Financial Development and Source of Growth
New Evidence1
Author:
Samy Ben Naceur
Search for other papers by Samy Ben Naceur in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Robert Blotevogel
Search for other papers by Mr. Robert Blotevogel in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Mark Fischer
Search for other papers by Mr. Mark Fischer in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Haiyan Shi
Search for other papers by Haiyan Shi in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

This paper examines how financial development affects the sources of growth—productivity and investment—using a sample of 145 countries for the period 1960-2011. We employ a range of econometric approaches, focusing on the CCA and MENA countries. The analysis looks beyond financial depth to capture the access, efficiency, stability, and openness dimensions of financial development. Yet even in this broad interpretation, financial development does not appear to be a magic bullet for economic growth. We cannot confirm earlier findings of an unambiguously positive relationship between financial development, investment, and productivity. The relationship is more complex. The influence of the different dimensions of financial development on the sources of growth varies across income levels and regions.

Abstract

This paper examines how financial development affects the sources of growth—productivity and investment—using a sample of 145 countries for the period 1960-2011. We employ a range of econometric approaches, focusing on the CCA and MENA countries. The analysis looks beyond financial depth to capture the access, efficiency, stability, and openness dimensions of financial development. Yet even in this broad interpretation, financial development does not appear to be a magic bullet for economic growth. We cannot confirm earlier findings of an unambiguously positive relationship between financial development, investment, and productivity. The relationship is more complex. The influence of the different dimensions of financial development on the sources of growth varies across income levels and regions.

I. Introduction and Motivation

We provide new evidence that financial development is not a magic bullet for economic development. Instead, the relationship between finance, productivity, and investment is complex, and there is no unambiguously positive relationship where “finance” boosts productivity and investment everywhere and at all times. This result seems intuitive once we acknowledge that financial development has many dimensions. Consistent with Čihák et al. (2012), we distinguish between four dimensions: (i) financial depth; (ii) financial efficiency; (iii) financial stability and openness; (iv) and access to financial services. Financial stability and stock market efficiency are the only dimensions that appear related to productivity and capital accumulation across time and countries. The effect of other dimensions depends on country characteristics, such as income level and region. For example, financial openness can boost productivity in low-income countries, but the positive effect vanishes in advanced countries. Effects can also vary over time, with financial depth, for example, contributing positively to growth in the pre-2005 period.

We also examine whether financial development exerts particular effects in the CCA and MENA region. But we find only mild evidence for differential regional effects. CCA and MENA oil importing countries may stand to gain extra benefits from increasing the efficiency of their banking sector efficiency, measured by interest rate spreads and overhead costs. This results likely reflects the generally weak level of competition in these markets (see Rocha, 2011, for example), translating into high prices for borrowers and high operational costs.

Our paper complements the existing literature in three respects. First, we extend the data to include the recent global financial crisis and a large number of countries. Specifically, the sample contains unbalanced panel data for 145 countries from 1960 to 2011. We focus in particular on the CCA and MENA countries to see if financial development in these countries differs from other regions. Second, we use 16 different indicators of the four main dimensions of financial development—depth, efficiency, stability/openness and access—to capture all aspects of the financial sector. Our results about financial development are therefore more general than earlier contributions that rely merely on some financial indicator measuring countries’ financial depth. Third, we focus on how financial development affects the sources of growth, productivity and capital accumulation, and not growth itself.

The relationship between financial development and economic growth on the theoretical level has always been controversial. Robinson (1952) and Lucas (1988) believe that financial intermediaries develop in response to demand from the real sector. On the other hand, Schumpeter (1912), Gurley and Shaw (1955), Goldsmith (1969), Greenwood and Jovanovich (1990), and others see finance as an important contributor to growth by improving resource allocation through the provision of ex-ante information on investment projects, promoting saving through risk diversification, and easing exchange through the reduction of transaction costs.

