Assessing the Impact of Structural Reforms Through a Supply-side Framework: The Case of Argentina

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: llusinyan@imf.org

The paper uses a supply-side framework based on a production function approach to assess the role of structural reforms in boosting long-term GDP growth in Argentina. The impact of product, labor, trade, and tax reforms on each supply-side channel—capital accumulation, labor utilization, and total factor productivity, proxied with an efficiency estimate—is assessed separately and then combined to derive the total impact on growth. The largest effect of structural reforms, involving regulatory changes that promote competition and facilitate flexible forms of employment, comes through the productivity/efficiency channel. Pro-competition regulation also improves labor utilization, while lower entry barriers and trade tariffs are important for capital accumulation. Structural reforms could have substantial effects on Argentina’s long-term GDP growth; for example, an ambitious reform effort to improve business regulatory environment would add 1–1½ percent to average annual growth of GDP.

Abstract

The paper uses a supply-side framework based on a production function approach to assess the role of structural reforms in boosting long-term GDP growth in Argentina. The impact of product, labor, trade, and tax reforms on each supply-side channel—capital accumulation, labor utilization, and total factor productivity, proxied with an efficiency estimate—is assessed separately and then combined to derive the total impact on growth. The largest effect of structural reforms, involving regulatory changes that promote competition and facilitate flexible forms of employment, comes through the productivity/efficiency channel. Pro-competition regulation also improves labor utilization, while lower entry barriers and trade tariffs are important for capital accumulation. Structural reforms could have substantial effects on Argentina’s long-term GDP growth; for example, an ambitious reform effort to improve business regulatory environment would add 1–1½ percent to average annual growth of GDP.

A. Motivation

Argentina’s economic fortune has been on a declining path for a long time. Argentina’s per capita output relative to that of advanced economies nearly halved over the past 50 years (Chart). After the end of the Convergence vis-a-vis Advanced Economies commodity boom of the mid-2000s, the divergence has increased again. Underlying this, has been a disappointing productivity performance: yearly labor productivity growth has been close to zero on average since 1980, compared with a 2½ percent average increase in emerging market economies (EMs).

A01ufig01

Convergence vis-a-vis Advanced Economies

(PPP-adjusted real GDP per capita)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Source: WEO.

Low labor productivity reflects relatively weak total factor productivity and, even more, low resource utilization (particularly capital). Years of underinvestment have left Argentina with an estimated 10 percent gap in capital intensity compared to the median of EMs (Chart).1 As of 2017, Argentina’s employment rate (67 percent of working-age population) is close to the EMs median, but 10 percentage points below the median of advanced economies, and is particularly low for women.2 Finally, Argentina’s total factor productivity growth (TFP), proxied by a simple Solow-type residual, averaged essentially zero since 1980 compared to an average growth of over 1 percent in other EMs. However, this measure may be biased by the relatively greater cyclical volatility of Argentina’s economy over the last few decades. When adjusted for labor and capital utilization, TFP growth averaged ¾ percent per year since 1980 (BCRA, 2017).3

A01ufig02
Sources: Penn World Tables, and WEO.

Supply-side measures are needed to boost Argentina’s economy’s potential. Structural reforms should include opening-up the economy to international trade, increasing domestic competition, improving infrastructure, developing capital markets, and strengthening governance and institutional frameworks (for a summary of key structural policy areas, see Table 1). Without a significant reform effort, staff baseline projects only a gradual pick-up of Argentina’s GDP growth over the medium term, with limited catching up vis-à-vis advanced economies.

Advances in product market reforms appear particularly important. Argentina’s regulatory and administrative burden on businesses is one of the heaviest among EMs (Chart). The OECD indicator of product market regulation (PMR) shows Argentina has the worst overall PMR index among 42 OECD and non-OECD countries, owing to high barriers to entrepreneurship (including complex regulatory procedures which impede firm entry/expansion, and barriers in network sectors), a weak competition policy framework, high trade and other external barriers, and a significant involvement of the state in the economy, both through state-owned enterprises and price controls (see, Licetti and others, 2018; OECD, 2017). Particularly affected are retail and transport sectors (Appendix Figures A1A2). A large body of literature shows that product market reforms are likely to have a strong impact on growth and productivity (see, for example, EU, 2004; IMF, 2015a; Égert and Gal, 2016; Bouis and others, 2016). In addition to lowering the cost of doing business, well-functioning product markets facilitate a better allocation of resources across firms and sectors, lead to a better utilization of labor and capital, and yield stronger incentives to innovate.

A01ufig03
Sources: WEO and Fraser Institute.

