Abstract
Empirical tests of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve have provided results often inconsistent with microeconomic evidence. To overcome the pitfalls of standard estimations on aggregate data, a Full Information Partial Equilibrium approach is developed to exploit sectoral level data. A model featuring sectoral NKPCs subject to a rich set of shocks is constructed. Necessary and sufficient conditions on the structural parameters are provided to allow sectoral idiosyncratic components to be linearly extracted. Estimation biases are corrected using the model's restrictions on the partial equilibrium propagation of idiosyncratic shocks. An application to the US, Japan and the UK rejects the purely forward looking, labor cost-based NKPC.
1 Introduction
In its standard formulation, the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) relates current inflation πt to the current gap
Considerable effort has been dedicated to the estimation of the slope of the NKPC, i.e. the parameter λ in front of
The literature has taken two main approaches to tackle the error endogeneity problem. The first is based on single-equation Limited Information (LI) techniques. The guiding principle is to estimate the NKPC by applying GMM/IV methods to correct for the potential estimation bias. Mavroedis et al. (2014) present an extensive survey of this literature, which features a wide set of point estimates, often suffering from weak identification.1 The second is the Full Information (FI) approach, where the NKPC is estimated jointly with all the other structural equations of the NK model. The joint estimation aims to tackle the endogeneity problem head-on by explicitly characterizing the endogenous interactions of the macroeconomic variables through the restrictions derived from the fully-specied NK model. Schorfheide (2008) surveys this part of the literature and finds, again, a wide range of empirical estimates for λ, a significant fraction of which appears too small - namely they imply too much price stickiness - to be consistent with the degree of price rigidity that emerges from microeconomic evidence (Nakamura and Steinsson 2013). Overall, both LI and FI methods have strengths and weaknesses. The former is less prone to model misspecification, but the use of instruments is subject to problems of weak of identification and lack of robustness. The latter, while addressing the endogeneity issue in a more direct and coherent way, delivers in reality a test on the validity of the entire NK model, and not just of the NKPC.
In light of the surveyed evidence, Mavroedis et a. (2014) conclude that “the literature has reached a limit in how much can be learned about the New Keynesian Phillips curve from aggregate macroeconomic time series. New identification approaches and new datasets are needed to reach an empirical consensus”.
The goal of this paper is to propose a new methodology for the identification of the NKPCs. I name it Full Information Partial Equilibrium (FIPE) to emphasize that it is intended to combine the strengths of both the FI and the LI approaches. FIPE estimations are designed to move away from aggregate time series, and instead be applied to the extensive sectoral datasets that, in recent years, have become available for many countries. The proposed methodology is very flexible along two important dimensions. First, while the paper illustrates the workings of a FIPE approach in the context of a purely forward-looking model, it also indicates how to adapt the methodology to estimate popular alternative (“hybrid”) versions of the NKPC. Second, a FIPE analysis provides general closed-form statistics that can be exploited by a variety of econometric techniques, such as GMM or MLE methods. I present, as an example, an application in a Bayesian estimation setting.
The FIPE approach is centered around estimating sectoral NKPCs using, for identification, only the variability in sectoral gross output inflation and real marginal costs due to idiosyncratic shocks (demand, supply, mark-ups, long-run sectoral inflation). Similarly to aggregate shocks, idiosyncratic shocks cause endogeneity problems in the estimation of the NKPC. However, their propagation occurs in partial equilibrium and can thus be modeled explicitly by postulating minimal structural assumptions on sectoral demand and supply functions. Therefore, the FIPE strategy incorporates the FI intuition that estimation biases can be corrected by exploiting the restrictions from the model’s equilibrium conditions. In addition, the FIPE approach mimics the robustness of LI estimations to potential misspecifications of general equilibrium effects. In this way, the advantages of FI and LI are leveraged within a single procedure. The structural specification can then deliver consistent estimates even where popular LI identification strategies fail, e.g. when mark-up shocks are auto-correlated or in the presence of non stationary errors.2 At the same time, contrary to FI estimations, the focus on partial equilibrium dynamics renders unnecessary the specifications of structural equations such as the monetary policy rule.
The proposed methodology delivers a set of statistics, called FIPE moments. These are represented by closed-form theoretical covariances of sectoral inflation rates and real marginal costs, expressed as functions of the deep parameters of the model. They include, among others, sectoral Phillips curve slopes and the exogenous auto-covariances of sectoral structural shocks. Some parameters may be directly calibrated. The remaining free parameters can instead be estimated by combining the theoretical moments with empirical observations.
