogeneity H is high enough:

H > H ¯ = 3 ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν b 1 S > b ¯ 1 S . ( 45 )

For there to be a possibility of binding constraints in the union, H¯ must be less than 1, which implies that ϕ<13+2ν (our assumption in the previous section that ϕ<12+ν is therefore justified: it is a necessary condition for b1S>b¯1S to be possible in the first place). Inspecting the graphs yields the following lemma.

Lemma 4 (Inherited debt level) When H>H¯, the Southern debt level is affected by the expectation of {I, γN}. An expected constraint reduces debt: b1S,C(b1S,I=0)<b1S*, while an expected intervention increases debt: b1S,γN=0>b1S,γN=1>b1S,Canddb1S,γNdγN<0.

Panel II of figure 6 present the same arguments from the North’s perspective, and since the explanatory steps are analogous, we do not repeat them here.

3.3. Pareto-improving Institutional Design

Institutions to facilitate interventions are brought into existence if and only if the change in b1S brought about by expected period-1 bargaining (as illustrated in the previous subsection) is associated with a Pareto-improvement from the perspective of period 0, at least for some values of γN. We tackle this question next.

First best and laissez faire. A necessary condition for interventions to be useful is that the laissez-faire equilibrium deviates from the first-best frontier. By definition, the first-best allocation maximizes i{N,S}01λi,jVi,jdj subject to the market clearing conditions (11)-(12) and (38)-(39), and the Pareto weights {λi,j = λi}i∈{N,S},[0,1]. The laissez-faire equilibrium solves equations (18)-(23) and (44) subject to xS = zN = τS = 0. Defining {Vi,j = Vi}i∈{N,S},[0,1] and {Vi*}i∈{N,S} as the constrained and unconstrained regional welfare levels, this section’s counterparts to lemma 1 and proposition 1 are as follows.

Lemma 5 (First-best allocation) Irrespective of {λi}i∈{N,S}, the first-best allocation features cT1icT0i=2yT1eTandcT2icT1i=yT2yT1 for all i.

Proposition 4 (Laissez-faire equilibrium) Assume that ϕ is sufficiently low, i.e., φ[0,φ^)forSomeφ^>0. Then there exists some H¯(0,1) such that the laissez-faire equilibrium is a first-best allocation for some Pareto weights {λi}i∈{N,S} when H[0,H¯] but is located in the interior of the first-best frontier when H(H¯,1]. In the latter region, cT1icT0i=2yT1eTbutcT2S,C=c¯T2SandR2S>yT2yT1>r2. There also exists some H^(H¯,1) such that:

V N { = V N * f o r H [ 0 , H ¯ ] < V N * f o r H ( H ¯ , 1 ] a n d V S { = V S * f o r H [ 0 , H ¯ ] > V S * f o r H f o r ( H ¯ , H ^ ) < V S * f o r H ( H ^ , 1 ] .

Pareto-improving institutions. If unlimited interventions xS, zN, τS} can be selected in period 0, there is no difficulty in generating Pareto improvements from the perspective of period 0. The following lemma comes from extending the algebra of section 2.

Lemma 6 (Pre-crisis policy choice) Suppose that unlimited policies {xS, zN, τS} can be selected in period 0. When H>H¯, bargaining between North and South achieves a Pareto-improving (from the period-0 perspective) allocation on the first-best frontier. b1S is higher than in the constrained equilibrium.

The key obstacle that we impose, however, is that only the decisions {I, γN} can be made in period 0, while the interventions {xS, zN, τS} come from bargaining in period 1. We believe that this environment captures more accurately the institutional design problem faced by financial unions such as the Eurozone, and it captures real-world fears of moral hazard, i.e., that the expectation of future interventions may stimulate a level of Southern “overborrowing” that the North cannot offset. This obstacle removes the guarantee that the post-intervention equilibrium is Pareto-improving from the period-0 perspective.

The economic manifestation of this obstacle in our model takes the form of an externality in both regions mediated by the endogenous interest rate r2. As shown in subsection 3.2, households make their pre-crisis borrowing decisions based on {I,γN}, because the latter pins down their expectations of union-wide policies {xS, zNS}. But households are too small to internalize that their period-0 decisions actually determine the regional debt level b1S (which pins down the outside options in (28)), and thereby affect the period-1 choice of {xs, zNs}. Therefore, they may borrow too little or too much in period 0 relative to the preferred choice of the region as a whole. If the divergence is very large, the post-intervention allocation may involve the region being worse off than it was in the laissez-faire equilibrium.

Panels III and IV of figure 6 illustrate the welfare impact of endogenizing b1S for a given value of H, using the following two-step procedure. Firstly, we graph the period-0 regional welfares over all possible b1S, based on solving (28) subject to (18)-(23) and the period-0 equation:

c T 0 S = e T 2 y T 1 ( b 1 S + y T 1 ( 1 H ) ) , ( 46 )

which reflects household budget constraints and market clearing, but not period-0 household optimization. The constrained laissez-faire (i.e., I = 0) welfare is the welfare at the laissez-faire debt level:

b 1 S , C = y T 1 ( ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ ν + 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ ν H ) ,

and to the right of this point, panels III and IV trace out how welfares change as b1S,C rises above b1S. Secondly, we identify the debt level b1S corresponding to period-0 household optimization, which satisfies equation (44) and which we can read off the appropriate intersections in panels I and II. Using panels III and IV, we finally compare the welfare at that optimized debt level to the constrained laissez-faire welfare.

Panel III plots the Southern welfare levels VS,γN=1(b1S)andVS,γN=0(b1S):

V S , γ N = 1 ( b 1 S ) = 1 o g { κ ( b 1 S + y T 1 ( 1 H ) ) ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν } V S , γ N = 0 ( b 1 S ) = 1 o g { κ ( b 1 S + y T 1 ( 1 H ) ) × ( 2 ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 } ,

where κ=eT2yT2Πt={0,1,2}yNTt is a constant. Let us compare each to the laissez-faire welfare.

For a given level of b1S, if γN = 1, then period-1 bargaining leaves the South indifferent between laissez-faire and the intervention over t ∈ {1,2}. Since fixing b1S also fixes cT0S, then for a given level of b1S, γN = 1 means that the South’s period-0 welfare is the same whether there is intervention or not. Therefore, the shape of VS,γN=1(b1S) reflects how the South’s welfare varies with b1S in the absence of intervention, and VS,γN=1(b1S,C) represents the constrained laissez-faire (i.e., I = 0) welfare level.

Evaluated at the debt level b1S,C, the slope of VS,γN=1(b1S) is positive, which means that VS,γN=1(b1S) achieves a peak for some debt level higher than b1S,C. The reason is that increasing b1S both increases cT0S and also pushes down r2, which additionally shifts welfare from the North to the South. This interest rate effect is not internalized by Southern households, but does benefit the South as a whole. From panel I of figure 6, we know that b1S,γN=1>b1S,C. What panel III implies is that the increase in debt improves Southern welfare relative to laissez-faire if and only if b1S,γN=1(b1S,C,(b1S)M), and worsens welfare if b1S,γN=1>(b1S)M. Notice that (b1S)M is larger for levels of H such that starting from the laissez-faire debt level b1S,C, an increase in debt benefits Southern welfare significantly more by depressing r2 than it hurts welfare by tightening the Southern borrowing constraint.

VS,γN=0(b1S) represents the Southern welfare when all welfare gains from period-1 union-wide bargaining are given to the South instead of to the North. Its graph lies everywhere above VS,γN=1(b1S), and the gap between VS,γN=0(b1S)andVS,γN=1(b1S) at the debt level b1S,C is higher the tighter is the constraint of the South at that debt level. The increase in b1S,γN=0 relative to the constrained laissez-faire level b1S,C, as depicted in panel I of figure 6, is associated with a welfare improvement for the South if and only if b1S,γN=0(b1S,C,(b1S)N) in panel III.

Panel IV plots the Northern welfare levels VN,γN=0(b1S)andVN,γN=1(b1S):

V N , γ N = 0 ( b 1 S ) = 1 o g { κ ( y T 1 ( 1 H ) b 1 S ) ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ ν } V S , γ N = 1 ( b 1 S ) = 1 o g { κ ( y T 1 ( 1 H ) b 1 S ) × ( 2 ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 } .

Let us now compare each of these to the laissez-faire welfare.

Applying analogous arguments to those for the Southern welfare graphs, we can establish that the shape of VN,γN=0(b1S) reflects how the North’s welfare varies with b1S in the absence of intervention, and that VN,γN=0(b1S,C) represents the North’s constrained laissez-faire (i.e., I = 0) welfare level. Evaluated at the debt level b1S,C, the slope of VN,γN=0(b1S) is negative, which means that the peak of VN,γN=0(b1S) occurs at a level of debt lower than b1S,C. The reason is that increasing b1S not only reduces cT0N but also, as we mentioned above, pushes down r2. This interest rate effect is not internalized by Northern households, but does hurt the North as a whole as it is the saver region. The increase in b1S,γN=0aboveb1S,C from panel II therefore unambiguously reduces Northern welfare below its laissez-faire level in panel IV.

VN,γN=1(b1S) represents the Northern welfare when all welfare gains from period-1 bargaining are given to the North. Its graph lies everywhere above VN,γN=0(b1S), and the gap between VN,γN=1(b1S)andVN,γN=0(b1S) at the debt level b1S,C is higher the tighter is the constraint of the South at that debt level. The increase in b1S,γN=1 relative to the constrained laissez-faire level b1S,C, as depicted in panel II of figure 6, is associated with a welfare improvement for the North if and only if b1S,γN=1(b1S,C,(b1S)P) in panel III.

Applying the experiment in panels III and IV of figure 6 over the entire set of pre-crisis heterogeneity levels H ∈ [0,1], we derive the below proposition characterizing the set of Pareto-improving period-0 institutional designs {I,γN} as a function of H.

Proposition 5 (Institutional design) Assume that (f) is sufficiently low, i.e., ϕ[0,ϕ˜)forSomeϕ˜>0. Then we can define threshold levels H1 and H2 satisfying H1(H¯,1) and H2 ∈ (H1, 1) such that (i) institutions are Pareto-improving in period 0 if and only if they are set up according to:

I ( H ) = { 0 f o r H [ 0 , H 1 ] 1 f o r H ( H 1 , 1 ] ,

and (ii) the set of bargaining powers γN[γminN(H),γmaxN(H)] consistent with a period-0 Pareto improvement follow:

γ min N ( H ) > 0 a n d γ max N ( H ) = 1 f o r H ( H 1 , H 2 ] γ min N ( H ) > 0 a n d γ max N ( H ) < 1 f o r H ( H 2 , H 1 ] .

This proposition is illustrated by panels I and II of figure 7, which plot against H the exponentials of the regional welfare levels {exp(Vi)}i∈{N,S}, for different institutional designs {I, γN}. In the figure, Hmax=21+2ϕ+3ϕν1+ϕ+2ϕν lies above 1, but if ϕ is sufficiently low, then H1 and H2 lie below 1. We conclude this subsection by tracing out the connection between panels III and IV of figure 6 on the one hand, and panels I and II of figure 7 (and thereby, proposition 5) on the other.

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Institutional design

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

When H[0,H¯], i.e., the financial union is reasonably homogeneous in its initial endowments across regions, it is known in period 0 that the Southern borrowing constraint will never bind. Following proposition 4, there is no argument for setting up institutions to facilitate union-wide bargaining, so I = 0.

