Household Credit, Global Financial Cycle, and Macroprudential Policies
Credit Register Evidence from an Emerging Country
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund
  • | 2 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund
  • | 3 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

We analyze the effects of macroprudential policies on local bank credit cycles and interactions with international financial conditions. For identification, we exploit the comprehensive credit register containing all bank loans to individuals in Romania, a small open economy subject to external shocks, and the period 2004-2012, which covers a full boom-bust credit cycle when a wide range of macroprudential measures were deployed. Although household leverage is known to be a key driver of financial crises, to our knowledge this is the first paper that employs a household credit register to study leverage and macroprudential policies over a full economic cycle. Our results show that tighter macroprudential conditions are associated with a significant decline in household credit, with substantially stronger effects for foreign currency (FX) loans than for local currency loans. The effects on FX loans are higher for: (i) ex-ante riskier borrowers proxied by higher debt-service-toincome ratios and (ii) banks with greater exposure to foreign funding. Moreover, tighter macroprudential policy has stronger dampening effects on FX lending when global risk appetite is high and foreign monetary policy is expansionary. Finally, quantitative effects are in general larger for borrower rather than lender macroprudential policies.

Abstract

We analyze the effects of macroprudential policies on local bank credit cycles and interactions with international financial conditions. For identification, we exploit the comprehensive credit register containing all bank loans to individuals in Romania, a small open economy subject to external shocks, and the period 2004-2012, which covers a full boom-bust credit cycle when a wide range of macroprudential measures were deployed. Although household leverage is known to be a key driver of financial crises, to our knowledge this is the first paper that employs a household credit register to study leverage and macroprudential policies over a full economic cycle. Our results show that tighter macroprudential conditions are associated with a significant decline in household credit, with substantially stronger effects for foreign currency (FX) loans than for local currency loans. The effects on FX loans are higher for: (i) ex-ante riskier borrowers proxied by higher debt-service-toincome ratios and (ii) banks with greater exposure to foreign funding. Moreover, tighter macroprudential policy has stronger dampening effects on FX lending when global risk appetite is high and foreign monetary policy is expansionary. Finally, quantitative effects are in general larger for borrower rather than lender macroprudential policies.

1 Introduction

Banking crises often occur after periods of strong bank credit growth financed with foreign liquidity (Schularick and Taylor, 2012; Gourinchas and Obstfeld, 2012; Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009). Banking crises are also accompanied by credit crunches with significant real effects (Laeven and Valencia, 2013; Bernanke, 1983). These facts have generated broad agreement among academics and policymakers that macroeconomic and regulatory policies should acquire a macroprudential dimension (Claessens, 2015; Freixas et al., 2015; IMF, 2009).1 Macroprudential policy refers to instruments that aim to ensure financial stability by limiting cyclical vulnerabilities and systemic risk over the credit cycle.2 However, not all credit is the same, as credit to households has been suggested as a crucial driver of financial crises (Mian et al., 2017). Yet, despite the importance of understanding the effects of macroprudential policies for the household credit cycle, there is no systematic evidence on the ability of macroprudential policies to smooth local household credit cycles or to mitigate spillovers from the global financial cycle (Rey, 2016, 2013; Borio, 2014) on the local bank credit cycle.

In this paper we analyze the effects of macroprudential policies on local bank credit to households and how they interact with international factors such as foreign currency (FX) lending, foreign bank funding, and global risk appetite. Our laboratory for empirical identification is Romania, a fast-growing and small open emerging market economy in the European Union. Romania offers the ideal opportunity to study macroprudential financial policy because it (i) offers a comprehensive household credit register with detailed information on all loans extended by the banking sector to individuals; (ii) has deployed a wide range of macroprudential policies during the boom and bust of the 2000s; and (iii) is exposed to global financial conditions and foreign monetary policy, including through foreign bank funding and loans in foreign currency. To our knowledge, this is the first paper that employs a household credit register to study the effectiveness of macroprudential policies in mitigating risky household lending over a full economic cycle, and to document the ability of macroprudential policies to dampen the effects of the global financial cycle on local credit cycles, especially on riskier lending.

Our credit register includes the universe of bank loans to individuals in Romania during the 2004-2012 period, at quarterly frequency. Like other small and open emerging market countries, Romania is a bank-dependent economy where a large portion of the banking sector is foreign-owned, there is substantial foreign bank funding, and about one third of household loans are extended in foreign currencies (mainly Euros, EUR and Swiss Francs, CHF). These factors expose the economy to potential cross-border spillovers from foreign macroeconomic policies and the global financial cycle. We have information on close to 3,000,000 individual loans—residential mortgages and consumer loans—from 42 commercial banks. The credit register contains important household credit characteristics (e.g., loan volume and rate, loan-to-value ratio, debt-service-to-income ratio, etc.) and is matched with high-frequency supervisory information on bank balance sheets.

During 2004-2008 Romania experienced credit and housing booms that were fuelled by large capital inflows—an experience it shared with many emerging markets (Dell’Ariccia et al., 2012). During this period bank credit grew at an average of 23% in real terms. Over the subsequent four-year period, the economy was hit by the global financial crisis: real credit growth fell below 1% and GDP contracted at an average of 1.5% per year. Throughout the 2004-2012 period the National Bank of Romania (NBR) deployed a wide range of macroprudential instruments to manage financial risks. Policies included changes in minimum reserve requirements on local and foreign currency deposits (including foreign bank funding), limits on credit exposures in foreign currencies, changes in capital requirements and provisioning rules, and time-varying ceilings on loan-to-value (LTV) and debt-service-to-income (DTI) ratios for household loans.3

To capture changes in macroprudential policy conditions over the credit cycle, we construct an index by coding the numerous introductions and changes in macroprudential instruments as tightenings (+1) or loosenings (—1).4 Following the methodology of Cerutti et al. (2017), we then define the index as the running (cumulative) sum of these values such that each instrument is reflected in the index throughout the entire time it is in place and until it is changed or discontinued. Higher values of this index indicate a tightening of macroprudential conditions. In a similar manner we define two additional fine-grained macroprudential policy indices that group together, respectively, the instruments applied to banks (such as limits on leverage and provisioning rules) and those applied to borrowers (such as LTV and DTI limits). These indices allow us to distinguish the effects of different sets of macroprudential policies on bank credit cycles and risk-taking.

Similar to studies of monetary policy, our analysis faces the empirical identification challenge that macroprudential policy responds to and is correlated with local financial and economic conditions. As in the monetary policy literature (Kashyap and Stein, 2000; Jiménez et al., 2012), we exploit cross-sectional differences in microdata (in our case, in bank risk-taking in household lending) and time series, and control for key macroeconomic conditions (including in interactions). More concretely, employing the microdata from the NBR’s credit register, we emphasize double and triple interactions of macroprudential policies with loan characteristics (FX vs. local currency), borrower characteristics (more vs. less risky), or bank characteristics (more vs. less dependent on foreign funding); and (ii) specifications that additionally control for local and international macroeconomic and financial variables (also in interactions with loan, borrower, and bank characteristics). Furthermore, we analyze the data at a high frequency with bank×period and borrower county×period fixed effects. These fixed effects control for time-varying unobserved local macroeconomic shocks and bank characteristics. Therefore, we obtain identification within the same period through the differential characteristics of loans, borrowers, and banks. Our regressions also include loan-type×period fixed effects to ensure the results are not driven by systematic differences between mortgages and consumer loans. We also examine the ability of macroprudential policies to mitigate (exogenous) international spillovers from the global financial cycle (proxied by the VIX or Eurozone monetary policy) bank credit as well as its composition.

