Where Does Multinational Investment Go with Territorial Taxation? Evidence from the UK
Author: Ms. Li Liu

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: lliu@imf.org

In 2009, the United Kingdom changed from a worldwide to a territorial tax system, abolishing dividend taxes on foreign repatriation from many low-tax countries. This paper assesses the causal effect of territorial taxation on real investments, using a unique dataset for multinational affiliates in 27 European countries and employing the difference-in-difference approach. It finds that the territorial reform has increased the investment rate of UK multinationals by 15.7 percentage points in low-tax countries. In the absence of any significant investment reduction elsewhere, the findings represent a likely increase in total outbound investment by UK multinationals.

Abstract

In 2009, the United Kingdom changed from a worldwide to a territorial tax system, abolishing dividend taxes on foreign repatriation from many low-tax countries. This paper assesses the causal effect of territorial taxation on real investments, using a unique dataset for multinational affiliates in 27 European countries and employing the difference-in-difference approach. It finds that the territorial reform has increased the investment rate of UK multinationals by 15.7 percentage points in low-tax countries. In the absence of any significant investment reduction elsewhere, the findings represent a likely increase in total outbound investment by UK multinationals.

I. Introduction

Many countries strive to create competitive tax systems to attract internationally mobile capital. The United States, Germany and the United Kingdom have all used forms of accelerated depreciation allowances to encourage domestic investment. Many developing countries have offered lower corporate tax rates and temporary tax holidays to attract foreign investments. The taxation of profits earned overseas in the home country of multinational companies(MNCs) is another important channel for tax policies to influence both domestic and foreign investment. This topic has attracted considerable attention in recent policy debate regarding reforming the international tax system. For example, the US is considering moving to a territorial tax system, following proposals in the 2017 House and Senate’s international tax reform packages. In contrast to the lively policy debate, there is surprisingly little empirical evidence on how the taxation of foreign earnings influences multinational investments.1

This paper provides some of the first micro-level evidence on the causal effect of territorial taxation on the levels and locations of investments by multinationals, based on a 2009 policy reform of international tax rules in the UK. The United Kingdom used a worldwide approach prior to the year 2009, taxing foreign repatriations from countries with a statutory tax rate lower than the UK at a tax differential between the host country and the UK. The 2009 reform abolished the worldwide regime by going territorial and exempting active foreign earnings from UK taxation altogether. The reform thus reduced the dividend tax on foreign earnings in the low-tax countries. In contrast, the reform had little direct impact on foreign earnings in the high-tax countries. This is because the worldwide regime capped the dividend tax on foreign earnings at the UK corporate tax rate, so that there was no additional tax on repatriations from the high-tax countries even before the reform.

In principle, the two distinct approaches in taxing cross-border income can have very different implications on the allocation of multinational investment between domestic and foreign activities, and on the pattern of investment abroad.2 I use a simple investment model based on Bond, Devereux, and Klemm (2007) and Chetty and Saez (2010) to understand the effects of the reform on the level of investment by UK multinationals. The model yields three predictions of how investment would respond to the territorial reform, depending on the source of financing and on whether the tax reform is permanent or temporary. First, dividend exemption following the reform would increase investment by UK multinationals that use new equity to finance new investment.3 Second, dividend exemption would have no impact on the cost of capital for multinational investment financed with retained earnings, which is a result first suggested in Hartman (1985).4 Third, the irrelevance result of dividend tax on internal-funded investment would no longer hold when tax changes are anticipated or temporary. Anticipating a forthcoming reduction in the dividend tax, profit-maximizing MNCs would engage in inter-temporal tax planning by postponing repatriation and increasing investment before the reform.5

I test these predictions by exploiting the 2009 reform as a quasi-experiment. The basic idea is that a UK-specific reform should have no direct impact on the after-tax return to investment by non-UK multinationals, which can be used as a control group in the difference-indifference analysis. I analyze the investment responses in the low-tax countries separately from those in the high-tax countries, as the direct investment effect of the reform should concentrate in the low-tax countries. The identifying assumption underlying the research design is that investment by UK and non-UK multinational affiliates would have trended similarly in the absence of the tax reform. Graphical evidence shows similar trends in the investment series before the reform. Results of the placebo tests suggest that there are no differential changes in investment by UK affiliates relative to the control group in the low-tax countries in any of the three years in the pre-reform period. Moreover, should UK multinationals be affected more lightly than non-UK multinationals in the financial crisis, we would expect a similar rebound in their investment in both the low-tax and high-tax countries. However, as shown in the empirical analysis below, increases in investment by UK multinationals are only observed in countries with tax rates that are specifically lower than the UK rate.

The empirical analysis uses unconsolidated financial and ownership data on multinational affiliates in EU27 from the AMADEUS database provided by Bureau van Dijk,6, complemented by information on country-level corporate tax rates and other economic and governance characteristics. The main sample is an unbalanced panel with annual observations from 131,614 multinational affiliates between 2005 and 2011, of which 30,206 are UK affiliates. I obtain qualitatively similar results in regressions using a balanced panel, a smaller control group of firms with parent companies in the ten largest EU-27 countries, and a matched sample of firms with similar turnover, asset, and turnover growth rate.

I find that dividend exemption increased investment by UK affiliates in the low-tax countries. The finding is robust to controlling for a wide range of non-tax determinants of cross-border investment decisions. Quantitatively, the introduction of territorial system increased the gross investment rate by UK affiliates by 15.7 percentage points in the low tax countries in response to an average reduction of 9 percentage points in dividend taxes. The finding of a significant increase in investment in the low-tax countries is robust to changes in the sample (unbalanced and balanced panels), changes in the control group (with and without parent companies subjecting to worldwide taxation, with parent companies in the ten largest EU-27 countries, and matched panels), inclusion of additional controls (with and without industry- and county-level time trends, and with and without controlling for the euro crisis), investment measures (gross investment and net investment), and outlier winsorization (at the 97.5th and 99th percentiles). The finding of a significant increase in investment in the low-tax countries is also robust to controlling for average potential differential changes in investment between the treated and control group in a triple-difference estimation approach.

There are considerable heterogeneous effects of dividend exemption on investments by UK affiliates. The observed investment increase is mainly driven by financially constrained firms measured by the availability of free cash flow. The same group of cash-constrained firms are also more likely to issue new equity after the reform based on a difference-in-difference linear probability regression analysis. The investment increase is concentrated in larger and more complex multinational groups measured by their total number of related companies and total assets. There is no significant change in employment, labor productivity or profitability in the UK affiliates in the low-tax countries, yet there is a moderate increase in the average affiliate-level wage rate. The evidence suggests that workers may have also benefited from the reform by sharing tax savings with their companies.

The investment effect of the policy reform is estimated to be negative in the high-tax countries and positive in the UK, based on similar difference-in-difference approaches. However, both effects are estimated with imprecision so none of the coefficient estimate is significant at conventional statistical levels. The results therefore do not provide strong evidence of any significant reallocation of investment from domestic to foreign activities, or from the high- to low-tax countries following the reform. In aggregate, the investment increase in the low-tax countries is estimated to be €5.6 billion, which is approximately nine times the amount of estimated foregone tax revenue.

This paper relates to several strands of literature in corporate taxation and corporate finance. First, it contributes to the broader literature on FDI and taxation by quantifying the significant role of home country tax.7 Second, it adds to the literature studying the behavioral responses of multinationals to the taxation of cross-border income (Bradley, Dauchy, and Hasegawa, 2017; Desai, Foley, and Hines, 2001; Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes, 2011; Egger and others, 2015; Foley and others, 2007; Graham, Hanlon, and Sheylin, 2010; Grubert, 1998; Hasegawa and Kiyota, 2017; Hines, 1996; Hines and Rice, 1994; Slemrod, 1990). While most of these papers focus on the dividend payouts and tax planning activities of multinationals, this paper joins Grubert and Mutti (2000), Altshuler, Grubert, and Newlon (2000), Altshuler and Grubert (2003), and Hanlon, Lester, and Verdi (2015) by studying the real investment decisions of multinationals. Third, it contributes to the debate between the “old view” and the “new view” of dividend taxation by providing new evidence on the impact of dividend taxation on cross-border investment.8 Fourth and finally, this paper joins a growing literature (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013), Matheson, Perry, and Veung (2014), and IMF (2014)) that focuses on the spillover effects of fiscal policy in a global economy.

