Effects of Timeliness on the Trade Pattern between Primary and Processed Goods1
  • 1 0000000404811396https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396International Monetary Fund

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: SBaniya@purdue.edu

This paper investigates the effect of timeliness in accessing the intermediate inputs on the trade pattern. In particular, any country that has a higher ability to transport goods on time has a comparative advantage in industries that place a higher value on the timely delivery of their inputs, and this comparative advantage pattern is stronger for processed goods than for primary goods. To do this, a measure for how intensively any industry demands for the timely delivery of its intermediate inputs is constructed combining Hummels and Schaur (2013)’s calculations of the time sensitivity of products with the input-output tables.

Abstract

This paper investigates the effect of timeliness in accessing the intermediate inputs on the trade pattern. In particular, any country that has a higher ability to transport goods on time has a comparative advantage in industries that place a higher value on the timely delivery of their inputs, and this comparative advantage pattern is stronger for processed goods than for primary goods. To do this, a measure for how intensively any industry demands for the timely delivery of its intermediate inputs is constructed combining Hummels and Schaur (2013)’s calculations of the time sensitivity of products with the input-output tables.

I. Introduction 2, 3, 4, 5

1. According to the UNCTAD Handbook of Statistics, more than 76 percent of total exports were that of primary commodities for African region, whereas, the figure was less than 19 percent for Asia in 2013.6 This paper provides an important explanation for specialization in industries that value timely delivery of inputs—hence the trade pattern between primary and processed goods across countries. In particular, this pattern of trade is explained by introducing the idea of “indirect time costs” of trade arising from input-output linkages: the time costs incurred while accessing the intermediate inputs, after controlling for various confounding factors, significantly determines the trade specialization pattern between primary and processed goods.

2. For this analysis, the indirect time costs of trade across products is computed using the U.S. input-output coefficients, and Hummels and Schaur (2013)’s calculations of the ad-valorem tariff equivalent of consumers’ willingness to pay more for a good to be delivered one day earlier. The measure of time sensitivity across products computed in Hummels and Schaur (2013) is denoted in this paper as the “direct time costs” of trade as it provides the consumers’ valuation of timely delivery of goods. According to Hummels & Schaur (2013), time cost of one day in transit is equivalent to an ad-valorem tariff rate of 0.6-2.3 percent. On the other hand, the indirect measure of time sensitivity across products computed in this paper provides producers’ valuation of timely delivery of their bundle of intermediate inputs. In particular, this measure for how intensively producers demand for the timely delivery of the bundle of their intermediate inputs is constructed following the procedure carried out in Nunn (2007). For each good g, such a measure for indirect time sensitivity is the share weighted average of input specific direct time costs.

3. Figure 1 provides the summary statistics of direct and indirect measures of time sensitivity by product type. On average, there is an insignificant difference between primary and processed goods in terms of how intensively consumers demand for the timely delivery of products (direct time cost). However, on average, there is a statistically significant difference between primary and processed goods in terms of how intensively producers demand for the timely delivery of their intermediate inputs (indirect time cost). That is, what differentiates the primary goods and processed goods, on average, is not the direct time costs, but the indirect time costs. This is because processed goods compared to primary goods undergo relatively longer production stages (whose length of production chain increases with the degree of processing), and thus, demand for timely delivery of their intermediate inputs for the management of global production networks. In addition, Table 2 shows that goods that use the most time sensitive inputs are processed goods, and these goods mostly use processed inputs, which are again time sensitive. As a result, processed goods face higher indirect time costs than primary goods do, and therefore, transportation infrastructure reform is particularly important for processed goods than for primary goods through the indirect effects of improvement in timeliness in trade.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Direct and Indirect Measures of Time Sensitivity

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Table 1.

Measure for Time Sensitivity Across Products

article image
Note: The direct time sensitivity measure, t_g, as computed in Hummels and Schaur (2013), provides a measure for how intensively the good g is demanded by consumers on time, i.e. the premium the consumers or the end-users of good g are willing to pay for the good g to arrive one day earlier. However, the indirect time sensitivity measure computed in this paper, t˜g, provides a measure for how time sensitive the bundle of intermediate inputs used in the production of good g is, i.e. how intensively the sector g or the producer demands for its inputs on time, or the premium sector g is willing to pay for its bundle of intermediate inputs j to arrive one day earlier.
Table 2.

List of Most Time Sensitive Inputs by their End Use

article image
article image

4. I examine the effects of time costs of trade on the pattern of trade using the empirical specification as in Nunn (2007) for a particular period of time. This reduced-form econometric specification, which has been used by many others in the literature (Djankov et al., 2010; Li and Wilson, 2009; Gamberoni et al., 2010; Cosar and Demir, 2014), explains export volumes by the interactions of a product characteristic with a country characteristic. A positive coefficient for the interaction between product specific indirect time sensitivity and country specific quality of transportation infrastructure suggests that countries that can transport goods on time export relatively more in products for which timely delivery of inputs is of a higher concern. Further, I assess if such a comparative advantage pattern is significantly different for primary and processed goods. The main finding of this paper is that any country that can transport goods on time exports relatively more in those products that demand for timely delivery of their inputs, and this comparative advantage pattern is stronger for processed goods than for primary goods. In particular, on average, a 10 percent improvement in the transportation infrastructure quality of a country leads to approximately 5.9 percent increment in the export volume of primary goods and 12.8 percent increment in that of processed goods (using IV Results in Table 3 for all products). This paper is then applied to Latin American region to examine if the indirect effects of timeliness in trade is as important for Latin American countries as it is for the rest of the world.

Table 3.

Effects of Transportation Infrastructure on the Trade Pattern (Baseline)

article image
Dependent variable is 2013 aggregate export volume. All the regressions control for other factor interactions, and include country and product fixed effects. Physical geography features are used as instruments for infrastructure. The direct effect of reforms for a sector g comes from the improvement in country i’s ability to transport its final product g on time, whereas, the indirect effect of reforms for the sector g comes from the improvement in its ability to access the intermediate inputs j used in the production of good g on time. A positive coefficient of the variable Qi * tg implies a comparative advantage in products that are time sensitive; whereas, a positive coefficient of Qi*t˜g implies a comparative advantage in products that use time sensitive inputs. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

5. These conclusions have serious developmental policy implications and suggest important future research directions. First, boosting primary sector-based income (such as agriculture and extraction) is critical for developing countries, where majority of the population participates in the primary activities. For instance, over 70 percent of the population in Nepal is engaged in agriculture and forestry, and about 61 percent of them are women (ILO, 2008). It is important that the developing countries focus their efforts into linking the existing and potential farmers to their consumers and productive inputs through improved transportation. Better access to both upstream and downstream markets via improved transportation (Donaldson and Hornbeck, 2013) help the farmers by increasing their production and sales, and the value of their time sensitive raw agricultural products as the farmers will then be able to reach the market on time and impede the depreciation of quality or freshness of their inputs and final products. This is particularly important for countries like Nepal that is geographically disadvantaged, where it takes about 2 to 5 days for farmers to reach the nearest highway in the remote mountainous region (Nepal Department of Roads Statistics). In fact, this paper shows that each day in time saving while transporting raw vegetables and fruits to consumers and while accessing the intermediate inputs of such agricultural goods are equivalent to a reduction in tariff rate of about 1.024 percent and 1.0028 percent levied on the value of the goods, respectively (See Table 7). Hence, timeliness in trade is imperative in enhancing farm and small agriculture-based business income, particularly for women who represent majority of the agricultural labor force in developing countries.