When H(H¯,H1], i.e., the financial union is slightly heterogeneous, it is known that the Southern borrowing constraint will bind, but not very tightly. As a result, the Pareto gains from period-1 bargaining will be small. In panel III of figure 6, b1S,γN=1(b1S,C,(b1S)M)andb1S,γN=0(b1S,C,(b1S)N) are both satisfied, as the South benefits from the increase in debt induced by the expectation of intervention. However, in panel IV of figure 6, the welfare result is more negative. Northern welfare is necessarily lower under γN = 0 than for laissez-faire, and because the Pareto gains are small, the gap between VN,γN=1(b1S)andVN,γN=0(b1S) is small. Therefore, (b1S)P is low, which in turn means that b1S,γN=1>(b1S)P. In other words, even if the North is allocated all the bargaining power in advance, i.e., γN = 1, the North is still worse off from the period-0 perspective if I = 1 is selected. These results are reflected in panels I and II of figure 7: for H(H¯,H1], Southern welfares under {I = 1, γN ∈ [0,1]} are higher than under 1 = 0, while Northern welfares are lower. There are no Pareto-improving allocations from the period-0 perspective, so as proposition 5 states, the solution is I = 0.

When H ∈ (H1,H2], i.e., the financial union is moderately heterogeneous, the Pareto gains from period-1 bargaining become moderately large as well. In panel III of figure 6, b1S,γN=1(b1S,C,(b1S)M)andb1S,γN=0(b1S,C,(b1S)N) continue to hold as VS,γN=0(b1S) rises further above VS,γN=1(b1S), so the relative positions of the welfare lines in panel I of figure 7 remain unchanged. By contrast, there is a significant change in panel IV of figure 6. As Pareto gains are now moderately large, VS,γN=1(b1S) rises substantially above VS,γN=0(b1S), so that (b1S)P becomes larger and b1S,γN=1(b1S,C,(b1S)P) becomes satisfied. Therefore, in panel II of figure 7, the Northern welfare under {I = 1, γN = 1} becomes higher than under 1 = 0. Changing from I = 0 to I = 1 does generate a Pareto improvement from the period-0 perspective as long as γN is sufficiently high (and definitely above 0).

When H ∈ (H2,1], i.e., the financial union is highly heterogeneous, the Southern borrowing constraint becomes very tightly binding at the laissez-faire allocation and Pareto gains are very large. There is now a significant change in panel III of figure 6. The large Pareto gains continue to ensure that b1S,γN=0(b1S,C,(b1S)N) is satisfied. However, the graph for VS,γN=1(b1S) reaches its peak much earlier and just above b1S,C, because for these levels of H, an increase in debt benefits Southern welfare a little by depressing r2, but it hurts welfare substantially by tightening the constraint. Therefore, b1S,γN=1>(b1S)M becomes true. In panel I of figure 7, the Southern welfare under {I = 1, γN = 1} dips below the welfare level under I = 0. Regarding the North, the relative positions of the graphs in panel IV of figure 6 and panel II of figure 7 remain the same as for H ∈ (H1, H2]. In summary, changing from I = 0 to I = 1 now generates a Pareto improvement from the period-0 perspective if and only if γN lies in an intermediate region: γN[γminN(H),γmaxN(H)]withγminN(H)>0andγmaxN(H)<1. Too much bargaining power must not be given to the North or to the South.

3.4. Discussion

Overborrowing. Northern fears that setting up crisis-time bargaining institutions may induce the South to borrow more and thereby hurt the North are rationalized in our model for financial unions whose heterogeneity is low. The expectation of intervention does increase the level of Southern pre-crisis debt b1S, which makes the sudden stop more severe, reduces the union-wide interest rate r2, and shifts welfare from the North to the South. This negative effect on the North cannot be overcome by the period-1 generation of Pareto gains, even if all the Pareto gains are given to the North.

However, when the financial union is moderately or highly heterogeneous, this overborrowing worry diminishes relative to the Pareto gains from crisis-time bargaining. These Pareto gains can be distributed between North and South in a manner to completely offset the negative impact on the North of higher pre-crisis Southern borrowing. In this context, the higher b1S generated by the anticipation of period-1 bargaining is actually a positive sign that the North and South are fully exploiting their respective comparative advantages (as savers and borrowers) in an unimpeded union-wide capital market.

In highly heterogeneous unions, care must be taken to limit the North’s bargaining power γN, so that the South receives some of the Pareto gains during t ∈ {1,2}. Otherwise, the externality from household borrowing becomes very severe—Southern households borrow so much that the South as a whole has a very low outside option during the period-1 bargaining process—and as a result, the South’s welfare is not improved from the period-0 perspective.

4. A More Elaborate Financial Union

Having proven our main results in a simple financially-closed union containing endowment economies, we now generalize the results above to a model with financial openness of the union to the rest of the world, and with production. The potential for Pareto-improving policies continues to hold, subject to modifications related to the presence of capital inflows from outside the union, and the intratemporally distortive effects of interventions.

4.1. The Environment for Periods t ∈ {1,2}

Our financial union F still has the two regions i ∈ {N, S}, with each region continuing to be composed of a unit measure of countries j ∈ [0,1]. However, relative to the baseline model, each country now additionally contains a unit measure of firms in each of the tradable and nontradable sectors, who produce output by investing in capital. Both households and firms have access to loans from inside the union at interest rate r2 and from the rest of the world ROW at interest rate r. Households face limits on how much they can borrow both from inside the union and from ROW, while firms do not. Since capital inflows from ROW to F in period 1 are subject to borrowing limits while capital outflows from F to ROW are not, we must have r2r. Therefore, households borrow as much as they can from ROW and the remainder from the intra-union loans market, while firms borrow everything they need from ROW only.

All households within each region begin period 1 with the same inherited debt positions with respect to the intra-union market and to ROW, while all firms within each region begin with the same level of capital invested in each sector. Similarly to the baseline model, we again assume that all governments within each region pursue identical policies.

Households. The representative household in country j of region i has log preferences:

U i , j = ( l o g c T 1 i , i + ν 1 o g c N T 1 i , j ) + ( l o g c T 2 i , j + ν l o g c N T 2 i , j ) , ( 47 )

where cTti,iandcNTti,j are respectively the consumption of tradable and nontradable goods in country j of region i in period t, and ν captures the taste for nontradable goods. The amended budget and borrowing constraints are:

c T 1 i , j + p 1 i , j c N T 1 i , j + ( 1 + τ i ) c T 2 i , j + ( 1 η i ) p 2 i , j c N T 2 i , j r 2 b 1 i D 1 i + π T 1 i , j + π N T 1 i , j + x i + D 2 i , j r + π T 2 i , j + π N T 2 i , j + z i D 2 i , j r 2 ( 48 )
b 2 i , j r 2 ( c T 1 i , j + p 1 i , j c N T 1 i , j + b 1 i + D 1 i π T 1 i , j π N T 1 i , j x i D 2 i , j r ) ϕ ( π T 2 i , j + π N T 2 i , j + z i ) ( 49 )
D 2 i , j ϕ R O W ( π T 2 i , j + z i ) , ( 50 )

where p1i,j is the relative price of nontradable goods in country j of region i in period t, πTti,jandπNTti,j are respectively the profits of firms in the tradable and nontradable goods sectors in period t, bti,j is the inherited debt of each household in country j of region i at the beginning of period t relative to the intra-union market (with b1i,j=b1i for all i,j), Dti,j is the inherited debt of that household at the beginning of period t relative to ROW (where D1i,j=D1i for all i,j), ϕ ∈ (0,1) is the fraction of period-2 total income that is pledgable within the union F as collateral against borrowing in period 1, ϕROW ∈ (0,ϕ) is the fraction of period-2 tradable income that is pledgable to ROW in period 1, xi and zi are the lump-sum transfers or taxes provided by all governments in region i to each household under its authority in periods 1 and 2 respectively, and τi and ηi are respectively a tax on the consumption of tradable goods and a subsidy on the consumption of nontradable goods imposed by all governments in region i in period 2.

Nontradable outputs are pledgable only within the union F and not to lenders in ROW. This assumption reflects that owing to common financial institutions within F, the pledgability of future outputs is likely superior within F than between F and ROW. It also clarifies the exposition: the main results below do hold even if nontradable outputs are partially pledgable to ROW, but the algebra is more cumbersome. Regarding household wealth, we assume that each household in country j of region i owns an equal share of the profits of all the firms within that country, but that households and firms have only an arms-length relationship: firms are not allowed to pass on borrowed resources to households.

The household’s first-order conditions yield:

( 1 + τ i ) c T 2 i , j r 2 c T 1 i , j ( 51 )
ν c T 1 i , j = p 1 i , j c N T 1 i , j ( 52 )
( 1 + τ i ) ν c T 2 i , j = ( 1 η i ) p 2 i , j c N T 2 i , j ( 53 )
D 2 i , j { = ϕ R O W ( π T 2 i , j + z i ) i f r 2 > r o r ( 49 ) i S b i n d i n g < ϕ R O W ( π T 2 i , j + z i ) o t h e r w i S e . ( 54 )

Firms. The profits of the representative firms in the tradable and nontradable sectors of country j of region i are:

π T 1 i , j = ( 1 δ i ) y T 1 i , j r k T 2 i , j , w h e r e y T 1 i , j = A 1 1 α T ( k T 0 i , j ) α T ( 55 )
π T 2 i , j = ( 1 ξ i ) y T 2 i , j r k T 1 i , j , w h e r e y T 2 i , j = A 2 1 α T ( k T 1 i , j ) α T ( 56 )
π N T t i , j = p t i , j y N T t i , j r k N T , t 1 i , j , w h e r e y N T t i , j = ( k N T , t 1 i , j ) α N T , ( 57 )

where yTti,jandyNTti,j are respectively the tradable and nontradable outputs in period t, At1αT captures the level o tradable sector productivity in period t, kT,t1i,jandkNT,t1i,j are respectively the capital invested in the tradable and nontradable goods sectors in period t – 1 for use in production in period t, and δi and ξi are the taxes on the production of tradable goods in periods 1 and 2 respectively by all governments in region i.

In period 1, firms take capital levels kT0i,jandkNT0i,j as given (where kT0i,j=kT0iandkNT0i,j=kNT0i for all i, j, and they optimally select kT1i,jandkNT1i,j:

k T 1 i , j = A 2 ( ( 1 ξ i ) α T r ) 1 1 α T = ( 1 ξ i ) α T y T 2 i , j r , w h e r e y T 2 i , j = A 2 ( ( 1 ξ i ) α T r ) α T 1 α T ( 58 )
k N T 1 i , j = ( α N T p 2 i , j r ) 1 1 α N T = α N T p 2 i , j y N T 2 i , j r , w h e r e y N T 2 i , j = ( α N T p 2 i , j r ) α N T 1 α N T . ( 59 )

Government. We consider two interventions.

  • Governmental loan {xi, δi, ξi}i∈{N,S}: Northern governments provide transfers to Southern governments in period 1 and get repaid in period 2, and all transfers are funded using production taxes:
    {xS=δN01yT1N,jdj>0xN=δS=0}and{zN=ξS01yT2S,jdj>0zS=ξN=0}.(60)
  • This intervention requires governments to be able to commit to repay loans in period 2, getting around households’ borrowing constraints.