The paper proceeds as follows. The next section describes the policy reform that provides exogenous changes in the dividend taxes on UK multinationals. Section III provides a simple conceptual framework for the effect of dividend exemption on outbound multinational investment. Section IV describes the data used in empirical analysis. Section V discusses empirical strategy and specification. Section VI presents empirical findings on the effect of dividend exemption on UK investment and discusses the implications of these findings. Section VII briefly concludes.

II. The 2009 Territorial Tax Reform

The current territorial system was introduced in 2009, which exempts UK multinationals’ foreign earnings from additional taxes in the UK. Before then, the UK taxed corporate profits on a worldwide basis; repatriation from lower-taxed countries were liable to additional UK taxes. To avoid double taxation, UK multinationals can claim credits for taxes paid to the host country on foreign earnings, but only up to their UK tax liability on those earnings. For example, if a UK multinational has an investment in Ireland, it will pay Irish tax at a rate of 12.5 percent. When the Irish profits are remitted as dividends to the UK parent company, they are liable to additional taxes at 15.5 percent, which is the difference between the UK and Irish taxes.9

The total tax on foreign earnings is capped at the UK rate so that the amount of corporation taxes on foreign earnings are the same they would be if the profits were earned in the UK. Therefore, there are no additional taxes on repatriated earnings from countries with statutory tax rates higher than the UK’s. For example, foreign earnings in France pay a French tax of 35 percent and are not liable for any additional taxes upon repatriation. In general, the additional UK tax on each pound of dividend repatriation (τUK,div) is the difference between the statutory tax rate in the host country (τj) and the UK (τUK).

The additional dividend taxes place UK multinationals at a competitive disadvantage with companies in other countries that exempt foreign earnings. This consideration prompted the government to issue a discussion document in June 2007 that proposed that the UK “go terri-torial.”10 The territorial tax system was subsequently introduced in the 2009 Finance Bill and went into effect on July 1. By abolishing UK taxes on all foreign-source dividend repatriations, the reform introduced differential changes in dividend taxes depending on the location of foreign affiliates.11 Specifically, the reform reduced the tax rate on dividends remitted from low-tax countries from τUK to τj while that from high-tax countries remained unchanged:

Dividend Tax Reduction = {τUKτj,0,τjτUKτj>τUK.

The tax differential τUKτj represents the maximum amount of tax savings on a £1 dividend repatriated from a low-tax country j. This is because under the worldwide system, excess credits arising from low-tax countries (known as “eligible unrelieved foreign tax”) can be used to offset dividend taxes on earnings from high-tax countries. There were restrictions on the maximum amount of excess credits that could be used for offsetting,12 so the reduction in the dividend tax rate is between zero and the tax differential τUKτj accounting for cross-crediting.

From a practical perspective, the territorial tax reform can also affect multinational investment by reducing their tax planning costs. This is because only a small amount of revenue was collected on repatriation prior to the reform, for which there are two potential explanations: (1) Either the bulk of foreign earnings were reinvested overseas, or (2) they were brought home via sophisticated tax planning to avoid taxes. To the extent that costly tax planning can be viewed as an implicit tax on repatriation, this additional tax burden was also abolished by the territorial tax reform.

III. Conceptual Framework

I use a simple two-period model based on Bond, Devereux, and Klemm (2007) and Chetty and Saez (2010) to illustrate the effect of dividend taxation on business investment. At the beginning of period 0, a UK affiliate in the foreign country has a cash holding of C. In period 0, it invests an amount of I, which can be financed by retained earnings or by receiving new capital injection of E≥0 from the parent company. At the end of period 0, the foreign affiliate pays a dividend in the amount of D = C + E — I to its UK parent. During period 1, the foreign affiliate produces output and earns revenue with the production function f(I,E), where f(.) is strictly concave, strictly increasing, continuous, and continuously differentiable.13 At the end of period 1, the foreign affiliate returns the entire net wealth to the UK parent company by paying out a dividend. Tax rates of td0 and td1 are levied on dividend payments in periods 0 and 1, respectively.14 A tax rate of tc is levied on corporate revenue in the second period.

The foreign affiliate chooses I and E to maximize the present value of net distributions, given by:

V=(1td0)(C+E1)E+(1td1)β(1tc)f(I,E),

where β=11+r is the parent company’s discount factor, and r is the risk-free interest rate between the two periods, subject to the non-negativity constraints on dividend payments and new share issues. The first-order conditions for investment and new equity issues are:

fI=(1+r)(1tc)[1td01td1+λD1td1]

and:

fE=(1+r)(1tc)[1(1td0)(λD+λE)1td1],

where λD and λE are shadow values associated with the non-negativity constraints. There are two financial regimes in this model, which are depicted in Figure 1, under which the optimal strategy of finance depends on the level of initial cash flow C relative to firm-specific investment opportunities. Further, assume a constant td between the two periods (an assumption to be extended later), that is, td0=td1=td.

A. Regime 1: Financed by New Equity

Under this regime, new investment is financed with new share issuance. Dividend payout is zero (D = 0 so that λD > 0) and share issuance is positive (E > 0 so that λE = 0). This happens when the initial cash flow C is so low relative to investment opportunities that, if the firm issues the level of new shares set by the optimal condition, it would not be able to finance the optimal level of investment and pay positive dividends in the current period. The first-order conditions are:

fI=(1+r)(1tc)[1+λD1td],(1)

and:

fE=(1+r)(1tc)[1λD1td1].(2)

In this case, the foreign affiliate invests all the cash it has: I = C + E and finances its investment with new equity at the margin. Condition ((2)), which determines the amount of equity injection, indicates that the repatriation tax also plays a role in this decision.

Implicit differentiating of equations ((1)) and ((2)) suggests that ∂ fI/∂(1-td) < 0 and ∂ fE/∂(1-td) < 0. Under this regime, a reduction in td implies a lower marginal cost of investment, and a higher level of investment. A lower td also implies a lower marginal cost of issuing new shares, which increases the amount of new shares (with fI,E > 0). The firm is considered financially constrained in this regime because a windfall increase in its cash flow would reduce the shadow value of internal funds λD, which leads to an increase in both its new share issues and investment.

These results are similar to those of the standard “old view” models where marginal investments are financed by funds from outside investors. Proceeds from these investments are returned to investors and subject to dividend tax rates (Poterba and Summers, 1984). A higher dividend tax rate raises the effective tax rate on investment income and discourages investment, with potentially adverse welfare consequences. Conversely, a reduction in the dividend tax, as in the case of the 2009 reform, would potentially encourage investment by UK multinationals in low-tax countries.

B. Regime 2: Financed by Retained Earnings

In the second regime, the initial cash flow C is sufficiently high relative to investment opportunities. New investment is financed with retained earnings, implying that D > 0 so that λD = 0, and E = 0 so that λE > 0. The first-order condition ((1)) now becomes:

fI=(1+r)(1tc),(3)

where the cost of capital and optimal level of investment no longer depend on td. The intuition is that, with a constant td, a dividend tax lowers both the cost of investment and return on the investment by the same amount, and therefore has no effect on the cost of capital. This result reproduces the “new view” or the “trapped equity” view of dividend taxation (Auerbach, 1979; Hartman, 1985; King, 1974), which predicts that investment using mature capital does not depend on the dividend tax.

Comparing equations ((1)) and ((3)) confirms the standard pecking order in which external finance is no less expensive than internal finance. In the context of cross-border investment, the result implies that UK multinationals should first finance their investments by exhausting their internal funds before turning to new capital injections from multinational groups. It is more tax efficient for the foreign affiliate to retain the initial earnings to avoid a tax on dividend repatriation.

C. Anticipation Effect of Changes in Dividend Taxes

The results in Regime 2 hinge on the assumption of a constant dividend tax. The irrelevance result of dividend taxation for internal-funded investment no longer holds when there is temporary change in the tax rate or any expectation of such changes.

Suppose that the foreign affiliate anticipates in period 0 that the rate of dividend tax will decrease in the next period (td0>td1). In this case, the first-order condition that determines the optimal level of investment for firms in Regime 2 becomes:

fI=(1td01td1)(1+r1tc).(4)

Equation ((4)) shows that a higher dividend tax in period 0 (relative to the next period) reduces the marginal cost of investment in period 0 to below 1+r1+tc for firms relying on retained earnings. Consequently, the optimal investment level in period 0 would be higher than that determined by equation ((3)), even for a new investment financed with retained earnings.