The early consensus of the empirical literature on the finance and growth nexus has, by and large, supported the positive relationship between development and growth using cross-country, time-series, and panel data, as well as industry- and firm-level studies (see Levine 2005 for a literature review). More recent evidence, however, points to a more complex relationship, which depends on the level of financial and economic development, as well as the quality of institutions. Applying a threshold regression model, Deidda and Fattouh (2002) argue there is no significant relationship between financial development and growth in low-income countries, whereas the relationship is positive and strongly significant in high-income countries. Rioja and Valev (2004a) add that this relationship varies according to the level of financial development, finding a positive and significant effect of financial development on growth only with medium and high levels of financial development. Rioja and Valev (2004b) find that finance affects growth through capital accumulation in low-income countries and through productivity growth in middle- and high-income countries.

Recent papers by Cechetti and Karroubi (2012) and Arcand and others (2012) have revisited the finance-growth nexus, showing that the level of financial development is good for economic growth only up to a point between 90 percent and 100 percent of GDP, turning negative for high-income countries. This result is consistent with “the vanishing effect of financial development” (Law and Singh, 2014). These studies suggest that the positive effect of finance on economic growth may be more nuanced, but they do not reject the prevailing consensus that finance is good for growth.

The global financial crisis has been a turning point. Using recent data up to 2010, Rousseau and Watchel (2011) and Beck and others (2012b) find a much lower effect of finance on growth than previous studies. In fact, Rousseau and Watchel (2011) find that the finance-growth relationship disappeared during the period between 1990 and 2004. They attribute the vanishing effect to financial crises related to rapid and excessive financial deepening. Arcand and others (2012) suggest that the vanishing relationship between finance and growth could be attributed to “the fact that many countries have reached the point at which financial deepening starts having a negative effect on growth.” Beck and others (2012a) explain that the vanishing effect could also be related to the increase in the share of household loans to the detriment of company loans: they find that enterprise credit is positively associated with economic growth, whereas household credit is not. By extending the sample to include the global financial crises, though on a relatively small sample of 46 countries, Bezemer and others (2014) find a high ratio of bank credit to GDP has a negative effect on growth. They suggest that this negative relationship between finance and growth is due to a shift in the share of credit away from nonfinancial institutions.

This paper is organized as follows: section 2 describes the dataset, the empirical model, and the econometric methodology; section 3 discusses the empirical findings; and section 4 concludes with some plausible factors that might explain the vanishing effect of the finance-growth nexus.

II. Data

This study utilizes available data on financial development and the sources of growth for a large number of countries between 1960 and 2011. Our dataset is limited only by source data availability. Accordingly, the number of observations across both country and time dimensions varies in each model. In line with prior work, we employ multi-year, non-overlapping averages of the available data when possible, 2 which isolates and removes business cycle effects, focusing on the relationship between each financial indicator and the sources of economic growth. This section describes the measures of sources of growth, financial development, and control variables.

A. Sources of growth

We add to the literature by decomposing economic growth using standard growth-accounting practices into total factor productivity (TFP) growth and capital stock accumulation, both of which are extracted from the Penn World Tables. This dataset offers a comprehensive global database with estimates for capital stock and TFP since 1950. The methodology used accounts for heterogeneity in labor income over time and constructs the capital stock based on decomposed assets (higher weights to fixed assets), allowing for accurate and comparable estimates of TFP for a wide array of countries over a long-time period.3

B. Financial development indicators

We examine a wide range of financial indicators to capture the four main dimensions of financial sector development—depth, efficiency, stability/openness, and access. We therefore extend the analytical approach of much of the existing literature that focuses on credit and monetary aggregates. Relying primarily on the Global Financial Development Database, which includes a wealth of financial sector indicators, we consider the effects of depth, efficiency, stability, openness, and access on the two dominant sources of growth (productivity and capital accumulation). Due to a potentially non-linear relationship between economic growth and control variables, we transform all variables into natural logarithm forms. 4 Table 1 defines each included indicator by dimension, while Figures 1 and 2 show basic relationships between the financial variables and the sources of growth

Figure 1.1
Figure 1.1

Productivity Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

Five Year Non-Overlapping Averages

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 143; 10.5089/9781484302637.001.A001

Figure 1.2
Figure 1.2

Productivity Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

Three Year Non-Overlapping Averages

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 143; 10.5089/9781484302637.001.A001

Figure 1.3
Figure 1.3

Productivity Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

Annual Observations

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 143; 10.5089/9781484302637.001.A001

Table 1:

Data Description

article image
article image

C. Control variables

To assess the strength of an independent relationship between growth and financial development, we introduce control variables as suggested by the finance-growth literature. The logarithm of initial real GDP per capita is introduced to control for economic convergence. Average years of schooling are included to control for the level of human development. We also use the trade-to-GDP ratio, the ratio of government consumption to GDP, and oil prices to control for openness and the role of the state in the economy.