Reforms of labor market regulations and tax systems would also likely increase efficiency and resource utilization. Stringent labor market regulations, such as high firing costs and restrictions on temporary employment, hamper efficient allocation of resources in the economy, discourage investment, and lead to labor underutilization and informality (see Canales Kriljenko and others, 2017). High tax burden, especially on labor, have similar adverse effects on investment, labor utilization (particularly formal employment), and overall competitiveness of the economy (see Dudine and others, 2017).

The main objective of this paper is to quantify the impact of structural reforms on long-term GDP growth in Argentina. We use a supply-side framework based on a production-function approach, following Égert and Gal (2016), to assess the role of the reforms in boosting long-term GDP growth through their impact on (i) capital accumulation, (ii) labor utilization, and (iii) total factor productivity or efficiency.4 A key advantage of this method is that it presents GDP growth as the sum of separable and independent supply-side components, allowing us to analyze the effect of reforms for each component separately first and then together to obtain the overall impact on growth. The main novelty in our paper is that we proxy TFP with an estimated measure of efficiency (using a stochastic frontier analysis approach) rather than a Solow-type residual.

The paper finds that structural reforms can have significant impact on long-term GDP growth through all three supply-side channels. The largest effect of structural reforms generally comes through the productivity/efficiency channel. We find that regulatory changes that promote competition and ease labor market regulations (especially facilitating flexible forms of employment) matter the most for the efficiency channel. Pro-competition regulation also appears to improve labor utilization, together with lower tax rates on income and payroll, while lower entry barriers (cost of starting a business) and trade tariffs are especially important for capital accumulation. For Argentina, policies to promote capital and labor utilization promise to have larger payouts, given the size of the gaps accumulated in both areas. An ambitious reform effort, which were to improve business regulatory environment (closing half the gap with Australia and New Zealand over two decades), would add 1–1½ percent to average annual growth of GDP. Reducing trade tariffs and payroll taxes (closing half the gap with Australia and New Zealand) could each boost average annual real GDP growth by about 0.1 percent.

B. Framework and Data

A production function approach is used to estimate the impact of structural reforms on GDP growth. Following Égert and Gal (2016) and Égert (2017a), we quantify the impact of structural reforms on per capita GDP growth based on the following production function framework

Δln(YN)GDP growthper capita=α1αΔln(KY{z})Change in capital-output ratio+Δln(EWP{z})Change inemployment rate+11α(ΔTE{z})Change in technicalefficiency(1)

where α is the output elasticity of capital and z is a set of structural variables, including indicators of product and labor market regulations (see Appendix 1 Table A2). The specification in Eq. (1) assumes constant returns to scale and a constant working-age population ratio. Different from Égert and Gal (2016), the change in TFP is not derived as a Solow-type residual but is proxied by a change in technical efficiency, estimated with a stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) approach (see Box 1 and Appendix 2). In the SFA framework, the change in TFP can be expressed as a sum of (i) the change in the country-specific technical efficiency, and (ii) the technological change common to all countries. For our analysis, we assume that the common technological change is zero, as this is a component of GDP growth which is unlikely to be affected by Argentina’s (or any small country) specific reform.

The link between structural variables and each supply-side channel is estimated separately. Following the literature (for example, Barnes and others, 2013; Bouis and Duval, 2011; Égert and Gal, 2016; Égert 2017a), cross-country, reduced-form panel data regressions are estimated for both the capital-output ratio and employment rate, relating them to both structural and macroeconomic variables. We rely mostly on random-effects model with robust standard errors (as opposed to cross-sectional or between estimates) as this allows us to capture both cross-sectional (between-country) and time-series (within-country) information.5 This is important because, while we expect structural variables to vary more across countries, factor utilization is most likely to be affected by within-country cyclical fluctuations. Technical efficiency is estimated within an SFA approach, conditional on the same set of structural and macroeconomic variables (see Box 1).

A sample of about 60 advanced and emerging economies is used in the paper. We build a sample of 32 EMs (of which seven Latin American countries) and 27 advanced economies covering the period of 1980–2016 (the sample periods, however, vary for different variables depending on data availability). Real output, total stock of capital, employment, and other macroeconomic data are mainly from the IMF WEO database, The Penn World Tables, and World Bank WDI. A wide range of data sources are used for structural variables covering the areas of business regulations, labor market, taxation, trade barriers, governance, educational attainment, wealth, energy use, and financial development (see Appendix 1 for data description).