As mentioned, the empirical data must represent time series variation of inflation and real marginal costs generated only by idiosyncratic shocks. As a preliminary step to estimation, the data must therefore be purged from the effect of aggregate shocks. To this end, the paper provides necessary and sufficient conditions on sectoral parameters that allow the inflation and real marginal cost series to be linearly decomposed into two parts. One is the series variation caused by idiosyncratic shocks. The other is the component attributable to aggregate shocks, expressed as the product of common components and sector specific loadings. Aggregate shocks can then be preliminarily removed from the series by means of standard principal components procedures applied to a panel of sectors. Hence, the paper provides the theoretical conditions that justify the form of the inflation process postulated in Bovin et al. (2009).
An interesting issue connected to our empirical strategy is how sectoral slopes estimated from idiosyncratic shocks are related to the aggregate slope λ. With this regard, the theoretical literature has emphasized two main points. First, in the presence of strategic complementarities, the aggregate degree of Calvo price stickiness is disproportionally influenced by the most sticky among the cross section of sectors (Carvalho 2006). The second point deals instead with the within sector response of prices to shocks. Models with Calvo price adjustments, such as the one studied in this paper, are ill-suited to provide a justification for the presence of different frequencies of price adjustment to aggregate versus idiosyncratic shocks. As a consequence, in the Calvo model the slope of the sectoral Phillips curve is assumed to be the same in response to both shocks (Maćkowiak et al. 2009). However, models where stickiness is explicitly based on firms’ rational inattention predict that prices should be more flexible in response to idiosyncratic shocks (Maćkowiak and Wiederholt 2009, Melosi 2014). Taken together, these considerations indicate that first moments
As an application, I use FIPE moments in conjuction with Bayesian techniques to estimated sectoral NKPC slopes for two large economies, the US and Japan, and a small open economy, the UK. Real marginal costs are proxied by the labor share. The estimation results echo findings common in the empirical literature: first moments
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 lays out the assumption on sectoral demand and supply functions, and develops sectoral Phillips curves with time varying long-run inflation rates. Section 3 gives necessary and sufficient conditions for the linear decomposition of aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks, and derives the FIPE moments. Section 4 presents the results of the empirical application. Section 5 concludes.
2 Sectoral Phillips curves in a standard New Keynesian model
This section derives a sectoral version of the standard NKPC,
where β ∈ (0,1) is a discount factor,
2.1 Preferences and production technologies
There is a double continuum of goods (i, j) in the economy, with i ∈ [0,1] representing a sector and j ∈ [0,1] indicating a particular variety within sector j. Each pair (i, j) represents both the good and the firm which produces it under monopolistic competition. The variables
Demand functions for good (i, j) and for sector i’s overall bundle are derived from constant elasticity utility aggregators with elasticities given by
where the elasticity
Similarly, sectoral demands relative to aggregate demand, written in first difference, are defined as
where
We turn to the definition of firms’ supply functions. We assume that the log nominal marginal cost is the same for all firms j within a given sector and is given by
The variable
where the Km-th additional factor is
Example. Normalize
We conclude this section with the specification of the stochastic process for the exogenous variables of the model. In some instances, shocks are presented into a normalized form to yield less cluttered equilibrium conditions. The process for the sectoral demand shifter
The log sectoral mark-up
Finally, the process for the growth rate
The auto-correlations ρω, ρμ, pz belong to the interval [0,1]. All the shocks are assumed to be mutually independent, and their variances are indicated, respectively, with
2.2 Staggered prices
In every period t, each monopolistically competitive firm (i, j) can freely reset its price with probability 1 – θi. Prices are indexed at the sectoral level, i.e. firms that cannot optimally reset their price mechanically increase them at an exogenous and sector specific rate
where
The assumptions made so far ensures that a set of sectoral NKPCs (1) is obtained using standard log-linearization techniques5. In particular, the slope λi of the sectoral Phillips curve is
2.3 Estimation challenges
To build some intuition about the challenges in estimating the NKPC we write, after some manipulations of (1),
The quantity
An inspection of (12) immediately reveals two main estimation issues. First, all the components of the unobserved error that are dated t are correlated with the regressor
3 A Full Information Partial Equilibrium approach
From a theoretical perspective, the FIPE approach is developed in two steps. The first, presented in Section 3.1, provides conditions under which the marginal cost and inflation processes can be linearly separated into aggregate and idiosyncratic components. The second, outlined in Section 3.2, demonstrates that closed-form representations for the second moments of the inflation and the real marginal cost variables can be derived from the idiosyncratic components.