  • Tax-subsidy with debt relief {xi, δi, τii}i∈{N,S}: Northern governments provide transfers to Southern governments in period 1 funded by production taxes, and Southern governments impose a budget-neutral combination of taxes and subsidies on consumption in period 2:
    {xS=δN01yT1N,jdj>0xN=δS=0}and{τN=ηN=0τS,ηN>0},(61)
    whereτScT2S,j=ηSp2S,jcNT2S,jfor all j.(62)
    21

    This intervention requires governments in period 1 to be able to commit to undertake specific fiscal policy actions in period 2, but not to be able to commit to repay.

Resource constraints. Equations (60)-(62) already capture the notion of political closure, i.e., governments in ROW have no influence on public transfers within the union. Our financial union is no longer financially closed to the rest of the world, but the intra-union loans market must still clear:

b 1 S = b 1 N ( 0 , ( b 1 S ) max ) and Σ i { N , S } 0 1 b 2 i , j d j = 0. ( 63 )

where (b1S)max is the highest value of debt consistent with non-negative Southern consumption in period 1. The market for nontradable goods must clear within each country j:

c N T t i , j = y N T t i , j for all i , j , t . ( 64 )

Combining the household budget constraint (48), production functions (55)-(57), government budget constraints (60)-(62), and market-clearing conditions (63)-(64), we establish the union-wide resource constraints on tradable goods:

Σ i { N , S } 0 1 c T 1 i , j d j = ( D 1 N + D 1 S ) + Σ i { N , S } ( A 1 ( k T 0 i ) α T r k T 0 i r k N T 0 i ) + Σ i { N , S } 0 1 D 2 i , j r d j ( 65 )
Σ i { N , S } 0 1 c T 2 i , j d j = Σ i { N , S } 0 1 D 2 i , j d j + Σ i { N , S } 0 1 ( A 2 ( k T 1 i , j ) α T r k T 1 i , j r k N T 1 i , j ) d j ( 66 )
Σ i { N , S } 0 1 D 2 i , j d j Σ i { N , S } 0 1 ϕ R O W ( A 2 ( k T 1 i , j ) α T r k T 1 i , j ) d j . ( 67 )

Competitive equilibrium allocations. A rational expectations equilibrium is a set of prices and allocations {r2,{pti,j,cTti,j,cNTti,j,yTti,j,yNTti,ji}t{1,2},kT1i,j,D2i,j}i{N,S},j[0,1] which satisfy the households’ constraints and first-order conditions (48)-(54), the production equations (55)-(59), and the market-clearing conditions for the union (64)-(67), subject to the set of inherited debt levels and government policies {b1i,D1i,xi,δi,zi,ξi,τi,ηi}i{N,S} defined by (60)-(63).

As in the baseline model, the equilibrium values of all variables are identical for all countries j within each region i, so we again suppress country superscripts in favor of regional superscripts. The amended system of equations is as follows:

( 2 + α N T ν ) c T 1 N = ( B 1 N Φ T 1 N ) + ( ϕ R O W r + 1 ϕ R O W r 2 ) ( Π 2 + Φ T 2 S ) ( 68 )
c T 1 S + ( 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) c T 2 S r 2 = ( B 1 S + Φ T 1 N ) + ( ϕ R O W r + 1 ϕ R O W r 2 ) ( Π 2 Δ T 2 S ) ( 69 )
R 2 S c T 2 S c T 1 S r 2 1 + τ S ( 70 )
c T 1 S ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) c T 2 S r 2 ( B 1 S + Φ T 1 N ) + ( ϕ R O W r + ϕ r 2 ) ( Π 2 Δ T 2 S ) ( 71 )
c T 1 N + c T 1 S = ( B 1 N + B 1 S ) + ϕ R O W r ( Π 2 Δ T 2 S ) + D 2 N r ( 72 )
( 1 + α N T ν ) r 2 c T 1 N + ( 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) c T 2 S = ( 1 ϕ R O W ) ( Π 2 Δ T 2 S ) + ( Π 2 + Φ T 2 S ) D 2 N ( 73 )
D 2 N ϕ R O W ( Π 2 + Φ T 2 S ) and r 2 r ( 74 )
Φ T 1 N ( Φ T 1 N ) max = y T 1 N and Φ T 2 S ( Φ T 2 S ) L a f f f e r = α α T T 1 α T Π 2 , ( 75 )

where B1i=b1i+D1i+rkT0i+rkNT0iyT1i represents region i’s inherited debts less its tradable output in period 1 (where B1N+B1S is assumed to be a negative constant), Πt=(1αT)At(αTr)αT1αT represents the profits of tradable-sector firms in period t in the absence of distortions, ΦT1iδiyT1iandΦT2iξiyT2i are the revenues raised by region i using taxes on tradable production in periods 1 and 2 respectively, and ΔT2S=Π2[1(1ξS)11αT] is the tax-induced reduction in Southern profits in period 2. (ΦT1N)max=yT1N because {kT0i,kNT0i}i{N,S}, are exogenous. Owing to the distortive nature of the period-2 production tax, ΔT2S is larger than ΦT2S, while the value of (ΦT2S)Laffer comes from the peak of the Laffer curve. Walras’ Law means that one out of the equations (72) and (73) is redundant.

There are now two sets of equations that hold with complementary slackness. The first set comprises equations (70) and (71), similarly to the baseline model. We assume that in the absence of the intra-union borrowing constraint (71), the interest rate within F is strictly higher than r:

r 2 * = 2 ( 1 ϕ R O W ) Π 2 ( 1 + α N T ν ) ( ( B 1 N + B 1 S ) + 2 ϕ R O W r Π 2 ) > r .

The only way that the intra-union interest rate r2 can go below r2*, and possibly even touch r, is for the Southern constraint to be binding.

The second set of equations that hold with complementary slackness is given by equation (74). If r2 > r, then both North and South borrow the maximum possible from ROW, so D2N=ϕROW(Π+ΦT2S). Our model’s pattern of lending matches Chen et al. (2012): the South borrows from both the North and ROW, while the North lends to the South using both its own saving and also intermediated funds from ROW. In our model, the North earns a riskless premium (r2r) > 0 on all the funds it intermediates from ROW. If r2 = r, then the Southern constraint continues to bind, implying that D2N=ϕROW(Π+ΔT2S), but now D2N lies below ϕROW(Π+ΦT2S), and is given by the residual from equation (72).

Capital inflows from ROW in period 1 allow the union as a whole to expand its tradable consumption in that period. The union’s period-1 current account balance is given by:

Ψ 1 = 1 r ( B 1 N + B 1 S + y T 1 N + y T 1 S ) 1 r α T 1 α T ( 2 Π 2 Δ T 2 S ) 1 r α N T ( ν c T 2 N + ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) c T 2 S ) 1 r ( ϕ R O W ( Π 2 Δ T 2 S ) + D 2 N ) .

The first sum in brackets is exogenous and represents the principal repayments of all inherited debts. The negative terms represent new borrowing from ROW by tradable-sector firms, nontradable-sector firms, and households respectively.

4.2. Pareto Efficiency of the Laissez-Faire Equilibrium

First best. The first-best allocation maximizes i{N,S}01λi,jUi,jdj subject to the market-clearing conditions (64)-(67) and the Pareto weights {λi,j = λi} i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1], ignoring the borrowing constraint (49).

Lemma 7 (First-best allocation) Irrespective of {λi} i∈{N,S}, the first-best allocation features cT2icT1i=r2*,kT1i=A2(αTr)11αT,andkNT1i=αNTνcT2ir for all i, and the union-wide condition (67) holds with equality.

While the levels of consumption {cTti}i{N,S},t{1,2} do depend on the Pareto weights {λi} i∈{N,S}, the intertemporal ratio cT2icT1i does not. The difference from the baseline first-best allocation is that there are now expressions for the optimal sectoral investment levels {kT1i,kNT1i}i{N,S}. Each country’s tradable production depends only on the ROW interest rate r, and the resulting output is then either distributed among the regions according to the weights {λi} i∈{N,S}, or repaid in interest to ROW. Since nontradable goods cannot be transported between countries, their production and consumption in each region depends not just on r but also on {λi} i∈{N,S}.

The union borrows up to its constraint from the rest of the world, which means that the period-1 current account balance Ψ1 does not depend on the Pareto weights.

Laissez faire. The laissez-faire equilibrium follows equations (68)-(75), setting δN = ξS = τS = 0. The resulting allocations are indexed by B1S (keeping the sum B1N+B1S constant) and are shown by the solid lines in figure 8. The dashed lines represent the unconstrained equilibrium, i.e., the equilibrium calculated ignoring condition (71). The unconstrained and constrained levels of tradable consumption in the South are:

c T 1 i * = 1 2 + α N T ν ( B 1 i + ( 1 + α N T ν ) ( B 1 N + B 1 S ) 2 + ϕ R O W r Π 2 and c T 2 i * = r 2 * c T 1 i * for all  i ( 76 )
c T 1 S , C = { c T 1 S * for B 1 S [ 0 , B ¯ 1 S ] ω 1 B 1 S ω 2 ( B 1 N + B 1 S ) + ω 3 ϕ R O W r Π 2 for B 1 S ( B ¯ 1 S , B 1 S , r ) B 1 S + ϕ R O W + ϕ r Π 2 + ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ν c ¯ T 2 S r for B 1 S B 1 S , r and c T 2 S , C { c T 2 S * for B 1 S [ 0 , B ¯ 1 S ] c ¯ T 2 S for B 1 S > B ¯ 1 S , ( 77 )
Figure 8.
Figure 8.

Laissez-faire equilibrium with ROW and production

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

where {ωk}k{1,2,3}>0,ω1(12+αNTν,1),c¯T2S=(1ϕROWϕ)Π21+(αNT+ϕ(1αNT))ν, and there exist 5, and B¯1SandB1S,r satisfying B1S,r>B¯1S>0 (we assume that r is below r2*, as stated above, but also high enough so that cT1S,C does not go to zero to the left of B1S=B1S,r. The equilibrium is defined up to (B1S)max=ϕROW(1+αNTν)+ϕ(1+ν)1+(αNT+ϕ(1αNT))νΠ2r, which also implicitly defines (b1S)max.

Panels I and III of figure 8 illustrate that the constraint becomes binding when B1S>B¯1S. Panel II shows that as in the baseline model, r2 and R2S diverge for B1S>B¯1S. The difference from the baseline model is that for B1SB1S,r, the intra-union interest rate r2 cannot decline below r without leading to unlimited capital outflows from F to ROW, so instead it stays fixed at r. Since the decline in r2 as B1S increases within (B¯1S,B1S,r) cushions Southern consumption from the tightening constraint, the absence of a continued interest rate decline means that cT1S,C falls more steeply with B1SwhenB1SB1S,r (i.e., the slope magnitude 1 is greater than ω1, and R2S increases more steeply as a result.

Panel IV compares the constrained regional welfares {Ui,j = Ui} i∈{N,S},j∈[0,1] to their unconstrained levels {Ui*} i∈{N,S}. While the relative behavior of the graphs mostly echoes the baseline model, there is a difference for B1SB1S,r: since r2 is fixed and can play no cushioning effect for these high debt levels, constrained Southern welfare falls more steeply with B1S while Northern welfare increases more steeply. Therefore, the graphs for both regions have a kink at B1S=B1S,r.