The intuition is straightforward. Anticipating a reduction in the dividend tax makes postponing dividend payouts to period 1 more attractive. Instead, the firm should invest all the retained earnings in period 0. In the context of the territorial tax reform, the implication is that UK multinationals would increase their investments in the years immediately preceding the reform, postponing repatriating dividends until afterwards. The following sections set out to test these predictions by empirically examining the responsiveness of investments by UK multinationals to the introduction of the dividend exemption regime in 2009.

IV. Data

The primary dataset for empirical analysis consists of an unbalanced panel of 131,614 multinational affiliates in EU-27 countries between 2005 and 2011. It is based on the unconsoli-dated financial statements of multinational subsidiaries in the commercial AMADEUS database, which is provided by Bureau van Dijk.15 A company is defined as a multinational subsidiary if it has an ultimate parent company owning at least 50 percent of its shares and is in a country different from its parent. The ultimate parent companies are from 158 countries in the dataset.

The main sample excludes companies with missing/zero turnover or total assets, and financial companies whose main productive assets typically are not tangible capital. The main sample also excludes observations with missing industry or unspecified home country information. Table 2 shows the geographical distribution of multinational affiliates in the main sample.

The main accounting variables are flows of investment, sales, cash flow, and earnings before interest and tax (EBIT).16 Investment spending (It) is computed as changes in fixed capital assets based on the net book values of tangible and intangible fixed assets plus depreciation, i.e. Kt — Kt-1 + depreciation, where Kt denotes book value of the fixed asset in year t. Gross investment rate, Investmentt, is defined as the ratio between current-year gross investment spending and beginning-of-year net fixed capital asset. Similarly, net investment rate, Investment_Nett, is defined as the ratio between current-year net investment spending and beginning-of-year net fixed capital asset. Sales refers to operating revenue. Profit margin is calculated as earnings before interest and tax (EBIT) divided by sales. All ratio variables are winsorized at top and bottom 1 percentile to minimize the influence of outliers.

A limitation of the AMADEUS data is that information on the ownership structure refers to the latest report year, which is 2011 for most observations in the sample. I assume that the same parent-affiliate ownership structure applies to earlier years. If there are changes of ownership structure over the sample period, there may be potential mis-classifications of parent-subsidiary connections, introducing attenuation bias against findings of significant policy effects.17 Consider that the UK’s moving to an exemption system increases the competitiveness of UK parent companies in the international market. As a result, they acquire more foreign subsidiaries in low-tax jurisdictions.18 By including these newly acquired subsidiaries in the analysis, the estimation results would capture the overall investment response to dividend exemption by allowing for endogenous investment changes in the extensive margin via mergers and acquisitions.

I merge data for the statutory corporate tax rate at the affiliate location provided by the Oxford Centre for Business Taxation Tax Database.19 This is a measure of total statutory tax rates, including top corporate tax rate at the federal level, any surcharge levied, and any local corporate tax rates in a given country-year. Subsidiaries in the main sample face statutory corporate tax rates that range from 0.10 to 0.404 with a mean of 0.285.

To identify the set of low-tax countries, I define an indicator variable low tax which takes the value 1 if a country’s corporate tax rate is below the UK’s corporate tax rates in both 2005 and 2011, and 0 otherwise. Table 1 lists the low-tax and high-tax countries and their tax rates. I further merge data on GDP per capita, population, and unemployment rate to capture the aggregate market size and demand characteristics in the host country, as well as measures of governance quality and financial stability to capture the quality of the institution in the host country. Home-country characteristics, including growth rate of GDP per capita, population, and the unemployment rate, are also included to capture macroeconomic conditions in the parent country.20 Table 3 presents the descriptive statistics of the key variables that are used in regression analysis.

V. Empirical Strategy

By exempting taxes on foreign earnings, the 2009 territorial tax reform reduced the effective tax rate on dividends repatriation and the cost of capital on new investment in many low-tax countries. Identification builds upon the idea that only UK affiliates benefited from this reform, while the investment decisions of non-UK multinationals should not be affected by a UK-specific reform. This differential impact permits a within-year comparison of investments between UK and non-UK affiliates in the same host country. Formally, I examine the effect of investment by UK affiliates in the standard difference-in-difference (DD) specification:

INVESTMENTikt=ai+dt+βxXikt+βzZkt+ϵikt,(5)

where i indexes firms, k indexes host country, and t indexes time. The dependent variable INVESTMENTikt denotes gross investment in fixed capital asset scaled by book value of fixed asset in (end of) year t — 1. The main variable of interest, DEit, is an indicator equal to 1 for UK affiliates starting from 2009, and zero otherwise. The coefficient βDE represents the DD estimate of the effect of dividend exemption on investment by UK affiliates. Based on the theoretical discussions in Section III, βDE should be positive and significant if a non-trivial fraction of new investment by UK affiliates is financed with new equity.

A full set of firm fixed effects (ai) is included to control for the unobserved firm-specific productivity differences and unobserved time-invariant characteristics of the parent company. Firm fixed effects further subsume host-country fixed effects (given that affiliates do not change their location), which control for time-invariant differences across host countries that may affect multinationals’ location choices. These may include, for example, perceived average quality of governance during the sample period, common language and/or former colonial ties, and geographical distance between the home and host country. I include a full set of time dummies (dt) to capture the effects of aggregate macroeconomic shocks, including the effects of the great recession, that are common to all multinational affiliates in each year. xikt denotes a possible empty vector of firm-level controls, and εikt is the error term.

Most specifications include the statutory corporate tax rates at source to control for the potential confounding effects of concurrent tax reforms in host countries. The most comprehensive specification includes a full set of industry-by-year interactions and country-by-year interactions to control for industry- and country-specific macro-economic shocks to private investment, which would otherwise be captured by the DD estimates. While these controls help address differences between UK and non-UK affiliates, they may not fully capture how affiliates with parents in different countries handle time-varying macro shocks. In this aspect it is also important to control for a set of the parent countries’ time-varying characteristics (zkt), including growth rate of GDP per capita, population size, and unemployment rate.21

As shown in Table A.1 Panel A, there are fewer affiliates in the treated group, but they are significantly larger than the non-UK affiliates in the control group. The UK affiliates in the treated group are also more liquid and profitable. I employ two alternative approaches to address the concern that UK and non-UK affiliates may not have identical observable characteristics, and that these differences may explain the different trends in their investment over time. First, I control directly for a set of non-tax variables that should capture firm-specific investment opportunities (xikt), which include lagged output, cash flow scaled by lagged asset, lagged profit margin as a measure of profitability, and one-period lagged growth rate of output. By including these variable, the DD estimate captures the impact of the tax reform independent of these non-tax determinants of investment. Alternatively, I implement a matching DD strategy by replicating the DD tests on a subsample of matched firms based on their pre-reform characteristics (Heckman, Ichimura, and Todd, 1997). The treated and control groups in the matched sample are comparable in firm size and cash flow (Table A.1, Panel B).

(a) Key Identifying Assumption The policy variation is at the parent-country-by-year level, so the key identifying assumption is that the UK’s tax reform is independent of other UK-specific shocks.22 I present empirical evidence to validate this assumption in three aspects. First, using data on gross fixed capital formation in the private sector, Figure 2 shows that domestic private investment trended very similarly in the major economies in EU27 during the sample period. For example, total private investment in the UK exhibited a similar pattern to France’s over the entire period of 2005-2012. The pattern of total private investment in the UK was also very similar to that of Germany around the years of the great financial crisis between 2008-2012. Moreover, there are very similar trends between private investment in the UK and the GDP-weighted average private investment in the rest of EU-27 countries (Figure 2 Panel B). The lack of evidence on differential trends in domestic investments highlights that, at the aggregate level, the financial crisis affected UK multinationals and non-UK multinationals similarly. Otherwise, we would expect any differential investment trend by UK multinationals in the low-tax countries also to appear in the high-tax countries and in domestic investment. Given that the definition of a low-tax country is based on the corporate tax rate in the UK, there is no reason to expect systematic changes in investments by UK multinationals in these countries other than the implementation of the territorial tax reform.