3.1 Separating aggregate and idiosyncratic components
The central aspect of our analysis is the characterization of the stochastic process for the real marginal cost
An important features of the stochastic process for
Assumption 1. Consider a group of sectors for which the constants λi and δi satisfy
Assumption 1 is slightly milder than the requirement that λi and δi are the same across given group of sectors. For a group of sectors that share the same constant κ, the intrinsic persistence r is defined as follows,
Definition 1. For a group of sectors that satisfy Assumption 1, the intrinsic persistence r ∈ (0, 1) is given by the the smaller of the two characteristic roots of second order difference equation,
with χ0 ≡ β–1 and
Assumption 1 guarantees that the intrinsic persistence r is the same across all sectors belonging to a common group. While Appendix B provides a detailed characterization of the intrinsic and extrinsic persistences, we briefly present here a more intuitive discussion.
Equation (14) is the homogeneous part of the difference equation describing the evolution of marginal cost gaps in response to aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks. The equation thus provides information about dynamic persistence r of the gap’s stochastic process due only to the intrinsic, endogenous propagation of the shocks caused by the nominal and real rigidities. The extrinsic persistence, instead, is derived from the inhomogeneous part of the equation, whose process depends solely on the exogenous persistence of the underlying shocks. Note that the intrinsic persistence r is the same in response to both aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks.7
While for idiosyncratic shocks the extrinsic component equals the exogenous persistence ρs, for aggregate shocks such characterization doesn’t hold anymore. This can be easily seen in our Example in Section 2.1. An aggregate structural shock, like an increase in productivity Zt, will in fact cause a cascade of additional general equilibrium “reduced-form” shocks to other factors, like the wage Wt. It follows that the overall extrinsic persistences generated by a structural shock to Zt does not depend on the exogenous persistence of Zt alone, but also on the endogenous persistence of the response of all the other factors. Our partial equilibrium approach aims exactly at side-stepping the task of modelling explicitly such complex endogenous propagation. Note also that since the root r lies within the unit circle, real marginal cost gaps, and hence sectoral inflation, could be subject to non-structural (sunspot) dynamics. This paper abstracts from the role of sunspot shocks, which could nonetheless be easily introduced into the model.
Define ιs an indicator which equals –1 if s = z and 1 otherwise. We then have the following result,
Proposition 1. Assumption 1 is necessary and sufficient for the real marginal cost gap
where
Proof. See Appendix B. □
According to Proposition 1, the real marginal cost gap can be decomposed into a component that linearly depends only on aggregate factors, and into an idiosyncratic part which is the sum of three MA(∞) processes. The explicit functional form for the weights
The representation (16) makes clear one important distinction between idiosyncratic demand and supply shocks on one side, and idiosyncratic mark-up shocks on the other. Consider a positive unit impulse
Similarly to what we have done with the marginal cost gap, define the inflation gap
We then have the following Corollary to Proposition 1
Corollary 1. The process for the inflation gap
where
Proof. See Appendix B.
In empirical applications of our FIPE methodology, Proposition 1 and Corollary 1 are used as a preliminary step to separate aggregate and idiosyncratic components of the real marginal cost and inflation gaps data. In practice, this separation requires the use of econometric techniques, such as principal components methods. Assumption 1, by guaranteeing the validity of Corollary 1, provides necessary and sufficient conditions that justify the FAVAR model that Boivin et al. (2009) employ to study the inflation process at the sectoral level.
The results of this section can also be cast in the language of the panel literature. Every group of sectors to which Assumption 1 applies form a panel data. Corollary 1 implies that the dependent variable
3.2 FIPE moments
In this section we establish the existence of closed form expressions for the projection of the inflation gaps
Corollary 2. Take ρω = ρz ≡ ≡. Then, for a given value of ≡, the projections of ξt onto
where each function bj(r, R) has a closed form expression and R is the relative variance ofthe mark-up shock, i.e.
The representation (20) holds even when the projections are performed with variables in differences.