Our main results are as follows. We show that tighter macroprudential conditions are associated with a decline in the volume of household credit, especially for riskier foreign (vs. local) currency loans. The estimates are statistically and economically significant for all FX loans, and are of similar magnitude across EUR and CHF loans. They suggest that a tightening of macroprudential policy by one standard deviation reduces average foreign currency loan volume by 12% more than it does local currency loan volume. In addition, the mitigating effects of tighter macroprudential policy on FX credit are stronger for ex-ante riskier borrowers, measured with the DTI at loan origination. For borrowers with the same level of risk, a tightening of macroprudential policies reduces FX credit relative to local currency credit, suggesting that banks substitute away from riskier types of lending. Macroprudential policy is also more effective in reducing loan growth in (riskier) foreign currencies by banks that are relatively more exposed to foreign funding.

Turning to the cross-border spillover effects of global financial conditions, we find that macro-prudential policy is more potent at dampening lending in (riskier) foreign currencies when global risk appetite is high, as proxied by low European VIX, and when foreign monetary policy rates are low. We obtain the largest quantitative effects for tranquil periods of low VIX, suggesting greater effectiveness of macroprudential policies during economic booms compared to busts. Moreover, we split macroprudential instruments into bank- and borrower-side measures. This disaggregation is useful because bank-side measures (which target, for instance, provisioning and capital) could be less binding during periods of benign financial conditions and may be easier to circumvent (Aiyar and Wieladek, 2014; Jiménez et al., 2017). Consistently, we find that borrower-side measures are generally more effective at dampening risky lending decisions than bank-side measures,5 while bank-side measures are relatively more effective for banks with greater reliance on foreign funding.

Our paper is related to two main strands of literature. First, the paper adds to the literature on macroprudential policies and credit cycles. Although household leverage booms are known to be a key driver of financial crises and to predict poor subsequent economic performance, including outside the 2007-2009 global financial crisis (Mian et al., 2017; Mian and Sufi, 2015), to our knowledge this is the first paper that employs a household credit register to study leverage and macroprudential policies over a full cycle. In this context, Romania is an excellent case study because it experienced a full boom-bust cycle in household credit during the period of analysis, during which it adopted numerous macroprudential policies. Given this wide range of macroprudential policies, we are able to examine the effectiveness of certain groups of instruments that place quantitative restrictions, respectively, on financial institutions or borrowers. Most papers in this literature are cross-country studies,6 where identification and heterogeneity analysis—for instance, analyses across riskier loans, borrowers, or banks—is difficult to achieve.7 Using microdata, Jiménez et al. (2017) analyze the effects of bank-side macroprudential policies, in particular dynamic provisioning, on bank credit to the Spanish corporate sector. They document a smoothing effect of the policy on the credit supply cycle, with beneficial effects on firm real outcomes during crisis times. Similar to this paper, we employ extensive loan-level data from a credit register to examine the impact of macroprudential policies, but our focus is on household credit rather than corporate credit.8 Different from this paper, we document a larger impact of borrower-side macroprudential policies in tranquil times (when the VIX is low), whereas Jiménez et al. (2017) find that bank-side macroprudential policies (dynamic provisioning) have a stronger impact during crisis times.

Second, the paper is related to the literature on spillovers from international capital flows and the global financial cycle (Rey, 2013, 2016; Borio, 2014) on domestic lending and the real sector (Forbes and Warnock, 2012). Studies of cross-border spillovers analyze the impacts of different dimensions of global financial conditions—such as changes in investors’ uncertainty and risk aversion, and monetary policy of major central banks—to bank lending and risk-taking (Coimbra and Rey, 2017; Bruno and Shin, 2015a,b; Giannetti and Laeven, 2012a,b) through the activities of international banking groups (Cetorelli and Goldberg, 2012, 2011). For the case of Mexico, Morais et al. (2017) show that European and U.S. banks transmit monetary policy shocks from core countries to local firms’ borrowing and investment through an international bank lending and risk-taking channel of global monetary policy.9 Bräuning and Ivashina (2017a) find a strong link between U.S. monetary policy and credit cycles in emerging markets. Baskaya et al. (2017) document the impact of international capital flows and global risk appetite on domestic credit to firms in Turkey.

Our contribution is to push these questions one step further by asking how effective macroprudential policies used by emerging markets are in mitigating the transmission of global financial conditions to the local credit cycle. Our evidence suggests they are indeed effective, with tighter local macroprudential policies reducing spillover effects to local household credit from global risk appetite and expansionary foreign monetary policy. These effects are stronger for foreign currency credit and during periods of high risk appetite (low VIX) or low foreign monetary policy rates.

Our analysis also suggests that borrower-side measures are generally more effective (than bank-side measures) at dampening risky credit growth (in foreign currencies) that is driven by loose global financial conditions.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the institutional background of the analysis, including the macroeconomic context, the macroprudential policy framwork, and the banking sector in Romania. Section 3 describes the data and the econometric specifications. Section 4 discusses the results. Section 5 concludes. Appendix tables are labelled “A” throughout the paper.

2 Institutional Background

2.1 Macroeconomic Environment

Romania is bank-dependent emerging market economy, where a large portion of the banking sector is foreign-owned, there is substantial foreign bank funding, and about one third of household loans, including most residential mortgages, are extended in foreign currencies (especially EUR and CHF). These conditions expose the domestic economy to potential cross-border spillovers from foreign macroeconomic policies and the global financial cycle.

We analyze the effectiveness of macroprudental policymaking in Romania over a full boom-bust cycle. In the years prior to joining the EU in 2007, Romania experienced an economic boom, with average GDP growth of 7.3% between 2004 and 2008. An accompanying credit boom was fuelled by the expansion of foreign-owned banks—mostly Austrian and French banks—and large capital inflows. Total bank credit, including in foreign currencies, grew at an average of 23% in real terms during 2004-2008 (see Figure A1). As a result, the credit-to-GDP ratio more than tripled in just four years, reaching 40% of GDP in 2008. The global financial crisis led to an economic slowdown followed by a modest recovery. Real GDP fell by 7.8% during 2009-2010 and averaged 1.5% in 2011-2012. Post-crisis bank loan claims, at end-2012, were only four-fifths of their pre-crisis peak level. In addition, the large share of foreign currency loans extended before the crisis coupled with currency depreciation led to a significant rise in non-performing loans, slowing down credit growth and balance sheet recovery (Everaert et al., 2015).10 Similar to other countries in emerging Europe, Romania benefitted from the “Vienna Initiative” in the early stages of the crisis. As part of this initiative, West European banking groups with significant exposures to the East European market committed to maintain credit flow to the economies in the region.11

Over the sample period, the banking system comprises 42 banks, of which 30 private commercial banks, 2 state-owned and development banks, and 10 branches of foreign banks. The largest five banks account for almost 80% of total banking sector assets.12 Banks have average capital ratios (Tier 1 capital in percent of total assets) of 7.4%. The banking system is largely foreign-owned due to significant foreign bank entry through mergers and acquisitions during the boom period.13 Foreign bank assets account for 79.2% of total banking sector assets over 2004-2012, starting at 54% in 2004 and peaking at 89% at the end of the boom. As a result, there is a relatively large degree of reliance on foreign funding, at almost 20% of total assets, exposing domestic banks to external funding shocks.