C. Structural Reforms and Impact on Capital, Labor, and Efficiency

Capital Deepening

There is evidence in the literature that product market reforms affect investment and capital accumulation. Regulation affects investment through its impact on: (i) price markups and entry costs, which affect the number of firms (Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2001; Alesina and others, 2005); (ii) the cost of adjusting or expanding the capital stock for existing firms; and (iii) the rate of return on capital, which affects the demand for capital. The empirical literature on investment has emphasized the role of macroeconomic and financial determinants at the expense of structural drivers. Still, there is some evidence that less restrictive product market regulation is conducive to greater capital deepening (see Égert, 2017b).6 Alesina and others (2005), for example, explore the link between product market regulation and investment at a sectoral level (for network industries) and find that entry barriers are negatively related to investment in OECD countries. Simulations based on general equilibrium models also tend to illustrate the positive impact of product market reforms on capital accumulation (de Bandt and Vigna, 2008). In contrast, Bouis and others (2016), looking at major reform episodes in five network industries, do not find evidence that product market deregulation boosts investment. In our analysis, we explore the relation between a number of structural variables (see Appendix Figure A3) and the capital-output ratio, controlling for macroeconomic (output) volatility (which we expect to discourage investment).

Our results confirm that reducing entry barriers, especially the cost of starting a business, and trade tariffs boost capital deepening (Appendix Table A3). This is in line with the finding in the literature that only policies that affect firms’ cost of entry have long-run effects on investment (Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2003; Schiantarelli, 2010).7 In addition, we find that capital intensity is affected (negatively) by output volatility and (positively) by the availability of private credit and latest technologies. The latter variable is related to the degree of trade openness and is used instead of trade tariffs in some specifications. Variables that proxy the cost of capital (corporate tax rate, real interest rate, relative investment prices) and labor market regulations do not seem to be strongly associated with investment. Simulations show that cutting the cost of starting a business (proxied by the number of required procedures) to close half the gap relative to the average of Australia and New Zealand would increase Argentina’s capital-output ratio by 0.2 percentage points, bringing it closer to the median of EMs and regional peers. The increase would be more modest (less than 0.1 percentage point) if Argentina’s trade tariffs were reduced half way to the levels in these two countries.

Employment Rate

A large body of literature has looked at the effects of structural policies on labor market outcomes. A recent reassessment of such policies in advanced economies by Gal and Theising (2015) confirms earlier results of a positive impact on employment from a smaller tax wedge on labor (see also IMF, 2015b), lower unemployment benefits, and stronger active labor market policies. More competition-friendly product market reforms (which lower markups and prices and thus increase the demand for final goods) should stimulate firms’ demand for labor and increase real wages (so that labor supply increases to match the greater demand for labor). Empirical evidence generally confirms that product market deregulation is likely to boost employment (see, for example, Nicoletti and others, 2001a/b; de Bandt and Vigna, 2008; Fiori and others, 2012; Gal and Theising, 2015; Schiantarelli, 2016). Evidence from both advanced and emerging market economies suggests that more rigid labor market institutions (stricter employment protection legislation or EPL) tends to negatively affect employment rates of more disadvantaged workers (women, less educated, youth) and could lead to greater labor market segmentation and informality (Muravyev, 2014). Fiori and others (2012) and Bouis and others (2016) find that, in countries with more stringent EPL, product market reforms have greater potential to deliver job gains.8 In our analysis, in addition to structural indicators showed in Appendix Figure A4, we include the output gap (to account for the macroeconomic conditions) and several demographic variables (such as shares of female and children in the population, and dependency ratios).

Results from panel data regressions show a robust positive link between employment rate and pro-competition regulation (Appendix Table A4). Implementing product market reforms to close half the gap with the average of Australia and New Zealand would increase Argentina’s employment rate from the current 67 percent to 73. Changes in labor market regulations are not strongly related to the overall employment rate, in line with the literature. Instead, the effect of changes in the tax rate appears statistically important, though small (both with or without the interaction with tax compliance). A reduction in Argentina’s top marginal income and payroll tax rate from the current 58 percent to 50 percent is associated with an increase in Argentina’s employment rate of about one percentage point.

Efficiency of Factor Utilization

Total factor productivity is generally found to be the main channel through which structural reforms affect growth. Many studies (especially at firm- and industry-level) find robust evidence that pro-competition product market reforms help increase TFP growth (Nicoletti and Scarpetta, 2003; EU, 2004; Faini and others, 2006; Buccirossi and others, 2009; Bourles and others, 2013; IMF, 2015a; Dabla-Norris and others, 2016; Bailliu and others, 2016; Égert, 2017c). While labor market deregulation generally appears to have a smaller positive impact on TFP (Bouis and Duval, 2011), some studies find that stringent employment protection does lower productivity growth (Bassanini and others, 2009, and Cette and others, 2014). IMF (2015) shows that the most significant productivity gains for EMs are associated with reforms that improve business regulations, ease labor market restrictions, and fiscal structural reforms.9 While all these studies tend to derive TFP as a Solow-type residual, we estimate technical efficiency using a SFA approach (see Box 1 and Appendix 2). This has the advantage to simultaneously estimate efficiency in the production function and its determinants. In addition to structural indicators, we control for the impact of the change in terms of trade and the output gap.