Proof. See Appendix B, which also provides the closed form expression for the functions bj(r, R) at any (positive or negative) lag j. □
Corollary 2 is based on the assumption that ρω = ρz, i.e. that exogenous demand and supply shocks have the same auto-correlation. In our context this is a mild assumption since, as noted in the discussion of Proposition 1, demand and supply shocks already play an almost identical role in defining the stochastic process for
Note also that the formulation (20) holds even when the moments are calculated using lagged variables. This is a convenient result in light of the observation that the idiosyncratic error
Finally, Corollary 2 allows us also to obtain explicit moments involving the auto-covariance of
so that Γ ∈ [0,1) is the contribution of the (normalized) variable
for any integer j and for given functions
3.3 Beyond the pure forward-looking model
In search for formulations that can better fit the data, the literature has departed from the pure forward-looking NK model and has proposed alternative versions of the Phillips curve and of the real marginal cost. A strength of the FIPE methodology is that it can be flexibly adapted to these cases.
For instance, while (1) already incorporates in
For both these alternative formulations, the FIPE approach would be implemented as follows. First, the introduction of lagged variables implies that (14) is now of third order. Hence, Definition 1 might have to be modified to take into account the potential presence of multiple roots (i.e. multiple intrinsic persistences r) that lie within the unit circle. Correspondingly, Assumption 1 would also have to be adjusted to ensure that all such roots are the same within sector groups. With these modifications, the moving average decomposition in Proposition 1 is still valid. Of course, the weights
4 FIPE in a Bayesian application
In this section we provide an empirical application of the theoretical results of the FIPE approach developed above. Specifically, the results of Section 3.1 are first used to remove aggregate shock trough standard principal components methods. In turn, the moments representation of Section 3.2 is exploited within a Bayesian estimation context. Our application is based on calibrations for the extrinsic persistences ρs that lead to an ARMA(1,1) process for the real marginal cost gaps.
4.1 An ARMA(1,1) specification
A Bayesian approach to the use of the FIPE moments is particularly attractive because the projections b(r, R) depend on two parameters - the intrinsic persistence r and the relative variance R - which have intuitive interpretations and for which some prior knowledge can be elicited. With the aim of providing an even sharper intuition for the parameters (r, R) we make the assumption that all shocks have the same persistence, and follow either a random walk or of an i.i.d. process,
The assumptions above may appear restrictive, but they still allow us to move beyond the i.i.d. case typically analyzed in the LI literature. In particular, estimating the model under the two polar possibilities p ∈ {0, 1} can shed light on the sensitivity of the estimated NKPC’s slopes to different assumptions about the persistence of the underlying shocks. Moreover, the above calibration for the extrinsic persistences lead to a stochastic process for the forcing variable mt that is indeed quite general, i.e.
The real marginal cost gap then follows an ARMA(1,1). The intrinsic persistence r is identified as the coefficient of the AR(1) part, while the MA(1) part disappears in the random walk case ρ = 1. The coefficient
First, the New Keynesian literature usually assigns a non-negligible role to mark-up shocks in explaining the variability of the aggregate forcing variable. Our prior is that this intuition carries over to the idiosyncratic component
Second, recall that, in the discussion about Assumption 1, it was pointed out that the intrinsic persistence r is the same in response to both aggregate and idiosyncratic shocks. Our prior for r is then constructed as a distribution centered around the estimated AR(1) coefficient of an ARMA(1,1) model, fitted to the time series of an aggregate proxy for
The likelihood of the data is obtained as follows. First of all, to address the problem of non-stationarity, we estimate (19) in first differences, namely we use projections of
Define Σa the covariance matrix of the elements of
The analytic expressions for Σa and Σb are provided in Appendix C. Define b(λi, r, R, Γ) the vector of regression coefficients of
and call
Assume that the i.i.d. shocks ∊ω, ∊z, ∊μ and ∊γ are jointly normally distributed. Proposition 1 then implies that idiosyncratic real marginal costs are jointly normally distributed with respect to each other and with respect to the inflation gaps ξt. It follows that,
Suppose that we have a sample of T observations for each sector i. We approximate the sectoral likelihood Li(·|·) of the data as
where fi(·|·) is the probability density function of the normal distribution (24). The likelihood contains an approximation, since each fi(·|·) is conditioned on
To increase the number of observations used in the estimation, we employ a pooled version of the sectoral likelihood. Assume that the slopes λi are drawn from a distribution with mean
where Δξ and Δm represent the entire collection of time and sector observations of first differences of inflation gaps and real marginal costs. Note that the multiplication in L(·|·) of sectoral likelihoods is justified since, at this stage, all aggregate shocks have been removed, and hence the evolution of the observables are independent across sectors.