Household credit claims account for about half of total private credit. Between 2005 and mid-2008 household debt increased at an average annual rate of 77%. More than half of outstanding bank loan claims are in foreign currencies. This remarkable rise in household debt was mirrored in unhedged foreign currency exposures for banks, as wages are largely denominated in local currency (IMF, 2010). Figure 2 shows household credit by type and currency based on loan originations in the credit register. Ten percent of individual loans are residential mortgages and almost 90% are consumer loans (including mortgage-backed consumer loans). Consumer loans account for 60% of total credit volume and mortgages for 40%. Housing is priced in EUR, therefore mortgages are mostly denominated in foreign currency (81% of loans in EUR, 7% of loans in CHF, and the rest in USD, GBP, and YEN). About 20% of consumer loans are extended in forex (mainly EUR).

Figure 1:
Figure 1:

Household Credit Growth and Macroprudential Policy

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 013; 10.5089/9781484338599.001.A001

Notes: The figure plots household bank credit growth (in real terms, year-on-year) and the macroprudential policy index during 2004-2012. The macroprudential policy (MPP) index is constructed following the approach in Cerutti et al. (2017) by coding introductions and changes in macroprudential instruments employed by the NBR as tightenings (+1) or loosenings (—1). The index is defined as the running (cumulative) sum of these values such that each macroprudential instrument is reflected in the index throughout the entire time it is in place until it is changed or discontinued. Higher values of the index indicate a tightening of macroprudential conditions. Household credit is deflated by the CPI 2005=100. Data sources: National Bank of Romania.
Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Household Credit by Type and Currency

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 013; 10.5089/9781484338599.001.A001

Notes: The figure plots total bank credit by type (mortgages, consumer loans) and currency (RON, EUR, CHF, and other currencies) during 2004-2012. Data sources: National Bank of Romania.

2.2 Macroprudential Policies

The NBR adopted a wide range of macroprudential measures during the 2004-2012 boom-bust cycle.14 Table A1 reports the date when each measure was introduced and its detailed description. Before the global financial crisis the aim was to limit the impact of strong capital inflows on domestic credit and to address the risks of FX lending to unhedged borrowers. Subsequently, lending standards were reduced to support credit and economic recovery.

During 2004-2006, the NBR targeted the level and composition of lending by gradually raising reserve requirements on foreign currency deposits and cutting those on local currency deposits.15 These measures were accompanied in 2005 by an outright limit on foreign currency credit exposures to unhedged individuals and firms (in percent of banks’ common equity). To further discourage risky borrowing and constrain household debt, the NBR imposed limits on loan-to-value (LTV) ratios for mortgages and debt-service-to-income (DTI) ratios for all loans. The DTI ceiling was later further reduced and applied to borrowers’ total debt as opposed to each individual loan.

A number of macroprudential policies were reversed or harmonized with EU-wide regulations in 2007 when Romania joined the EU. Banks were allowed to set LTV and DTI ceilings based on internal risk management models (subject to central bank guidelines), foreign currency credit limits were removed, and minimum capital requirements were reduced from 12% to 8%. The NBR enforced the Basel II regulatory framework, harmonizing risk-weights and tightening operational risk management. As the credit boom continued, in August 2008 the NBR required banks to explicitly consider interest and exchange rate risk in setting DTI limits, using their internal risk models, and raised provisioning requirements for foreign currency credits to unhedged borrowers.

As the first wave of the global financial crisis unfolded in 2009 and credit crashed, reserve requirements for all bank deposits regardless of currency were drastically reduced. Mortgage lending to first-time home buyers was supported through the launch of a government subsidy program in 2009 which, among others, exempted new mortgages from LTV limits. In 2011 the NBR set new currency-specific LTV and DTI ceilings (see Neagu et al. (2015) for a detailed analysis).

Macroprudential Policy Index. Given the large number of macroprudential measures and the high frequency with which they were implemented and changed, it is difficult to examine their impact in isolation. Doing so would open up the possibility that effects which we ascribe to one particular measure are confounded by other measures that occur at or around the same time. Therefore, we follow the approach in Cerutti et al. (2017) and measure macroprudential policy using an index which is coded manually from the list of measures taken by the NBR. Table A1 lists the macroprudential instruments together with a variable that codes each instrument as +1 for a tightening and —1 for a loosening in the period in which the instrument is in place (starting with the quarter when it is introduced until the quarter when it is removed, if within the sample period). The simultaneous introduction of two or three measures is coded as +2 or +3. The macroprudential policy index (MPP) is computed as the running (cumulative) sum of this variable starting in 2004:Q1. The index ranges between 0 and 12, with a mean of 5.943 and standard deviation of 3.581, and with higher values indicating a tighter macroprudential policy stance. The maximum was attained in 2006:Q4 and the minimum was attained in 2011:Q2-Q3.

Using the same approach we also classify the macroprudential measures into two groups to create MPP indices separately for bank- and borrower-based instruments. In the spirit of Cerutti et al. (2017), the bank-based macroprudential index captures quantitative restrictions on financial institutions’ balance sheets, targeting assets or liabilities or both, such as changes in reserve requirements on FX-denominated liabilities, ceilings on FX credit exposures to unhedged borrowers, and changes in provisioning and loan classification rules. Borrower-based measures refer to macroprudential instruments that aim at reducing risks associated with household indebtedness, for instance through time-varying LTV and DTI limits.16 (See Table A1 for details on the coding of each index.)

3 Data and Empirical Strategy

To estimate the impact of macroprudential policies on household credit we combine two confidential micro datasets, both sourced from the NBR: a loan-level dataset (household credit register) with information on individual loans originated by the entire banking system, and a bank-level dataset with supervisory information on bank balance sheets. The credit register contains information on loan originations (rather than loan exposures). The two datasets are merged on a unique bank identifier. We add information on domestic and global macroeconomic and financial conditions from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics. The final dataset is at the quarterly frequency over the 2004:Q1-2012:Q4 period. Loan and bank variables are winsorized at the 1% level to minimize the impact of outliers.

Descriptive statistics for regression variables are shown in Table 1. Variable sources and definitions are reported in Table A2.

Table 1:

Descriptive Statistics

article image
Notes: The sample period is 2004-2012. Loan amount is expressed in local currency (Romanian New Leu, or RON). The DTI is available for both mortgages and consumer loans and is trimmed at a maximum value of 300%. The OTHER category of foreign currency loans refers to loans in U.S. Dollar, British Pound Sterling, and Japanese Yen (which account for less than 0.5% of all loans over the sample period). All loan type variables are dummies. Loan and bank variables are winsorized at the 1% to minimize the impact of outliers. See Table A2 for variable definitions and sources.