Production Frontier and Efficiency: A Simple Illustration

For a given set of countries, a production or efficiency frontier is the greatest level of output that is possible to produce given the factors of production utilized, and the technology adopted. The further away a country’s actual output is from the efficiency frontier, the less technically efficient is the country. This distance depends on country-specific characteristics. To estimate this frontier and a country’s distance from it, a stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) technique is used in this paper (see Appendix 2 for technical details). In this setting, the efficiency of production is not a residual from the estimated production function, but a more “structured” variable—its mean and/or variance reflect factors (including structural determinants) that explain the level and volatility of efficiency across countries. Country-specific random shocks are expected to capture the cyclical variability of efficiency at the country level, while common time effects capture the impact of global shocks.

To illustrate the results of SFA, in a simple case output per worker is modeled as a function of capital per worker (see Appendix Table A5 for estimation results). The results show that as of 2016, given its very low level of capital per worker, Argentina was somewhat behind the production function but the distance was not out of line compared to other (more capital-intensive) economies (Chart). This is in line with BCRA’s growth accounting framework (BCRA, 2017) showing that Argentina’s low labor productivity growth seems more a consequence of underinvestment in physical capital. However, our results also show that the estimated efficiency for Argentina has worsened in the last decade, whereas the median of EMs and the full sample of countries remained broadly unchanged (Chart). Compared to the average technical efficiency of Australia and New Zealand in 2016, Argentina was more than 10 percent inefficient. Furthermore, the aggregate efficiency performance likely masks important differences in intersectoral productivity (not covered in this paper). For example, there is evidence that productivity growth in the agricultural sector has been relatively upbeat (Dabla-Norris and others, 2013).

A01ufig04

Production Frontier, 2016

(Thousands of PPP dollars)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Source: IMF staff estimates.1/ Heterogenous and heteroskedastic efficiency model.
A01ufig05

Output per Worker (Y/L) and Technical Efficiency (TE)

(Thousands of PPP dollars unless otherwise indicated)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Source: IMF staff estimates.1/ Heterogenous and heteroskedastic efficiency model; 2/ Index, right axis.

Our result show that efficiency is strongly associated with both product and labor market indicators. The results from a full-fledged SFA (Appendix Table A6) suggest that regulations promoting competition (the combined index of perceived regulatory quality from WB-WGI, 2016) and less regulated labor market (especially in terms of working time regulation) lead to greater efficiency (that is, lower inefficiency in the SFA model and Appendix Table A6).10 This is especially relevant for Argentina as these are areas where the country seem to underperform relative to others (Chart)—hence, there is a greater scope to catch up. Using the conservative (lower-bound) estimate of the elasticity of technical efficiency with respect to the indicator of pro-competition regulations, suggests that Argentina’s efficiency could increase by over 10 percent if reforms were to close half the gap with Australia and New Zealand.11 It is important to note that this is unlikely to happen quickly, and would likely require many years of sustained reform effort.12 Other potential determinants of efficiency, such as measures of human capital have not been found robust in our SFA regressions.

A01ufig06
Source: World Bank WGI, 2016 Update.

D. What is the Potential Impact of Structural Reforms on Growth?

Finally, we combine the effects of structural reforms on efficiency, capital, and labor. We use Eq. (1) and the results from the previous Section on the estimated elasticities of efficiency, capital, and labor with respect to changes in structural variables (z).13 We focus on the effects of the four policy changes which have been found to have the strongest impact on capital intensity, employment rate, and efficiency in our cross-country regressions, that is: (i) measures that make product market regulation more competition and private-sector friendly, in particular by reducing the costs to start a business; (ii) measures that ease labor market regulations, in particular by facilitating flexible forms of work arrangements; (iii) eliminating trade tariffs; and (iv) cutting top marginal income and payroll tax rate.

Illustrative simulations suggest that structural reforms could have substantial effects on long-term GDP growth. We simulate the impact on long-term GDP growth of structural reforms that would get Argentina closer to Australia and New Zealand, two countries that have experienced significant reforms in the past and tend to show the highest scores in many structural indicators considered in this paper. We thus assume that, following the reforms, the structural policy variables for Argentina would slowly converge to the average value for Australia and New Zealand, with half the distance covered over a twenty-year period. For example, introducing measures to reduce the gap in the cost of starting a business (an area where Argentina’s gap with the frontier is the largest) would be associated with additional annual GDP growth of 0.15 percent only through the increase in capital intensity and about one percent through both the capital and efficiency channels (Chart).14

A01ufig07
Source: IMF staff estimates.For each policy variable, the chart shows Argentina’s distance from the frontier and the estimated increase in annual growth rate of real GDP if half of the distance is closed in twenty years, together with the supply-side channel through which GDP is affected.