D. Empirical Methodology

The basic specification used in this paper follows the general regression model used in other studies (Levine 2005) and can be summarized as:

g i t = α y i , t 1 + β F i , t + γ X i , t + η i + λ t + ϵ i , t ( 1 )

where git represents growth in either total factor productivity or the capital stock. yi,t−1 represents initial real GDP per capita and serves as a measure of the tendency for growth rates to converge across countries over time. The nexus of interest is the impact of Fi,t, the financial dimension, on each respective component of economic growth. Xi,t represents the vector of macroeconomic control variables and includes initial GDP per capita, the trade to GDP ratio, average years of schooling, and the government consumption to GDP. ηi is an unobserved country-specific effect, λt is a time-specific effect, ϵi,t is the time-varying error term, and i and t represent country and time period, respectively.

Rewriting Eq.1 using the first difference as suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991), we obtain the following equation:

Δ g i t = α Δ y i , t 1 + β Δ F i , t + Δ γ X i , t + Δ λ t + Δ ϵ i , t ( 2 )

Although this differentiation eliminates the country specific effect, it introduces a new bias because of the correlation of the new error term with the lagged new dependent variable.

Arellano and Bond (1991) propose that the lagged levels of the dependent variables be used as instruments in the regression equation in differences.

To reintroduce the cross-section dimension of the regression and to address the issue of the persistence of the lagged dependent variables as weak instruments in the GMM difference regression, we use the system GMM proposed by Arellano and Bond (1997). The new estimates consist of the stacked regression in differences and levels where the lagged levels are used as instruments in the difference regression and the difference as instruments in the level regression.

The consistency of the system GMM is tested using the tests proposed by Arellano and Bond (1997). The first is a Hansen test of over-identifying restrictions, which tests the validity of the instruments. The second test examines whether the differenced error term is second-order serially correlated. Failure to reject both tests lends support to our estimator.

To ensure that the Arellano-Bond test detects the desirable serial correlation properties in the residuals of the differenced equation, the capital accumulation regressions contain two lags of the dependent variable. In the TFP regressions, one lag of the dependent variable is sufficient. We restrict the number of instruments to less than the number of included countries to guard against a proliferation of instruments, which can bias the GMM estimates.

We supplement the baseline specification above to investigate heterogeneity and non-linearity within the sample. Descriptions of the five included specifications follow, each of which was estimated for each financial indicator and both sources of growth:

g i t = α y i , t 1 + β F i , t + δ F i , t x I N T + γ X i , t + η i + λ t + ϵ i , t ( 3 )

To capture non-linearities, we interact the financial variables with one of five alternatives: (1) income level; (2) inflation regime; (3) quality of institutions; (4) level of financial development; and (5) regional dummies. The dummy variables used in specifications (i-iv) were created by splitting the sample equally into three ranked subgroups. Regional subgroups include the Caucasus and Central Asia (CCA), Middle East and North Africa Oil Exporters (MENAPOE), and the Middle East and North Africa Oil Importers (MENAPOI).

III - Empirical Results

We find evidence to support a nuanced view of the importance of financial development and economic growth. Our results display no unambiguously positive relationship between “finance” and the sources of growth. In some cases, excessive financial development may have detrimental effects on growth. We do find evidence, however, that the dimensions of financial stability and efficiency are linked to growth. Nonperforming loans and stock market turnover emerge as the only two indicators of financial development to exhibit a general relationship with productivity growth and capital accumulation which is both robust and economically significant.

A. Unconditional correlations

Data plots (Figures 1 and 2) display simple scatter plots between each of the financial indicators and either TFP growth or capital accumulation. The data included for each financial dimension— access, depth, efficiency, openness, and stability—are represented in the logarithmic forms as discussed in the data section above. As shown in the panels, there is little evidence of a strong overarching relationship between any of our financial indicators and the sources of growth. This is echoed in unconditional correlation coefficients, presented in Table 3. Even when the effect is significant, it is small and fails to consider the important contributions from other relevant macroeconomic, institutional, regional, or developmental characteristics.