3.1 Credit Register

The microdata on individual loans to households comes from the “Central Credit Register” maintained by the NBR in its capacity of bank supervisor. The credit register collects, stores, and compiles information on all the loans extended by reporting financial institutions in Romania. The data come from regulatory reports sent by financial institutions to the NBR and is recorded in the “central credit file” on a monthly basis. The credit register includes loans that are larger than a threshold of RON 20,000 (approximately USD 4,500).

For each granted loan we observe the issuing bank, the terms of the loan such as loan amount, currency, maturity, and interest rate,17 as well as key information on the borrower such as location (in one of 41 local economic areas, or “counties”) and age. We also know the LTV and DTI ratios that are associated with each loan and respectively each borrower. The loans are tracked over time so we also know if and when they were classified as non-performing, rescheduled, or restructured.

The final dataset contains 2,965,479 individual loans over the 2004-2012 period, of which 2,654,962 consumer loans and 310,517 mortgages. Further, 996,240 loans are in foreign currencies (868,745 in EUR, 118,007 in CHF, and the rest in other currencies). These loans were extended by 42 banks to 1,437,059 unique individual borrowers (282,364 mortgage borrowers). The average loan amount is approximately USD 44,000 for mortgages and USD 11,000 for consumer loans.

3.2 Macro Variables

We are interested in examining the ability of macroprudential policies to mitigate potential effects from global macroeconomic and financial conditions. We work with two measures of global conditions. The first measure, a proxy for global uncertainty and risk aversion, is the European VIX, that is, the Euro Stoxx 50 Volatility Index, which measures implied volatility of near-term options on the Euro Stoxx 50 Index (that comprises Eurozone blue chip stock index with liquid futures and options). The VIX is a commonly used indicator of global and regional funding liquidity conditions (Miranda-Agrippino and Rey, 2015). A lower VIX reflects lower uncertainty and higher investor risk appetite.

Given the relatively high degree or eurorization of the Romanian economy, our second proxy for global financial conditions is the Euro OverNight Index Average (EONIA) targeted by the European Central Bank (on a quarterly basis, measured as the average of monthly values). The EONIA is the one-day interbank interest rate for the Eurozone.18

In a handful of specifications without period fixed effects, we control for the domestic economic cycle with a measure of the NBR’s monetary policy stance, the real growth rate of seasonally-adjusted GDP, and the CPI inflation rate. To capture the NBR’s monetary policy stance we use the policy rate, i.e., the 7-day repo rate at which the NBR conducts open market operations on the secondary government securities market.

3.3 Empirical Specifications

In this section we present the empirical strategy to identify the impact of macroprudential policy on bank credit to households. Our empirical specifications assess the role of macroprudential policies as a potential counteracting force against risky credit growth and cross-border spillovers from international financial conditions, by exploiting differences in loan, borrower, and bank characteristics. Our approach hinges on double and triple interaction terms, coupled with demanding fixed effects, and enables us to more confidently ascribe causal interpretations to our estimates.

A simple empirical model of the level effect of macroprudential policies on household credit is based on the following specification:

Lijkt=αit+ηkt+βMPPtz+Xtzδ0+Zitzδ1+Wjktδ2+εijkt(1)

where Lijkt is the log(loan volume) extended by bank i to individual borrower j in county k in year t, and z is an appropriate lag.19 Macroeconomic, bank, borrower controls are respectively included in matrices X, Z, and W. Xtz includes the domestic monetary policy rate, GDP growth, CPI inflation, and the VIX (our barometer for risk appetite). The matrix of bank characteristics Zitz includes bank size (log-total assets), capital and liquidity ratios, return on assets (ROA), non-performing loan ratio (NPL), bank risk profile (risk weighted assets divided by total assets), the share of foreign funding in total assets, and an indicator for foreign-owned banks. The matrix Wjkt comprises borrower and loan characteristics such as borrower age, an indicator for FX loans,20 and an indicator for loans that were granted under the first-home mortgage program. Importantly, in all regressions we also add loan-type×period fixed effects (in particular, mortgage×period fixed effects) to make sure the results are not driven by systematic differences between residential mortgages and consumer loans.

In this specification, the coefficient of interest on macroprudential policy MPP is β, capturing the response of bank credit to macroprudential policy, and is expected to be negative. The unbiased estimation of β hinges on the identifying assumption that macroprudential policy is orthogonal on the error term ε. This assumption fails if macroprudential policies respond to the level of credit or to credit growth (reverse causality), or if there are confounding macroeconomic factors that correlate with macroprudential policies but are not fully captured by the included controls (omitted variables).

Our identification strategy will therefore exploit variation in loan, borrower, and bank characteristics, or differential effects. In particular, we use specifications with double and triple interactions, which are more robust to identification concerns. We control for unobserved (time-varying) borrower and bank-level heterogeneity with interacted bank×period fixed effects and borrower county×period fixed effects. In most specifications we include time-varying fixed effects by quarter during 2004-2012. (that is, bank×year-quarter and borrower county×year-quarter fixed effects). In several specifications where we have less variation across the various dimensions of interest in a given quarter, we use bank×semester and county×semester fixed effects. With year-quarter fixed effects, we do not independently estimate the level effect of macroeconomic variables such as macroprudential policy, VIX, domestic or foreign monetary policy, and instead we focus solely on differential effects.

Given the likely endogeneity of macroprudential policies with respect to the local economic cycle, we also make sure that the coefficients of the interaction effects of interest are robust to this concern by controlling for all the interaction terms of interest with measures of the local cycle. To determine which dimensions of the local cycle—monetary or real—are correlated with macroprudential policies, we regress the macroprudential policy index (MPP) on the domestic monetary policy rate, GDP growth, and CPI inflation. The results (shown in Table A3) indicate that the only robust determinant of MPP is the GDP growth rate. Therefore, to alleviate the potential concern that the results are picking up the effects of economic growth, all specifications with MPP interactions additionally include the corresponding GDP growth interactions.

Our workshorse specifications are given by:

Lijkt=αit+ηkt+βMPPtz×RISK+Zitzδ1+Wjktδ2+εijkt(2)

where RISK can be a loan-, borrower-, or bank-level variable. The terms MPP and RISK are omitted for simplicity, but they are introduced in all the regressions when not spanned by the fixed effects. If RISK is a dummy for FX loans, then the coefficient of interest β captures the differential effect of a tightening of macroprudential policies on FX loans compared to local currency loans. RISK can also be a bank-level variable that captures bank reliance on foreign funding, which allows us to ask if macroprudential policies are relatively more effective in dampening the risky lending of those banks which are more sensitive to external shocks and hence may cause greater spillovers to the domestic credit market. RISK can also capture ex-ante borrower riskiness as measured by DTI, or the riskiness of foreign-currency borrowers as a double interaction FX×DTI.

To examine whether cross-border spillovers from changes in investor risk attitude and foreign monetary policy are mitigated by macroprudential policies, we estimate specifications given by:

Lijkt=αit+ηkt+βMPPtz×SPILLOVERtz×RISK+Zitzδ1+Wjktδ2+εijkt(3)

where SPILLOVER is either the VIX or the EONIA, and RISK is a dummy for FX loans. The relevant main terms for MPP, SPILLOVER and RISK and their double interactions are omitted for simplicity, but they are introduced in all the regressions when not spanned by the fixed effects. The triple interaction term MPP × SPILLOVER × RISK allows us to determine if macroprudential policies can tame banks’ risky lending when risk appetite is high (i.e., the VIX is low) or when foreign monetary policy rates are low, and thus to test whether macroprudential policymaking is equally effective during booms and busts.

