Benefits of Global and Regional Financial Integration in Latin America

The timing is ripe to pursue greater regional financial integration in Latin America given the withdrawal of some global banks from the region and the weakening of growth prospects. Important initiatives are ongoing to foster financial integration. Failure to capitalize on this would represent a significant missed opportunity. This paper examines the scope for further global and regional financial integration in Latin America, based on economic fundamentals and comparisons to other emerging regions, and quantifies the potential macroeconomic gains that such integration could bring. The analysis suggests that closing the financial integration gap could boost GDP growth be ¼ - ¾ percentage point in these countries, on average.

Abstract

The timing is ripe to pursue greater regional financial integration in Latin America given the withdrawal of some global banks from the region and the weakening of growth prospects. Important initiatives are ongoing to foster financial integration. Failure to capitalize on this would represent a significant missed opportunity. This paper examines the scope for further global and regional financial integration in Latin America, based on economic fundamentals and comparisons to other emerging regions, and quantifies the potential macroeconomic gains that such integration could bring. The analysis suggests that closing the financial integration gap could boost GDP growth be ¼ - ¾ percentage point in these countries, on average.

I. Introduction: Time For More Regional Financial Integration in Latin America? 1

After a period of endemic economic and financial crises during the 1980s-90s, many Latin American (LA) countries opened up their previously closed economies to international financial institutions at the turn of the millennium, aiming to attract capital, gain technical expertise, and cushion themselves against regional instability. In some extreme cases, such as Mexico and Uruguay, the financial system came to be completely dominated by global banks, with few or no domestic banks remaining. In addition, their experience with financial crises prompted most LA countries to implement stricter financial regulations. This strategy of importing global institutions and know-how, together with tighter regulations, appeared to have served the region well: with the exception of the Argentine and Uruguayan crises of 2001-02, no LA economy has suffered a financial crisis in the new century. In fact, LA even emerged from the global financial crisis (GFC) of 2008-09 largely unscathed, with high commodity prices fortuitously buffering export revenues and growth in this resource-rich region.

Nevertheless, the GFC marked a turning point. In its aftermath, global banks, particularly from the U.S. and Europe, began retreating from LA and other emerging markets to their home bases and core businesses, weakened by slow growth in advanced economies, and encumbered by significantly tighter banking regulations. Adding to this, the end of the commodity super-cycle and slowdown in China saw the main growth driver of the LA region evaporate, indicating a new reality and a need to identify alternative, non-commodity avenues for growth. Developing these new avenues would, in turn, require fresh investment and deep financial markets. The retrenchment of global banks from LA therefore began at a time when the countries of the region would face the need to further develop and deepen their financial systems and markets rather than see them shrink. While this was certainly inopportune, it has perhaps created an opportune moment for LA countries to look to each other for potential synergies that could provide the scale and support their financial systems need. In other words, if current circumstances preclude the possibility of advancing financial integration at a global level, the timing may now be as propitious as ever to investigate the scope for enhanced regional integration in LA, and to act on this.

Regional integration would not be a substitute for the goal of expanding ties with the global economy, but rather a complementary sub-set of this broader goal. Given the current trend among global banks to continue withdrawing from LA and other emerging market economies, increased regional integration in LA, to the degree economically feasible, can serve as a useful step towards further global integration in the future. If, for example, on account of regional integration, LA countries were to assimilate technical know-how, and regulatory and operational best practices from regional leaders, this would raise financial standards across the region, leaving the countries well-prepared for eventual deeper linkages with advanced economies and others.

There are important initiatives underway to promote financial integration within LA, which seem to have garnered a considerable degree of political support. For example, the Pacific Alliance (PA) countries (Mexico, Colombia, Chile and Peru) put forward the Latin American Integrated Market (MILA) initiative in 2011, which seeks to establish a unified capital market among these countries. While initial progress of the MILA initiative has been limited, and activity on the platform minimal, this is likely due to a lack of coordination between the PA countries on technical, logistical and regulatory elements, rather than inadequate political support. In addition, the relatively dormant Mercosur alliance (comprising Brazil, Argentina, Uruguay, Paraguay and Venezuela), created in 1991 with the ultimate objective of establishing a common market among its members through harmonized regulations and taxes, may have a chance at revival given the recent change of regime in Argentina.

Taking all this into account, the timing seems ripe to pursue greater regional financial integration in LA; failure to capitalize on this situation would represent a significant missed opportunity. This paper examines the scope for further financial integration in LA, based on economic fundamentals and comparisons to other emerging market regions, and quantifies the potential macroeconomic gains that such integration could bring. The analysis focuses more specifically on seven Latin American economies: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Panama, Peru and Uruguay (LA-7). The paper is structured as follows. Section II defines the concept of financial integration, and describes the various indices of financial integration constructed and used in our analysis. Section III examines whether there is a deficit of global and regional integration in LA, compared to other regions, as well as to countries’ own economic fundamentals. Section IV lays out the pros and cons of greater financial integration in LA, and quantifies the potential macroeconomic gains from integration. Section V concludes.