Table 4.

Latin America - LAC (Regression Results with Truncated Sample)

article image
p>Dependent variable is 2013 aggregate export volume. All the regressions control for other factor interactions, and include country and product fixed effects. Instruments (physical geography features of countries) used are as described in IV Approach. The direct effect of reforms for a sector g comes from the improvement in country i’s ability to transport its final product g on time, whereas, the indirect effect of reforms for the sector g comes from the improvement in its ability to access the intermediate inputs j used in the production good g on time. A positive coefficient of the variable Qi * tg implies a comparative advantage in products that are time sensitive; whereas, a positive coefficient of Qi*t˜g implies a comparative advantage in products that use time sensitive inputs. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Table 5.

Analysis of Results—A Case for Sugar (Numerical Example)

article image
Table 6a.

Effect of a 10% Improvement in the LPI Level of an Average Country (World)

article image
Table 6b.

Effect of an 8.34% Improvement in the LPI Level of an Average Country in LAC

article image
Policy Shock: We introduce an 8.34% improvement in the quality of transportation infrastructure (LPI) of Latin America. This conservative policy shock will increase the 2016 LPI level of Latin America (2.665) to the 2016 LPI level of Middle East and North Africa (2.887), which has the next best level of infrastructure quality after Latin American region. We use the coefficients obtained in Table 3 for LAC (Column 2). Data Source: 2013 aggregate export volume come from UN Comtrade Database. 2016 LPI comes from World Bank’s LPI Database. Direct measures of time sensitivity come from Hummels and Schaur (2013), and the indirect measure of time sensitivity is as computed in this paper. I aggregate these measures of time sensitivity to the GTAP product level listed in this table for this policy analysis.
Table 6c.

Effect of an 8.34% Improvement in the LPI of an Average Country in LAC (High and Upper Middle Income Countries in Latin America)

article image
Policy Shock: We introduce 8.34% improvement in the quality of transportation infrastructure (LPI) of Latin America. This conservative policy shock will increase the 2016 LPI level of Latin America (2.665) to the 2016 LPI level of Middle East and North Africa (2.887), which has the next best level of infrastructure quality after Latin American region. We use the coefficients obtained in Table 5 (High and Upper Middle Income Countries) for LAC (Column 2).
Table 7.

Measures of Direct and Indirect Time Sensitivity at the GTAP Sectoral Level

article image
article image
Note: The sectoral aggregation is carried out so that sectors with similar degree of processing, and direct and indirect time sensitivity are under the same category. In this table, TS is an abbreviation for time sensitivity.

6. Another policy implication comes from the finding that timeliness in accessing the intermediate inputs is particularly important for processed goods industries due to input-output linkages. This indicates that an improvement in transportation infrastructure—hence timeliness and better access to markets (Donaldson and Hornbeck, 2013)—is exceedingly essential to provide an incentive to marginal private firms to enter into processed goods industries that can create higher paying employment opportunities in developing countries (Baniya and Akgul, 2016). Poor countries like Nepal face the challenge of disproportionate distribution of labor force into primary and industrial sectors, which lowers productivity and slows down economic growth. In fact, less than 7 percent of the population in Nepal participates in the industrial sector (ILO, 2008). Therefore, improvement in the ability to access the inputs on time is critical in enhancing private sector investment and innovation in processed agriculture-based industries, to create skilled and higher paying jobs (Michaels, 2008), and to reallocate domestic labor resources into primary and industrial sectors in a productive way. Moreover, increased production in the processing sector drives up the demand for primary goods (intermediate inputs), further increasing the prices of agricultural commodities and overall farm-based income. Furthermore, improved timeliness in trade lowers trade cost, and enhances competitiveness and connectivity, thereby integrating these industries in global value chains (Bekkers, et al., 2015) leading to overall economic growth (Alder, 2012). In addition, developing countries will experience industrialization, urbanization and better access to basic facilities (Baum-Snow, 2007) across regions, including remote and interior parts, thereby leading to decentralization of population density across regions (Baum-Snow et al., 2012) and a reduction in inter-regional gaps in prices and wages (Donaldson, 2012) as a result of improved transportation infrastructure.

7. This paper contributes to various strands of literature on the value of time in trade. First, similar to other papers in this literature, this paper incorporates the idea that trade costs include not only tariffs and transport costs, but also time costs. Hummels (2001) is among the first to study time cost distinctly from other trade costs: time cost of one day in transit is equivalent to an ad valorem tariff rate of 0.8 percent, which reduces the probability that a country will export to the U.S. by 1 percent for all goods and 1.5 percent for manufactures. Several studies in this literature (Djankov, Freund and Pham, 2010; Li and Wilson, 2009; Gamberoni, Lanz and Piermartini, 2010) show that time costs have a significant effect on the comparative advantage, particularly in time sensitive industries. In addition, Cosar and Demir (2014) uses geo-referenced data to show how a significant public investment on domestic transportation infrastructure in Turkey leads to its comparative advantage in time sensitive products. For instance, products that are perishable and seasonal in nature face higher time costs, and logistics delays can depreciate the value of perishable and time-sensitive products, which might lead to unwanted costs of holding inventories. Hence, time-sensitive industries in countries that cannot transport goods on time are less likely to produce and export. However, unlike these studies, this paper emphasizes the importance of time costs in influencing producer behavior, and hence the trade pattern, by introducing the idea of indirect time cost arising from input-output linkages that is ignored in the literature in addition to the commonly studied direct time cost. In fact, Villar (2004) shows that the concentration of economic activity is more the consequence of improvements in transportation between upstream and downstream firms than those between firms and consumers—further supporting the importance of indirect time costs on the trade pattern.