Second, I examine any differences in investment trends at the affiliate level in each of the years before the legislation, both graphically in Figure 3 (in the next section), and in placebo tests. Specifically, I test whether investments by UK affiliates increased in 2007 or 2008 prior to the tax reform in the low-tax countries, by replacing the DEit variable with an interaction term between a post 2007/2008 dummy indicator and an indicator for a UK affiliate, respectively. Figure 5 summarizes the coefficient estimates of the interaction terms. None of the coefficient estimates are significantly different from zero, except the one for the DEit variable. Columns 1 to 3 of Table 4 confirm that there were no significant differential increases for the treated group in low-tax countries in any year before the reform, a conclusion reached by replacing the DEit variable with an interaction term between a year 2006/2007/2008 dummy indicator and an indicator for UK affiliates. The earlier years provide placebo tests by demonstrating parallel trends. Third, because the tax reform did not change the incentive to use debt financing in the low-tax countries, Column 4 uses firms’ leverage ratio as an alternative placebo test. Column 4 reports an insignificant DEit coefficient estimate, suggesting that we cannot distinguish the response of leverage from zero. Thus, the key identification assumption passes this alternative placebo test.

VI. The Effect of Dividend Exemption on Multinational Investment

A. Graphical Evidence

Following discussions in the previous section, Figure 3 shows the average investment by UK and non-UK affiliates around the dividend exemption reform in the low-tax countries (Panel A), and in the high-tax countries (Panel B). There are some distinct patterns in the two panels. In the low tax countries, the reduction in real investments (relative to its 2006 level) of UK affiliates closely tracked that of non-UK affiliates up to 2009. Both group started to increase their investments after the financial crisis, where there was a greater increase in investments by UK affiliates. This differential increase could potentially be attributed to the territoriality reform. While the investments of UK affiliates have decreased more than those of non-UK affiliates since 2006 in the high-tax countries, changes in investment were quite similar in the years prior to 2009. The investment gap widened in 2009 and diminished within two years because of rapid increases in investment made by UK affiliates in high-tax countries.

There are at least two threats to identification. The first is that contemporaneous change unrelated to the tax reform, which could have differential impact on UK and non-UK affiliates. For example, UK affiliates might be more resilient to the financial crisis compared to their non-UK peers, which could explain the smaller declines in their investments. This highlights the importance of controlling for time-invariant affiliates and parent company characteristics in the regressions, as well as time-varying industry trends that absorb the differential impact of the financial crisis across industries. Second, concurrent tax reforms in other countries are likely to confound the effect of dividend exemption, which is of primary interest in this paper. For example, Japan also switched to territorial taxation in 2009. Given that Japan had a statutory corporate tax rate of 38 percent, the outbound investment of Japanese multinationals may also have increased afterwards, resulting in a downward bias in the estimated effect of dividend exemption for UK companies. This consideration highlights the importance of focusing on non-UK affiliates with headquarters in countries with exemption systems.

To summarize, Figure 3 provides visual evidence of the effect of dividend exemption on UK outbound investment. The following sections use regression analysis to control for a large set of potential confounding factors, and provide conclusive evidence of a link between dividend taxation and outbound investment by UK multinationals in the low-tax countries.

B. Baseline results

Table 5 presents regression results from the difference-in-difference estimation of equation ((5)), focusing on multinational affiliates operating in the low-tax EU-27 countries. All regressions include a full set of firm fixed effects and year fixed effects, with heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors clustered at the firm level.

The first column reports a positive and highly significant coefficient estimate for DEit , suggesting that dividend exemption has systematically increased investment by UK affiliates in low-tax countries. The empirical evidence is consistent with the theoretical prediction when a substantial fraction of new UK outbound investment is financed with new equity. To assess the robustness of this finding, the second column adds controls that capture firm-specific investment opportunities, including one-period lagged turnover, cash flow scaled by lagged asset, lagged profit margin, and growth rate of lagged turnover. To control for the difference in the sectoral composition of UK affiliates, which may be subject to different macroeco-nomic shocks, the third column adds industry by time fixed effects to control for time-varying shocks across industries at the one-digit NACE level. The basic result remains unchanged.

Column 4 includes the host-country’s statutory tax rate on corporate income to control for the potential confounding effects of concurrent tax reforms on business investment. Column 4 also adds GDP per capita, population size, unemployment rate, and indicators of governance quality and financial institution stability in the host country in order to control for the impact of local market conditions that would otherwise be captured by the DEit coefficient estimate. To assess the robustness of the results to differential country-specific shocks, Column 5 adds a full set of host-country by year interactions to control for country-specific factors that may affect private investment across host countries. The empirical estimates do not appear to be sensitive to the inclusion of this rich set of control variables.

While time-invariant parent company characteristics and time-invariant home country characteristics are already controlled for through the inclusion of affiliate fixed effects, it is still possible that UK affiliates were exposed to different shocks at home. To address this concern Column 6 adds additional time-variant GDP growth rates, GDP per capita and employment rate in the home countries. The baseline results remain unchanged. Column 7 interacts the DEit variable with the reduction in rate of dividend tax to capture the magnitude of the tax reform. The finding suggests that for every one percentage point decrease in the dividend tax rate, there is a 1.59 percentage point increase in real investment per euro of fixed assets by UK affiliates in low-tax countries. Column (8) restricts firms in the treated group to being part of a UK multinational group with at least one affiliate in the high-tax countries. The estimated effect of the tax reform slightly increases in this subsample, but the difference is not statistically significant. Finally, column (9) interacts the discrete policy variable with a tax differential variable that equals to the statutory corporate tax rate difference between the host country and the UK. Note that the tax differential variable represents the maximum reduction in the dividend tax due to cross-crediting and other planning activities. The estimated tax effect is positive and highly significant, confirming the positive effect of the tax reform on investment by UK multinationals in the low-tax countries.

C. Robustness

This section assesses whether the findings are robust to a number of alternative specifications and samples. Table 6 summarizes the results. First, Column 1 clusters the standard errors by host-home country pair. This is to address the concern that in tax reform studies, the standard errors are understated by assuming independence across firms within the same tax jurisdiction (Bertrand, Duflo, and Mullainathan, 2004). Column 2 excludes non-UK affiliates with parent countries featuring worldwide taxation. To the extent that investment decisions by these firms may be influenced by tax planning consideration under the worldwide system, they may be less comparable to those under the exemption system. Column 3 controls for the potential confounding effect of the eurozone crisis by including an interaction term between an indicator that takes value of 1 for host countries in the eurozone and the post-2009 indicator. Therefore the DEit estimate in Column 3 identifies the impact of the 2009 reform independent of the exchange rate crisis. To ensure that the identified tax effect is not entirely driven by firm entries and exits, Column 4 uses a balanced sample of firms that were established before 2005 and survived through 2010. The resulting DEit coefficient estimates from the four regressions are statistically indistinguishable from the preferred estimate in Table 5 Column 6.23

Column 5 implements a matching DD strategy (Heckman, Ichimura, and Todd (1997)) to address the concern that companies in the treated UK and control affiliates may not have similar observable characteristics, and that these differences may explain different trends in investment over time. The regression in Column 5 replicates the DD analysis on a subsample of matched firms from a Mahalanobis distance matching procedure based on pre-reform firm-level turnover, turnover growth, employment, and operating profits. The matching DD analysis further controls time-varying industry shocks and host-country macroeconomic conditions. The resulting estimate has a wider confidence interval due to fewer observations, but nevertheless, remains positive and significant at the 10 percent level. To address the concern that multinationals from smaller countries like Latvia or Cyprus may be differentially affected by the economic uncertainty around 2009, Column 6 uses only affiliates from the ten largest EU27 countries as the control group.24 The findings remain very similar to those based on the full sample.

Finally, to ensure that the identified tax effect is not driven by any outliers in the outcome variables, Column 7 in the upper panel uses a gross investment rate winsorized at 97.5th per-centile as the dependent variable, while Columns 1 and 2 in the lower panel use net investment rates winsorized at 99th and 97.5th percentiles as dependent variables, respectively. The estimated effect of the tax reform remains positive and significant, although the magnitude of the estimate is reduced by half. However, it is not significantly different from the preferred estimate in Table 5 Column 6.

To further address the concern that UK and non-UK affiliates might be subject to different shocks during the sample period, I use a a triple-difference specification that extends equation ((5)) by pooling observations from both low- and high-tax countries and adding main effects and interaction terms for UK affiliates in the low-tax countries. Even if UK and non-UK affiliates were affected differentially around the reform period, the triple-difference approach would control for these omitted variables in the low-tax countries by differencing out average changes in investment between the treated and control group in the high-tax countries. In particular, I estimate the following equation:

INVESTMENTikt=ai+dt+βDE,LowDEit×LowTaxk+βUK,postUKi×Postt+βPost,LowPostt×LowTaxk+βxXikt+βzZkt+ϵikt.(7)

Note that this model contains a full set of firm and year fixed effects and that the interaction effect of UKi and Lowk is subsumed in the firm fixed effect (given that the AMADEUS data does not track relocation of affiliates over time). Table 7 presents the regression results, where each column follows the same specification as in Table 5, and reports very similar results for the main variable of interest. In the most demanding specification in Column 6 of Table 7, the coefficient for the three-way interaction term remains positive and significant at the 10 percent level. The estimated post-reform investment increase by UK affiliates in the low-tax countries is more than 11 percentage points higher than for the average non-UK affiliate.