Figure 2.1
Figure 2.1

Capital Stock Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

Five Year Non-Overlapping Averages

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 143; 10.5089/9781484302637.001.A001

Figure 2.2
Figure 2.2

Capital Stock Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

Three Year Non-Overlapping Averages

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 143; 10.5089/9781484302637.001.A001

Figure 2.3
Figure 2.3

Capital Stock Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

Annual Observations

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 143; 10.5089/9781484302637.001.A001

Table 2:

Summary Statistics of Raw Financial Variables

article image
Note: Summary statistics are of untransformed annual observations.
Table 3:

Unconditional Correlations

article image
Note: Financial variables are included in log forms. * denotes p<0.05, **denotes p<0.01, ***denotes p<0.001

B. Dynamic panel regressions

Baseline regressions

Results for the productivity and capital accumulation regressions are reported in Tables 4-19. For each dependent variable (productivity growth or capital accumulation), column 1 displays the parsimonious baseline specification, while columns 2-6 include additional considerations for income differentiation (column 2), inflation regimes (column 3), institutional quality (column 4), financial depth (column 5), and regional characteristics (column 6). Consistent with other studies in the literature, measures of initial income levels, openness, government size, and human capital are included as control variables (Beck and others 2000c).

Table 4:

Private Credit

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 ***p<0.01
Table 5:

Liquid Liabilities

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 6:

Stock Market Capitalization

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 7:

Interest Rate Spread

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 8:

Stock Market Turnover

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 9:

Net Interest Margin

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 10:

Bank Overhead Costs

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 11:

Non-Performing Loans

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 12:

Stock Price Volatility

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 13:

Bank Z-Score

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 14:

Loan-to-Deposit Ratio

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 15:

Capital Adequacy Ratio

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 16:

Foreign Claims to GDP

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 17:

Chinn Ito Index

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01
Table 18:

Assets and Liabilities to GDP

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.0, *** p<0.01
Table 19:

Bank Branches

article image
Dummy variables for time periods were also included in each model. Results for these are not reported here. t-statistics in parentheses based on cluster-robust standard errors * p<0.1 ** p<0.05 *** p<0.01

High nonperforming loans, per our results (Table 11), result in an economically sizable negative effect on productivity growth and capital accumulation. This result speaks to the importance of a healthy banking system for channeling financing to growth-enhancing investment, even in countries with developed sources of non-bank financing. A one standard-deviation decline in NPLs, corresponding to a decline in the ratio of NPLs to gross loans from 13 to 6 percent, is associated with a 1.2 and 1.5 percentage point improvement in annual TFP and investment growth, respectively. Similarly, the stock market turnover ratio has a significantly positive effect on TFP and capital accumulation, in line with theoretical and empirical work that emphasize stock market liquidity improves the efficiency of the capital allocation process and therefore facilitates long-term growth (Holmstrom and Tirole 1993; Bencivenga, Smith, and Starr 1995).

Financial depth and financial openness are two dimensions that also have significant associations with either TFP or investment in the benchmark specification. However, the significance of the estimated coefficient seems to be due to specific country-year observations (more below), therefore making it difficult to generalize for the entire sample.

For all other dimensions of financial development, we fail to detect a general relationship with the sources of growth. Previous studies already found that deeper financial markets—banking and non-banking—do not lead to better growth outcomes (Loayza and Ranciere 2006; Rioja and Valev 2004a, 2004b; and Cecchetti and Kharroubi 2012). We analyze all other dimensions of financial development to generalize this finding: financial development is no magic bullet for generating growth.

Instead, our results support the notion that the relationship between financial development and the sources of growth are marked by thresholds and vary across country characteristics. Specifically, the effect of finance depends on a country’s: (1) income level; (2) policy regime; (3) institutional quality; and (4) region. While disappointing for advocates of the unfettered good of developing financial markets, our results underscore the complexity of the channels that lead from finance to growth. The effectiveness of financial development to accelerate productivity and investment appears to depend on the specific economic circumstances of individual countries.