8. Next, this paper adds to the literature on the importance of quality of transportation infrastructure and timeliness in trade on the international trade and specialization pattern particularly in those industries that have production fragmented into vertical stages and that are highly integrated in global value chains (Hummels, 2001; Nordas, 2007). With increasing product differentiation, vertical specialization and international outsourcing, the importance of non-tariff trade costs in determining trade has increased over time (Miroudot, Lanz and Rigoussis, 2009). Moreover, increasing trade and specialization in intermediate goods have increased the need for timely and effective transport and logistics services (Nordas and Piermartini, 2004). Moreover, timeliness and predictability of delivery times are crucial for intermediate compared to final goods since they are a part of international supply chains (Gamberoni, Lanz and Piermartini, 2010). In fact, industries that follow just-intime business practices and rely on international supply chains face a significant cost, because the entire production process might come to a halt if a single input is missing or if there is a delay in the delivery of the intermediate goods (Li and Wilson, 2009). This literature focuses on the costs of holding stocks and inability to respond to consumer orders and defective components. Moreover, the importance of timeliness in delivery and the fulfillment of quality standards, which depend on the availability, cost and quality of transport, communication and other logistics services, in the vertical supply chains has been emphasized by Hummels, Ishii and Yi (2009), Nordas (2003), and Kremer (1993). Following similar idea, this paper is the first to examine if timeliness in trade is significantly more important for processed goods than for primary goods through the channels of production networks.

9. A challenge in this empirical study is to find an identification strategy that addresses the potential endogeneity between infrastructure and trade (Martincus and Blyde, 2013; Duranton, Morrow and Turner, 2013). For instance, while road and other logistics improvements might increase export performance of the regions that make a reform, it is also possible that growing trade prospects might lead to transport cost reducing investments in these regions. This paper implements a country's physical geography features (such as the mean elevation and distance to coast) to address the reverse causality between trade and investment in transportation infrastructure quality. Moreover, sectors in which timeliness is important (e.g. chemicals and ferrous metals) trade-off time costs and freight cost, and locate themselves near the source of final demand (Hummels and Schaur, 2013; Evans and Harrigan, 2005). In particular, the time taken to deliver intermediate and final goods causes uncertainty about demand, costs and product characteristics, providing an incentive to upstream and downstream firms to cluster around each other (Harrigan and Venables, 2004). I address this co-location issue (endogeneity between availability of upstream activities in a region and the downstream production and exports) due to the correlation between downstream industrial demand for intermediate inputs and the time cost in accessing the inputs following Hummels and Hillberry (2002). They emphasize both the direct and indirect effects of trade frictions on the trade volume, and suggest controlling for industrial demand for intermediate goods that drives up downstream production and exports, and are correlated with the time costs in accessing the inputs. Omitting this variable from the estimating equation causes the trade barrier variable to pick up both the direct and indirect effects of time costs of trade. Another way to address this issue is to use an extensive set of fixed effects as done in Hummels and Hillberry (2002). In addition, a robust measure of indirect time sensitivity across products is constructed by eliminating the diagonal elements of the input-output matrix to address double counting.

10. Chapter 1 (Effects of Timeliness on the Trade Pattern between Primary and Processed Goods) is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data sources and construction of the measure for indirect factor intensities across products, and Section 3 displays the summary statistics. Section 4 presents and analyzes the empirical framework implemented to examine the effect of improvement in timeliness in trade via transportation infrastructure reform on the trade pattern. Section 5 discusses the reverse causality issue between trade and transportation infrastructure, and Section 6 shows the baseline results with the control for this endogeneity using IV estimations. Section 7 presents several robustness checks, including the magnification effects in the presence of indirect time cost of trade. Section 8 concludes the main findings of this paper, and Section 9 discusses the future work in progress and leads us to Chapter 2 (Effects of Transportation Infrastructure Reform on the Export Participation and Composition using the Firm-Heterogeneity CGE model in GTAP).

II. Data Sources and Variable Computations

11. The aggregate export volume by country and by product for the year 2013 (Xig) are extracted from the UN Comtrade database. This includes all the available countries and HS-6 digit products. Countries are denoted by i and products are denoted by g. The data on country-specific factor endowments and product-specific (HS-6 classification) factor intensities are from UNCTAD Revealed Factor Intensity Indices (RFII) database (2007). The factors included in this database are physical capital (K), human capital (H), land (M) and natural resources (R). We use the logistics performance index of a country as a proxy for the quality of transportation infrastructure (Q) from the World Bank’s Logistics Performance Index, 2012 database (See Appendix Figure 12). Direct time sensitivity by 4-digit HS classification are expressed in ad-valorem terms (tg), and they are computed in Hummels and Schaur (2013). The UN Broad Economic Categories classification corresponded with 6-digit HS classification can be used to group products into different categories: primary and processed goods. The U.S. input-output table at the IO industry level is obtained from the BEA database (2007), and the country specific input-output tables at the GTAP sectoral level are obtained from GTAP database version 9.

12. The measure for indirect time sensitivity across products are computed following the procedure carried out in Nunn (2007) in calculating the measure of contract intensity across industries. First, the U.S. input-output table is used to identify which intermediate goods are used, and in what proportions, in the production of each good g. Next, the input specific direct time sensitivity expressed in ad-valorem terms and computed in Hummels and Schaur (2013) are extracted. The input specific direct time sensitivity or cost is the premium that the demanders of this input, i.e. the firms producing the good g, are willing to pay for one day in time savings in the delivery of the input. Using this information, the measure for indirect time costs across products are computed as follows:

t˜g=Σj[θjg*tj],

where θjg is the share of input j in the total inputs used in the production of good g, and tj is the input specific direct time cost faced by the firms producing good g. The difference between the measure for time intensity across industries studied in the literature (tg) and the one studied in this paper (t˜g) can be understood in the following way. The direct time cost measure, tg, as computed in Hummels and Schaur (2013) and as studied by others, provides a measure for how intensively the good g is demanded on time, i.e. the premium the consumers or the end-users of good g are willing to pay for the good g to arrive one day earlier. However, the indirect time cost measure computed in this paper, t˜g, provides a measure for how time sensitive the bundle of intermediate inputs used in the production of good g is, i.e. how intensively the sector g demands for its inputs on time, or the premium sector g is willing to pay for its bundle of intermediate inputs j to arrive one day earlier.

13. Similarly, the Nunn-measure for factor intensities of inputs across products for physical capital, human capital, land and natural resources are computed using the input-output information as described above and the data on revealed factor intensity indices obtained from UNCTAD’s RFII database (2007). In particular, the measures for physical capital, human capital, land and natural resource intensity of inputs across products are computed as k˜g=Σj[θjg*kj];h˜g=Σj[θjg*hj];m˜g=Σj[θjg*mj];r˜g=Σj[θjg*rj], respectively. Similar interpretation follows for other factor intensity measures. For instance, kg gives the measure for how physical capital intensive the sector g itself is, whereas, k˜g gives the measure for how physical capital intensive the bundle of intermediate inputs j used in the sector g is. The existing literature studies only the direct measures of factor intensities and ignores such indirect measures of factor intensities, and this paper tries fill this gap.