Panels V and VI illustrate the behavior of variables which are important in our generalized model but were missing from the baseline model. Panel V shows the Southern tradable and nontradable outputs in period 2, which are determined by the corresponding period-1 investment levels, kT1i=A2(αrr)11αTandkNT1i=αNTνcT2ir for all i. Tradable production does not vary with B1S, while nontradable production moves in line with the value of cT2S from panel I. Panel VI shows the period-1 current account position of the union, which is flat for B1S[0,B1S,r] but increases when B1S>B1S,r. In the latter region, the North chooses to borrow less from ROW than its borrowing constraint allows, so tradable consumption inside the union declines. Even though the union as a whole is able to borrow more from ROW, and the South values consumption highly at the margin, the North does not intermediate funds from ROW to the South because the latter region is borrowing-constrained in the intra-union loans market and cannot absorb more funds.

The above results are summarized in the proposition below.

Proposition 6 (Laissez-faire equilibrium) The laissez-faire equilibrium is a first-best allocation for some Pareto weights {λi} i∈{N,S} when B1S[0,B¯1S,r], but lies in the interior of the first-best frontier when B1S>B¯1S. In the latter region cT2S,C=c¯T2SandR2S>r2*>r2. Ψ1 is flat for B1S[0,B1S,r]butdΨ1dB1S=12+αNTν>0whenB1S>B1S,r.ThereexitSB̂<(B1S)max such that welfare levels follow:

U N { = U N * f o r B 1 S [ 0 , B ¯ 1 S ] < U N f o r B 1 S > B ¯ 1 S a n d U N { = U S * f o r B 1 S [ 0 , B ¯ 1 S ] > U S * f o r B 1 S [ B ¯ 1 S , B ^ 1 S ] < U S * f o r B 1 S > B ^ 1 S ,

where B^1S<B1S,r iff r is sufficiently low. Define Ui,CF as the counterfactual welfare for region i when we use equations (68)-(75) and fix D2N=ϕROW(Π+ΦT2S), even if the result of doing so is the infeasible configuration of interest rates r2 < r. Then for B1S>B1S,r, UN > UN,CF and US < US,CF.

4.3. Pareto-improving Interventions

Echoing our approach for the baseline model, we start at a constrained equilibrium, i.e., B1S>B¯1S, and select policy tools {δNSS} to maximize the Nash product (28) subject to equations (68)-(75). We again assume that all the governments within each region i bargain as a coalition, with bargaining powers satisfying γN = 1 – γS ∈ [0,1].

The impact of small changes in the interventions can be analyzed using the same steps as in the baseline model. We analyze the configuration B1S(B¯1S,B1S,r] to begin with and return later to B1S>B1S,r. In order to focus in this section on those results that are new relative to the baseline model, let us go straight to the expression for the Pareto gains:

d U i ( δ N , ξ S , τ S ) | d U i ( δ N , ξ S , τ S ) = 0 = 1 c T 1 i 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S 1 + α N T ν 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) ( 1 ϕ R O W ϕ ) ( 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) 1 + ( α N T + ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ) ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d Φ T 2 S 1 c T 1 i 1 r 2 ( ( 1 r 2 R 2 S 1 + α N T ν 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) ( 1 ϕ R O W ϕ ) ( 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) 1 + ( α N T + ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ) ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ( ϕ R O W r 2 r + ( 1 ϕ R O W ) ) ) ξ S α T 1 ξ S α T d Φ T 2 S + 1 c T 1 i 1 r 2 ( 1 r 2 R 2 S 1 + α N T ν 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ) c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) ( 1 α N T ) 1 + ( α N T + ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ) ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S c T 1 S c T 1 i α N T ( 1 + ν ) ( 1 + α N T ν 1 + α N T ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) ν ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S , ( 78 )

where dΦT1N has been set to satisfy dU−iNSS) = 0 conditional on arbitrary values of {dΦT2S=1ξSαT(1ξS)(1αT)yT2SdξS,dτS}. At the laissez-faire equilibrium, R2S>r2 and δN = ξS = τS = 0, so there are positive Pareto gains from regional bargaining and interventions.

In the baseline model, regional bargaining was able to achieve allocations on the first-best frontier: interventions reduced R2S and increased r2 until they eliminated the intertemporal distortion arising from the borrowing constraint. In our more elaborate financial union, only distortive interventions are available, so the interventions generate new intratemporal distortions as they mitigate the existing intertemporal distortions.

In the above expression, the two terms indexed by dΦT2S capture the effects of the governmental loan. The first term indicates a reduction in the intertemporal distortion similar to that in the baseline model, but the second term is negative, indicating that the tax-induced decrease in period-2 Southern tradable output hurts union-wide consumption and welfare. The two terms indexed by S capture the effects of the tax-subsidy intervention with debt relief. The first term indicates a reduction in the intertemporal distortion similar to that in the baseline model, but the second term is negative, indicating that the tax-induced increase in period-2 Southern nontradable output hurts union-wide welfare. The welfare benefits from the additional Southern consumption of nontradable goods fall short of the welfare losses owing to higher repayments to ROW by Southern nontradable-sector firms.

Distortive interventions are not used all the way until the intertemporal distortion is eliminated, but rather until the marginal reduction in the constraint-induced intertemporal distortion is equal to the marginal increase in the policy-induced intratemporal distortion. Therefore, regional bargaining is no longer able to bring the union to the first-best frontier, and it traces out a second-best frontier instead.22

Figure 9 illustrates the effects of Pareto-improving interventions for B1S(B¯B1S,r], with the governmental loan indexed by ΦT2S and the tax-subsidy intervention with debt relief indexed by τS. The qualitative effects of these interventions in panels I through IV are similar to those in the baseline model, but the Pareto-efficient magnitudes of both interventions are smaller owing to the distortions that they generate.

Figure 9.
Figure 9.

Impact of intervention with ROW and production for B1S(B¯1S,B1S,r]

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

The new results from our extended model are shown in panels V and VI. The interventions now affect period-2 output, because firms base their period-1 investment decisions on period-2 taxes and prices. The governmental loan reduces Southern tradable and nontradable output, while the tax-subsidy intervention with debt relief increases Southern nontradable output:

d y T 2 S d Φ T 2 S < 0 , d y N T 2 S d Φ T 2 S < 0 a n d d y T 2 S d τ S = 0 , d y N T 2 S d τ S > 0.

The interventions have opposite effects on the current account balance. The governmental loan causes the balance to increase toward surplus, because it reduces period-1 borrowing: the reduction in Southern period-2 tradable output tightens the borrowing constraint of Southern households, while the reduction in tradable and nontradable output in the South reflects lower investment by Southern firms in both sectors. The tax-subsidy intervention causes the current account balance to decrease toward deficit, because the higher p2S generates higher investment by Southern nontradable-sector firms. Summarizing these results:

d Ψ 1 d Φ T 2 S > 0 a n d d Ψ 1 d τ S < 0.

The Pareto gain expression above continues to apply for the configuration B1S>B1S,r, if we set r2 = r. The qualitative results in figure 9 also continue to apply, with two exceptions. Firstly, the interest rate r2 remains fixed at r instead of increasing at the beginning of the interventions. As we increase the size of the interventions, it is possible—but not certain— that r2 eventually rises above r. Secondly, when B1S>B1S,r, the laissez-faire current account balance is higher than the first-best level, which in turn may alter the sign of dΨ1dΦT2S from positive to negative for small values of the governmental loan. The reason is that this intervention causes the North to borrow more from ROW in order to pass on the capital flows, packaged as governmental loans, to the South.

The above results are summarized in the proposition below, which characterizes the outcome of regional bargaining when only distortive interventions are available.

Proposition 7 (Second-best frontier) When B1S>B¯1S, each intervention achieves a Pareto improvement relative to the laissez-faire equilibrium, but each has different effects on {yT2S,yNT2S,Ψ1}. Bargaining between North and South achieves an allocation on the second- best frontier, defined by the condition dUiNSS)|dU-iNSS) = 0 for i ∈ {N,S}. If both interventions are available, then both are used at the frontier, i.e., ξS > 0 and τS > 0. The condition ΦT2S(ΦT2S)Laffer never binds, but the condition ΦT1N(ΦT1N)max may do so.

Combining the interventions. The availability of the two distortive interventions depends on different political factors: the governmental loan depends on the ability of the South to commit to repay, while the tax-subsidy intervention requires the North to offer up-front debt relief. If only one out of the two interventions is available, then that is what regional bargaining should focus on. However, if both interventions are available, then both should be used. Each marginal reduction in the intertemporal distortion is less costly in terms of marginal intratemporal distortions if the latter distortions are spread out throughout the economy, rather than focused on one sector.

Deviating from the second-best combination of interventions reduces the welfare gains for both North and South, as Pareto gains remain unexploited. Excessive use of the governmental loan causes an excessive reduction in Southern tradable output in period 2, and an excessively large union-wide current account surplus in period 1. Excessive use of the tax-subsidy intervention with debt relief causes an excessive stimulus to Southern nontradable output in period 2, and an excessively large union-wide current account deficit in period 1.

4.4. The Environment for Period t = 0

Having shown that the potential for Pareto improvements during t ∈ {1,2} carries over from our baseline model to our more elaborate financial union, we next explore whether regional bargaining during crises continues to be Pareto-improving from the pre-crisis perspective, as it was in the baseline model under some conditions.

Echoing the approach in section 3.1, we again add a pre-crisis period labeled as t = 0, but there are two differences. Firstly, there is a unit measure of firms in each of the tradable and nontradable sectors which invest capital in period 0 to produce output in period 1. Secondly, in addition to the intra-union loans market with interest rate r1, loans from ROW are available at interest rate rr1. As in section 4.1, households face borrowing constraints, while firms do not.

Households. The representative household in country j of region i has the amended log preferences:

V i , j = ( l o g c T , 1 i , j + ν 1 o g c N T , 1 i , j ) + ( l o g c T 0 i , j + ν l o g c N T 0 i , j ) + U i , j , ( 79 )

where cTti,jandcNTti,j are respectively the consumption of tradable and nontradable goods in country j of region i in period t, and Ui,j follows equation (47). The new equations for household debt and the borrowing constraint are:

b 1 i , j r 1 ( c T 0 i , j + p 0 i , j c N T 0 i , j e i , j p 0 i , j y N T 0 D 1 i , j r ) ( 80 )
D 1 i , j ϕ R O W ( π T 1 i , j + x i , j ) , ( 81 )

where ei,j is the tradable endowment of each household in country j of region i in period 0 (with ei,j = ei for all j), yNT0 is the nontradable endowment common to all countries in period 0, p0i,j is the price of nontradable goods in country j of region i in period 0, and the other variables are as defined in section 4.1. The equations (48)-(50) continue to apply.

In addition to the conditions (51)-(54), the household’s consumption choices now also satisfy the following conditions for period 0:

c T 1 i , j = r 1 i , j c T 0 i , j ( 82 )
ν c T 0 i , j = p 0 i , j c N T 0 i , j , ( 83 )

while equation (81) holds with equality.

Firms. The period-1 profits of the representative firms in the tradable and nontradable sectors are given by equations (55) and (57). Therefore, the period-0 investment decisions take the following form:

k T 0 i , j = A 1 ( ( 1 δ i ) α T r ) 1 1 α T = ( 1 δ i ) α T y T 1 i , j r , w h e r e y T 1 i , j = A 1 ( ( 1 δ i ) α T r ) α T 1 α T ( 84 )
k N T 0 i , j = ( α N T p 1 i , j r ) 1 1 α N T = α N T p 1 i , j y N T 1 i , j r , w h e r e y N T 1 i , j = ( α N T p 1 i , j r ) α N T 1 α N T . ( 85 )

Resource constraints. The additional market-clearing conditions for the union are:

c N T 0 i , j = y N T 0 for all i , j ( 86 )
Σ i { N , S } 0 1 c T 0 i , j d j = e T + Σ i { N , S } 0 1 D 1 i , j r d j ( 87 )
Σ i { N , S } 0 1 D 1 i , j d j Σ i { N , S } 0 1 ϕ R O W ( A 1 ( k T 0 i , j ) α T r k T 0 i , j ) d j , ( 88 )

where eTΣi{N,S}01ei,jdj is the total period- tradable endowment within the union. As in section 3.1, we assume that eS[0,eT2], and we define HeNeSeT=12eSeT[0,1].