For given values of
where
4.2 Data description and priors
The data source we employ is the EU KLEMS Database, March 2008 release. The database contains information for 3-digit industries at annual frequency for the period 1970-2005. We consider three groups of industries, corresponding to the categorization in Basu et al. (2006): Non-Durable manufacturing (sector group 1), Durable Manufacturing (sector group 2), Non-Manufacturing (sector group 3). Groups are of roughly equal size of 10 industries each. We posit that Assumption 1 holds within each group.
First differences of inflation gaps are constructed from sectoral log price of gross output, using a discount parameter calibrated to a standard annual value of β = 0.97. First differences in the real marginal cost are calculated from the log labor share in gross output. Our estimation thus tests the labor share-based, purely forward looking Phillips curve in Galì and Gertler (1999) and Cogley and Sbordone (2008). For each group of sectors, common factors are extracted from the series via standard principal components procedures, with the number of components selected according to the ER test in Bai and Ng (2002). The remaining idiosyncratic series, used in the estimation, typically explan 20-30% of the variance of the original series.
In the construction of the vectors
Priors are set as follows. Due to the significant uncertainty found in the empirical literature, we choose an agnostic prior for the distribution of
4.3 Estimation results
To discuss the estimation results, we need first to identify a target value for the slope
A well-known problem with empirical estimates of the slope of the NKPC is that, even when estimates return a positive coefficient, the implied degree of price stickiness appears too large to be consistent with the micro evidence. However, the the appropriate degree of microeconomic price stickiness is also subject to considerable debate. To take all these uncertainties into consideration, we then present three measures - main, conservative, very conservative -of target values for λ.
The main target measure is constructed by assuming a monthly probability of price adjustment equal to .2, which implies a monthly θm = .8. This value is consistent with the median frequency of adjustment for posted prices reported in Nakamura and Steinsson (2008). The argument for focusing on posted prices, instead of regular prices, can be defended by recalling that our identification scheme relies on responses to idiosyncratic shocks, which should be associated with much more price flexibility than aggregate shocks (Boivin et al. 2009, Kehoe and Midrigan 2015, Nakamura and Steinsson 2013, Carvalho 2006). Monthly frequencies are then cumulated geometrically to obtain an annual value of θa = .812 = 0.07 (see Dennis 2006 for a discussion). In turn, these calculations yield an annual slope λa equal to 12. In an attempt to reconcile the low estimates for λ with the micro evidence, the literature has also emphasized that, in the presence of real rigidities, the estimated parameter
Following the steps above, our conservative measure is computed from θm = . 86, or a monthly probability of adjustment equal to .14, which corresponds to the median frequency of adjustment for regular prices reported in Klenow and Kryvtsov (2008). The implied annual slope, adjusted for the usual constant, is λa = 1.5.
Similarly, a very conservative can derived by setting θm = .90, corresponding to the monthly price stickiness for regular prices in Nakamura and Steinsson (2008).13 After adjusting for the constant, we obtain an implied λa = 0.6. We can also provide an additional derivation for our very conservative measure of the target slope. It is clear that the geometric transformations of the monthly Calvo parameter is subject to a large non-linearity, with the target slope rising quickly as the time horizon increases. To reduce this non-linearity, we postulate that the real marginal cost gap follows a monthly AR(1) process, with autoregressive parameter equal to rm = 0.94 (corresponding to the annual ra = .5 used, in the previous section, as mode for the prior). The monthly slope is set to λm = 0.02, obtained from the conservative θm = 0.86. Next, we ask what would be the λa obtained by trying to fit, at an annual frequency, the original process of the Phillips curve variables.14 The answer is a fitted annual slope equal to 2.1, which divided by the usual constant gives again a value around λa = .6.