Income Thresholds

We next investigate whether the role of finance changes as a country becomes richer. Our estimations suggest that some of the positive effects of financial development, touted by the traditional literatures on financial development, accrue only in low-income countries (Law and Singh, 2014). Advanced economies, on the other hand, can suffer from “excessive” financial development.

To uncover the differential impact of financial development across stages of development, we create time-varying income categories. In each period, we take the bottom third of countries in the income distribution to be low-income, the countries in the middle as middle-income, and the top third as advanced. Dummy variables designate each country observation to one of the three income categories. The interaction terms between the income dummies and the financial indicator then measure the differential impact of finance at three stages of development.

Column 2 shows the results for specifications that contain these interaction terms. Low-income countries with more borrowing from foreign banks experience significantly faster TFP growth than those without integration into the international banking system. Deeper credit markets also support TFP, although the coefficient is only significant at the 10 percent level. In addition to deepening, the health of the banking sector is crucial. The detrimental effects on investment from poor asset quality of banks are more pronounced in low-income countries than elsewhere. Stock market development, on the other hand, does not emerge as an important determinant of growth in low-income countries.

Taken together, the low-income interactions suggest that integrating the domestic banking sector into international financial markets can deliver significant benefits at the early stages of development, if countries safeguard financial stability. The regressions do not identify the channels responsible for generating the growth benefits, but previous studies (Giannetti and others 2002) suggest that financial integration facilitates access to foreign technology and markets.

Our results do not suggest that financial development has a significantly different impact in middle-income countries. The middle-income interaction term is never significant. This result stands in contrast to the inverted U-shape hypothesis of financial development (Rioja and Valev 2004b) positing that financial development matters most at intermediate stages of development.

Advanced economies, on the other hand, can experience the downside of financial development having gone too far. According to the estimates in columns 3 and 9, deeper credit markets and more foreign borrowing from international banks depresses TFP in advanced countries. Previous studies have documented that cross-border banking flows can be destabilizing if they lead to current account reversals and exchange rate volatility. These phenomena were on striking display during the global financial crisis in 2008/09. Countries with the largest and most open banking sectors also suffered the largest output losses in that crisis (UNCTAD 2010). In unreported results that exclude the most recent observation from the estimations, the negative sign on the advanced country interaction disappears and the coefficient becomes insignificant.

Inflation and Institution Thresholds

We do not find robust evidence that the effect of financial development depends on a country’s policy regime or institutional soundness. Analogous to our approach in identifying income thresholds, we create three inflation and institution categories, respectively, for every period: low, medium, and high. Country observations in the bottom third of the distribution of inflation outcomes and institutional quality in each period are classified as low, the middle third as middle, and the top third as high. We interact the resulting dummy variables with the relevant financial indicator to examine the importance of policy regime and institutional quality.

The interaction terms of financial development with inflation and institution thresholds (Tables 4-19) are not significant, with two exceptions. First, the premium on safeguarding financial stability is larger in environments characterized by low inflation and high institutional quality. This result strikes an intuitive chord. In countries with high inflation and bad institutions, the marginal impact on productivity and investment from financial instability will be less given that the non-conducive environment already saps the sources of growth. Second, macroeconomic stability and resilient institutions can bring out the beneficial effects from financial development. Financial integration under strong institutions and larger stock markets in low-inflation environments lead to faster investment growth. This result is particularly important for advanced countries to guard against the unwanted consequences of “excessive” financial development.

Regions

Finally, column 6 shows specifications that focus on three country groups—the Caucasus and Central Asia (CCA), as well as the oil exporters and importers in the Middle East and North Africa—to examine if financial development in these countries leads to systematically different outcomes than in other countries. The estimates suggest that all three country groups in fact exhibit some mild differences from the rest of the world.

The CCA countries seem to see economically large benefits from increasing the efficiency in their banking sectors. Regulatory barriers have protected incumbent banks in these regions, reducing pressures to increase efficiency in banking operations and credit allocation decisions.