Competitive equilibrium allocations. Building on the definition of the rational expectations equilibrium in section 4.1, we expand the set of prices and allocations to include {r0,p0i,j,cT0i,j,cNT0i,j,kT0i,j,D1i,j}i{N,S},j[0,1], and we expand the set of equilibrium conditions to include equations (80)-(88). We solve the system of equations subject to the degree of heterogeneity H and the government policies {xi, δi,ziiii}i∈{N,S} defined by (60)-(62).

Again suppressing country superscripts in favor of regional superscripts, we can solve for the tradable consumption levels in period 0 and the implied levels of household debt:

c T 0 i = c T 1 i r 1 for all i b 1 S = c T 1 S r 1 [ e T 2 ( 1 H ) + ϕ R O W r ( Π 1 + Φ T 1 N ) ] = b 1 N .

Combining these expressions with the firms’ optimization conditions and the union’s resource constraints, we derive the formulae for B1SandB1N+B1S:

B 1 S = ( 1 + α N T ν ) c T 1 S r 1 e T 2 ( 1 H ) ϕ R O W ( r 1 r 1 ) ( Π 1 + Φ T 1 N ) Π 1 ( 89 )
B 1 S + B 1 N = α N T ν ( c T 1 S + c T 1 N ) ( 1 ϕ R O W ) ( 2 Π 1 Δ T 1 N + Φ T 1 N ) , ( 90 )
w h e r e r 1 = c T 1 S + c T 1 N e T + ϕ R O W r ( 2 Π 1 Δ T 1 N + Φ T 1 N ) a n d Φ T 1 N ( Φ T 1 N ) L a f f f e r = α T α T 1 α T Π 1 . ( 91 )

Therefore, the union-wide equilibrium can be reduced to the set of prices and allocations {r2,p2S,cT1S,cT2S,cT1N,D2N} as a function of {H, δN, ξS, τS}, subject to the equations (68)-(74) and (89)-(91). The new limit (ΦT1N)Laffer allows period-0 investment to adjust according to expectations of the period-1 production tax, so ΦT1N(ΦT1N)Laffer is a fighter condition than ΦT1N(ΦT1N)max.

Using the amended system of equations, we find that the borrowing constraint of Southern households becomes binding when the degree of pre-crisis heterogeneity is high:

H > H ¯ = ( 3 + 2 α N T ν ) ( 1 + ϕ R O W r 2 Π 1 e T ) ϕ ( 1 + ( α N T + ( 1 ϕ R O W ) ( 1 α N T ) ) ν ) ( 1 ϕ R O W ) ( 1 + ( α N T + ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ) ν ) ( 92 ) B 1 S > B ¯ 1 S .

For H(H¯,1], the laissez-faire equilibrium lies strictly in the interior of the first-best frontier, and the question of whether to allow crisis-time intervention becomes relevant. For very high values of H, the condition ΦT1N(ΦT1N)Lafffer may bind, because large interventions are chosen in periods t ∈ {0,1} to combat the large intertemporal distortions afflicting the union under laissez-faire.

Institutional design. As in section 3.1, regional coalitions of Northern and Southern governments must decide at the beginning of period 0 on the values of I ∈ {0,1} and γN ∈ [0,1]. As the above equations make clear, the expectation of intervention affects the optimization conditions for households and firms in period 0, so the choice of {I,γN} helps to determine the equilibrium levels of B1SandB1S+B1N for any given value of H. For I = 0, no crisis-time interventions are allowed; for I = 1, regional coalitions bargain in period 1 over unlimited interventions {δNSS}, while taking B1S and γN as given.

4.5. Pareto-improving Institutional Design

An advantage of our baseline model was that we could derive closed-form solutions for final allocations as a function of the pre-crisis degree of heterogeneity H and the choice of {I,γN}. Therefore, in section 3.3, we were able to analytically prove that regional bargaining during crises was Pareto-improving from the pre-crisis perspective for some values of H and γN. In our more elaborate financial union, the second-best nature of the post-intervention frontier means that we cannot derive closed-form solutions for all the final allocations, so for the analysis of pre-crisis welfare changes, we go straight to illustrative simulations.

Our simulations are designed to demonstrate the existence of Pareto improvements from the pre-crisis perspective, not to approximate any specific real-world financial union. To construct figures 10 and 11, we have chosen parameters to facilitate comparisons to the proofs and graphs from section 3.3.23 We plot the unconstrained allocation, the constrained laissez-faire allocation (corresponding to I = 0), and then the post-intervention allocations (corresponding to I = 1) for two values of the bargaining parameter, γN = 0 and γN = 1. We focus on a union with enough pre-crisis heterogeneity that the Southern borrowing constraint is expected to bind, i.e., H>H¯=0.28.

Figure 10.
Figure 10.

Simulation: impact of constraint on pre-crisis welfare

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

Figure 11.
Figure 11.

Simulation: institutional design

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 205; 10.5089/9781484375631.001.A001

Parameters: ϕ = 0.05, ϕROW = 0.01, αT = 0.5, αNT = 0.2, ν = 1, r = 1, eT = 0.5, A1 = 2, A2 = 4.

Figure 10 illustrates how the level of B1S and regional welfares change as we move from the unconstrained allocation to the constrained laissez-faire allocation. Panel I shows that the expectation of the binding Southern borrowing constraint reduces the level of B1S, because Southern households consume less and nontradable-sector firms invest less when they expect lower tradable and nontradable consumption in period 1.

Panel II plots the change in regional welfares, {Vi – Vi*}i∈{N,S}. The numerical findings from our elaborate financial union follow closely the predictions of proposition 4 from the baseline model. When H is such that the constraint is just binding, the constraint benefits the South and hurts the North because it tilts the “intertemporal terms of trade” in favor of the former; but when H is larger, the constraint hurts the South as well, because the intertemporal transfer of consumption away from period 1 becomes more and more painful.

Figure 11 focuses on how union-wide allocations change when crisis-time bargaining is allowed. Panel I shows that the expectation of intervention increases B1S above its laissez-faire level, because the increase in Southern consumption in period 1 stimulates higher Southern consumption and nontradable-sector investment in the previous period as well. The post-intervention level of B1S is higher when the South expects to have more bargaining power in crisis-time bargaining.

As in the baseline model, the union-wide sum of the inherited debts of households, b1S+b1N, is equal to zero. However, equations (72) and (90) establish that in our more elaborate financial union, the sum B1S+B1N changes in response to expected interventions, because the interventions generate distortions to tradable output in periods 1 and 2. Period-1 distortions reduce both of the terms in equation (90), while period-2 distortions reduce only the first term. Panel II of figure 11 shows that for our chosen parameters, the post-intervention value of B1S+B1N increases above its laissez-faire level. Therefore, the impact of period-1 distortions on the second term of equation (90) turns out to be the dominant influence.

Finally, panels III and IV demonstrate that for some parameter configurations, Pareto improvements may exist from the pre-crisis perspective. The lines in these panels show the change in regional welfares from the laissez-faire allocation to the post-intervention allocations, {Vi,γN-Vi}{N,S},γNε{0,1}. Relative to the baseline model, our more elaborate financial union has new economic mechanisms in action. The interventions generate distortions in tradable and nontradable output in periods 1 and 2, which affect investment levels as well as the pledgability of union-wide output to ROW in periods 0 and 1. In addition, welfare gains from the pre-crisis perspective are hampered by the fact that period-1 distortions are not taken into account during regional bargaining in period 1, because that bargaining process treats {kT0i,kNT0i}i{N,S}, as exogenous.

Nevertheless, for our chosen parameters, our numerical findings yield no surprises relative to the baseline model, and in fact the results from our more elaborate financial union are best understood by comparing them to proposition 5 and figure 7. VS,γN = 0 always lies above the laissez-faire level VS, while VS,γN = 1 lies above VS for H(H¯=0.28,H2=0.80]. VN,γN = 0 lies everywhere below the laissez-faire level VN, while VN,γN = 1 dips below VN for H(H¯=0.28,H1=0.43) and then exceeds VN for H ∈ (H1 = 0.43,1]. Therefore, in our more elaborate financial union, there exist values of H and γN such that regional bargaining during crises continues to be Pareto-improving from the pre-crisis perspective.

5. Conclusion

The financial integration of heterogenous regions of countries generates novel economic problems. Over and above the risk-sharing concerns that lay at the heart of the literature on optimal currency areas, we need to think about designing institutions which facilitate the efficient flow of capital from the core to the periphery, and which mitigate the financial crises that arise when the flows turn out to have been misdirected and/or excessive. Waves of financial integration mediated by asymmetric debt flows are especially subject to sudden stops when financial frictions bind, and lessons from the emerging markets literature may become surprisingly relevant—and indeed exacerbated via an endogenous interest rate—even if the member countries of the union are all advanced. The key element is that the institutions to efficiently manage capital flows may exist within but not between such countries, both because the cross-border flows are new and because political sovereignty constraints limit the creation of supranational entities until crises occur.

We have designed a model with the above environment in mind. We identify two interventions—governmental loans and/or tax-subsidy packages with debt relief—which could be used to tackle union-wide financial imperfections, going beyond the standard toolkit of monetary and fiscal policies. We focus on generating Pareto improvements so as to respect political sovereignty constraints. We analyze changes in pre-crisis welfare as well, so as to address the real fear that crisis-time bargaining may generate pre-crisis overborrowing; we find that such concerns are dominated by the size of crisis-time Pareto gains when the degree of heterogeneity of the financial union is sufficiently high.

Our baseline model and more elaborate financial union provide complementary messages. The baseline model captures our fundamental mechanisms while being simple enough to generate all final allocations, with and without intervention, in closed form. As a result, we are able to prove all of our main results and trace through all the relevant economic channels.

The more elaborate financial union preserves the result that Pareto improvements are possible, while also showing that the final allocations move from first-best to second-best, and the two interventions have quite different effects on tradable and nontradable output. In addition, we show that the current account balance of the union as a whole becomes excessively large when the governmental loan is overused relative to tax-subsidies and debt relief. The results for pre-crisis welfares do not follow closed-form solutions in the more elaborate financial union, but the numerical simulation results can be easily understood via comparison with the proofs from the baseline model.

For sufficiently heterogeneous financial unions, our main lesson holds for both the baseline model and the more elaborate financial union, and from both crisis-time and pre-crisis perspectives: inter-regional lending and debt relief institutions need to be built.