E. Conclusion

Structural reforms will take time to materialize but are essential to boost Argentina’s economic potential in a sustained way. Argentina’s catching up with advanced economies in terms of GDP per capita requires a series of structural reforms that will take a long time to get ingrained. In Australia, for example, one of the benchmark counties in this paper, wide-ranging structural reforms continued for over three decades.15 This paper provided some quantitative insights into potential long-run effects that structural reforms could have on Argentina’s growth.

Policies and regulations which would promote investment and capital deepening should be at the core of the structural reform agenda. Facilitating firm creation and entry, including by reducing high costs to start a business, and opening the economy to trade, by lowering tariffs and promoting technology spillovers, would contribute to growth through greater capital deepening and efficiency gains. In addition, productivity could further benefit from less restrictive labor market regulations, while lower tax burden and pro-competition policies and regulations would boost growth mainly through higher employment and efficiency.

Table 1.

Argentina—Structural Policy Areas: Distortions, Effects, and Reform Actions

article image
Sources: IMF staff, OECD, and World Bank (various publications).

Appendix 1. Data Sources and Description

Table A1.

List of Countries

article image
Table A2.

List of Variables

article image
article image
Figure A1.
Figure A1.

Restrictiveness of Product Market Regulations (PMR)

(Index from 0=least restrictive to 6=most restrictive)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Sources: OECD Going for Growth 2017, and OECD Economic Surveys: Argentina 2017.Note: LATAM=average of Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Costa Rica, and Brazil.
Figure A2.
Figure A2.

Restrictiveness of Sectoral Regulation

(Index from 0=least restrictive to 6=most restrictive)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Source: OECD Going for Growth 2017.Note: LATAM=average of Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Costa Rica, and Brazil.
Figure A3.
Figure A3.

Capital Deepening and Structural Measures

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Sources: World Bank, Penn World Tables, WEF, and WEO.
Figure A4.
Figure A4.

Employment Rate and Structural Measures

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 183; 10.5089/9781484362990.001.A001

Sources: World Bank, Penn World Tables, Fraser, and CBR Labour Regulation Index Dataset, University of Cambridge. Note: Excludes Luxembourg and Cyprus.

Appendix 2. Stochastic Frontier Analysis

SFA: Main Elements1

The level of output for country i at time t, denoted with Yi,t can be represented as

yi,t={f(Xi,tt;β)exp(vi,t)}θi,t(zi,t;γ)(1a)

where the first term in {…} is the country-specific efficiency frontier, in which Xi,t denotes the quantities of inputs (e.g., labor and capital), β is the vector of parameters that define the production function (common to all countries), t is time trend (proxy for technological change), and exp(vi,t) is a random shock which captures measurement errors and exogenous shocks. The second term, θit (zit; γ) ∈ (0,1], captures the time-varying distance of actual output from the efficiency frontier, and is referred to as the degree of technical efficiency, such that θit = 1 indicates that the country is achieving the optimal output with the technology embodied in the production function f(·). Technical efficiency, in turn, is conditional on explanatory variables zi,t, such as structural policy variables, with the vector of parameters γ. The SFA technique used in the paper allows for a simultaneous estimation of the parameters of the stochastic frontier and of the technical efficiency with a maximum likelihood method (see Battese and Coelli, 1995).

For a log-linear Cobb-Douglas production function, with capital (K) and labor (L) as inputs, and ui,t = −ln(θi,t) denoting inefficiency, Eq. (1a) can be written as follows:2

Frontier:lnYi,t=β0+βtt+βLlnLi,t+βKlnKi,t+vi,tui,t(2a)
Modelofinefficiency:ui,t=z0+γzzi,t+wi,t(3a)

The point estimates of technical efficiency (TE) can be derived via E[exp{−ui,t|}], where = vi,tui,t is the model error term comprised of the two independent, unobservable error terms. The coefficient βt on the time trend represents the change in the frontier output caused by technological change. Kumbakhar and Lovell (2000) show that a change in TFP, defined as output growth unexplained by input growth, can be expressed as

ΔTFP=ΔT+ϵTE+(ε1)[εLεϵxL+εKεϵxK]

where ΔT=βt=dydt is technological change, ΔTE=dudt is change in technical efficiency, and ϵL(ϵK) output elasticities with respect to labor (capital), with ϵ = ϵL + ϵK specifying returns to scale (ϵ = 1 is the case of constant returns to scale).