Smoothed posterior density of
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of r for the USA. For each of the three sector groups, estimation are carried out for the two configurations ρ = 0 and ρ = 1 of the extrinsic persistence. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
We present estimations for two large economies, the US and Japan, and for a small open economy, the UK. Posterior distributions are approximated using a Random Walk Metropolis-Hastings algorithm with 500,000 draws.15 We begin with a discussion of the results for the US, which have been the focus of much of the early empirical NK literature.
Smoothed posterior density of
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Figure 1 depicts the (smoothed) posterior density of the average slope
Smoothed posterior density of
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Posterior densities for the remaining model parameters are reported in Appendix D. For brevity, we present in Figure 2 only the posteriors for r. Notice that for the sector group 1 posterior densities track closely the respective prior. This conclusion extends also to the posteriors of R and Γ. The explanation is that for, ρ = 0, posterior densities of
Finally, Figures 3 and 4 report estimation results for Japan and the UK, respectively.16 For both countries, and for all values of ρ, the slope
5 Conclusions
Econometric tests of the validity of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve have yielded conflicting findings, often at odds with the microeconomics evidence. The likely reason is that estimates on aggregate data are subject to significant challenges, due to the presence of omitted variables and model misspecifications.
I propose a new approach to estimation, which exploits the extensive sectoral datasets that have become available in recent years. The new methodology aims at leveraging the advantages of both the structural Full Information and the single-equation Limited Information literatures. The identification strategy is based on modeling the partial equilibrium responses to a variety of sectoral idiosyncratic shocks. For these reasons, the methodology can be characterized as Full Information Partial Equilibrium (FIPE).
The FIPE approach is flexible along two lines. First, it is easily extended to alternative hybrid versions of the NKPC. Second, the theoretical moment conditions delivered by the FIPE analysis can be employed as an input to a variety of econometric techniques.
Since the FIPE identification is based on idiosyncratic shocks, a preliminary step to estimation requires the purging of sectoral time series of the effects of aggregate shocks. To this end, I provide necessary and sufficient conditions on the assumed interaction between nominal and real rigidities that allow inflation and marginal cost time series to be linearly separated into aggregate and idiosyncratic components. Standard principal analysis techniques, applied to a panel of sectors, can then be used recover idiosyncratic time series.
As an application, I employ the FIPE methodology in a Bayesian framework to estimate sectoral NKPCs for the US, Japan and the UK. I find that the pure-forward looking NKPC, with the real marginal cost proxied by the labor share, is rejected by the data.
6 References
Bai J., Ng S. (2002), Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models, Econometric 70, pp. 191–221.
Boivin J., Giannoni M. P., Mihov I. (2009), Sticky prices and Monetary Policy: Evidence from Disaggregatd US Data, American Economic Review 99, pp. 350–384.
Basu S., Fernald J.G., Kimball M. S. (2006), Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? American Economic Review, 96, pp.1418–1448.
Batini N., Jackson B., Nickell S. (2005), An open-economy new Keynesian Phillips cirve for the UK, Journal of Monetary Economics 52, pp. 1061–1071.
Carvalho C. (2006), Heterogeneity in Price Stickiness and the Real Effect of Monetary Shocks, Frontiers of Macroeconomics vol. 2, issue 1, pp. 1–55.
Clarida R., Galií J., Gertler M. (1999), The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective, Journal of Economic Literature 37, pp. 16611707.
Cogley T., Sbordone A. M. (2008), Trend Inflation, Indexation, and Inflation Persistence in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve, American Economic Review 98, pp. 2101–21026.
Dennis R. (2006), The Frequency of Price Adjustment and New Keynesian Business Cycle Dynamics, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper Series 2006-22.
Fuhrer J. C. (1997), The (Un)Importance of Forward-Looking Behavior in Price Specifications, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 29, pp. 338–350.
Fuhrer J.C, Moore G. (1995), Inflation persistence, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, pp. 127–159.
Gali J., Gertler M. (1999), Inflation dynamics: a structural econometric analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics 44, pp. 195–222.
Gali J., Gertler M., Lopez-Salido D. (2005), Robustness of the estimates of the hybrid New-Keynesian Phillips curve, Journal of Monetary Economics 52, pp. 1107–1118.
Klenow P. J., Kryvtsov (2008), State-Dependent and Time-Dependent Pricing: Does it Matter for Recent U.S. Inflation, Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 863–904.
Lindé J. (2005), Estimating New-Keynesian Phillips Curves: a full information maximum likelihood approach, Journal of Monetary Economics 52, pp. 1135–1149.