III. Summary Statistics

14. Table 1 provides the average time sensitivity of products and that of their bundle of intermediate inputs for different product groups: processed goods and primary goods.7 We find that the difference in the direct time costs tg between primary and processed goods, on average, is not significant; however, on average, there is a significant difference in the measure for time intensity of the inputs (indirect time costs: t˜g) between primary and processed goods. This implies that, on average, primary and processed goods do not differ significantly based on the intensity with which consumers demand for the timely delivery of goods. However, on average, primary and processed goods differ significantly based on the intensity with which the producers demand for the timely delivery of their inputs. This further supports the hypothesis that processed goods producers, on average, face higher indirect time costs arising through input-output linkages than primary goods producers do.

15. Table 2 below presents the six most time sensitive inputs, in order, i.e. the products that have the highest measure for time sensitivity tg as computed in Hummels and Schaur (2013). We see that all of these most time sensitive inputs are processed goods according to BEA classification. In addition, along with these inputs, a list of products that use these inputs in high proportion compared to other products are also provided. We see that the products that use the most time sensitive inputs are processed goods, and these processed goods mostly use processed inputs compared to primary inputs.

16. The summary statistics includes only those countries and products that are included in the sample used in this paper. Figure 2 provides a box plot of regional logistics performance index (LPI) in order. Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia have the lowest levels of LPI, whereas, East Asia and Pacific, Europe and Central Asia, and North America have the highest levels of LPI. This paper provides an application to Latin American region, which has the level of LPI around the world average. Figures 3 and 4, respectively, plot the country-specific shares of primary and processed goods in 2013 total commodity exports by LPI (2012). Figure 3 shows that countries with higher level of LPI tend to export relatively less primary goods. Next, Figure 4 shows that the share of processed commodities in total exports rises as the LPI increases until the LPI level of slightly over 3. After that level of LPI, the share of processed commodities in total exports falls as well, implying that the share of commodities other than primary or processed goods (e.g. higher value added goods) in total exports increases as the LPI increases. Figures 3 and 4 highlight the Latin American (LA) countries to show where LA countries stand against the rest of the world in terms of LPI and export shares of primary and processed goods for the application to Latin American region later in the paper.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Logistics Performance Index by Region

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Source: WB LPI Database 2012 and 2014
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Share of Primary Goods in 2013 Total Exports by 2012 Logistics Performance Index

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Source: Logistics Performance Index are from World Bank’s LPI Database (2012). Products are classified as primary and processed based on BEC classification. 2013 Export Volume are from UN Comtrade Database
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Share of Processed Goods in 2013 Total Exports by 2012 Logistics Performance Index

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Source: Logistics Performance Index are from World Bank’s LPI Database (2012). Products are classified as primary and processed based on BEC classification. 2013 Export Volume are from UN Comtrade Database. The summary statistics includes only those countries and products that are included in the sample used in this paper.
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Country-Specific Weighted Average Upstreamness of Products by LPI

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Source: Measure of upstreamness of products are extracted from computations in Fally (2012). This index provides a measure for how far a product is from its final use. Weights are export shares of products..

IV. Empirical Framework

17. Following the empirical specification as in Nunn (2007), I examine how a country’s ability to transport goods on time determines its comparative advantage in products that value timely delivery of their inputs, and therefore, the trade pattern between primary and processed goods. Similar specification has been used in other papers that carry out a similar analysis focusing on direct time costs (e.g. Djankov, Freund & Pham, 2010; Li & Wilson, 2009; Gamberoni, Lanz & Piermartini, 2010). I adopt this empirical specification that explains export volumes by the interactions of a country specific factor endowment with a product specific factor intensity.

Baseline Framework:

lnXig=γ0+μi+ηg+λΩiVg+γΩiV˜g+λ4Qi*tg+γ4Qi*t˜g+?ig,whereλΩiVg=λ0+λ1lnKi*lnkg+λ2lnHi*lnhg+λ3lnRi*lnrgγΩiV˜g=γ0+γ1lnKi*lnk˜g+γ2lnHi*lnh˜g+γ3lnRi*lnr˜g

Xig is the 2013 export volume of commodity g from country i to the world, and μi and λg are country specific fixed effects and product specific fixed effects, respectively. The control variables on the right hand side of this equation are defined in Section 2 (data and variable computation), where K, H and R represent physical capital, human capital and natural resource endowment across countries, and the small letters k, h and r represent corresponding factor intensities across products. The variables of interest here are as follows.

Qi represents the infrastructure component of the logistics performance index obtained from the World Bank’s LPI database (2012). Next, tg represents the direct time costs of trade obtained from the calculations in Hummels and Schaur (2013); whereas, t˜g represents the indirect time costs of trade computed in this paper using input-output information and input specific direct time costs.

The first value addition of this paper is the inclusion of the terms γΩiV˜g and γ4Qi*t˜g (ignored in the literature) in this empirical model to assess the effect of improvement in timeliness in accessing the intermediate inputs on the trade pattern. Here, the total effect of improvement in timeliness in trade (through the transportation infrastructure reforms) on the export volume is the sum of the two terms:

λ4*tg+γ4*t˜g,where

λ4 * tg represents the direct effect of transportation infrastructure reforms, while γ4*t˜g represents the indirect effect of transportation infrastructure reforms arising through the input-output linkages. The direct effect of reforms for a sector g comes from the improvement in the ability to transport its final product g to its consumers on time, whereas, the indirect effect of such reforms for the sector g comes from the improvement in the ability to access the intermediate inputs j used in the production of the sector’s final product g from the upstream industries on time. This indirect effect has not been studied in the literature, and therefore, I try to fill this gap through this paper.

The positive coefficient of each interaction term indicates that a country exports relatively more in those industries that intensively use the factor, which the country is abundantly endowed with. For instance, if the coefficient of interest (γ4) is positive, it indicates that countries that can transport goods on time export relatively more in industries for which timely delivery of their inputs is of a higher concern. Similarly, if the coefficient (λ4) is positive, it indicates that countries that can transport goods on time export relatively more in industries that face higher direct time costs. Hence, in this paper, I am assessing two different comparative advantage patterns. The former comparative advantage arises due to the indirect effect of timeliness in trade, while the latter arises due to the direct effect of timeliness in trade. I estimate both the coefficients λ4 and γ4 (as opposed to other papers in the literature) to estimate both the direct effect (λ4 * tg) and the indirect effect (γ4*t˜g) of transportation infrastructure reforms on the export pattern, respectively. This also enables us to compare the size of the direct and indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms on the trade pattern. The coefficients of these interaction terms capture only the effect of country’s characteristic on the trade pattern and not on the export volume. The latter effect is captured completely once we incorporate the country and product specific fixed effects (μi and λg) in addition.