II. Definition and Measurement of Financial Integration

This section defines the concept of financial integration (II A), and proposes a number of indicators to measure it, based on a principal component analysis (II B). These indicators are used in the analytical sections III and IV.

A. Defining the Concept of Financial Integration

Financial integration is the process through which the financial markets of two or more countries or regions become more connected to each other. This process can take many forms, including cross-border capital flows (for example, firms raising funds on capital markets cross-border), foreign participation in domestic markets (for example, a parent bank’s ability to set up a subsidiary abroad), sharing of information and practices among financial institutions, or unification of market infrastructures. It can have a regional or global dimension, depending on whether a country’s financial market is more closely connected to neighboring countries or to global financial centers/institutions.

Financial integration is thus a multi-faceted concept with no universally-accepted definition. From a theoretical point of view, integration may be signaled by the convergence of the prices of assets with the same characteristics (law of one price). Perfect integration exists if similar assets have the same price even if they are traded on different markets. To work with a more tractable indicator, we define financial integration by two main criteria:

  • The first criterion is the degree of cross-border financial activity. In this sense, the concept of integration is very close to that of “financial globalization”, defined as “the extent to which countries are linked through cross-border financial holdings, and proxied by the sum of countries’ gross external assets and liabilities relative to GDP” IMF (2008). According to this criterion, any barrier to exchange or market access impedes the free movement of capital and limits integration.

  • The second criterion is the degree of convergence and consolidation across markets. Financial openness and free access are not sufficient conditions for integration. Two markets can be perfectly open to each other but still imperfectly integrated because, for example, they keep very distinct market structures.2 In their definition of an integrated financial market, Baele and others (2004, pp6) include the feature that market participants “face a single set of rules when they decide to deal with financial instruments and/or services.” According to this second criterion, a single (common and fully harmonized) market is the ultimate form of financial integration.

Importantly, these two criteria are interconnected. The convergence of market structures facilitates and creates incentives for cross-border capital flows, while financial openness offers opportunities to import financial institutions and know-how from abroad, paving the way for greater harmonization across markets.

In practice, financial integration is always imperfect. Segmentation stems from various sources, including capital flow restrictions (some of which have a prudential purpose), technical constraints hindering cross-border flows, insufficient harmonization of financial regulations, cultural barriers, and country-specific risks that deter foreign investors.

B. Building Indicators of Financial Integration

Building on the earlier defined concept, our paper constructs a number of composite indicators of financial integration that combine information from various dimensions of the concept (Table 1).

Our baseline composite index combines financial openness and financial convergence. The first component is the de facto openness of the financial account measured by the sum of stocks of foreign assets and liabilities as a share of GDP. The second component is the regional dispersion of stock market returns measured by the standard deviation of returns of Morgan Stanley Capital Interactions (MSCI) indices across countries of the same region (lower standard deviations would imply greater convergence). Although this indicator of regional convergence is widely used in the literature (Baele and others, 2004), it presents obvious drawbacks (in particular, differences in returns may be related to idiosyncratic risks) but the analysis is limited by data availability. To combine the two indicators, a principal component analysis (PCA) is used, where the standardized variables’ weights are the squared factor loadings.3

The analysis also uses three alternative integration indices:

  • The first alternative index replaces the traditional broad indicator of external openness (stock of external assets plus liabilities as a ratio to GDP) with the narrower external liability-to-GDP ratio. Indeed, some countries may hold large proportions of financial assets abroad, while having a low level of de facto integration. These assets, which may coexist with capital controls, could reflect past capital outflows (for example, Argentina) or large current account surpluses (for example, China). Limiting the measure of openness to include only external liabilities is one way to circumvent this problem.

  • In the second alternative indicator, the first two components are identical to those used in the baseline index but a third component is added, which is the ratio of private sector credit provided by banks to GDP. There are two reasons why a measure of financial depth may enter the integration index. First, since financial integration allows savers to invest in a broader range of investment and risk-sharing instruments, while enabling borrowers to tap a broader range of financing and risk management instruments, at home and abroad, the concepts of integration and depth are closely related. Second, to reap the full benefits of integration and be a meaningful contributor to an integrated playing field, individual markets need to have a certain size. Thus, the depth criterion excludes markets that are too small even if they meet the other two criteria.

  • The third alternative index provides a better picture of regional integration by including a measure of relative regional openness (ratio of regional assets and liabilities to total foreign assets and liabilities of a given country), alongside global financial openness and regional convergence. The intuition is that countries are regionally integrated in a meaningful way when they fulfill three conditions: they have to be (1) open globally, (2) relatively more open to their neighbors, (3) and present signs of financial convergence. We include global openness (defined in absolute terms) in addition to the regional openness measure (defined in relative terms) in order to ensure that the concept of “regional integration” is meaningful and captures both the scale and the direction of financial flows. For example, a country could be a closed economy with the exception of linkages with one neighbor. If we did not include the global openness measure, this country would appear to be highly regionally integrated despite the fact that it is a de facto closed economy.

Table 1.

Financial Integration (FI) Composite Indicators

article image

Divides the world into 1 “region” of advanced economies and 7 emerging market regions: Africa, Asia, Europe, Latin America, Middle East and North Africa, Commonwealth of Independent States, and other small states.