All the macroeconomic and bank-level variables in baseline specifications are averaged over the past two quarters.21 The regressions use the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) estimator with standard errors that are clustered on bank.

4 Results

We analyze the credit supply effects of macroprudential policies—for the overall MPP index, the bank-based, and the borrower-based indices—in regressions at the bank-loan-quarter level. We first discuss the results for risky loans (in foreign currencies or to high-debt borrowers), then the results for banks with heavy reliance on foreign funding, and finally the findings for cross-border spillovers from investor risk appetite and foreign monetary policies.

4.1 FX Loans

Table 2 presents regression results for the level and the differential impact of the macroprudential policy index (MPP) on bank lending to households. Column 1 shows the level specification from equation 1, which includes bank×year, borrower county×year, and loan-type×year fixed effects, as well as loan, bank, and borrower controls (see Table A4 for full regression results.). Here we are able to estimate the link between the level of macroprudential policies and loan growth by exploiting within-year (quarterly) variation in macroprudential policies. The regression results indicate a negative and statistically significant link between MPP and bank credit, suggesting that a tighter macroprudential policy stance is associated with lower loan volumes.22

Table 2:

Macroprudential Policies and Household Credit—FX Loans

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during year t (column 1) or quarter t (columns 2-4). In column 1, other controls refer to macroeconomic variables (local monetary policy, GDP growth, inflation), bank variables (size, capital, liquidity, ROA, NPL, risk profile, share of foreign funding, and foreign bank dummy), borrower age, and loan variables (dummy for first-home mortgages). In the remaining columns macroeconomic variables and bank variables are spanned by the fixed effects so we only control for borrower age and loan variables (dummy for mortgages and for first-home mortgages). GDP growth interactions refer to GDP growth × FX. All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.

In columns 2-3 we focus on the impact of MPP on the currency composition of bank credit. We show the baseline specification from equation 2 where we interact MPP with a dummy for foreign currency loans FX, as FX loans are riskier when extended to unhedged borrowers. Furthermore, we account for time-varying macroeconomic conditions (including loan demand) at the county level with a set of demanding county×year-quarter fixed effects, which allows us to focus on variation in the currency extended by different banks to borrowers in the same county and quarter. Loan-type×year-quarter fixed effects ensure that comparisons are made for loans of the same type (either mortgages or consumer loans). This specification further includes the usual controls as well as interactions of GDP growth with the FX dummy to avoid the possibility that the coefficient on the interaction term of interest (MPP×FX) captures the effects of the local economic cycle instead of those of macroprudential policies (as discussed in Section 3.3). The estimates in column 2 of Table 2 indicate that a tightening of macroprudential policy by one standard deviation (SD) or 3.581 units reduces average foreign currency loan volume by close to 18% more than it does for local currency loan volume.23

In columns 3-4 we distinguish between the effects of different groups of macroprudential instruments such as bank-oriented policies (column 3) and borrower-oriented policies (column 4). We choose to include these indices one at a time in the specifications due to their high correlation with one another. To the extent that the omission of an index would cause an omitted variable bias in the estimated coefficient on the included index, we would observe strong effects for all indices. However, the results suggest that this is not the case—despite this potential bias, the coefficient on MPP × FX in column 3 is statistically insignificant for the bank index. Column 4 suggests that borrower-oriented measures are more effective in reducing risky FX lending than bank-oriented measures.

In Table A5 we further unpack the coefficients from Table 2 to test for differential effects of macroprudential policy for loans in different currencies (EUR, CHF, other) relative to RON. For the overall index we find similar coefficient magnitudes for EUR and CHF loans, and larger magnitudes for other currency loans (USD, GBP, YEN). That said, the latter effect is not quantitatively significant since other-currency FX loans make up less than 0.5% of the sample. The estimates suggest that macroprudential policies, especially borrower-based measures, reduce FX loan growth uniformly across major currencies such as EUR and CHF.

4.2 Borrower Riskiness (DTI, FX)

We conduct a similar exercise in Table 3 to estimate the impact of macroprudential policies on the risk composition of household credit. Our measure of ex-ante borrower creditworthiness is borrower DTI.24 Focusing on a measure of ex-ante borrower risk is important because ex-post measures such as loan defaults may confound the bank’s assessment of loan risk when granting the loan, with subsequent events that influence loan performance (see, e.g., Dell’Ariccia et al. (2017) and Jiménez et al. (2014)).

Table 3:

Macroprudential Policies and Household Credit—Borrower Riskiness (DTI, FX)

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during quarter t. The DTI ratio is divided by 100. In all columns macroeconomic variables and bank variables are spanned by the fixed effects so “other controls” refer to borrower age and loan variables (dummy for first-home mortgages). GDP growth interactions refer to GDP growth×DTI (column 1), or respectively GDP growth×DTI×FX and GDP growth×DTI×RON (columns 2-4). All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.

Here all specifications include borrower county×year-quarter and bank×year-quarter fixed effects. Column 1 shows that the coefficient on MPP × DTI is negative but statistically insignificant. However, when we break down this effect by currency (column 2), using a spline of the MPP × DTI term with FX and RON loan dummies, we notice that the coefficient estimate on MPP × DTI × FX is negative and statistically significant, while that on MPP × DTI × RON is positive and statistically significant. Notice that this result is similar for bank- and borrower-based MPP indices (columns 3-4). It suggests a strong negative impact of macroprudential policies on FX loan volumes and a positive impact on RON loan volumes for riskier (higher DTI) borrower. Therefore, for a given level of borrower risk, a tightening of macroprudential policies changes the composition of bank credit away from (riskier) FX lending in favor of (less risky) local currency lending.25

Comparing foreign and local-currency loans extended in a given quarter by a given bank to borrowers from the same county and with the same risk profile (DTI), and using the estimates in column 2 of Table 3, we find that a tightening of macroprudential policies by one SD (3.581 units) reduces FX loan growth by 11.6% and increases RON loan growth by 6.3% on average, for a differential of 17.9 percentage points.26 These results suggest that tighter macroprudential policies reduce the ex-ante riskiness of bank credit, as measured by borrower DTI, conditional on loan currency. In particular, for a given level of borrower creditworthiness, tighter macroprudential policies dampen the riskier forms of bank lending, in foreign currencies, and increase the less risky forms of bank lending, in local currencies. As a result, the currency composition of loan originations changes away from FX and towards the local currency.

These effects are further examined in Table A6, which shows a decomposition by individual currency (EUR, CHF, OTHER). For the overal MPP index, in column 1 we find stronger dampening effects of tighter macroprudential policies on EUR and other foreign currency loans (as opposed to CHF). The results are broadly consistent for bank- and borrower-side indices (columns 2-3).