Next, I wish to examine if timeliness in trade is an important source of comparative advantage for processed goods than for primary goods. Furthermore, I wish to examine which of the two channels discussed above is relatively more important in determining the comparative advantage in processed goods. We saw earlier that, on average, primary goods and processed goods are significantly different in terms of indirect time costs, t˜g, but not in terms of direct time costs, tg. Hence, I suspect that the comparative advantage pattern between processed goods and primary goods arises from the indirect effects, more than from the direct effects, of the improvement in timeliness in trade through transportation infrastructure reforms. To test this, I run the baseline regression separately for the primary goods and processed goods, and compare the direct and indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms between the two types of goods. The results for these baseline equations are reported in Table 3 under Section 6. Note that this can also be achieved by including the terms λ5(Qi * tg * I) and γ5(Qi*t˜g*I) in the above regression, where I is a dummy that equals 1 if a good is a processed good and 0 if it is a primary good. This also tests whether the comparative advantage pattern arising through direct and indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms are significantly different for processed goods compared to primary goods. In particular, a positive estimate of γ5 indicates that timeliness in transporting intermediate inputs is an important source of comparative advantage for processed goods than for primary goods. Finally, to control for the endogeneity between trade and transportation infrastructure, I use the instrumental variable approach, which I will discuss in the next section.

V. Endogeneity

A. Control for Reverse Causality between Trade and Infrastructure

18. A fundamental problem that arises when carrying out such an analysis is the reverse causality between trade and transportation infrastructure. In particular, a country that has a better trade prospect or that plans to improve its current trade flows also invests more on transportation infrastructure. Hence, although transportation infrastructure reforms might increase trade flows, it is also possible that conditions of trade flows in a country can provide an incentive to invest in transportation infrastructure.

19. To address this problem, I extract the data on physical geography features across countries obtained from the country geography database provided by Portland State University. A country’s physical geography features are then used as instruments for its quality of transport infrastructure. This database provides information on mean elevation (Ei), mean distance to the nearest coastline or sea navigable river (Di), percentage of land area within 100km of ice free coast or sea navigable river, percentage of population within 100km of ice free coast or sea navigable river, distance from a country’s centroid to the nearest coast or sea navigable river, and percentage of land area in the geographical tropics. Among these variables, I extract the first two for the IV estimation. These variables are valid instruments, because, first, these geographical features are clearly exogenous to trade. Next, these geographical features will affect the ability of a country to transport goods on time, because countries with higher Ei (perhaps due to the presence of a large quantity of mountains) and higher Di mostly have poor road networks and sea networks, respectively. Further, the geographical features of a country have no direct effect on the exports of the country; hence they are excludable. The results for the second stage of the 2SLS estimation for different product groups using these instruments are reported in Table 3 in Section 6. I carry out similar IV estimations across different product groups to examine if timeliness in trade is an important source of comparative advantage for processed goods.

Instrumental Variable Approach

  • First Stage:
    Qi*tg=α0+μi+ηg+ιΩiVg+αΩiV˜g+ι4Ti*tg+α4Ti*t˜g+vig(1)
    Qi*t˜g=β0+μi+ηg+κΩiVg+βΩiV˜g+κ4Ti*tg+β4Ti*t˜g+δig(2)
  • Second Stage:
    lnXig=γ0+μi+ηg+λΩiVg+γΩiV˜g+λ4  Q1*tg^+γ4  Q1*tg^+?ig(3)

Correlation Between Transportation Infrastructure and Physical Geography

article image
I extract the data on physical geography features across countries from the country geography database provided by Portland State University. This database provides information on mean elevation (Ei), mean distance to the nearest coastline or sea navigable river (Di), percentage of land area within 100km of ice free coast or sea navigable river, percentage of population within 100km of ice free coast or sea navigable river, distance from a country’s centroid to the nearest coast or sea navigable river, and percentage of land area in geographical tropics. Among these variables, I extract the first two for the IV estimation. LPI stands for the logistics performance index extracted from the World Bank’s LPI database (2012).

VI. Results

20. Table 3 presents the regression results for the baseline equation for different product groups. It reports the coefficients for only those comparative advantage sources that are of interest to this paper: Qi * tg and Qi*t˜g. We can see that the coefficient estimate for the variable of interest, Qi * tg and Qi*t˜g, are positive and statistically significant when I run the regression for the sample that includes all products, both primary and processed goods, and processed goods only. In addition to the conclusions of the literature (usual sources of comparative advantage), I find that countries that can transport goods on time export relatively more in industries for which timely delivery of inputs is of a higher concern. Secondly, both the direct and indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms are positive and significant for the first three product groups, however, the indirect effects arising through input-output linkages are larger than the direct effects of reforms.

21. Next, I run this regression separately for processed and primary goods to test if this comparative advantage pattern is stronger for processed goods. Both the direct and indirect effects are significant for processed goods; in particular, I find that the indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms for processed goods are larger than the direct effects. However, the effect of timeliness in trade seems negative (contraction) or insignificant for primary goods. Hence, countries with better quality of transport infrastructure specialize in industries that have a higher value for timely delivery of their inputs, and this comparative advantage pattern is stronger for processed goods than for primary goods, because processed goods face higher time costs in accessing their inputs than primary goods do. Further, I find that timeliness in trade is particularly important for processed goods than for primary goods.

22. This result is further confirmed after controlling for reverse causality using IV estimation approach: physical geography features of a country as instruments for its quality of transportation infrastructure in Table 3. In particular, the coefficients of interest are all positive and significant except for the sample containing primary goods only. Hence, from these exercises, I conclude that countries with higher quality of transportation infrastructure specialize relatively more in products that value timely delivery of their inputs. Moreover, timeliness is particularly an important source of comparative advantage for processed goods compared to primary goods as processed goods undergo larger production stages. However, one might suspect that the coefficients are slightly magnified in the IV estimation results. So, I try to address the co-location between upstream and downstream industries in the presence of indirect time costs that is possibly leading to this magnification effect following Hummels and Hillberry (2002) in the next section. Before we address this issue, I present below the analysis of results for Latin America.

23. Table 3 shows that only the direct effects of transportation infrastructure reforms seem to be positive and significant for Latin American countries, when I run the regression for the sample containing all products, primary and processed goods, and processed goods only. Improvement in timeliness in trade do not seem to have significant indirect effects, arising through input-output linkages, on the trade pattern in Latin America. However, Figure 2 shows that the 2012 LPI level of Latin America ranges from slightly over 2 to 3.17, which indicates that the average level of upstreamness, and the average direct and indirect time sensitivity of products of Latin America are rising with LPI8. Hence, I now examine how the share of different types of commodities (e.g. primary, processed and higher value-added goods) in Latin America changes with the level of LPI to investigate if the existing production structure in Latin America is giving rise to such a different trade impact compared to the rest of the world. Figure 6 shows that within Latin American countries with low levels of LPI (less than 2.5) we see a sharp fall in the share of processed goods (which face larger indirect time costs) with a rise in LPI. This is a very different pattern in Latin America compared to the rest of the world with a similar level of LPI. Hence, it is possible that such contrasting results in Table 3 for Latin America was identified off of this group of Latin American countries. Therefore, I next examine if the indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms are significantly positive for the sample of Latin American countries with higher levels of income or higher levels of LPI. Table 4 reports the results with such restricted samples for Latin America.