2

A more general translog form [lnYi,t = β0 + βtt + βLlnLi,t + βKlnki,t + 0.5 [βLL(lnLi,t)2 + βKK(lnKi,t)2 + βttt2] + βKL(lnLi,t)(lnKi,t) + βLtt · lnLi,t + βKtt · lnKi,t + vi,tθi,t] has also been tested for robustness but additional terms compared to the standard form in Eq. (2a) have not been found to be significant.

Appendix 3. Empirical Results and Robustness Analysis

Table A3.

Use of Capital

Dependent variable: log of employment rate ln(K/Y)

article image
Notes: z-statistics in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Regressions include a constant term, year effects, and time trend (not reported here). RE=fixed-effects estimator. See Appendix 1 for the definitions and sources of variables.

Columns (1)–(5): number of procedures; (6): number of days.

Table A4.

Use of Labor

Dependent variable: log of employment rate ln(E/WP)

article image
Notes: z-statistics in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Regressions include a constant term, year effects, and time trend (not reported here). RE=random-effects, FE=fixed-effects, MG=mean group estimator. See Appendix 1 for the definitions and sources of variables.
Table A5.

Stochastic Frontier Analysis: A Simple Illustration

Frontier: ln(Y/L)i,t = β0 + βtt + β1ln(K/L)i,t + vi,tui,t

Model of inefficiency: ui,t = z0 + γzzi,t + wi,t

Dependent variable: log real GDP-to-labor ratio

article image
Notes: z-statisaics in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.See Appendix 1 <or the definitions and sources of variables.
Table A6.

Stochastic Frontier Analysis with Conditional Inefficiency Effects

Frontier: lnYi,t = β0 + βtt + βLlnLi,t + βKlnKi,t + vi,tui,t

Model of inefficiency: ui,t = z0 + γzzi,t + wi,t

Dependent variable: log real GDP

article image
Notes: z-statistics in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. See Appendix 1 for the definitions and sources ofvariables.

References

  • Alesina, A., Ardagna, S., Nicoletti, G., and F. Schiantarelli. 2005, Regulation and Investment, Journal of the European Economic Association 3(4): 791825.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Artana, D., Bour, E., Bour, J.L., and N. Sumsel, 2010, Strengthening long-term growth in Argentina, Paper prepared for the OECD Economic Development and Review Committee (EDRC) Seminar “Beyond the crisis – returning to sustainable growth in Latin America.” Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bailliu, J., and Ch. Hejzler, 2016, Structural Reforms and Economic Growth in Emerging-Market Economies, Bank of Canada Review, Autumn 2016: 4760.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banks, G., 2005, Structural Reform Australian-style: Lessons for Others? Based on presentations to the IMF and World Bank (Washington DC, 26-27 May 2005). Productivity Commission. OECD (Paris, 31 May 2005). Available via Internet at: http://www.oecd.org/australia/39218531.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barnes, S., Bouis, R., Briard, P., Dougherty, S., and M. Eris, 2013, The GDP Impact of Reform: A Simple Simulation Framework, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 834.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bassanini, A., Nunziata, L., and D. Venn, 2009, Job Protection Legislation and Productivity Growth in OECD Countries, Economic Policy April 2009: 349402.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Battese., G.E. and T.J. Coelli, 1995, A Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects in a Stochastic Frontier Production Function for Panel Data, Empirical Economics 20, pp. 325332.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • BCRA, 2017, Informe de Política Monetaria, January.

  • Blanchard, O., and F. Giavazzi, 2003, Macroeconomic Effects of Regulations and Deregulation in Goods and Labor Markets, Quarterly Journal of

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bouis, R., and R. Duval, 2011, Raising Potential Growth after the Crisis: A Quantitative Assessment of the Potential Gains from Various Structural Reforms in the OECD Area and Beyond, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 835.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bouis, R., Duval, D., and J. Eugster, 2016, Product Market Deregulation and Growth: New Country-Industry-Level Evidence, IMF Working Paper WP/16/114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buccirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G., and C. Vitale, 2009, Competition Policy and Productivity Growth: An Empirical Assessment, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7470.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourles, R., Cette, G., Lopez, J., Mairesse, J., and G. Nicolleti, 2013, Do Product Market Regulations in Upstream Sectors Curb Productivity Growth? Panel Data Evidence from OECD Countries, The Review of Economics and Statistics 95(5): 17501768.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canales Kriljenko, J.I., Munkacsi, Z., and P. Dudine, 2017, Labor Market Informality in Argentina: Evolution, Incentives, and Policies. In: Argentina: Selected Issues. IMF Country Report No. 17/410. Available via Internet at: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/CR/Issues/2017/12/29/Argentina-Selected-Issues-45531