References

  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen. 1993. “Shocking Aspects of European Monetary Unification,” in Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union, Francisco Torres and Francesco Giavazzi (eds.), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Paul R. Masson. 1995. “Fiscal Flows in the United States and Canada: Lessons for Monetary Union in Europe,” European Economic Review, Vol. 39 (2), 253274.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beetsma, Roel M. W. J., and Henrik Jensen. 2005. “Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interactions in a Micro-Founded Model of a Monetary Union,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 67 (2), 320352.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benigno, Gianluca, Huigang Chen, Christopher Otrok, Alessandro Rebucci, and Eric R. Young. 2013. “Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policies,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 89, 453470.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benigno, Gianluca, Huigang Chen, Christopher Otrok, Alessandro Rebucci, and Eric R. Young. 2016. “Optimal Capital Controls and Real Exchange Rate Policies: A Pecuniary Externality Perspective,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 84, 147165.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benigno, Pierpaulo, and Federica Romei. 2014. “Debt Deleveraging and the Exchange Rate,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 93, 116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bianchi, Javier. 2010. “Credit Externalities: Macroeconomic Effects and Policy Implications,” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 100 (2), 398402.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bianchi, Javier. 2011. “Overborrowing and Systematic Externalities in the Business Cycle,” American Economic Review, Vol. 101 (7), 34003426.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, Christopher J. Erceg, and Jesper Lindé. 2015. “Jump Starting the Euro Area Recovery: Would a Rise in Core Fiscal Spending Help the Periphery?,” NBER Working Paper No. 21426.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Francesco Giavazzi. 2002. “Current Account Deficits in the Euro Area: The End of the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle?,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 33 (2), 147210.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bolton, Patrick, and Olivier Jeanne. 2011. “Sovereign Default Risk and Bank Fragility in Financially Integrated Economies,” IMF Economic Review, Vol. 59 (2), 162194.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Broner, Fernando, Aitor Erce, Alberto Martin, and Jaume Ventura. 2014. “Sovereign Debt Markets in Turbulent Times: Creditor Discrimination and Crowding-Out Effects, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 61, 114142.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Arvind Krishnamurthy. 2001. “International and Domestic Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crises,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 48 (3), 513548.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A. 1998. “Capital Flows and Capital Market Crises: The Simple Economics of Sudden Stops,” Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 1 (1), 3554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and Luis-Fernando Mejia. 2004. “On the Empirics of Sudden Stops: The Relevance of Balance-Sheet Effects,” NBER Working Paper No. 10520.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chen, Ruo, Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, and Thierry Tressel. 2012. “External Imbalances in the Euro Area,” IMF Working Paper No. 12/236.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cremers, Emily T., and Partha Sen. 2009. “Transfers, the Terms of Trade, and Capital Accumulation,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 42 (4), 15991616.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Grauwe, Paul. 1993. “The Political Economy of Monetary Union in Europe,” The World Economy, Vol. 16 (6), 653661.

  • de Grauwe, Paul. 1996. “Monetary Union and Convergence Economics,” European Economic Review, Vol. 40 (3–5), 10911101.

  • de Grauwe, Paul. 2012. “The Governance of a Fragile Eurozone,” Australian Economic Review, Vol. 45 (3), 255268.

  • Djajić, Slobodan, Sajal Lahiri, and Pascalis Raimondos-Møller. 1998. “The Transfer Problem and the Intertemporal Terms of Trade,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 31 (2), 427436.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dogra, Keshav. 2014. Optimal Debt Restructuring and Lending Policy in a Monetary Union,” Mimeo, Columbia University.

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, Ilan Goldfajn, and Rodrigo O. Valdés. 1995. “Currency Crises and Collapses,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 219293.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Michael Woodford. 2003. “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 34, Issue 1, 139235.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Farhi, Emmanuel, and Iván Werning. 2012. “Dealing with the Trilemma: Optimal Capital Controls with Fixed Exchange Rates,” NBER Working Paper No. 18199.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Farhi, Emmanuel, and Iván Werning. 2013a. “Fiscal Unions,” NBER Working Paper No. 18280.

  • Farhi, Emmanuel, and Iván Werning. 2013b. “Fiscal Multipliers: Liquidity Traps and Currency Unions,” NBER Working Paper No. 18381.

  • Fornaro, Luca. 2015. “International Debt Deleveraging,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP10469.

  • Galí, Jordi, and Tommaso Monacelli. 2008. “Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Currency Union,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 76 (1), 116132.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Luigi Spaventa. 2010. “Why the Current Account May Matter in a Monetary Union: Lessons from the Financial Crisis in the Euro Area,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8008.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goyal, Rishi, Petya Koeva Brooks, Mahmood Pradhan, Thierry Tressel, Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, Ross Leckow, and Ceyla Pazarbasioglu. 2013. “A Banking Union for the Euro Area,” IMF Staff Discussion Note No. 13/01.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, Thomas Philippon, and Dimitri Vayanos. 2016. “The Analytics of the Greek Crisis,” NBER Working Paper No. 22370.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guerrieri, Veronica, and Guido Lorenzoni. 2011. “Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings, and the Liquidity Trap,” NBER Working Paper No. 17583.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hale, Galina. 2013. “Balance of Payments in the European Periphery,” FRBSF Economic Letter, 201301.

  • Iacoviello, Matteo. 2005. “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle,” American Economic Review, Vol. 95 (3), 739764.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jeanne, Olivier, and Anton Korinek. 2010. “Excessive Volatility in Capital Flows: A Pigou-vian Taxation Approach,” American Economic Review, Vol. 100 (2), 40307.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jeanne, Olivier, and Anton Korinek. 2013. “Macroprudential Regulation Versus Mopping Up After the Crash,” NBER Working Paper No. 18675.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter. 1969. “The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View,” in Monetary Problems of the International Economy, Robert A. Mundell and Alexander K. Swoboda (eds.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keynes, John M. 1929. “The German Transfer Problem,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 39, 17.

  • Korinek, Anton. 2011. “The New Economics of Prudential Capital Controls,” IMF Economic Review, Vol. 59 (3), 523561.

  • Korinek, Anton, and Enrique G. Mendoza. 2014. “From Sudden Stops to Fisherian Deflation: Quantitative Theory and Policy,” Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 6, 299332.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Philip R.. 2012. “The European Sovereign Debt Crisis,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 26 (3), 4968.

  • Martin, Philippe, and Thomas Philippon. 2014. “Inspecting the Mechanism: Leverage and the Great Recession in the Eurozone,” NBER Working Paper No. 20572.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Midrigan, Virgiliu, and Thomas Philippon. 2011. “Household Leverage and the Recession,” NBER Working Paper No. 18675.

  • McKinnon, Ronald. 1963. “Optimum Currency Areas,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 53, 717724.

  • Mendoza, Enrique G. 2002. “Credit, Prices and Crashes: Business Cycles with a Sudden Stop,” in Preventing Currency Crises in Emerging Markets, S. Edwards and J. Frankel (eds.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique G. 2006. “Lessons from the Debt-Deflation Theory of Sudden Stops,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96 (2), 411416.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique G. and Katherine A. Smith. 2006. “Quantitative Implications of a Debt-Deflation Theory of Sudden Stops and Asset Prices,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 70, 82114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique G., Linda L. Tesar, and Jing Zhang. 2014. “Saving Europe?: The Unpleasant Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity in Integrated Economies,” NBER Working Paper No. 20200.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Merler, Silvia, and Jean Pisani-Ferry. 2012. “Sudden Stops in the Euro Area,” Bruegel Policy Contribution No. 2012/06.

  • Mundell, Robert A. 1961. “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 51 (4), 657665.

  • Mundell, Robert A. 1973. “Uncommon Arguments for Common Currencies,” in The Economics of Common Currencies, H. G. Johnson and A. K. Swoboda (eds.), London: Allen and Unwin Limited.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice. 2013. “Finance at Center Stage: Some Lessons of the Euro Crisis,” CEPR Discussion Papers 9415, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ohlin, Bertil. 1929. “The Reparation Problem: A Discussion,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 39, 172173.

  • Reis, Ricardo. 2013. “The Portuguese Slump and Crash and the Euro Crisis,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 46 (1), 143210.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shambaugh, Jay C. 2012. “The Euro’s Three Crises,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, 157231.

  • Waysand, Claire, Kevin Ross, and John C. De Guzman. 2010. “European Financial Linkages: A New Look at Imbalances,” IMF Working Paper No. 10/295.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

Proofs

Lemma 1. Take first-order conditions of the first-best maximization problem and rearrange:

c T t i , j = 2 y T t λ i j i Σ i { N , S } 0 1 λ i , j d j c T 2 i , j c T 1 i , j = y T 2 y T 1 f o r a l l i , j .

Setting λi,j = λi for all i,j, we obtain the desired result. ■

Proposition 1. The arguments in subsection 2.2 establish that the laissez-faire equilibrium is Pareto efficient if and only if b1S[0,b¯1C]. Equation (26) and the market-clearing conditions establish the consumption levels for b1S>b¯1S. The market and shadow interest rates are:

r 2 = y T 2 ( 1 2 + ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν ) 1 2 b 1 S + 1 2 y T 1 a n d R 2 S = y T 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ( 1 2 + ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν ) b 1 S ( 1 2 + 1 2 ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν ) + y T 1 ( 1 2 + 3 2 ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν ) .

We derive the required welfare results by substituting equations (25) and (26), along with the market-clearing conditions, into the expression (1). ■

Proposition 2. The arguments in subsection 2.3 establish the existence of Pareto improvements starting from b1S>b¯1S. As the intervention continues, we know from the text that dr2 > 0. In addition:

d c T 2 S = 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν d z N < 0 a n d d c T 1 S = 2 ρ x z ( γ N ) 1 r 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν d z N > 0 d R 2 S < 0 d p 2 S = 1 y N T 2 ( 1 ϕ ) ν 1 + ϕ ν d z N < 0 a n d d b 2 S = ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ν d z N < 0.

As r2 increases and R2S decreases, eventually we achieve R2S=r2. This condition combined with the union’s resource constraint (12) establishes that R2S=r2=cT2icT1i=yT2yT1 for all i, which means that the union is restored to the first-best frontier. Substituting this equality into equations (19) and (21)-(22), we derive the expression for the frontier, equation (29).

We derive the formulae (30)-(31) for consumption at the ends of the Pareto frontier by observing that US (xS, zN, 0) = US (0,0,0) for γN = 1 and that UN (xs, zN, 0) = UN (0,0,0) for γN = 0. In other words, using equations (1), (23), and (26):

l o g { ( c T 1 S , γ N = 1 ) 2 y T 2 y T 1 } = l o g { ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v y T 1 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v b 1 S ) ( y T 2 1 ϕ 1 + φ v ) } l o g { ( c T 1 N , γ N = 0 ) 2 y T 2 y T 1 } = l o g { ( 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v y T 1 + 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v b 1 S ) ( y T 2 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + φ v ) } .

Substituting equations (30)-(31) into the expression cT2S=(yT2zN)1ϕ1+ϕν from the text, we can characterize the set [zN,γN=0, zN,γN=1] :

z N , γ N = 0 = y T 2 1 + φ v 1 ϕ ( 1 + φ + 1 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v + 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ ν y T 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 ϕ z N , γ N = 1 = y T 2 y T 2 1 + ϕ v 1 ϕ ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 φ 1 + ϕ ν .

The properties zN,γN=0 < zN,γN=1 and dzNdγN>0 follow by inspection. Using equation (29), we can back out the corresponding bounds for the set [xS,γN=0, xS,γN=1].

Suppose that φ<12+v, so that panel I of figure 5 is the relevant configuration. The upper end of frontier (29) may be bounded by zN ≤ (zN)max. If so, then while zN cannot be increased further, welfare can still be transferred from South to North by reducing xs until Us (xs, zN, 0) = Us (0,0,0). The lower end of frontier (29) may be bounded by xs ≤ (xs)max. If so, then while xs cannot be increased further, welfare can still be transferred from North to South by reducing zN until UN (xS, zN, 0) = UN (0,0,0).