Figure 6
Figure 6

Country-Specific Weighted Average Indirect Time Sensitivity of Products by LPI

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Figure 7.
Figure 7.
Figure 7.

2013 Composition of Exports by 2012 Logistics Performance Index (World vs Latin America)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

24. As expected, Table 4 shows that the coefficient estimates for the variables of interest, Qi * tgandQi*t˜g, are positive and statistically significant for this restricted sample of Latin American countries across the first three product groups (all products, primary and processed goods, and processed goods only). Similar to the results for the entire world in Table 3, the indirect effects arising through input-output linkages are larger than the direct effects of reforms for this restricted sample. In fact, the indirect effects of reforms seem particularly stronger for processed goods than for primary goods. I find that Latin American countries (with higher levels of income or LPI) that can transport goods on time export relatively more in industries for which timely delivery of inputs is of a higher concern. Similar to the results in Table 3 for the world, Latin American countries do not seem to have significant trade effects of transportation infrastructure reforms on the primary goods. In fact, Latin American countries with higher levels of LPI or income seem to have either no significant effect or a contraction effect, respectively, on the existing primary goods exports with a rise in transportation quality. This prompts us to study the effects of transportation infrastructure reforms on the export participation in addition to the existing export volume (See Chapter 2).

Figure 8a.
Figure 8a.

Effect of a 10% Improvement in the LPI Level of an Average Country (World)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Figure 8b.
Figure 8b.

Effect of an 8.34% Improvement in the LPI of Latin America

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

Figure 8c.
Figure 8c.

Effect of an 8.34% Improvement in the LPI of Latin America (High and Upper Middle Income Countries in Latin America)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

VII. Robustness Check

A. Magnification Effects

25. Hummels and Hillberry (2002) emphasize the importance of addressing the co-location between upstream and downstream firms in the presence of trade costs that can lead to magnification effects on trade due to input-output linkages. Many papers in this literature show that firms face a trade-off between time costs and freight costs, and the value of time in the management of production chains provides an incentive to upstream and downstream firms to cluster around each other. In particular, Hummels and Hillberry (2002) suggest that industrial expenditure on intermediate inputs are correlated with the trade frictions, and omitting it from the estimating equation causes the trade barrier variables to pick up both the direct and indirect effects of frictions. In the context of this paper, what good and how much of that good a country produces and exports depends on what upstream activity or intermediate inputs and how much of these inputs are available locally because of the presence of time cost in transporting the intermediate inputs from upstream to downstream industries. For instance, Nepal is a major exporter of finished tea products, because tea farming is done abundantly in Nepal. The availability of upstream activity or intermediate inputs in a region drives up the downstream industrial demand for these locally available intermediate inputs, and thus, downstream production and exports in that region. Hence, I now control for this omitted variable in the following way.

For each industry g in country i, the industrial demand for locally available intermediate inputs is given by:

Ind.Demandig=j(θjgi*Yij),where

θjgi is the share of input j in the total intermediate inputs used in industry g in country i, and Yij is the industrial output of input j in country i.

Here, the downstream industrial demand for intermediate inputs in a region is a function of the quantity of upstream industrial output available in that region. Clearly, the industrial demand for intermediate inputs drives up the downstream production and exports. Moreover, what upstream activity is present in a region determines the downstream industrial demand for these locally available intermediate inputs, which directly depends on the time costs in accessing these intermediate inputs j, i.e. Ind. Demandig and Qi*t˜g are correlated. Therefore, in the estimating equation used in this paper, it is important to control for industrial demand for locally available intermediate inputs. Hence, I now estimate the following:

Baseline Co-location Equation:

lnXig=γ0+μi+ηg+λΩiVg+γΩiV˜g+λ4Qi*tg+γ4Qi*t˜g+Ind.Demandig+?ig, where

Ind.Demandig=Σj(θjgi*Yij)

To compute Ind. Demandig, I use the country specific input-output tables at the GTAP sectoral level obtained from the GTAP database, version 9. This is the best available data for country-specific input output tables to my knowledge in terms of the maximum number of countries and sectors covered.

Before reporting the regression results for the above co-location equation, I present below the aggregated direct and indirect time sensitivity measures at the GTAP sectoral level in Table 7. We see that the time sensitivity measures are larger for sectors that undergo larger number of production stages. As argued earlier, this is because goods that are heavily integrated in the global production chains face larger indirect time costs. I wish to exploit this variation in product characteristic and the variation in regions in terms of quality of transportation infrastructure to explain the comparative advantage pattern between primary and processed goods.

B. Endogeneity between Upstream and Downstream Production

26. In addition to controlling for the reverse causality issue between the trade and transportation infrastructure using physical geography features of a country (denoted by Ti below) as instruments for the quality of transportation infrastructure, I wish to control for the reverse causality issue between downstream production and the industrial demand for intermediate inputs. Clearly, the causality runs in the other direction as well. If the trade prospect of a downstream industry is high, thereby leading to high downstream production, the industrial demand for locally available intermediate inputs, and therefore, the industrial output of the locally available upstream industries will also rise. That is, the upstream and downstream productions are jointly determined. Moreover, what downstream activity is present in a region also determines the quantity of locally available intermediate inputs in the presence of such indirect time costs. To control for this endogeneity issue, I use the interaction of the exogenously given natural resources endowment of country i and the natural resource intensity of the bundle of intermediate inputs used in the production of the upstream industry as an instrument for the availability of the upstream input. That is, I use

(Ri*r˜j)as an instrument for Yij.

I define the instrument for Ind. Demandig as follows:

Dem.Instrg=j(θjig*(Ri*r˜J))

The correlation between Ind. Demandig and Dem. Instrig is 0.43.

I now estimate the following IV regression:

Control for Co-location and Reverse Causality Issues:

□ Instrumental Variable Approach:

  • ▪ First Stage:
    Qi*tg=μi+ηg+ιΩiVg+αΩiV˜g+ι4Ti*tg+α4Ti*t˜g+σ1Dem.Instrig+vigQi*tg˜=μi+ηg+κΩiVg+βΩiV˜g+κ4Ti*tg+β4Ti*t˜g+σ2Dem.Instrig+δigInd.Demandig=μi+ηg+πΩiVg+pΩiV˜g+π4Ti+ρ4Ti*t˜g+σ3Dem.Instrig+ωig
  • ▪ Second Stage:
    lnXig=μi+ηg+λΩiVg+γΩiV˜g+λ4Qi*tg^+γ4Qi*tg˜^+𝝇Ind.Dem^andig+ɛig

27. Table 8 shows that when I include Ind. Demandig in the baseline equation to control for the co-location effects, the magnitude of the variable of interest, Qi*t˜g, gets smaller indicating that we do face the problem of co-location in our estimation. However, the coefficient estimates of interest are still significantly positive and consistent to our previous conclusions. In particular, a country that has a higher ability to transport goods on time has a comparative advantage in those industries that place a higher value on the timely delivery of their inputs. Also, even after addressing the magnification effects, the indirect effects of reforms are still larger than the direct effects across the first three product groups.