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cardarelli, R., and L. Lusinyan, 2015, U.S. Total Factor Productivity Slowdown: Evidence from the U.S. States. IMF Working Paper WP/15/116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • CBR-LRI, CBR Labour Regulation Index, June 2016— Adams, Z., Bishop, L., and S. Deakin, 2016, CBR Labour Regulation Index (Dataset of 117 Countries), Cambridge: Centre for Business Research.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cette, G., Lopez, J., and J. Mairesse, 2014, Product and Labor Market Regulations, Production Prices, Wages, and Productivity, NBER Working Paper No. 20563.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dabla-Norris, E., Ho, G., Kochhar, K., Kyobe, A., and R. Tchaidze, 2013, Anchoring Growth: The Importance of Productivity-Enhancing Reforms in Emerging Market and Developing Economies, IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/13/08.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dabla-Norris, E., Ho, G., and A. Kyobe, 2016, Structural Reforms and Productivity Growth in Emerging Market and Developing Economies, IMF Working Paper WP/16/15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Bandt, O., and O. Vigna, 2008, The Macroeconomic Impact of Structural Reforms, Banque de France, Quarterly Selection of Articles No. 11.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dudine, P., Fenochietto, R., Malta, V., and M. Mendes Tavares, 2017, How to Reduce Argentina’s Tax Wedge. In: Argentina: Selected Issues. IMF Country Report No. 17/410. Available via Internet at: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/CR/Issues/2017/12/29/Argentina-Selected-Issues-45531

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Égert, B., 2017a, The Quantification of Structural Reforms: Extending the Framework to Emerging Market Economies. OECD (forthcoming).

  • Égert, B., 2017b, Regulation, Institutions and Aggregate Investment: New Evidence from OECD Countries, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1392.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Égert, B., 2017c, Regulation, Institutions and Productivity: New Evidence from OECD Countries, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1393.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Égert, B., and P. Gal, 2016, The Quantification of Structural Reforms in OECD Countries: A New Framework. OECD ECO/WKP(2016)78.

  • EU, 2004, The Link Between Product Market Reforms and Productivity: Direct and Indirect Impacts. Available via Internet at: http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/pages/publication7724en.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Faini, R., Navaretti, G.B., Haskel, J., Scarpa, C., and Ch. Wey, 2006, Contrasting Europe’s Decline: Do Product Market Reforms Help? In T. Boeri, M. Castanheira, R. Faini, V. Galasso (Eds), Structural Reforms Without Prejudices, UK: Oxford University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fiori, G., Nicoletti, G., Scarpetta, S., and F. Schiantarelli, 2012, Employment Effects of Product and Labor Market Reforms: Are there Synergies? Economic Journal 122/558: F79-F104.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fraser, 2016, Economic Freedom of the World - 2016 Annual Report, Fraser Institute.

  • Gal, P., and A. Theising, 2015, The Macroeconomic Impact of Structural Policies on Labour Market Outcomes in OECD Countries: A Reassessment, OECD Economic Department Working Paper No. 1271.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 2015a, Structural Reforms and Macroeconomic Performance: Initial Considerations for the Fund, Staff Report. Available via Internet at: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2015/101315.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 2015b, Fiscal Policy and Long-Term Growth, IMF Policy Paper. Available via Internet at:https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2015/042015.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 2016, Argentina: Selected Issues. IMF Country Report No. 16/347. Available via Internet at:https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2016/cr16347.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 2017, Estimating the Stock of Public Capital in 170 Countries. Available via Internet at:https://www.imf.org/external/np/fad/publicinvestment/pdf/csupdate_jan17.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF-WEO, World Economic Outlook database, April 2017.

  • Kumbakhar, S.C., and C.A.K. Lovell, 2000, Stochastic Frontier Analysis, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K.

  • Licerti, M., Iootty, M., Goodwin, T., and J. Signoret, 2018, Strengthening Argentina’s Integration into the Global Economy Policy: Proposals for Trade, Investment, and Competition. The World Bank Group. Available via Internet at: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/938061523423972108/pdf/125115-PUB-PUBLIC-pubdate-4-10-18.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Muravyev, A., 2014, Employment Protection Legislation in Transition and Emerging Markets. IZA World of Labor, 2014.

  • Nicoletti, G., Haffner, R.C.G., Nickell, S., Scarpetta, S., and G. Zoega, 2001a, European Integration, Liberalization, and Labor Market Performance, in Bertola G., T. Boeri and G. Nicoletti (eds.) Welfare and Employment in United Europe, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nicoletti, G., Bassanini, A., Ernst, E., Jean, S., Santiago, P., and P. Swaim, 2001b, Product and Labor Markets Interactions in OECD Countries. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 312.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nicoletti, G., and S. Scarpetta, 2003, Regulation, Productivity and Growth: OECD Evidence, Economic Policy 18 (36): 972.