D. Heterogeneity Analysis

I use several proxies for ex ante financial constraints including firm size, liquid asset position, and profitability, to test for differences in investment responses between constrained and unconstrained firms. If the method of financing represents an important consideration for UK affiliates as suggested in Section III, we should expect to find consistent, systematic differences in investment responses for groups of firms based on these proxies. The proxies are defined based on pre-2009 firm-level average characteristics, excluding firms that recently entered or did not survive through 2010. I divide firms in the main sample into deciles (for each indicator), and estimate the effect of the tax reform by interacting the DEit with the decile indicators:

INVESTMENTikt=ai+dt+Σj=110βDE,DecilejDEit×I{iϵDecilej}+βxXikt+βzZkt+ϵikt,(8)

where I{i ∊ Decilej} is the jth decile indicator defined above, and all other variables are as previously defined. The coefficient BDE,Decilej represents the quantity of interest: the effect of the 2009 dividends exemption on investment by UK affiliates relative to non-UK affiliates in the jth decile of the relevant financial constraints indicator.

Panel A of Figure 4 reports the coefficient estimates βDE and the 90 percent confidence interval across firm sizes. It shows that only medium-to-large UK affiliates in the upper deciles of the turnover distribution significantly increased their investments in response to the 2009 reform. Interestingly, investment did not increase for firms with the largest turnover, i.e. those in the top decile of turnover distribution. This is most likely because these firms are financially unconstrained. Panel B shows a similar pattern in investment across total assets. Panel C reports the results based on the distribution of free cash flow. The evidence shows a higher sensitivity of investment in the cash-poor sample. The investment increase is predominately concentrated in the 2nd-7th deciles of cash flow distribution. In contrast, there is no significant increase in investment by firms in the lowest cash-flow decile, possibly because these are poorly-performing firms.25

Figure 4 Panel D shows that investment increase is mainly concentrated in the 4th-8th deciles of firm profitability.26 The results suggest that firms with extremely low profitability did not increase their investments in response to the tax reform, neither did extremely profitable firms which are more likely to rely on retained earnings to finance their investments.

Theoretical consideration in Section III suggests that increases in investment by UK affiliates should be mainly due to new capital. Evidence consistent with this hypothesis would be more prominent investment responses in larger, more liquid company groups.27 Panel E reports the results across the distribution of company group sizes (the number of related companies in the same company group), and the results suggest higher investment sensitivity in larger multinational groups. Finally, Panel F reports the results based on the distribution of company group assets. The measure is constructed by summing up the total assets of all affiliates with the same parent company in the main sample.28 The results are roughly consistent. There is higher sensitivity of investment in large MNCs measured by total asset of company group.

E. Timing of the Investment Responses

The exemption system was formally introduced in the Financial Bill in April, 2009 and became effective on July 1.29 Despite this narrow three-month window between the announcement and implementation of the exemption system, in 2008, UK companies may nevertheless have anticipated the coming reduction in dividend taxation. The impact of anticipation on investment would again depend on the source of finance. If new investment is financed out of new equity, a forward-looking UK affiliate would delay its investment until after the implementation of the policy. In this case, there would be a temporary reduction in investment by UK affiliates in 2008, followed by an overshoot in 2009 in low-tax countries .

For internal-financed investment, equation ((4)) shows that the cost of capital becomes cheaper in 2008 given a forthcoming reduction in the tax rate. A forward-looking UK affiliate would increase its investment in low-tax countries prior to the tax reform, resulting in a downward bias in the DD estimate. To identify the effect of anticipation on investment, equation ((5)) adds an interaction term between a Year2008 dummy and an indicator for UK affiliates:

INVESTMENTikt=ai+di+β2008Year2008t.UKMNCi+β1DEit+βxXikt+βzZkt+ϵikt,

where all other variables are as previously defined. The β2008 coefficient captures any differential change in investment by UK affiliates in 2008, relative to the 2006 base-year level.

Table 8 summarizes the results in low-tax countries. The dependent variable in the first three columns is gross investment. Column 1 includes only firm fixed effects and year fixed effects, while Column 2 follows the most comprehensive specification by including additional controls at firm, host country and home country levels. In both columns the coefficient estimate of β2008 is statistically indistinguishable from zero, suggesting the lack of strategic investment responses by UK affiliates prior to the tax reform.30

To examine how quickly investment in low-tax countries reacted to dividend exemption, Column 3 adds two interaction terms between a post-2010/2011 year dummy and an indicator for UK affiliates, respectively. Each coefficient would capture the differential change between investment by UK and non-UK affiliates following the corresponding year, conditioned on any changes that already occurred in 2009. The estimate coefficient of DEit remains positive and highly significant, while the DD coefficient in 2010 is also positive and significant at the 10 percent level. The results suggest that UK affiliates respond to dividend exemption by immediately increasing current investment in low-tax countries. This is plausible given that the tax reform has been well trailed, so firms are ready to respond after the introduction of dividend exemption. Columns 4 to 6 repeat the analysis using net investment as the dependent variable, and the results remain qualitatively similar.

F. The Effect of Dividend Exemption on Other Outcomes

According to the discussions in Section III, new equity should be the major source of finance for new investment following the dividend tax cut. Therefore a higher level of new equity issued to UK affiliates would be consistent with the observed investment increases in low-tax countries. To obtain a rough estimate of the amount of new equity at the affiliate level, I first impute the amount of paid-in capital as the difference between shareholder funds and aftertax profit, as there is no data available on the amount of new equity. This is a very noisy measure of paid-in capital, as it also includes other accumulated comprehensive income or loss as part of the shareholders’ fund. The amount of new equity is therefore computed as changes in the paid-capital between two consecutive years. To reduce the amount of measurement errors in this variable, I construct a dummy indicator that takes value of 1 if the imputed new equity is positive, and zero otherwise. I then run a binary discrete choice model of the following form:

NewEquityit=ai+di+βDEDEit+βDE,CashpoorDEit×I{iϵCashPoor}+βxXikt+βzZkt+ϵikt,(9)

where NewEquityit represents the binary variable of receiving new equity, I{iCash Poor} is an indicator that takes the value of 1 for all subsidiaries in the 2nd-7th deciles of the cash flow distribution, and all other variables are as previously defined. I{iCash Poor} is constructed this way as investment increases are concentrated in the subsample of UK affiliates in the 2nd-7th deciles of the cash flow distribution in Section VI VI.D. Bearing in mind the above data caveats as possible limitations, regression results from a fixed-effect linear probability model suggest that the tax reform significantly increases the probability of getting additional paid-in capital for the cash-poor UK affiliates by around 6 percentage points (β^DE,Cashpoor=0.060witharobuststandarderrorof0.036) On the other hand, there is no significant change in the probability of obtaining new equity for the cash-rich UK affiliates (β^DE,Cashrish=0.024withastandarderrorof0.028).

Columns 3 to 6 in Panel B of Table 6 examine the effect of dividend exemption on firm-level wage rate, employment, labor productivity, and profitability in low-tax countries. Wage rate is the only variable that shows a significant change in the tax reform, conditioned on investment increase. As there are no significant changes in the variables measuring labor productivity or profitability; the increase in affiliate wages can be interpreted as evidence on international rent sharing of the increase in the after-tax profits of the multinational group following the tax reform (see, for example, Budd, Konings, and Slaughter (2005)).

G. Reallocation or Increase in Total Investment?

The increase in investment by UK affiliates in low-tax countries could represent an increase in total investment by UK multinationals due to a lower cost of capital. Alternatively, it may reflect a reallocation of investment from high-tax countries to low-tax countries, thus having no impact on aggregate investment. This concern is particularly relevant around the time of the great recession, when many companies are resource-constrained with limited investment capacity. Another consideration is that if UK multinationals used high-tax affiliates to lower taxes on repatriation, the territorial tax reform may have also lowered the value of high-tax investment, which facilitates such tax planning. To test these two competing hypothesis, I analyze investment by UK multinationals in the high-tax countries, as well as in the UK.