Table 8.

Control for Magnification Effects

article image
Dependent variable is 2013 aggregate export volume. All the regressions control for other factor interactions, and include country and product fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

28. Columns 3 and 4 present the results separately for the processed and primary goods. This exercise confirms that the comparative advantage pattern in products that value timely delivery of intermediate inputs is stronger for processed goods than for the primary goods even after controlling for the magnification effects.

29. The results for the second stage of the IV estimation for different product groups are also reported in Table 8. Along with the above mentioned instrument for industrial demand for intermediates, I use physical geography features of a country as instruments for the quality of transportation infrastructure of the country. Again, the IV estimations are consistent with the OLS estimates. Overall, timeliness in transporting intermediate inputs is a relatively more important source of comparative advantage for processed goods than for primary goods.

Table 9.

Analysis of Results—A Case for Sugar (Numerical Example)

article image
Figure 8d.
Figure 8d.

Effect of a 10% Improvement in the LPI of an Average Country

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 044; 10.5089/9781475585537.001.A001

C. Robust Measure for Indirect Time Sensitivity

30. It might be a concern that the measure of indirect time cost constructed in this paper includes the direct time cost in addition to the time cost in accessing other inputs, leading to double counting, and thereby overestimating the indirect effect of transportation infrastructure reforms. Hence, for the robustness check, I now use a robust measure for indirect time cost, which excludes the diagonal elements of the input-output matrix so that it corrects this issue. In particular,

tg˜=Σjg[θjg*tj]

31. The results using this second measure of indirect time cost, denoted as t˜g′, is presented below in Table 10. We can see that this robust measure of indirect time cost does not change the main conclusions of this paper. However, the direct effects now seem more important than reported earlier for both primary and processed commodities, as expected. Also, the magnitude of the indirect effects is smaller than the baseline results. However, this exercise confirms that our main results are consistent even while using this conservative measure of indirect time cost. Thus, I conclude that the indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms are larger than the direct effects across many robustness checks. As concluded earlier, any country that has a higher quality of transportation infrastructure has a comparative advantage in products that value timely delivery of inputs. Overall, timeliness in trade drives the comparative advantage pattern in processed goods, which mainly comes from the indirect channel.

Table 10.

Robust Measure of Indirect Time Intensity

article image
Dependent variable is 2013 aggregate export volume. All the regressions control for other factor interactions, and include country and product fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

D. Dropping the Extraction Sector

32. This robustness check analyzes the previous result by dropping the mining sector from the analysis. It might be a concern that the time sensitivity of the extraction sector is significantly different compared to the rest of the primary goods commodities, and including the extraction sector within the primary goods commodities might underestimate the importance of timeliness in trade for the primary goods commodities. Hence, I now run the above regression without including the extraction sector in this analysis. The results are presented below in Table 11. We can see that dropping the mining sector does not change the result of this paper. However, the direct effects seem more important than reported earlier for the sample containing all products.

Table 11.

Dropping the Extraction Sector

article image
Dependent variable is 2013 aggregate export volume. All the regressions control for other factor interactions, and include country and product fixed effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

33. Therefore, from all the robustness checks carried out in this paper, I conclude that the IV regression results in Table 3, is a well-specified model that can be used to explain the comparative advantage in processed goods arising from the indirect effects of timeliness in trade. The results reported in Table 3 could be a slight over-estimation of importance of timeliness in determining the comparative advantage between primary and processed goods via the indirect channel based on various robustness checks, but I believe that the baseline IV estimation analysis reported in Table 3 is consistent across many robustness checks. Hence, using the IV estimations in Table 3, I conclude that, on average, a 10 percent improvement in the transportation infrastructure quality of a country leads to approximately 5.9 percent increment in the export volume of primary goods and 12.8 percent increment in that of processed goods.

VIII. Conclusion

34. In this paper, I emphasize the role of a country’s ability to transport goods on time in explaining the trade pattern between primary and processed goods. In particular, to explain the comparative advantage in processed goods for countries with better quality of transportation infrastructure, I focus on the interaction between the intensity with which producers demand for the timely delivery of their intermediate inputs and countries’ quality of transportation infrastructure. This paper shows that a country’s ability to access intermediate inputs on time can become an important source of comparative advantage in processed goods. Through this paper, I add to the literature by focusing on the value of time in the management of production chain, which explains the trade pattern between primary and processed goods. That is, I assess a clear effect of the cost of time delays incurred while transporting intermediate inputs from upstream to downstream industries on the trade pattern.

35. This is achieved, first, by the construction of a measure for how intensively producers demand for the timely delivery of their bundle of intermediate inputs following the procedure carried out in Nunn (2007) in constructing a measure for contract intensity across industries. Such a measure for indirect time cost across industries is computed as the share weighted average of input specific direct time cost (computed in Hummels and Schaur, 2013), where the direct time cost is the ad-valorem tariff equivalent of consumers’ willingness to pay more for a good to be delivered one day earlier.

36. I test the effects of indirect time costs on the pattern of trade following the empirical specification as in Nunn (2007). The estimating equation explains export volumes by the interactions of a product characteristic with a country characteristic. Physical geography features of a country, such as the mean elevation and distance from the coast, are used as instruments of the quality of transportation infrastructure to address the endogeneity between trade and investment in the transportation infrastructure. Further, the paper controls for the magnification effects (endogeneity between availability of upstream activities in a region and the downstream production and exports) due to the correlation between downstream industrial demand for intermediate inputs and the time cost in accessing the inputs. In addition, a robust measure of indirect time sensitivity across products is constructed by eliminating the diagonal elements of the input-output matrix to address double counting. This work is then applied to the Latin American region to examine the effects of timeliness in trade on the comparative advantage pattern in processed goods.

37. I find that countries that can transport goods on time export relatively more in industries for which timely delivery of their inputs is of a higher concern. And, this comparative advantage pattern is stronger for processed goods than for primary goods, because processed goods face higher time costs in accessing their inputs than primary goods do. In other words, timeliness in accessing the intermediate inputs is an important source of comparative advantage for processed goods arising from the value of time in the management of production chain. Further, I find that both the direct and indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms are positive and significant for the sample containing all products, both primary and processed goods, and processed goods only. However, the indirect effects are larger than the direct effects. On the other hand, I do not find consistently significant effect of timeliness in trade for primary commodities. Further, the indirect effects of transportation infrastructure reforms for processed goods are significantly and consistently larger than those for primary goods across various empirical specifications. Hence, timeliness in trade is particularly important for processed goods. I conclude that, on average, a 10 percent improvement in the transportation infrastructure quality of a country leads to approximately 5.9 percent increment in the export volume of primary goods and 12.8 percent increment in that of processed goods.