Maćkowiak B., Moench E., Wiederholt M. (2009), Sectoral price data and models ofprice setting, Journal of Monetary Economics 56, pp. 578–599.
Maćkowiak B., Wiederholt M. (2009), Optimal Sticky Prices under Rational Inattention, Ameican Economic Review 99, 769–803.
Mavroedis S. (2004), Identification Issues in Forward-Looking Models Estimated by GMM, with an Application to the Phillips Curve, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37, pp. 421–48.
Mavroedis S., Plagborg-Moller M., Stocks J.H. (2014), Empirical Evidence on Inflaton Expectations in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve, Journal of Economic Literature 52, pp. 124–188.
Melosi L. (2014), Estimating models with dispersed information, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomis 6, pp. 1–31.
Nakamura E., Steinsson J. (2008), Five Facts About Prices: A Reevaluation of Menu Cost Models, Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 1415–1464.
Nakamura E., Steinsson J. (2013), Price Rigidity: Microeconomic Evidence and Macroeconomic Implications, Annual Review of Economics, Annual Reviews 5, pp. 133–163.
Pasaran M. H. (2006), Estimation and Inference in Large Heterogeneous Panels with a Multifactor Error Structure, Econometrica 74, pp. 967–1012.
Roberts J.M. (1995), The New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27, pp. 975–984.
Roberts J.M. (2005), How Well Does the New Keynesian Sticky-Price Model Fit the Data?, B. E. Journal of Macroeconomics: Contributions to Macroeconomics 5.
Rudd, Whelan (2005), New tests ofthe New Keynesian Phillips Curve, Journal of Monetary Economics 52, pp. 1167–1181.
Rotemberg J. J., Woodford M. (1999), The Cyclical Behavior of Prices and Costs, Handbook of Macroeconomics, Taylor, J.B., and M. Woodford, eds., Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Sbordone A.M. (2002), Prices and unit labor costs: a new test of price stickiness, Journal of Monetary Economics 49, pp. 265292.
Schorfheide F. (2008), DSGE Model-Based Estimation of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 94, pp. 397433.
Yun T. (1996), Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity, and business cycles, Journal of Monetary Economics 37, pp. 345–370.
A Sectoral Phillips curves
In every time t firms in sector i that can freely change their price will all choose the same (log) value
where it,t+s and
with as usual
Condition (28) guarantees that the expected discounted sum of marginal profit equals zero for any firm which freely resets its price at t. This condition can be linearized around an appropriate non-stochastic steady state with the property that for each sector i firms that are allowed to reset choose the same log price
where i and r are, respectively, the log nominal and real steady state interest rate. As usual we take r > ΔY and hence β ∈ (0,1). Finally, linearizing around the steady state conditions
or,
By the law of iterated expectation and using (29) we have
The log inflation rate for sector s is
We can then derive the sector specific forward-looking Phillips curve (1).
B Proof of Propositions
Proof of Proposition 1. We calculate the form of the impulse responses to aggregate and idiosyncratic shock by considering the path of the real marginal cost gap in a perfect-forecast equilibrium. Combining (4) with (6), and substituting into (1) we obtain, after some algebra, the following second order difference equation
for some set Km of aggregate factors {qkt} and corresponding sectoral loadings
The impulse responses to shocks to the aggregate factors are easily obtained by focusing on the case git = 0. Assume that the process
for a set of Km aggregate factors
We now derive the explicit form for the impulse response of to an idiosyncratic shock
where s ∈ {ω, z, μ} indicates that the constant
with ρs {ρω, ρz, ρμ} depending on the type of shock we are considering. The expression above clarifies that the extrinsic persistence of an idiosyncratic shock s equals ρs. It is easy to see that g(1) = (1 – ρs)(χ0 – ρs)∈0 and g0 = –(1 – ρs + χ0)∈0. One can verify that for the following sequence of values
where we assume
Summarizing, the solution for t ≥ 0 to time zero impulses from the three idiosyncratic shocks is
Summing all the past impacts of the shocks for all j ≥ 0 we obtain equation (16), where clearly
In an appendix available from the author it is shown that
This concludes the proof that Assumption 1 is sufficient to allow a linear decomposition in of
Proof of Corollary 1. Assume that there are only aggregate shocks. Then, by iterating forward (1) and using (16), we obtain the inflation forecast error in (12) due to aggregate shocks as,
Hence, since both
Now consider the case with idiosyncratic shocks only. Use
Proof of Corollary 2. If we use expression (16) to iterate forward (1), we obtain,
where
with
with
with
C Moments
Define ιρ an indicator function which equals 1 if ρ = 0 and 0 if ρ = 1 and define
We can write the process for
Define the following moments for the errors,
Also,
No lagged values of
The variance covariance matrix Σa is then given by
The vector Σb is simply
Inclusion of lagged values of
The greater the value of
The covariance matrix Σa under
D Prior and posteriors for r, R, Γ
This section provides more details on prior and posterior densities.