For MENA oil exporters, the only financial dimension that appear significant in the regressions is efficiency measured by bank overhead costs to total assets. Puzzlingly, however, the dummy carries the wrong sign, suggesting that greater financial efficiency is associated with detrimental effects on productivity. Equally counterintuitive, oil-importing countries in the MENA region seem to suffer weaker productivity in response to tighter net interest margins and greater financial stability, measured by bank Z score and loan to deposit ratios. To make sense of these puzzling results, we underscore the notion that financial development can help support growth only if institutional prerequisites are in place. MENA oil importers and exporters, however, with a financial system dominated by banks, have weak creditor rights and supervisory regimes (Rocha et al, 2011). The case of MENA countries illustrates that increasing financial activity in environments without adequate infrastructure is more likely to undermine growth prospects than boost them.

IV - Conclusion

We fail to establish positive relationships between most financial development indicators, investment, and TFP growth. Most of the various dimensions of financial development are effective in bolstering the sources of growth depending on a country’s characteristics. The one indicator that jumps out in importance for economic growth is financial stability, particularly in the banking sector. This result implies for countries seeking to accelerate their financial development, the first and foremost attention must be on reducing risks to financial stability. A country’s risk of suffering a financial crisis increases as a function of the size of their financial sector (Schularick and Taylor 2012). Rousseau and Wachtel (2011) show that the rising incidence of financial crises since 1990 is the single most important factor for explaining the vanishing growth effects of financial development.

Stability considerations aside, too rapid financial development may also engender other types of economic costs. Financial development can give rise to externalities that undermine economic growth, especially regarding the allocation of scare resources. Skilled workers in the sense that entrepreneurs working in finance are not available to engage in research and development with higher productivity effects (Cecchetti and Kharroubi 2012). Similarly, financial sectors focusing on enabling the transfer of assets (real estate mortgages) instead of the purchase of goods and services may contribute to destabilizing asset price bubbles. The positive impact on real economic activity of asset transfers may be small or altogether zero (Bezemer and others 2014).

Instead, we support the nonlinearities in the finance-sources of growth relationship identified by some earlier studies: that the effectiveness of financial development as a means of generating growth varies across income levels and regions. For low- and middle-income countries, deeper financial markets tend to reduce productivity growth and investment which may be linked to the uncompetitive markets in these countries. Productivity growth in low-income countries seems to benefit from more open financial markets. In middle-income countries, better financial access is associated with higher growth on investment.

The results also suggest that financial development in the CCA countries, as well as the MENA oil exporters and importers, has slightly different effects than in the rest of the world. Indicators of financial stability and efficiency carry an unexpected sign for these regions, highlighting the need for a sound institutional framework based on effective creditor rights and banking supervision. We see some evidence that CCA and MENA oil importing countries stand to gain from increasing efficiency and competition in their banking sectors.

Our paper reinforces what policymakers across the world already know: financial development needs to proceed according to country-specific circumstances, and safeguarding financial stability is a pre-requisite to avoid entering the territory where financial development starts undermining, instead of fostering, growth.

References

  • Arcand, J., Berkes, E., Panizza, U., 2012. “Too Much Finance?WP/12/161, IMF working paper.

  • Arellano, Manuel & Bond, Stephen, 1991. “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58(2), pages 27797.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck T., Buyukkarabacak B., Rioja F. and Valev N., 2012a. “Who Gets the Credit? And Does It Matter? Household vs. Firm Lending Across Countries,The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 12(1), pages 146.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., Degryse, H., Kneer, C., 2012b. “Is More Finance Better? Disentangling Intermediation and Size Effects of Financial Systems”, Center for Economic Research, Discussion Paper No. 2012060, Tilburg University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., Levine, R., and Loayza, N., 2000c. “Finance and the Sources of Growth”, Journal of Financial Economics Vol 58.