(a) Investment Responses in High-Tax Countries Table 9 presents the DD estimation re sults based on equation ((5)), focusing on multinational affiliates in the high-tax EU-27 countries. Each column follows the same specification as in Table 5, with heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors clustered at the firm level.

Column 1 shows that the territorial tax reform has a somewhat negative effect on UK affiliates’ investments in high-tax countries, which may suggest the presence of strategic investment in these countries to benefit from cross-crediting. However the size of the coefficient estimate is much smaller and statistically insignificant after controlling for other non-tax firm-level determinants of investment in Column 2. It remains insignificant throughout Columns 3 to 7, which control for additional industry, and host and home country characteristics, and in Column 8, which excludes affiliates with parents under the worldwide tax system. While the negative sign of the DD estimate is consistent with lower values of investment in high-tax countries that may facilitate tax planning prior to the reform, the regressions fail to find any significant responses of investment by UK multinationals in high-tax countries. Table A.2 in the Appendix presents the estimated effects of the tax reform on other outcome variables in high-tax countries. There is no significant change in compensation, employment, labor productivity or firm-level profitability in high-tax countries. Interestingly, total leverage of UK affiliates in high-tax countries is found to be significantly higher after the tax reform. This finding is consistent with the fact that the tax incentives for profit shifting, including debt shifting to high-tax countries, is larger under the territorial system.

(b) Investment Responses in the UK To analyze the investment responses of UK-owned affiliates at home, I use a similar DD strategy with two alternative control groups: (1) non-UK multinational affiliates operating in the UK, and (2) UK affiliates that are part of a domestic company group.31 Table 10 summarizes the regression results with non-UK multinational affiliates as the control group in Panel A, and with domestic firms as the control group in Panel B.32 Columns 1 to 4 each use the same specification as that in Table 5, while Columns 5 and 6 focus on identifying anticipation effects in 2008. In Panel A, the coefficient estimate of DEit is mostly negative and insignificant, suggesting that there are no differential investment responses by UK-owned affiliates relative to non-UK foreign affiliates. In Panel B, the coefficient estimate of DEit is statistically insignificant across all specifications, suggesting that there is no differential investment response by UK-owned affiliates relative to affiliates of domestic company groups. Regression results in both panels are essentially “no effects”, given that the coefficient estimate of the policy variable is associated with large standard errors.

Conceptually, there is no particular reason to expect investment changes at home, given that the tax reform did not change the after-tax rate of return in the UK. This finding is consistent with Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011), which analyzes the responses of U.S. multinationals following a one-time tax holiday for the repatriation of foreign earnings introduced in the Homeland Investment Act of 2004. Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011) find that very few firms benefited from the holiday by increasing their domestic investments, employment, or R&D investments. Instead, these firms primarily responded by returning funds to share-holders.33 To reconcile with Egger and others (2015), which finds that the territorial system induced UK affiliates to pay out significantly more dividends immediately after the reform, the lack of investment response at home may suggest that repatriations were used to pay off debts or were returned to shareholders. Unfortunately, further investigation on the impact of dividend exemption on UK multinational groups requires additional data from a consolidated financial statement at the company group level. I leave this exercise to further research.

H. Discussions

(a) Relabeling or real investment responses? There may be concern that changes by multinationals in reported investment due to taxes is likely to be shifting rather than real behavior. This can be a common perception, but is a questionable one and deserves some clarification. First, this analysis focuses on the affiliates of large multinational companies. Unlike small owner-managed businesses, it is highly unlikely for multinational affiliates to relabel personal expenses as capital expenditures. Second, there is no tax incentive to engage in relabeling other expenses as capital expenditure. Doing so implies changing from expensing to accelerated depreciation, which is less tax advantageous in lowering the total tax bill.

In general, common strategies used by multinationals to shift their profits are debt shifting, licensing and royalty payment, and transfer mispricing. None of these activities are captured in capital investment. In fact, while the observed pattern in investment (an increase in low-tax countries and no significant response in high-tax countries) is consistent with changing incentives in investment from the worldwide to the territorial system, the observed pattern in total leverage (no significant responses in the low-tax countries and significant increases in the high-tax countries) is also consistent with increased tax incentives for profit shifting under the territorial system.

(b) Quantitative impact To gauge the quantitative impact of the 2009 reform on outbound investment of UK multinationals in low-tax countries, I calculate the increase in investment at the firm and country levels. First, the pre-reform average fixed asset for the UK affiliates across low-tax countries is around €16.31 million. Given a DD coefficient estimate of 0.157, it implies that the average investment increase in the UK affiliates is around €0.82 million (in real 2006 terms). Second, I estimate the increase in aggregate investment by summing up investment increases across all UK affiliates in each country.34 Figure 6 shows the increase in investment across host countries. In aggregate, the predicted investment increase is around €5.6 billion (in real 2006 terms) in the low-tax countries, where Ireland, the Czech Republic, and Poland benefit the most from additional foreign direct investments resulting from the UK’s tax reform. The aggregate investment increase in low-tax countries is approximately 9 times the amount of estimated foregone tax revenue, suggesting that the tax reform has had a strong bang for the buck effect by stimulating £9 of foreign investment by UK multinationals in the low-tax countries for every £1 loss in tax revenue at home.35

VII. Conclusion

In this paper I analyze the causal effect of territorial taxation on the outward direct investment of multinationals in a quasi-experimental setting. The 2009 reform switched the UK from a worldwide to a territorial tax system and, as such, lowered effective tax rates on repatriated earnings from countries with tax rates lower than the UK’s corporate tax rate.

The findings provide robust evidence that the taxation of foreign earnings in the home country has a strong effect on the level and location of foreign investment. On average, outbound investment by UK multinationals increased by 15.7 percent in reaction to the territorial reform that reduced taxes by 9 percentage points. The results shed light on the debate regarding whether the United States should implement the territorial tax system by showing that in UK, there is no evidence that the investment increase in low-tax countries leads to the reallocation of foreign direct investment from high-tax countries, or results in any significant investment distortion or loss at home. The evidence is suggestive in nature, as the estimated effect of the reform is associated with sizable standard errors. Theoretically, we may also expect investment to decrease in high-tax countries following the reform, as taxes on investment in these countries can no longer be offset against those from low-tax countries. However, unless UK or US multinationals are financially constrained as a group, any investment reduction in the domestic market is unlikely (see, for example, Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011))

The findings that UK multinationals increased their investments in countries with lower corporation taxes bears further implications for tax policy design in small capital-importing countries. In particular, the UK multinationals’ immediate investment responses after the reform suggest that the trend to shift from worldwide to territorial taxation in major capital-exporting countries may put downward pressure on corporate tax rates in small countries that compete with each other to attract inward foreign direct investment. Consistent with these findings, Matheson, Perry, and Veung (2014) also report that the bilateral UK FDI financed from new equity has become more sensitive to a host-country’s statutory tax rate following the UK’s move to territoriality.

Corporate investment is not the only behavioral margin through which UK multinationals respond to territorial taxation. By exempting foreign-source income from taxation at home, the reform may cost considerable revenue by encouraging profit shifting to abroad. If this is the case, it is important to consider proper anti-avoidance measures to protect the tax base at home. Preliminary findings from the current analysis suggest that the territorial reform did not lead to systematic changes in the reported profitability of UK affiliates abroad. The average response may mask the important heterogeneity of behavioral responses at the firm level, and there are a number of alternative channels for multinationals to shift profit.36 Further analysis of the impact of territorial taxation on the extent of base erosion and profit shifting, together with a more comprehensive welfare analysis of the territorial reform, are forthcoming in future research.