D.1 Priors
Priors are independent from each other. The prior for μ is assumed to be a normal with mean zero and variance equal to 9. For the other parameters, we rewrite the moments conditions in terms of auxiliary monotonic transformations, over which we postulate our priors. In particular, for r and R we use the auxiliary parameters
The prior for Γ is dealt with in a slightly different way. Notice that, when the forward-looking Phillips curve fails because λi = 0, then the covariance matrix Σa is singular. To avoid this situation, in our estimation implementation we write the moment conditions as functions of
D.2 Posteriors
The implied posterior distributions for the original parameters and r and R, and for the transformed
Smoothed posterior density of r for the US. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of R for the US. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of r for Japan. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of R for Japan. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of r for the UK. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of R for the UK. Dotted lines indicate prior densities.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Smoothed posterior density of
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
D.3 Posteriors diagnostics
In all the estimations, the rejection rates from the proposal are 24%. The following figures report the sample auto-correlations of the parameters draws.
Auto-correlation function of draws for
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for r and the US.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for R and the US.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for r and Japan.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for R and Japan.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for r and the UK.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for R and the UK.
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
Auto-correlation function of draws for
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 044; 10.5089/9781484345207.001.A001
This paper builds on an earlier unpublished work with A. Anzuini. I thank Alessio for the comments provided for this new paper. I also thank John Roberts and Luigi Paciello for insightful suggestions. The views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF. All errors are my own.
Seminal papers are Roberts (1995), Fuhrer and Moore (1995), Fuhrer (1997), Gali and Gertler (1999), Sbordone (2002), Rudd and Whelan (2004), Mavroedis (2004), Linde (2005), Roberts (2005).
For example, LI estimations usually need to assume that the unobserved error terms, commonly interpreted as a “mark-up” shock, is uncorrelated across time. In fact, if the mark-up shocks were allowed to be auto-correlated, then lags of the endogenous variables typically used in IV estimations would not be valid instruments.
We will remain mostly agnostic on the properties relating the evolution of
See Appendix A for details.
Section 3.1 is devoted to show under what conditions a linear separation between aggregate an idiosyncratic components is warranted.
The intuition is that, regardless the type of shock hitting the sector, (14) is always the homogeneous part of the difference equation describing the evolution of the real marginal cost gap. Hence, the intrinsic persistence
To make this interpretation more straightforward, assume that
Appendix C explicitly derives this formulation for the empirical analysis in Section 4.
There is clearly no reason to believe that the aggregate real marginal cost gap follows exactly the process (22). In fact, even if we assume that aggregate structural shocks follow either an i.i.d. or a random walk processes, still the aggregate factors would not in general be i.i.d. or random walk. As discussed in Section 3.1, this is do to the presence of general equilibrium effects, which induce endogenous persistence in the factors beyond that imposed on the exogenous structural shocks. This conclusion notwithstanding, we consider the procedure good enough to be used with the limited goal of eliciting a central value for the prior distribution of r.
Note that we are not estimating the slope of the Phillips curve by projecting inflation on measures of the output gap. This can be problematic as pointed out, for instance, by Gali and Gertler (1999). Instead, we are just using the often exploited theoretical relation between marginal cost gaps and output gaps to merely infer something about the auto-correlation of the former. Finally, in our exercise an ARMA(1,1) fits quite well our output gap series.
In particular, the priors for r and R are obtained from gamma distributions of appropriate monotonic transformations
This calibration also comes close to the counterfactual average duration of 12 months calculated by Kehoe and Midrigan (2015).
We employ an adaptive algorithm for the covariance matrix of the proposal distribution. The first 10,000 draws are discarded.
Batini et al. (2005) also estimate the slope of the Phillips curve for the UK economy.