  • Bencivenga, V., Smith, B. and Starr, R., 1995. “Equity Markets, Transaction Costs, and Capital Accumulation.World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1456, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bezemer, D., Grydaki, M., Zhang, L., 2014. “Is Financial Development Bad for Growth? “Research Report 14016-GEM, University of Groningen, Research Institute SOM.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cecchetti, G., Kharroubi, E., 2012. “Reassessing the Impact of Finance on Growth”, BIS Working Papers No. 381, Bank for International Settlements.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Čihák, M., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Feyen, E. and Levine, R. 2012. “Benchmarking Financial Systems Around the World.World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6175, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deidda, L. and Fattouh, B., 2002. “Non-linearity between Finance and Growth,Economics Letters, Elsevier, vol. 74(3), pages 339345.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giannetti, M., Guiso, L., Jappelli, T., Padula, M. and Pagano, M. (2002), “Financial Market Integration, Corporate Financing and Economic Growth”, European Commission Economic Papers N° 179.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldsmith, Raymond W. 1969. Financial Structure and Development. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

  • Greenwood, J., and Jovanovich, B. (1990), “Financial Development, Growth and the Distribution of Income”, Journal of Political Economy, 98, pages 10761107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gurley, John G. and Shaw, Edward S.Financial Aspects of Economic Development.American Economic Review, September 1955, 45(4), pages 51538.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Holmstrom, B., Tirole, J., 1993. “Market liquidity and performance monitoring.The Journal of Political Economy, August 1993, pages 678709.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Law, S. H. and Singh, N., 2014. “Does Too Much Finance Harm Economic Growth?,Journal of Banking & Finance, vol. 41(C), pages 3644.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, R., 2005. “Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence,Handbook of Economic Growth, in: Philippe Aghion & Steven Durlauf (ed.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, Chapter 12, pages 865934.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loayza N., Ranciere, R.Financial Development, Financial Fragility, and Growth,Journal of Money, vol. 38(4), pages 10511076.

  • Lucas, R.E. 1987. On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics 22, pages 4370.

  • Robinson J., 1952 The Generalization of the General Theory, in the Rate of Interest and Other Essays, Macmillan, London (1952).

  • Rocha, R., Arvai, Z. and Farazi, S. 2011, “Financial Access and Stability, A Road Map for the Middle East and North Africa,(Washington: The World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rioja, F. and Valev, N., 2004a. “Does one size fit all? A Reexamination of the Finance and Growth Relationship”. Journal of Development Economics 74 (2), pages 429447.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rioja, F. and Valev, N., 2004b. “Finance and the Sources of Growth at Various Stages of Economic Development”. Economic Inquiry 42 (1), pages 127140.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rousseau, P. and Wachtel, P., 2011. “What Is Happening to The Impact of Financial Deepening on Economic Growth?,Economic Inquiry, vol. 49(1), pages 276288.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schularick, M. and Taylor, A., 2012. “Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870-2008American Economic Review, 102 (2), pages 10291061 .

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schumpeter J.A., 1912. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. First edition. Duncker und Humblot, Berlin.

  • UNCTAD (2010), The Financial and Economic Crisis of 2008-2009 and Developing Countries, 2010.

1

The authors would like to thank Risto Herrala, Oussama Kanaan, Divya Kriti, Vina Nguyen, Farid Talishi, Natalia Tamirisa and participants at the IMF meeting on surveillance for helpful comments; Basil Awad for research assistance. Neil Hickey for editorial assistance; Rasha El-Askary and Jennifer Azar for administrative assistance. All errors and omissions are our own.

2

For variables with shorter available time series, we use either three year non-overlapping averages or annual observations.

3

http://www.rug.nl/research/ggdc/data/pwt/v80/capital_labor_and_tfp_in_pwt80.pdf for more details on the construction of the database.

4

All variables are transformed into logarithms except for the Chinn Ito index, which is used in its original form.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Financial Development and Source of Growth: New Evidence
Author:
Samy Ben Naceur
,
Mr. Robert Blotevogel
,
Mr. Mark Fischer
, and
Haiyan Shi
  • Figure 1.1

    Productivity Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

    Five Year Non-Overlapping Averages

  • Figure 1.2

    Productivity Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

    Three Year Non-Overlapping Averages

  • Figure 1.3

    Productivity Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

    Annual Observations

  • Figure 2.1

    Capital Stock Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

    Five Year Non-Overlapping Averages

  • Figure 2.2

    Capital Stock Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

    Three Year Non-Overlapping Averages

  • Figure 2.3

    Capital Stock Growth and Financial Sector Indicators

    Annual Observations