VIII. Figures

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

The Effects of Dividend Tax Cuts in Two Financial Regimes

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Common Trends in Aggregate Investment

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Notes: Panel A plots the gross fixed capital formation (as a share of GDP), which proxies for total private investment at the national levels, for Germany, France, and the UK, from 2006-2012. Panel B compares the gross fixed capital formation (as a share of GDP) in the UK, and the GDP-weighted average in non-UK EU27 countries, from 2006-2012.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Graphical Evidence

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Notes: Panel A plots the average investment rate during 2006-2011 (relative to the 2006 investment level) for UK and non-UK multinational affiliates in the low-tax countries. Panel B plots the average investment rate during 2006-2011 (relative to the 2006 investment level) for UK affiliates and non-UK affiliates in the high-tax countries. The solid vertical line depicts the reform year when territorial tax system was enacted, and the dashed vertical line depicts the year the policy reform was announced.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Heterogeneous Investment Responses in Low-Tax Countries

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Notes: This figure reports regression results by dividing the main sample into deciles of ex ante financial constraint indicators based on firm size, total assets, cash flow (as a fraction of lagged fixed asset), and profitability. The DD regressions include ten interaction terms between the DEt and each of the ten decile dummy indicators. All other variables are as previously defined. Each panel reports the ten coefficient estimates βDE,Decilej and the corresponding 90th confidence interval.
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Investment Responses in Low-Tax Countries: Timing

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Notes: This figure reports the regression results from varying the paper’s main investment regression specification (underlying Table 5, Column 6) in order to conduct placebo tests. For each year y between 2007 and 2009, the figure reports the coefficient estimate for the interaction term between a post-year-y indicator and an indicator that takes the value of 1 for UK-owned affiliates, and the corresponding 95th confidence interval.
Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Predicted Investment Increases in Low-Tax Countries

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Notes: This figure reports the predicted investment increase in the low-tax countries, using the coefficient estimates in Table 3, Column 7, and the actual decrease in dividend tax in each country following the UK’s change from the worldwide to the territorial tax system.

IX. Tables

Table 1.

Low-and High-Tax Countries in EU27

article image
Notes: Low-tax countries refer to those with corporate tax rates lower than the UK tax rate in both 2005 and 2011, and high-tax countries refer to the rest of the EU-27 countries.
Table 2.

Country Statistics

article image
Notes: The country in each row refers to the host country where the multinational affiliate is located. The country/region in each column refers to the home country/region where the ultimate parent of the multinational affiliate is located.
Table 3.

Descriptive Statistics

article image
Notes: Unconsolidated values, in thousand Euros, current prices. All ratios winsohzed at top and bottom 1 percentile. Country-level controls from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators 2009. Country-level corporate tax rates collected from Oxford CBT Tax Database.
Table 4.

Placebo Tests of Pre-Reform Differential Trends

article image
Notes: This table reports results of placebo tests in the low-tax EU-27 countries. The DEit variable is the interaction between a UK affiliate indicator (UKi) and an indicator for the year being 2009 onwards. The indicators Year2006,tYear2008,t each take the value of one in the respective year, and zero otherwise. Investment is gross investment scaled by book value of fixed capital asset in (end of) previous year. Leverage ratio is long-term debt relative to total asset. All firm-level ratio variables are winsorized at the top and bottom 1 percentile to remove the influence of outliers. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are clustered at firm level. ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 5.

Investment Response in Low-Tax Countries: Baseline Results

article image
Notes: This table reports difference-in-difference estimates of the effect of the 2009 dividends exemption on investment by UK affiliates in EU-27 countries that tax corporate profit at a lower rate than the UK. All columns display the coefficient on the DEit variable, which is the interaction between a UK affiliate indicator and an indicator for the year being 2009 onwards, from a regression of investment on this interaction, affiliate fixed effects, year fixed effects and additional controls. Investment is gross investment scaled by book value of fixed capital asset in (end of) previous year. “Affiliate-Level controls” indicates that the regression includes lagged turnover, lagged turnover growth rate, cash flow scaled by lagged asset, and lagged profit margin. All firm-level ratio variables are winsorized at top and bottom 1 percentile to remove the influence of outliers. “Host-Country-Level controls” indicates that the regression includes statutory corporate tax rate, GDP per capita, population size, unemployment rate, and indicators of governance quality and financial institution stability in the host country. “Host-Country-Year FEs” indicates that the regression includes two-way host country and year fixed effects. “Parent-Country-Level controls” indicates that the regression includes GDP growth rate and GDP per capital, and indicators of governance quality and financial institution stability in the home country where the ultimate parent company is located. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are clustered at firm level. ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 6.

Investment Response in Low-Tax Countries: Robustness Checks

article image
Notes: This table checks the robustness of the DD results, using the same regression specification as in 5 Column 6. The dependent variable in Panel A is the gross investment per euro of lagged capital winsorized at the top and bottom 1th percentile in Columns 1 to 5. The first column clusters the standard error at the host-home country-pair level. Column 2 excludes affiliates subject to a worldwide tax system in the home country. Column 3 controls the impact of the euro crisis by adding an interaction term between an indicator that takes the value of 1 for Eurozone countries and the post-2009 year indicator. Column 4 uses a balanced sample of firms surviving throughout the sample period. Column 5 uses a matched sample of UK and non-UK firms with comparable turnover, turnover growth, employment, and operation profits. Column 6 uses non-UK affiliates with parent companies in the ten largest EU-27 countries as the control group. Column 7 uses the gross investment rate winsorized at the top and bottom 2.5th percentiles. The dependent variable in Panel B, Columns 1-2 is the net investment per euro of lagged capital winsorized at the 1th and 2.5th percentiles, respectively. Panel B, Columns 3-6 examine the impact of the tax reform on compensation, employment, labor productivity, and reported profitability. All other variables are as previously defined. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are clustered at the firm level unless otherwise indicated. ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 7.

Investment Responses: Triple-Difference Estimation

article image
Notes: This table reports triple-difference estimates of the effects of the 2009 dividends exemption on multinational investments in the EU-27 countries, based on equation (7). All other variables are as previously defined in Table 5. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are clustered at firm level. ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 8.

Separating the Anticipation Effect

article image
Notes: This table reports difference-in-difference estimates of the effects of the 2009 dividends exemption on UK outbound investment on low-tax countries. Columns 1-3 report results using gross investment rates as dependent variables, and Columns 4-6 report results using net investment rates as dependent variables. All columns display the coefficients on the interactions between UK affiliate indicators and indicators for the year 2008 when the reform was announced. Columns 1-2 and 4-5 each display the coefficient on the DE variable, which is the interaction between a UK affiliate indicator and an indicator for the year being 2009 onwards. Columns 3 and 6 display the coefficients on the interaction terms between UK affiliate indicators and year indicators for 2009, 2010, and 2011, respectively.
Table 9.

Investment Response in High-Tax Countries

article image
Notes: This table reports difference-in-difference estimates of the effects of the 2009 dividend exemption on investment by UK affiliates in EU-27 countries that tax corporate profits at higher rates than the UK’s. Each column displays the coefficient on the DEit variable, which is the interaction between a UK affiliate indicator and an indicator for the year being 2009 onwards, from a regression of investment rate on this interaction, affiliate fixed effects, year fixed effects and additional controls. Investment rate is gross investment scaled by book value of fixed capital asset in (end of) previous year. “Affiliate-Level controls” indicates that the regression includes lagged turnover, cash flow scaled by lagged asset, lagged profit margin, and firm age. All firm-level ratio variables are winsorized at top and bottom 2.5 percentiles to remove the influence of outliers. “Host-Country-Level control” indicates that the regression includes statutory corporate tax rate, GDP per capita, population size, and unemployment rate at the host country level. “Host-Country-Year FEs” indicates that the regression includes two-way host country and year fixed effects. “Parent-Country-Level controls” indicates that the regression includes GDP growth rate and GDP per capital at the parent country level. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are clustered at the firm level. ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 10.

Investment Response in the UK

article image
Note: This table reports the difference-in-difference estimates of the effect of the 2009 dividends exemption on investment by UK affiliates in the UK. All columns display the coefficient on the DEit variable, which is the interaction between a UK affiliate indicator and an indicator for the year being 2009 onwards, from a regression of investment rate on this interaction, affiliate fixed effects, year fixed effects, and additional controls. Panel A reports results using non-UK multinational affiliates that operate in the UK as a control group. Panel B reports results using stand-alone firms and affiliates of domestic company groups in the UK as a control group. All variables are defined as they are in Table 1. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are clustered at firm level. ***, **, * denotes significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