Next, suppose that φ<12+v, so that panel II is the relevant configuration. Then both the bounds zN(zN)max and xs(xs)max only bound the upper end of the frontier (29), and the frontier kinks at the point corresponding to the tighter of the bounds. At that point, welfare can still be transferred from South to North by reducing xs until Us (xs, zN, 0) = Us (0,0,0).

In all these cases, moving away from the blue frontier means moving inside the first-best frontier. ■

Proposition 3. The arguments in subsection 2.3 establish the existence of Pareto improvements starting from b1S>b¯1S. As the intervention continues, we know from the text that dr2 > 0. In addition:

d c T 2 S = c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S < 0 a n d d c T 1 S = 2 ρ ( γ N ) 1 r 2 c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S > 0 d R 2 S < 0 d p 2 S = 1 y N T 2 c T 2 S ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S > 0 a n d d b 2 S = c T 2 S ϕ ( 1 + ν ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) d τ S > 0.

As r2 increases and R2S decreases, again we achieve R2S=r2=cT2cT1=yT2yT1. Substituting this equality into equations (19) and (21)-(22), we derive the expression for the frontier, equation (32). The same formulae (30)-(31) apply. Substituting them into the expression cT2S=yT21ϕ1+ϕ(ν+τS+ντS) from the text, we can characterize the set [τS,γN=0, τS,γN=1]:

1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ( ν + ( 1 + ν ) τ S , γ N = 0 ) = 2 ( 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v + 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + φ v .
1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ( ν + ( 1 + ν ) τ S , γ N = 1 ) = ( 1 + 3 φ + 4 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v b 1 S y T 1 ) 1 φ 1 + φ v .

The properties τS,γN=0, τS,γN=1 and dτSdγN>0 follow by inspection. Using equation (32), we can back out the corresponding bounds for the set [xS,γN=0, xS,γN=1].

Panels III, IV, and V of figure 5 show the frontiers corresponding to different levels of b1S. The upper end of frontier (32) may be bounded by τs ≤ (τS)max. If so, then while τs cannot be increased further, welfare can still be transferred from South to North by reducing xs until Us (xs, zN, 0) = Us (0,0,0). The lower end of frontier (29) may be bounded by xs(xs)max. If so, then while xs cannot be increased further, welfare can still be transferred from North to South by reducing τs until UN (xs, zN, 0) = UN (0, 0, 0). Again, moving away from the blue frontier means moving inside the first-best frontier. ■

Lemma 2. The arguments in subsection 2.4 establish that a tax on the non-collateralizable nontradable good, θs < 0, can generate a Pareto improvement starting from b1S>b¯1S. However, when the policy tools (xS, τS) are unlimited, the final post-intervention allocation is already at the first-best frontier, so the additional tax instrument is redundant. On the other hand, if the policy tools (xS, τS) are limited, then the post-intervention allocation may be in the shaded gray zone inside the blue frontier in figure 5, and Pareto gains are not exhausted using (xs,rs) alone. Since R2S>r2, we can use the arguments in the text to generate additional Pareto improvements using the tax θs < 0. The amended Pareto frontier is:

x S = b 1 S 2 y T 1 ϕ ( 1 + ν + τ S + ν τ S θ 1 θ ( γ + γ τ S ) ) 1 + ϕ ( ν + τ S + ν τ S θ 1 θ ( γ + γ τ S ) ) .

Lemma 3. This result follows directly from substituting dxs > 0 and dzN = dτs = 0 into the equations in subsection 2.3. ■

Lemma 4. The arguments in subsection 3.2 establish that for H>H¯, the Southern debt level is given by the intersection of the black line and the appropriate gray line in panel I of figure 6. Let us compare the expressions (25), (26), (30) and (31):

c T 1 S * ( b ¯ 1 S ) = c T 1 S , C ( b ¯ 1 S ) = c T 1 S , γ N = 1 ( b ¯ 1 S ) = c T 1 S , γ N = 0 ( b ¯ 1 S ) d c T 1 S * d b 1 S = 1 2 , while d C T 1 S , C d b 1 S = 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v < 1 2 d c T 1 S , γ N = 1 d b 1 S | b 1 S = b ¯ 1 S = 1 2 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v > 1 2 a n d d 2 c T 1 S , γ N = 1 d ( b 1 S ) 2 < 0 c T 1 S , γ N = 1 = c T 1 S , C f o r b 1 S = b ¯ 1 S a n d b 1 S = ( b 1 S ) max = 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν y T 1
d c T 1 S , γ N = 0 d b 1 S | b 1 S = b ¯ 1 S = 1 2 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v > 1 2 a n d d 2 c T 1 S , γ N = 0 d ( b 1 S ) 2 > 0.

Combined, these expressions establish that b1S,C<b1S*andb1S,γN=0>b1S,γN=1>b1S,C. Next, we turn to the maximization of (28) subject to (18)-(23), which implies:

max ( 1 o g ( c T 1 S , γ N ) 2 y T 2 y T 1 1 o g { ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν y T 1 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S ) y T 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν } ) 1 γ N × ( 1 o g ( 2 y T 1 c T 1 S , γ N ) 2 y T 2 y T 1 1 o g { ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν y T 1 + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν b 1 S ) y T 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ ν } ) γ N

Substituting (44) into the first-order condition of the above problem:

Q = ( 1 γ N ) 2 c T 1 S ( 1 o g ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν y T 1 + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν ( c T 1 S , γ N y T 1 ( 1 H ) ) ) log ( 2 y T 1 c T 1 S , γ N ) 2 y T 2 y T 1 ) y T 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ U 1 + ϕ ν γ N 2 2 y T 1 c T 1 S ( 1 o g ( 1 + 3 ϕ + 4 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν y T 1 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ ν ( c T 1 S , γ N y T 1 ( 1 H ) ) ) y T 2 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν log ( c T 1 S , γ N ) 2 y T 2 y T 1 ) = 0.

Then for a fixed degree of heterogeneity H, we derive:

d c T 1 S , γ N d γ N = Q / γ N Q / c T 1 S < 0 since Q γ N < 0 and Q c T 1 S < 0.

Combining with equation (44), we establish that db1S,γNdγN<0. ■

Lemma 5. Take first-order conditions of the first-best maximization problem, rearrange, and set λi,j = λi for all i,j, as in the proof of lemma 1. ■

Proposition 4. The arguments in subsection 3.2 establish that the laissez-faire equilibrium is Pareto efficient if and only if H[0,H¯]. When H[H¯,1], it must be that b1S,C>b¯1S,SocT2S,C=c¯T2SandR2S>yT2yT1>r2;whilecT1icT0i=2yT1eT holds because there is no borrowing constraint between periods 0 and 1. The unconstrained and constrained consumption levels from the intersections of the lines in panel I of figure 5 are:

c T 1 S * = y T 1 ( 1 1 3 H ) a n d c T 2 S * = y T 2 y T 1 c T 1 S * , c T 0 S * = e T 2 y T 1 c T 1 S * c T 1 S , C = y T 1 ( 2 + 4 ϕ + 6 ϕ ν 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ ν 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ ν 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ ν H ) a n d c T 1 S , C = c ¯ T 2 S , , c T 0 S , C = e T 2 y T 1 c T 1 S , C .

We derive the required welfare results by substituting these equations into the expression (33). ■

Lemma 6. This result follows from substituting the applying the analysis of section 2 to the model in section 3, applying not just (18)-(23) but also cT0i=eT2yT1cT1i for all i, the relation (44), and the utility expression (33). ■

Proposition 5. In addition to the unconstrained and constrained consumption levels above, we can also write the post-intervention consumption levels for γN = 1 and γN = 0, again using the intersections of the lines in panel I of figure 5:

c T 1 S , γ N = 1 = 1 2 y T 1 ( 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v 1 φ 1 + φ v ) 2 + 4 ( 2 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v H ) 1 φ 1 + φ v 1 2 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v 1 φ 1 + φ v y T 1 c T 1 S , γ N = 0 = 1 2 ( 4 + 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + φ v ) y T 1 1 2 y T 1 4 1 + φ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 φ + 3 φ v 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + φ v + ( 2 + H ) + ( 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 φ v 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + φ v ) 2 .

Substituting the above equations into the expression (33), we derive the welfare expressions as a function of H:

V S * = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 1 1 3 H ) 3 } V S , C = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 2 + 4 ϕ + 6 ϕ v 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ v H ) 2 1 ϕ 1 + ψ v } V S , γ N = 1 = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 1 2 ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ v + 3 ϕ v 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) 2 + 4 + ( 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ v + 3 ϕ v H ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν 1 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ v + 3 ϕ v 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν ) 3 } V S , γ N = 0 = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 1 2 4 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v ( 2 + H ) + ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v ) 2 1 2 ( 4 + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v ) ) 3 } V N * = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 1 + 1 3 H ) 3 } V N , C = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 2 + 2 ϕ + 4 ϕ v 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ v + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 2 + 3 ϕ + 5 ϕ v H ) 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v } V N , γ N = 1 = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 1 2 ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ v ) 2 + 4 ( 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v H ) 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ ν 1 2 ( 4 + 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 ϕ 1 + ϕ v ) ) 3 }
V N , γ N = 0 = 1 o g { κ y T 1 ( 1 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v 1 2 4 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v ( 2 + H ) + ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + ϕ v ) 2 ) 3 } ,

where κ=eT2yT2Πt={0,1,2}yNTt. We compare the levels and slopes of these expressions at H=H¯ and at H=Hmax=21+2ϕ+3ϕν1+ϕ+2ϕν. We also assess how many times Vi,C and Vi,γN must intersect with each other within H[H¯=Hmax], using the following auxiliary variables where appropriate to convert the welfare formulae into expressions with integer exponents:

ϵ 1 = ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ 1 + ϕ v ) 2 + 4 ( 2 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v H ) 1 + ϕ 1 + ϕ v a n d ϵ 2 = 4 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + ϕ v ( 2 + H ) + ( 1 + ϕ + 2 ϕ v 1 + 2 ϕ + 3 ϕ v 1 + ϕ + 2 φ v 1 + ϕ v ) 2

Notice that the use of auxiliary variables may generate additional non-feasible roots which must in turn be ruled out. This process produces the correct number of intersections within H[H¯,Hmax] and the correct sign of {Vi,CVi,γN}i{N,S} around the intersections.

We then prove that H1 < H2 by observing that since interventions move the union to the first-best frontier, it must be that at least one region must be better off as a result of the intervention, no matter the value of H. For ø small enough, H2 must be smaller than 1, which means that both H1 must also be smaller than 1.

Finally, the finding from lemma 4 that dcT1S,γNdγN<0anddb1S,γNdγN<0 establishes that the set of bargaining powers consistent with a period-0 Pareto improvement is always compact. ■

Lemma 7. Take first-order conditions of the first-best maximization problem and rearrange:

c T 2 i , j = 2 ( 1 φ R O W ) Π 2 1 + α N T v λ i , j Σ i { N , S } 0 1 λ i , j j c T 1 i , j = ( ( B 1 N + B 1 S ) + 2 φ R O W r Π 2 ) λ i , j Σ i { N , S } 0 1 λ i , j j } c T 2 i , j c T 1 i , j = r 2 * f o r a l l i , j k T 1 i , j = A 2 ( α T r ) 1 1 α T a n d k N T 1 i , j = α N T v c T 2 i , j r f o r a l l i , j ,

and our assumption that r2*>r establishes that condition (67) holds with equality. Setting λi,j = λi for all i,j, we obtain the desired result. ■

Proposition 6. The arguments in subsection 4.2 establish that the laissez-faire equilibrium is Pareto efficient if and only if B1S[0,B¯1S]. Equation (77) establishes the Southern tradable consumption levels for B1S>B¯1S, while the Northern tradable consumption levels are given by:

c T 1 N , C = 1 2 + α N T v ( B 1 N + ( ϕ R O W r + 1 ϕ R O W r 2 ) Π 2 ) a n d c T 2 N , C = r 2 c T 1 N , C .