4.3 Bank Exposure to Foreign Funding

Next we analyze how the effects of macroprudential policies on household credit vary with bank-level heterogeneity in funding model. In particular, we examine the importance of the share of foreign funding (non-resident foreign currency deposits) in banks’ total assets as a measure of banks’ exposure to global funding conditions and external shocks. Almost 90% of banks’ foreign funding comes from parent banks, and about 5% are loans from international development banks (such as the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the European Investment Bank). During 2009-2016 about 43% of non-resident deposits were short term (with maturity less than 2 years). Over the same period, more than 70% of non-resident deposits were in EUR and close to 20% in RON. As expected, foreign banks rely more heavily on foreign funding (the average ratio is 25% for foreign banks compared to 9% for domestic banks). In addition, foreign banks are conduits for external financial and monetary shocks (see, among others, Bräuning and Ivashina (2017b,a), Morais et al. (2017), Ongena et al. (2015), and Cetorelli and Goldberg (2012)). To ensure our results are not confounded by foreign bank ownership, we add relevant interactions with the foreign-bank dummy to the specifications.

We expect macroprudential policies to affect banks with varying degrees of exposure to foreign funding differently because many policies, such as minimum reserve requirement ratios, directly target banks’ FX-denominated liabilities. Therefore, we would like to construct a measure of foreign funding that matches the target of such measures as precisely as possible. Prior to 2005 reserve ratios applied to short-term FX funding (with a maturity of less than 2 years); during 2005Q1-2009Q1 reserve requirements were tightened to affect all FX funding (regardless of maturity). This measure was reversed in 2009Q2. In line with this sequence of policies, our bank-level measure of foreign funding refers to short-term FX non-resident deposits during 2004-2005 (defined as nonresident deposits with maturity less than 1 year, instead of 2 years, due to data availability), all FX non-resident deposits during 2005Q1-2009Q1, and again short-term FX non-resident deposits during 2009Q2-2012Q4 (defined as non-resident deposits with maturity less than 2 years).

In baseline Table 2 we documented a negative effect on the MPP×FX interaction variable. Here we ask whether this effect is stronger for banks with greater exposure to foreign funding. In Table 4 we show specifications with a triple interaction term of interest, MPP×FX×ForeignFunding that include the relevant loan and borrower controls, GDP growth interactions, bank and county×year-quarter fixed effects, as well as competing interactions with foreign-bank dummy.

Table 4:

Macroprudential Policies and Household Credit—Bank Exposure to Foreign Funding

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during quarter t. In all columns, macroeconomic variables and bank variables are spanned by the fixed effects (including the double-interaction Macroprudential policy×Foreign-funding) so “other controls” refer to borrower age and loan variables (dummy for first-home mortgages). GDP growth interactions refer to GDP growth×FX×Foreign-funding, GDP growth×FX (column 1), and additionally GDP growth×FX×Foreign-bank (columns 2-4). All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.

Comparing the results in columns 1 and 2 of Table 4 reveals that interactions with the foreign-bank dummy do not materially affect the coefficient on the triple interaction of interest, which remains negative and statistically significant. The estimated coefficient on MPP×FX×ForeignFunding suggests a stronger dampening effect of tigher macroprudential policies on FX loan growth for banks that rely more heavily on foreign funding. The coefficient estimate —0.025 in column 2 of Table 4 suggests that the dampening effect of a tightening in macroprudential policies on FX loan volume is larger by 8.2 percentage points for a bank with low exposure to foreign funding (10th percentile, or 2.01%) compared to a bank with high exposure to foreign funding (90th percentile, or 34.64%).27

The results in the remaining columns (3-4) reveal negative and statistically significant coefficient estimates for both the bank and the borrower-based indices. However, economic magnitudes indicate that bank-based measures are quantitatively more impactful. Standardizing the estimated coefficients on MPP × FX × ForeignFunding in columns 3-4 reveals that bank-based macroprudential policies have a dampening effect on FX credit that is about 5 times larger than that of borrower-based policies, for a given level of foreign funding reliance.28 The relatively higher effectiveness of bank-based instruments to reduce spillovers from banks’ access to foreign funding on the local credit cycle is a novel finding in the literature, which previously emphasized borrower-targeted instruments as relatively more effective in emerging market economies (see, e.g., Cerutti et al. (2017) and Ayyagari et al. (2017)).

4.4 Spillovers from Global Uncertainty and Risk Appetite

We turn to exploring the role of macroprudential policies in mitigating cross-border spillovers from the global financial cycle. In this section we focus on the European VIX, reflecting global uncertainty and investor risk appetite, as one proxy of global financial conditions. The results are reported in Table 5. In column 1 we show a specification that focuses on the interaction of macroprudential policy and the continuous variable VIX. To better identify the effect of this variable, which varies by quarter, we only include bank×semester and county×semester fixed effects. Therefore, we only exploit within-semester (quarterly) variation in the VIX. The coefficient estimates indicate that a decline in the VIX (an increase in risk appetite) increases household credit and this effect is reduced by a tightening of macroprudential policy. Specifically, with no macroprudential policy (MPP = 0), a reduction of the VIX by one unit, or approximately one tenth of a SD, raises household credit by 6.5%; this effect is undone by an increase in the MPP index by 3.7 units or one SD.29

Table 5:

Spillovers of Global Risk Appetite on Household Credit

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during year t. In all columns, other controls refer to macroeconomic variables (local monetary policy, GDP growth, inflation), bank variables (size, capital, liquidity, ROA, NPL, risk profile, share of foreign funding, and foreign bank dummy), borrower age, and loan variables (dummy for first-home mortgages). GDP growth interactions refer to GDP growths×VIX in column 1, and to GDP growth×VIX×FX and GDP growth×VIX×RON in columns 2-5. All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.

In columns 2-5 of Table 5 we dig deeper into the estimated effect of the VIX by allowing for differential effects for FX vs. local-currency loans. Breaking down the effect of MPP × VIX by loan currency (using a spline) yields positive and statistically significant coefficients which are not statistically different from one another (at the 1% level of significance). Therefore, when higher risk appetite increases puts upward pressure on lending to households, a tightening of macroprudential policies does not affect the currency composition of household credit. This non-effect, however, could conceal some nonlinearities. Therefore, we consider one more spline which further breaks down the currency-specific effect of MPP into periods of high vs. low VIX (above/below its average over the sample period). As seen in columns 3-5, the four-term spline introduced in these specifications reveals that macroprudential policies reduce FX loan growth relatively more than it does local-currency loan growth during periods of low VIX (high risk appetite); and than loan growth in any currency during periods of high VIX (low risk appetite). To examine the statistical validity of this result, we report p-values for one-sided t-tests that the coefficients on the triple interaction MPP × LowVIX × FX are greater (in absolute value) than those on the remaining spline terms. We find this to be true for all MPP indices considered. Put differently, macroprudential polices are more effective at dampening risky (FX) bank credit to households as global risk appetite increases. In addition, they are most effective during periods when risk appetite is high, pushing capital flows to emerging markets and, through the banking system, fuelling household credit booms.

In Table A7 we explore the effects of macroprudential policies on spillovers of global risk appetite to household credit growth by loan type, distinguishing between mortgages (columns 1-3) and consumer loans (columns 4-6). The results show that when risk appetite is high (VIX is low), the elasticity of loan growth with respect to the overall MPP index and the individual indices is larger for consumer loans compared to mortgages (column 1 vs. 4). For each specification, the p-values at the bottom of the table indicate that the coefficient on the triple interaction term MPP × LowVIX × FX is larger than that on all the other terms, consistent with the message of Table 5.