References

  • AlstadsÃe˛ter, Annette, Martin Jacob, and Roni Michaely, 2015, “Do dividend taxes affect corporate investment?Journal of Public Economics, Vol. forthcoming.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Altshuler, Rosanne, and Harry Grubert, 2003, “Repatriation Taxes, Repatriation Strategies and Multinational Financial Policy,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 87, No. 1, pp. 73107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Altshuler, Rosanne, Harry Grubert, and Scott Newlon, 2000, “Has U.S. Investment Abroad Become More Sensitive to Tax Rates?” in International Taxation and Multinational Activity, pp. 938 (National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., 1979, “Wealth Maximization and the Cost of Capital,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 93, No. 3, pp. 433446.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., 1981, “A Note on the Efficient Design of Investment Incentives,” Economic Journal, Vol. 91, No. 361, pp. 21723.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., 1983, “Taxation, Corporate Financial Policy and the Cost of Capital,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 21, No. 3, pp. 905940.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., 2002, “Taxation and Corporate Financial Policy,” in Alan J. Auerbach and Martin Feldstein (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 12511292 (Elsevier).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko, 2013, “Output Spillovers from Fiscal Policy,” American Economic Review, Vol. 103, No. 3, pp. 14146.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Becker, Bo, Marcus Jacob, and Martin Jacob, 2013, “Payout Taxes and the Allocation of Investment,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 107, No. 1, pp. 124.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bertrand, Marianne, Esther Duflo, and Sendhil Mullainathan, 2004, “How Much Should We Trust Differences-In-Differences Estimates?The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 119, No. 1, pp. 249275.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blouin, Jennifer L., Jana S. Raedy, and Douglas A. Shackelford, 2011, “Dividends, Share Repurchases, and Tax Clienteles: Evidence from the 2003 Reductions in Shareholder Taxes,” The Accounting Review, Vol. 86, No. 3, pp. 887914.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bond, Steve, Michael Devereux, and Alexander Klemm, 2007, “Dissecting Dividend Decisions: Some Clues About The Effects of Dividend Taxation from Recent UK Reforms,” in Joel Slemrod Alan Auerbach, James R. Hines (ed.), Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century, p. 46âĂS¸75 (Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bradford, David F., 1981, “The Incidence and Allocation Effects of a Tax on Corporate Distributions,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 122.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bradley, Sebastian, Estelle Dauchy, and Makoto Hasegawa, 2017, “Investor valuations of JapanâĂZ´s adoption of a territorial tax regime: quantifying the direct and competitive effects of international tax reform,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. forthcoming, pp. 150.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Budd, John W., Jozef Konings, and Matthew J. Slaughter, 2005, “Wages and International Rent Sharing in Multinational Firms,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 87, No. 1, pp. 7384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campbell, John L., James A. Chyz, Dan S. Dhaliwal, and William C. Schwartz, 2013, “Did the 2003 Tax Act Increase Capital Investments by Corporations?The Journal of the American Taxation Association, Vol. 35, No. 2, pp. 3363.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chetty, Raj, and Emmanuel Saez, 2005, “Dividend Taxes and Corporate Behavior: Evidence from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 120, No. 3, pp. 791833.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chetty, Raj, and Emmanuel Saez, 2010, “Dividend and Corporate Taxation in an Agency Model of the Firm,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 131.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Mooij, Ruud A., and Sjef Ederveen, 2003, “Taxation and Foreign Direct Investment: A Synthesis of Empirical Research,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 10, No. 6, pp. 673693.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Desai, Mihir A., C. Fritz Foley, and James R. Hines, 2001, “Repatriation Taxes and Dividend Distortions,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 54, No. 4.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Desai, Mihir A., and James R. Hines, 2003, “Evaluating International Tax Reform,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 56, pp. 487502.

  • Devereux, Michael P., Clemens Fuest, and Ben Lockwood, 2015, “The Taxation of Foreign Profits: A Unified View,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 125, pp. 8397.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dharmapala, Dhammika, Fritz Foley, and Kristin Forbes, 2011, “Watch What I Do, Not What I Say: The Unintended Consequences of the Homeland Investment Act,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 66, No. 3, pp. 753787.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dharmapala, Dhammika, and Nadine Riedel, 2013, “Earnings Shocks and Tax-motivated Income-shifting: Evidence from European Multinationals,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 97, No. 0, pp. 95107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dischinger, Matthias, and Nadine Riedel, 2011, “Corporate Taxes and the Location of Intangible Assets within Multinational Firms,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 95, No. 7, pp. 691707.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Egger, Peter, Valeria Merlo, Martin Ruf, and Georg Wamser, 2015, “Consequences of the New UK Tax Exemption System: Evidence from Micro-level Data,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 125, No. 589, pp. 17641789.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feld, Lars P., and Jost H. Heckemeyer, 2011, “FDI and Taxation: A Meta-Study,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 233272.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feld, Lars P., Martin Ruf, Uwe Scheuering, Ulrich Schreiber, and Johannes Voget, 2005, “Effects of Territorial and Worldwide Corporation Tax Systems on Outbound M&As,” ZEW Discussion Papers 13-088, ZEW Center for European Economic Research.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Foley, C. Fritz, Jay C. Hartzell, Sheridan Titman, and Garry Twite, 2007, “Why Do Firms Hold So Much Cash? A Tax-based Explanation,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 86, No. 3, pp. 579607.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gourio, Francois, and Jianjun Miao, 2011, “Transitional Dynamics of Dividend and Capital Gains Tax Cuts,” Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 14, No. 2, pp. 368383.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Graham, John R., Michelle Hanlon, and Terry Sheylin, 2010, “Barries to Mobility: The Lockout Effect of U.S. Taxation of Worldwide Corporate Profits,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 63, No. 4, pp. 11111144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Great Britain Parliament: House of Lords: Select Committee on Economic Affairs, 2009, “The Finance Bill 2009: 3rd Report of Session 2008-09,” Vol. Vol. 2.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grubert, Harry, 1998, “Taxes and the Division of Foreign Operating Income among Royalties, Interest, Dividends and Retained Earnings,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 68, No. 2, pp. 269290.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grubert, Harry, and John Mutti, 2000, “Do Taxes Influence Where U.S. Corporations Invest?National Tax Journal, Vol. 53, No. 4, p. 825.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanlon, Michelle, Rebecca Lester, and Rodrigo Verdi, 2015, “The Effect of Repatriation Tax Costs on U.S. Multinational Investment,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 116, No. 1, pp. 179196.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hartman, David G., 1985, “Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 26, No. 1, pp. 107121.

  • Hasegawa, Makoto, and Kozo Kiyota, 2017, “The Effect of Moving to a Territorial Tax System on Profit Repatriation: Evidence from Japan,” Journal of Public Economics, pp. 92110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heckman, James J, Hidehiko Ichimura, and Petra E Todd, 1997, “Matching as an Econometric Evaluation Estimator: Evidence from Evaluating a Job Training Programme,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 64, No. 4, pp. 60554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hines, James R., 1996, “Altered States: Taxes and the Location of Foreign Direct Investment in America,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 5, pp. 10761094.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hines, James R., and Eric M. Rice, 1994, “Fiscal Paradise: Foreign Tax Havens and American Business,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109, No. 1, pp. 149182.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF, 2014, “Spillovers in International Corporate Taxation,” Imf staff report, International Monetary Fund.

  • King, Mervyn A., 1974, “Taxation and the Cost of Capital,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 2135.

  • King, Mervyn A., 1977, Public Policy and the Corporation (London: Chapman and Hall.).

  • Kleinbard, Edward, 2011, “Stateless Income,” Florida Tax Review, Vol. 11, p. 699.

  • Matheson, Thornton, Victoria Perry, and Chandara Veung, 2014, “Territorial versus Worldwide Corporate Taxation: Implications for Developing Countries,” in Taxation and Development: The Weakest Link? (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mathur, Aparna, Nirupama S. Rao, Michael R. Strain, and Stan A. Veuger, 2016, “Dividends and Investment,” Public Finance Review, Vol. 44, No. 6, pp. 769787.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poterba, James M, and Lawrence H Summers, 1984, “New Evidence that Taxes Affect the Valuation of Dividends,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 39, No. 5, pp. 13971415.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Slemrod, Joel, 1990, “Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: Evidence from a Cross-Country Comparison,” in Taxation in the Global Economy, pp. 79– 122 (National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Yagan, Danny, 2015, “Capital Tax Reform and the Real Economy: The Effects of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut,” American Economic Review, Vol. 105, No. 12, pp. 353163.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zwick, Eric, and James Mahon, 2017, “Tax Policy and Heterogeneous Investment Behavior,” American Economic Review, Vol. 107, No. 1, pp. 21748.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

Appendix A. Supplementary Materials

Figure A.1.
Figure A.1.

Spatial Distribution of UK Subsidiaries

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2018, 007; 10.5089/9781484337493.001.A001

Notes: This figure shows the distribution of UK-owned affiliates in the EU-27 countries. Numbers in the square brackets refer to the five quantiles of the sample distribution. The top ten industries for the UK and non-UK affiliates in the host countries are the following:
article image
Figure A.2.