  • OECD, 2017, OECD Economic Surveys: Argentina 2017: Multi-dimensional Economic Survey, OECD Publishing, Paris. Available via Internet at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-arg-2017-en

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • PWT9.0, Penn World Table, version 9.0— Feenstra, R.C., Inklaar, R., and M.P. Timmer, 2015, The Next Generation of the Penn World Table, American Economic Review 105(10): 31503182.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schiantarelli, F., 2010, Product Market Regulation and Macroeconomic Performance: A Review of Cross-Country Evidence, In Business Regulation and Economic Performance: 2363.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schiantarelli, F., 2016, Do Product Market Reforms Stimulate Employment, Investment, and Innovation? IZA World of Labor 2016: 266.

  • WB-WDI, World Development Indicators database, The World Bank.

  • WB-WGI, 2016, The Worldwide Governance Indicators, 2016 Update, The World Bank.

  • WEF, World Economic Forum—The Global Competitiveness Report 2016–2017 database.

1

IMF (2016) discusses in detail Argentina’s capital accumulation and infrastructure gaps.

2

Artana and others (2010) show that while Argentina’s gap in labor utilization—measured in per capita hours worked relative to the United States—declined since mid-1990s, it remained relatively high at close to 10 percent by 2008.

3

TFP growth is very volatile with or without adjusting for resource utilization.

4

The paper does not cover short-run dynamics and the adjustment costs of the reforms.

5

The appropriateness of a random-effects model is tested and confirmed through the Hausman test (not reported in the paper).

6

The relation between PMR and capital-intensity (which is the inverse of capital productivity) may, however, not be straightforward: if more efficient markets make capital more productive, less capital would be needed to produce the same output, and K/Y would be lower. This is unlikely the case for Argentina, though, which starts from a very low capital-output ratio (the stock of capital grew at an average annual rate of 2.8 percent since 1980, compared 3.7 percent in the regional peers, 4.2 percent in EMs, and 3.1 percent in the advanced economies).

7

Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) show that product market deregulation which does not lower entry costs (number of firms remains unchanged) would have only short-term effects resulting in firms’ exit and the return of the economy to its prederegulation equilibrium. Instead, lower entry costs decrease the rents the firms require to enter and stay in the market and lead to entry of firms and more competition in the long run.

8

The basic intuition behind this is that the response of employment to product market deregulation depends on how far the economy is from the full-employment level. In countries with more stringent EPL, real wages are likely to exceed market-clearing levels and the economy is far away from full employment. Hence, a decrease in the markup as a result of deregulating product markets is more effective at the margin compared to the situation where EPL is less stringent and employment is closer to full employment levels.

9

Capital market development also has the potential to deliver large benefits, especially when accompanied by a reform of the legal system and property rights.

10

To better control for cyclical effects, output gap (as a proxy for such effects) is included in some specifications (Appendix Table A6, columns 5–7), although in principle there may not be a clear delineation between underutilization of resources because of exogenous shocks or because of underlying inefficiency. The results show the expected negative sign between more the output gap and inefficiency (that is, the more positive is the output gap, the smaller is the distance from the frontier) but do not significantly affect other estimates.

11

That is, with the average value of the WB-WGI (2016) indicator for these countries in 2015.

12

To put this into perspective, in the scale of -2.5=weak to +2.5=strong for the WB-WGI regulatory quality index, Australia’s indicator improved by about 0.6 points in twenty years from 1996. For Argentina, closing half the gap with the average of Australia and New Zealand would imply an improvement more than twice as large.

13

Output elasticity of capital, α, is set to 0.33 in simulations, which is the standard value in the literature but is on the low side compared to 0.57 (implied from the recent values from Penn World Tables for Argentina) or about 0.61 estimated in Appendix Table A6.

14

For Argentina, OECD (2017) finds that implementing a wide range of structural reforms to converge to the OECD average over a ten-year period would add 1½ percent to the annual growth rate. Estimates from existing studies for other EMs suggest similar large effects from structural reforms: for example, Bailliu and others (2016) estimate that implementing the structural reforms planned since 2014 in China, India, Indonesia, and Mexico (including product market reforms, trade and FDI liberalization, and infrastructure investment), would increase average annual real potential GDP by 1½–2 percentage points.

15

Structural reform process in Australia started in the 1970s, with tariff reductions; accelerated in the early 1980s, by further opening to trade, and in the late 1980s/1990s, with a focus on labor market reforms (shifting wage bargaining from centralized to enterprise level) and lowering company tax rate; and consolidated in the 1990s with strengthening competition policies (Banks, 2005).

Assessing the Impact of Structural Reforms Through a Supply-side Framework: The Case of Argentina
Author: Ms. Lusine Lusinyan