4.5 Spillovers from Foreign Monetary Policy

Our final set of specifications test the ability of macroprudential policies to affect the transmission of foreign monetary conditions to the local household credit cycle. Given the large degree of eurorization of the Romanian economy, our proxy for regional monetary conditions is the EONIA. Once again we estimate differential effects with double and triple interaction terms of the EONIA with the macroprudential policy index MPP and loan characteristics (FX), as shown in Table 6. All regressions include the usual controls and relevant interactions with the VIX. The regressions are saturated with bank-, borrower county, and loan-type×year-quarter fixed effects.

Table 6:

Spillovers of Foreign Monetary Policy on Household Credit

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during quarter t. In all columns, macroeconomic variables and bank variables are spanned by the fixed effects so “other controls” refer to borrower age and loan variables (dummy for first-home mortgages). GDP growth interactions refer to the term EONIA×GDP growth×FX. All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.

Looking at the estimated coefficients on EONIA×FX interactions in Table 6, we find that periods of low Eurozone monetary policy rates are associated with higher FX lending, suggesting cross-border spillovers of regional financial conditions. In addition, the positive and statistically significant coefficient on the triple interaction term EONIA×MPP×FX indicates that macroprudential policy reduces this spillover effect. Notice that this effect is not driven by simultaneous changes in domestic macroeconomic conditions given that the specification controls for the interaction term EONIA×GDP growth×FX. The results in columns 2-3 for bank- and borrower-oriented measures reveal stronger effects for borrower-based measures.

5 Conclusions

In this paper we examine the impact of macroprudential policies on domestic bank credit to households and its role in mitigating spillovers from the global financial cycle. Household leverage is an important driver of consumption booms and financial crises. Therefore, understanding the role of macroprudential instruments in smoothing the domestic credit cycle and insulating it from cross-border spillovers is crucial for policy design. To date, the literature largely focuses on corporate credit, with only few studies examining household credit.

We contribute to the literature by exploiting a comprehensive household credit register that contains all the individual loans extended by commercial banks in a financially-integrated emerging market economy. Our case study is Romania during 2004-2012. Romania is the ideal laboratory for our analysis due the availability of a credit register coupled with bank balance sheet data and borrower information, and because it has a majority foreign-owned banking system where banks rely on foreign funding from parent banks and hence are exposed to external shocks. In addition, Romania experienced a full boom-bust economic cycle over the period of analysis during which policymakers deployed a wide range of macroprudential policies, including adjustments in reserve requirement ratios and capital requirements, caps on loan exposures to unhedged borrowers, and loan-to-value and debt-service-to-income ceilings.

Our results suggest that macroprudential policies impact domestic bank credit differentially, with stronger dampening effects on foreign vs. local currency loans and risky vs. less risky borrowers (as proxied by their debt-service-to-income ratios). A tightening of macroprudential policies also reduces household credit extended by banks that are more reliant on foreign funding, especially credit that is denominated in foreign currencies. Further, macroprudential policy is more effective at taming credit growth in (riskier) foreign currencies when global risk appetite is high, as proxied by a low VIX, and when foreign monetary policy rates are low. Thus, macroprudential policies mitigate international spillovers of the global financial cycle on local household credit growth by dampening risky forms of lending.

References

  • Acharya, V. V., Eisert, T., Eufinger, C., and Hirsch, C. W. (2016). Real effects of the sovereign debt crisis in europe: Evidence from syndicated loans. Available at SSRN 2612855.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aiyar, Shekhar, C. C. W. and Wieladek, T. (2014). Does macropru leak? Evidence from a UK policy experiment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 46(s1):181214.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Akinci, O. and Olmstead-Rumsey, J. (2015). How effective are macroprudential policies? An empirical investigation. Journal of Financial Intermediation, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auer, R. and Ongena, S. (2016). The countercyclical capital buffer and the composition of bank lending. BIS Working Papers No 593.

  • Ayyagari, M., Beck, T., and Martinez Peria, M. S. (2017). Credit growth and macroprudential policies: Preliminary evidence on the firm level. BIS Papers No. 91, pages 1534.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baskaya, Y. S., Giovanni, J. d., Peydro, J.-L., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., and Ulu, M. F. (2017). Capital flows and the international credit cycle. Journal of International Economics, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, B. S. (1983). Non-monetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the Great Depression. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 1054.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhutta, N. and Keys, B. J. (2016). Interest rates and equity extraction during the housing boom. American Economic Review, 106(7):174274.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borio, C. (2014). The financial cycle and macroeconomics: What have we learnt? Journal of Banking & Finance, 45:182198.

  • Borio, C. and Zhu, H. (2012). Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: A missing link in the transmission mechanism? Journal of Financial Stability, 8(4):236251.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bräuning, F. and Ivashina, V. (2017a). Monetary policy and global banking. NBER Working Paper No. 23316.

  • Bräuning, F. and Ivashina, V. (2017b). U.S. monetary policy and emerging markets credit cycle. Unpublished manuscript.

  • Bruno, V. and Shin, H. S. (2015a). Capital flows and the risk-taking channel of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 71:119132.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, V. and Shin, H. S. (2015b). Cross-border banking and global liquidity. The Review of Economic Studies, 82:535564.

  • Camors, C. D., Peydro, J.-L., and Tous, F. R. (2015). Macroprudential and monetary policy: Loan-level evidence from reserve requirements. mimeo.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cerutti, E., Claessens, S., and Laeven, L. (2017). The use and effectiveness of macroprudential policies: New evidence. Journal of Financial Stability, 28:203224.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cetorelli, N. and Goldberg, L. S. (2011). Global banks and international shock transmission: Evidence from the crisis. IMF Economic Review, 59(1):4176.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cetorelli, N. and Goldberg, L. S. (2012). Banking globalization and monetary transmission. Journal of Finance, LXZ11(5):18111843.

  • Claessens, S. (2015). An overview of macroprudential policy tools. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 7:397422.

  • Claessens, S., Ghosh, S. R., and Mihet, R. (2013). Macro-prudential policies to mitigate financial system vulnerabilities. Journal of International Money and Finance, 39:153185.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coimbra, N. and Rey, H. (2017). Financial cycles with heterogeneous intermediaries. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 23245.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crowe, C. W., Dell'Ariccia, G., Rabanal, P., and Igan, D. (2011). Policies for Macrofinancial Stability: Options to Deal with Real Estate Booms. Staff Discussion Note SDN/11/91, International Monetary Fund.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Haas, R., Korniyenko, Y., Pivovarsky, A., and Tsankova, T. (2015). Taming the herd? Foreign banks, the Vienna Initiative and crisis transmission. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 24(3):325355.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell'Ariccia, G., Laeven, L.,, Igan, D., Tong, H., Bakker, B. B., and Vandenbussche, J. (2012). Policies for macrofinancial stability: How to deal with credit booms. Staff Discussion Note SDN/12/16, International Monetary Fund.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell'Ariccia, G., Laeven, L., and Marquez, R. (2014). Real interest rates, leverage, and bank risk-taking. The Journal of Economic Theory, 149:6599.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell'Ariccia, G., Laeven, L., and Suarez, G. A. (2017). Bank Leverage and Monetary Policy's Risk-Taking Channel: Evidence from the United States. The Journal of Finance, 72(2):613654.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, D. W. and Rajan, R. G. (2012). Illiquid banks, financial stability, and interest rate policy. The Journal of Political Economy, 120(3):552591.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dimova, D., Kongsamut, P., and Vandenbussche, J. (2016). Macroprudential Policies in Southeastern Europe. IMF Working Paper No. 16/29.