IX. Extension to the Firm Heterogeneity CGE Model

38. Moving forward, I examine the effect of an improvement in the quality of transportation infrastructure, i.e. logistics performance index, on the trade volume of existing exporters (intensive margin), the number of new varieties being traded (extensive margin) and industry productivity. For this policy analysis, we use the newly developed GTAP firm-heterogeneity model (Akgul et al., 2015), which explicitly models consumers’ love-of-variety, endogenous changes in the number of varieties, and trade-induced productivity changes. We use this model primarily because it enables us to examine the effect of transportation infrastructure reforms on the trade pattern between primary and processed goods arising through two channels. In particular, improvement in timeliness in trade leads to both the technical change in reducing the fixed trade costs and the technical change in reducing the variable trade costs, which increase the number of firms entering into the export market and the export volume, respectively. Further, we investigate if these effects of trade facilitation are significantly different for processed goods industry than for primary goods industry.

39. Trade facilitation in the standard GTAP model is incorporated as an efficiency change in the use of factor inputs by considering its implications on the effective price and quantity of imports from an exporter (Hertel et al., 2001). In particular, a shock in the trade-augmenting technology variable that reduced variable trade costs, AMS, affects the total imports from the exporter applying the reform via three distinct effects: substitution towards this exporter, expansion effect (less is required to obtain the same composite aggregate import), and the import substitution effect. This model is extended in Mirza (2010) to link the logistics performance index to the trade-augmenting technology variable, AMS, in order to analyze the effect of investments in trade facilitation related capital goods on trade. We extend this development, first by incorporating both the direct and indirect effects of improvement in logistics performance index on the trade-augmenting technical shifter, AMS. This informs us on the effects of trade facilitation on the variable trade cost. We then use the firm-heterogeneity model in GTAP to link the logistics performance index to the model variable for the technical change in fixed trade costs, AVAFS, in order to analyze the direct and indirect effects of trade facilitation on the fixed trade cost (selection or variety effects).

40. In order to compute the required shock on the technical change variables that will mimic the change in the logistics performance index, we need to further understand the effects of improved trade facilitation. On the one hand, trade facilitation affects variable trade costs via reductions in factor input requirements of production and leads to lower per unit costs. This has direct effects on prices. On the other hand, trade facilitation affects fixed export costs via reductions in factor input requirements devoted to customs procedures associated with exporting. As a result, it is important to isolate the variable and fixed costs components of the factor input usage efficiency. In order to achieve that, we econometrically specify the export volume based on a two-part model. The first stage estimates the effect of transportation infrastructure reforms on the probability that we observe a positive trade volume. This informs us on the fixed cost component of trade facilitation effects. The second stage estimates the effect of infrastructure reforms on the trade volume conditional on participation in trade. This informs us on the variable cost component of trade facilitation effects. Using this empirical information, we model the interaction of country-specific quality of transportation infrastructure and industry-specific time intensity as both the fixed cost to enter into the export market and the variable cost of trade. We then implement a targeted shock in logistics performance index in the firm-heterogeneity model in GTAP and compare the implications in the processed and primary goods industries with a focus on extensive margin effects for South and East Asia low income region. In addition to the impacts on export participation and composition, we analyze the effects on factor returns and reallocations, and decompose the welfare impacts.

X. References

  • Akgul, Z., N. B. Villoría, and T. W. Hertel (in review), “Introducing Firm Heterogeneity into the GTAP Model,” Journal of Global Economic Analysis, Purdue University, 2015.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Akgul, Z., N. B. Villoria, and T. W. Hertel, 2015, “Theoretically-Consistent Parameterization of a Multi-sector Global Model with Heterogeneous Firms,” GTAP Working Paper.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Abe, Kazutomo, and Wilson, John S., 2008, “Governance, Corruption, and Trade in the Asia Pacific Region,” (Washington: World Bank)

  • Albarran, P., R. Carrasco, and A. Holl, 2009, “Transport Infrastructure, Sunk Costs and Firm’s Export Behavior,” Working Paper 09-22, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassa, B., 1965, “Trade Liberalization and Revealed Comparative Advantage,” The Manchester School, 33(2), 99123.

  • Baniya, S., 2015, “Effects of Time Cost on the Trade Pattern,” Presented at the Midwest International Trade Conference (October), Pennsylvania State University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bloom, David E., David Canning, and Jaypee Sevilla, 2001, “Economic Growth and the Demographic Transition,” NBER Working Paper No. 8685.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blyde, J., 2012, “Paving the Road to Export: Assessing the Trade Impact of Road Quality,” International Economic Journal, pp. 119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clark, X, D. Dollar, and A. Micco, 2004, “Port efficiency, maritime transport costs, and bilateral trade,” Journal of Development Economics, 75, 417450.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cosar, A. K., and P. Fajgelbaum, 2013, “Internal Geography, International Trade, and Regional Specialization,” NBER Working Paper No. 19697.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cosar, A. K., and B. Demir, 2014, “Domestic Road Infrastructure and International Trade: Evidence from Turkey,” Koc University-TUSIAD Economic Research Forum Working Papers 1406, Koc University-TUSIAD Economic Research Forum.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V., 1980, “The General Validity of the Law of Comparative Advantage,” Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 88(5) (October), pp. 94157.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V., 2004, “Local Comparative Advantage: Trade Costs and the Pattern of Trade,” manuscript, University of Michigan.

  • Dixit, Avinash, and Victor Norman, 1980, “The Gains from Free Trade,” The Warwick Economics Research Paper Series (TWERPS) 173, University of Warwick, Department of Economics.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, S., C. Freund, and C. S. Pham, 2010, “Trading on Time,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 92(1) (February), pp.166173.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Duranton, G., P. Morrow, and M. A. Turner, 2013, “Roads and Trade: Evidence from the U.S.,” forthcoming, The Review of Economic Studies.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Escaith, Hubert, and Satoshi Inomata, 2013, “Geometry of Global Value Chains in East Asia: The Role of Industrial Networks and Trade Policies,” GLOBAL VALUE CHAINS IN A CHANGING WORLD, 135157 (Geneva: WTO Publications).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Evans, C. L., and J. Harrigan, 2005, “Distance, Time, and Specialization: Lean Retailing in General Equilibrium,” American Economic Review, 95(1), pp. 292313.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Francois, Joseph, and Miriam Manchin, 2007, “Institutions, Infrastructure, and Trade,” IIDE Discussion Papers 20070401, Institute for International and Development Economics.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frink, C., A. Mattoo, and I.C. Neagu, 2000, “Trade in International Maritime Service: How Much does Policy Matter?mimeo (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gamberoni, Elisa, Rainer Lanz, and Roberta Piermartini, 2010, “Timeliness and contract enforceability in intermediate goods trade,” Policy Research Working Paper Series 5482 (Washington: The World Bank).