From these formulae, the market and shadow interest rates can be derived. We derive the required welfare results by substituting the first-best and constrained formulae for tradable and nontradable consumption (the latter given by the output consistent with investment level kNT1i=αNTνcT2ir for each i) into the expression (47). ■

Proposition 7. We proceed in four steps. In the first step, we use the Pareto gains formula (78) to find the Pareto-optimal choice for each intervention given a fixed value of other intervention, along the two boundaries of the Pareto set, {dUi = 0}i∈{N,S}. Notice that the two conditions dUi|dU-i=0 = 0 for i ∈ {N, S} are multiples of each other, so they boil down to just one Pareto gains condition. Rearranging, the conditions for positive Pareto gains for the governmental loan and tax-subsidy interventions are, respectively:

R 2 S r 2 > ( 1 + α N T v ) ( 1 φ R O W φ ) 1 + ( α N T + φ ( 1 α N T ) ) ( v + τ S + v τ S ) ( 1 + ξ S α τ 1 ξ S α τ ) ( 1 + α N T ( v + τ S + v τ S ) ) ( 1 φ R O W φ ) 1 + ( α N T + φ ( 1 α N T ) ) ( v + τ S + v τ S ) ( 1 + ξ S α T 1 ξ S α T ) ( ϕ R O W r 2 r + ( 1 ϕ R O W ) ) ξ S α T 1 ξ S α T R 2 S r 2 > ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ( ν + τ S + ν τ S ) + α N T ( 1 + ν ) τ S ϕ ( 1 α N T ) ( ν + τ S + ν τ S )

Taking derivatives of the consumption levels and the interest rate from the system of equations, we can establish that if we start from a constrained laissez-faire allocation, interventions along the two boundaries of the Pareto set generate:

d c T 2 S < 0 , d c T 1 S > 0 , a n d i f r 2 > r , t h e n d r 2 > 0.

In fact, such interventions strictly decrease R2Sr2 and strictly increase the right hand sides of the above inequalities until the two sides become equalized. As a result, given a fixed value of one intervention, there is a unique Pareto-optimal choice for the other intervention along each of the two boundaries {dUi = 0}i∈{N,S}. This reasoning produces the second-best reaction functions ξS,SBS) and τS,SBs) for each B1S>B¯1S.

In the second step, continuing to stick to the two Pareto boundaries, {dUi = 0}i∈{N,S}, we prove the existence of intervention combinations achieving the second-best frontier. Specifically, we plot the reaction functions in (ξSS) space and showing that they intersect. The crucial elements to prove are: (i) ξS,SB,(τS) > 0 for all τS ∈ [0,τS,SBS = 0)], where τS,SBS = 0) > 0; (ii) ξS,SBS) is defined for all τS, which means as a corollary that it is defined for τS>maxξSτS,SB(ξS); (iii) τS,SBS) > 0 for all ξs ∈ [0, ξS,SB (τS = 0)], where ξS,SB (τS = 0) > 0; and (iv) τS,SB (ξs) is defined for some ξS>maxτSξS,SB(τS). The last condition comes from the observations that, firstly, τS,SB (ξs) is defined at least up to the point where marginal changes in ξs have no effect on cT1S, and secondly, that maxτSξS,SB(τS) lies to the left of this point.

In the third step, we extend the above two steps to interventions in the interior of the boundaries of the Pareto set, {dUi = 0}i∈{N,S}. Consider intervention paths which satisfy the following formula for the period-1 transfer dΦT1N as a function of the changes in the production tax and the tax-subsidy combination:

d Φ T 1 N ( d ξ S , d T S ; ξ S , τ S ) = θ ( ξ S , τ S ) d Φ T 1 N ( d ξ S , d T S ; ξ S , τ S ) | d U N = 0 + ( 1 θ ( ξ S , τ S ) ) d Φ T 1 N ( d ξ S , d T S ; ξ S , τ S ) | d U S = 0 ,

where θ (ξs, τs) is a continuously differentiable function, and we have suppressed the dependence of the intervention on the non-policy variables of the problem. Notice that we can go from one boundary of the Pareto set to the other by altering the value of the transfer. We can prove that the set of transfers dΦT1N corresponding to Pareto improvements from a specific allocation is compact, and that its boundaries move in a continuous fashion as the allocation gradually changes. Then the first two steps of this proof apply equally to all such intervention paths.

Finally, in the fourth step, we note that since the above steps apply whether r2 > r or r2 = r, they continue to apply in the cases when the economy starts in the r2 = r region and interventions move the economy into the r2 > r region. ■

*

This paper was previously presented as “Heterogeneous Countries in a Financial Union.” For helpful discussions, we thank Olivier J. Blanchard, Marcos Chamon, Atish R. Ghosh, Francesco Giavazzi, Bernardo Huberman, Subir Lall, Alberto Martin, Jonathan D. Ostry, Vania Stavkareva, and presentation attendees at the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association 2014, the North American Meetings of the Econometric Society 2015, the Royal Economic Society 2015, the Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory 2015, and the European Economic Association 2015. All errors remaining are our own.

1

Specifically, the authors find that a large portion of this financing occurred through cross-border interbank lending and purchases of securities issued by governments and financial institutions.

2

In an early analysis of the large current account deficits of Greece and Portugal, Blanchard and Giavazzi (2002) interpreted them as a by-product of beneficial financial integration, while cautioning that nontradable goods prices would fall when external debt was eventually repaid. Taking stock eight years later, Giavazzi and Spaventa (2010) warned that the external debt repayment problem would be more severe than had been expected: in their view, capital inflows into the periphery had been used for the consumption of tradable goods and the production of nontradable goods, rather than for investment in the tradable goods sector.

3

Using monthly data, Calvo et al. (2004) define a sudden stop as occurring when year-on-year private capital inflows fall two standard deviations below their mean.

4

This label is inspired by the terminology of Shambaugh (2012), who calls for the Eurozone to develop into a “financial union”—a union of countries within which imperfections in private financial markets are offset as much as possible by supranational financial institutions (such as Eurozone-wide deposit insurance, common supervisors, and a common risk-free bond). Our approach in this paper is to assume that some financial frictions still remain within the union (hence our addition of the word “imperfect”), and then to examine supranational fiscal policies (e.g., inter-governmental loans, debt relief, and budget-neutral taxes and subsidies) that can help manage such a union.

5

In addition to the papers already referenced above, see Dornbusch et al. (1995), Calvo (1998), Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2001), Mendoza (2002, 2006), Mendoza and Smith (2006), Bianchi (2010), Jeanne and Korinek (2010), and Korinek and Mendoza (2014). These papers have introduced a variety of borrowing constraints based on the value of tradable output, nontradable output, and capital.

6

Such policies include capital inflow taxes, capital controls, and macroprudential measures.

7

We later emphasize that this tax-and-subsidy policy combination works not because of its support of the real exchange rate per se, but because it supports the price of collateralizable nontradable goods and/or assets in borrower countries.

8

In the closed-economy literature, an early work with collateral constraints based on housing values is Iacoviello (2005). More recent papers, which have incorporated inter alia the zero lower bound on interest rates, include Guerrieri and Lorenzoni (2011), Midrigan and Phillippon (2011), Eggertsson and Krugman (2012), and Korinek and Simsek (2016).

9

For open-economy models, including models of countries inside monetary unions, see Benigno and Romei (2012), Dogra (2014), Blanchard et al. (2015), and Fornaro (2016).

10

Djajić et al. (1998) and Cremers and Sen (2009) show that inter-country transfers may benefit the donor country by increasing the interest rate, under the condition that discount rates and/or elasticities of intertemporal substitution in consumption differ between countries. In our model, by contrast, we show that such transfers can increase the interest rate when preferences are identical between countries, but some countries face binding borrowing constraints.

11

For the early literature, see also McKinnon (1963), Kenen (1969), and Mundell (1973). Later empirical works include Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1993), Bayoumi and Masson (1995), and De Grauwe (1993, 1996). Recent micro-founded theoretical models that are heirs to the optimal currency literature include Beetsma and Jensen (2005), Galí and Monacelli (2008), and Farhi and Werning (2013a). These papers establish that fiscal cushioning, including inter-country transfers, is desirable in currency unions after asymmetric shocks.

12

Our flexible-price model is isomorphic to a model with sticky prices and a flexible exchange rate.

13

In addition to the papers already referenced above, see De Grauwe (2012), Lane (2012), Hale (2013), Obstfeld (2013), Waysand et al. (2010), and Reis (2013).

14

For example, Farhi and Werning (2012) characterize the optimal use of capital controls.

15

These papers, encompassing a variety of mechanisms, include Bolton and Jeanne (2011), Mendoza et al. (2013), Goyal et al. (2013), Farhi and Werning (2013b), and Broner et al. (2014).

16

Bianchi (2011), Korinek (2011), and Benigno et al. (2016) use a borrowing constraint related to the current-period value of tradable and nontradable goods, arguing that future income may not be seizable by lenders because of fraud by borrowers. In the context of European integration, the future value seems more reasonable to include in the borrowing constraint, firstly because debt-recovery institutions in advanced economies are superior to those in emerging markets, and secondly because we wish to study how expectations about future nontradable prices may constrain lending today.

17

The blue line moves gradually from downward-sloping to upward-sloping as ϕ increases. φ<12+ν is equivalent to 1ϕ1+ϕν>12, which means that setting dxS = 0, an increase in the repayment dzN increases the interest rate. This sign of the inequality is justified in section 3.

18

In panel I, the dashed red line is bounded on both ends. In panel II, only the tighter bound is relevant.

19

The graphs evolve gradually as b1S increases; there is no discrete change in behavior at the thresholds.

20

To ensure comparability of these panels with those for the governmental loan, we plot xS on the horizontal axis. For any point on the graph, gNS is the reciprocal of the slope from the origin to that point.

21

This equality is feasible because {cT2S,j,p2S,j,cNT2S,j} turn out to be identical for all j in equilibrium.

22

The desire to equalize the marginal changes in the intertemporal and intratemporal distortions means that the condition ΦT2S(ΦT2S)Laffer never binds. On the other hand, the condition ΦT1N(ΦT1N)max may bind—and if it does so, the first-best frontier goes further out of reach.

23

The parameters are: ϕ = 0.05, ϕROW = 0.01, αT = 0.5, αNT = 0.2, ν = 1, r = 1, eT = 0.5, A1 = 2, and A2 = 4. Therefore, Π1 = 0.5, Π2 = 1, H¯=0.28, and the unconstrained interest rates are r1*=1.96andr2*=1.65. Our simulation strategy is: (i) firstly, for any B1SandB1S+B1N, find the unconstrained allocation, the constrained allocation, and the two post-intervention allocations indexed by {dUi = 0}i∈{N,S}, the latter drawing on the proof of proposition 7; and (ii) secondly, endogenize both B1SandB1S+B1N for a given H.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
An Imperfect Financial Union With Heterogeneous Regions
Author:
Filippo Balestrieri
and
Mr. Suman S Basu