  • Duenwald, C., Nikolay, G., and Andrea, S. (2005). Too Much of a Good Thing? Credit Booms in Transition Economies: The Cases of Bulgaria, Romania, and Ukraine. IMF Working Paper No. 05/128.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Everaert, E., Che, N., Geng, N., Gruss, B., Impavido, G., Lu, Y., Saborowski, C., Vandenbussche, J., and L, Z. (2015). Does Supply or Demand Drive the Credit Cycle? Evidence from Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe. IMF Working Paper No. 15/15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Forbes, K. J. and Warnock, F. E. (2012). Capital flow waves: Surges, stops, flight, and retrenchment. Journal of International Economics, 88(2):235251.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freixas, X., Laeven, L., and Peydró, J.-L. (2015). Systemic risk, crises, and macroprudential regulation. MIT Press.

  • Ghosh, A. R., Ostry, J. D., and Qureshi, M. (2017). Managing the Tide: How Do Emerging Markets Respond to Capital Flows? IMF Working Paper No. 17/69.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giannetti, M. and Laeven, L. (2012a). The flight home effect: Evidence from the syndicated loan market during financial crises. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(1):2343.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giannetti, M. and Laeven, L. (2012b). Flight home, flight abroad, and international credit cycles. American Economic Review, 102(3):219224.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gourinchas, P.-O. and Obstfeld, M. (2012). Stories of the twentieth century for the twenty-first. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(1):226265.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF (2009). Lessons of the Financial Crisis for Future Regulation of Financial Institutions and Markets and for Liquidity Management. IMF Policy Paper.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF (2010). Romania: Financial Sector Stability Assessment. IMF Country Report NO. 10/47.

  • IMF (2013). Key Aspects of Macroprudential Policy. IMF Policy Paper.

  • IMF (2014). Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy. IMF Policy Paper.

  • IMF-FSB-BIS (2016). Elements of Effective Macroprudential Policies: Lessons from International Experience. Joint Report.

  • Jiménez, G., Ongena, G., Peydró, J.-L., and Saurina, J. (2017). Macroprudential policy, countercyclical bank capital buffers and credit supply: Evidence from the Spanish dynamic provisioning experiments. Journal of Political Economy, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jiménez, G., Ongena, S., Peydró, J., and Saurina, J. (2012). Credit supply and monetary policy: Identifying the bank-balance sheet channel with loan applications. American Economic Review, 102(5):21212165.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jiménez, G., Ongena, S., Peydró, J., and Saurina, J. (2014). Hazardous times for monetary policy: What do twenty-three million bank loans say about the effects of monetary policy on credit risk? Econometrica, 2(82):463505.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kashyap, A. K. and Stein, J. C. (2000). What do a million observations on banks say about the transmission of monetary policy? American Economic Review, 90(3):407428.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keys, B. J., Piskorski, T., Seru, A., and Yao, V. (2014). Mortgage rates, household balance sheets, and the real economy. NBER Working Paper No. 20561.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2013). Systemic banking crises database. IMF Economic Review, 61(2):225270.

  • Lim, C. H., Costa, A., Columba, F., Kongsamut, P., Otani, A., Saiyid, M., Wezel, T., and Wu, X. (2011). Macroprudential policy: What instruments and how to use them? Lessons from country experiences. IMF Working Paper No. 11/238.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2015). House of debt: How they (and you) caused the Great Recession, and how we can prevent it from happening again. University of Chicago Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mian, A. R. and Sufi, A. (2016). Household debt and defaults from 2000 to 2010: The credit supply view.

  • Mian, A. R., Sufi, A., and Verner, E. (2017). Household debt and business cycles world wide. Quarterly Journal of Economics, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miranda-Agrippino, S. and Rey, H. (2015). World asset markets and the global financial cycle. NBER Working Paper No. 21722.

  • Morais, B., Peydro, J., and Ruiz, C. (2017). The International Bank Lending Channel of Monetary Policy Rates and Quantitative Easing: Credit Supply, Reach-for-Yield, and Real Effects. Journal of Finance, forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Neagu, F., Tatarici, L., and Mihai, I. (2015). Implementing loan-to-value and debt-service-to-income measures: A decade of Romanian experience. NBR Occasional Paper No. 15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ongena, S., Peydro, J.-L., and Van Horen, N. (2015). Shocks abroad, pain at home? bank-firm-level evidence on the international transmission of financial shocks. IMF Economic Review, 63(4):698750.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S. (2009). This time is different: Eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton University Press.

  • Rey, H. (2013). Dilemma not Trilemma: The global financial cycle and monetary policy independence. Jackshon Hole Conference Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rey, H. (2016). International channels of transmission of monetary policy and the Mundellian trilemma. IMF Economic Review, 64(1):635.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schularick, M. and Taylor, A. M. (2012). Credit booms gone bust: Monetary policy, leverage cycles, and financial crises, 1870–2008. The American Economic Review, 102(2):1029-1061.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Skimmyhorn, W. (2016). Assessing Financial Education: Evidence from Boot Camp. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 8(2):32243.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vandenbussche, J. (2012). Country Cases: Selected Central, Eastern, and South-Eastern Europe Countries. The Interaction of Monetary and Macroprudential Policies—Background Paper, International Monetary Fund.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vandenbussche, J., Vogel, U., and Detragiache, E. (2015). Macroprudential policies and housing prices: A new database and empirical evidence for Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 47(S1):343377.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

Appendix figures and tables

Figure A1:
Figure A1:

Household and Corporate Credit Growth

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 013; 10.5089/9781484338599.001.A001

Notes: The figure plots household and corporate credit growth in real terms (year-on-year). Credit is deflated by the CPI (2005=100). Data source: National Bank of Romania.
Table A1:

Macroprudential Policy Measures, 2004-2012

article image
article image
Table A2:

Variable Definitions and Sources

article image
Table A3:

Local Macro Determinants of Macroprudential Policies

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS on quarterly data over the period 2004-2012. The dependent variable is the overall macroprudential policy index (MPP). All variables enter contemporaneously. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.
Table A4:

Macroprudential Policies and Household Credit—FX Loans—All Covariates

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during year t (columns 1-2) or respectively quarter t (column 3). All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.
Table A5:

Macroprudential Policies and Household Credit—FX Loans—By Currency

article image
Notes: The estimates in this table come from OLS over the period 2004-2012. Observations are at the bank-loan-quarter level. The dependent variable is log loan-volume Lijkt extended by bank i to individual borrower j residing in county k during quarter t. In all columns macroeconomic variables and bank variables are spanned by the fixed effects so we only control for borrower age and loan variables (dummy for first-home mortgages). GDP growth interactions refer to GDP growth×FX×EUR, GDP growth×FX×CHF, and GDP growth×FX×OTHER. All macro and bank variables taken as averages over the last two quarters. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered on bank. *** indicates significance at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level and * at the 10% level.