Captures the integration of both emerging and advanced economies within one of 4 large geographic regions: Asia, Europe, Western Hemisphere and other countries.

Observes the degree to which international financial partner countries are geographically close or distant. First, distances between country pairs are normalized as one minus the distance divided by the global maximum such that near countries are scored close to 1 and far countries are scoredclose to zero. Distances are normalized by dividing all distances by the maximum distance between any 2 countries. Next, normalized distances areweighted by the reporting country’s share of either external assets plus liabilities or just the external liabilities vis-a-vis each of its partners.

Several variants of the relative regional openness concept are developed, as defining regions can be challenging (see Table 1). The first variant is an eight-region world (advanced economies, Africa, Asia, emerging Europe, Latin America and the Caribbean, Middle East and North Africa, Commonwealth of Independent States, and other small states), based on IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) classifications, which emphasize regionalism among emerging/developing economies. The second approach consolidates the world into just four regions (Asia, Europe, the Western Hemisphere, and the rest of the world) and captures the observed behavior that emerging/developing countries tend to integrate with nearby advanced economies (for instance, Mexico with the United States, or eastern with western Europe). The third variant replaces pre-determined regions with distance-based weights whose values rise when countries are geographically close. Bilateral financial positions (using external assets and liabilities) are then weighted with this distance, such that the regional openness indicator increases continuously when countries are more financially open to geographically close partners. Finally, the fourth variant uses the same methodology as the third, but focuses solely on external liabilities.

III. Is There a Deficit of Financial Integration in Latin America?

This section assesses the extent of global and regional integration in LA, based on a descriptive comparison to other regions (III A), and an econometric analysis to estimate an integration gap relative to what would be predicted by countries’ (or regions’) own macroeconomic fundamentals (III B).

A. How Does Integration in Latin America Compare with That in Other Regions?

By the turn of the century, most countries in LA had embarked on a process of financial liberalization. This process was characterized by a reduction of impediments to cross-border financial transactions, increased participation of foreign banks in the local banking systems, and greater cross-border capital market activity. Today most LA countries have fewer de jure restrictions on capital flows than Asian economies do (Galindo, Izquierdo, and Rojas-Suarez 2010).

However, de facto integration of LA with the rest of the world remains low. To assess the degree of financial integration, figures 1 and 2 use three measures of cross-border capital flows:4

  • The first, and most common, is international investment positions (IIP), presented here as the sum of foreign asset and liability stocks outstanding. While the dollar value of international assets and liabilities among all LA countries has grown over the last decade, the region has not increased its international exposure (foreign assets plus liabilities in percent of regional GDP). Nor has the region’s relative importance as a partner in international finance improved, unlike the allocation of international financial positions vis-à-vis emerging Asia, which doubled between 2004 and 2013 (figure 1).

  • The second measure looks at cross-border claims held by Bank for International Settlement (BIS) reporting banks. These data include not only traditional loans (across-borders) but also portfolio equity and debt holdings of BIS banks. Here again, the broad group of all LA countries has garnered a relatively low 3-5 percent of BIS claims over the last 10 years (figure 2, left panel).

  • The third indicator uses the datasets of bilateral portfolio and FDI stocks outstanding reported in the IMF’s Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey (CPIS) and Coordinated Direct Investment Survey (CDIS)5. While technically these are components of the IIP data, their bilateral nature permits investigation of regional integration. This indicator re-iterates the relatively low (and potentially declining) participation of the LA region, while highlighting the importance of FDI flows relative to portfolio investments (figure 2, right panel).

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Global Financial Integration in Latin America and the Caribbean: International Investment Positions1

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 001; 10.5089/9781475568684.001.A001

Sources: IMF, Balance of Payments Statistics.1 Values are not consolidated forintra-regional trade.
Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Global Financial Integration in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC): International Bank Claims, Portfolio, and FDP1

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 001; 10.5089/9781475568684.001.A001

Sources: IMF, Balance of Payments Statistics; BIS, Consolidated Banking Statistics; IMF, Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey; and IMF, Coordinated Direct Investment Survey.1 Values are not consolidated for intra-regional trade.2 BIS bank lending, immediate borrower basis. Foreign claims includes cross-border lending, holdings of debt and equity securities, and local currency lending to residents.3 Aggregate assets plus liabilities of Latin America, in percent of aggregate assets plus liabilities of all reporting countries.

Intraregional integration in LA also seems less advanced than in other emerging market regions. Figure 3 shows that there is greater intra-regional investment, through FDI and portfolio flows, among the ASEAN countries, reflecting both the fruits of long trade and financial negotiations, as well as the important presence of a large, diversified trade and financial center (i.e. Singapore). Regarding the evolution of regional integration over time, the available indicators of financial regionalism depict different trends depending on how it is measured. For portfolio assets, there is an apparent diversification away from regional assets in LA as the intraregional share has fallen from over 10 percent to under 5 percent since 2008 (figure 4, left panel). Data on FDI, only available since 2009, also suggest a declining trend (figure 4, right panel). However, indicators of cross-border bank lending do point to some momentum in LA. Table 2 highlights the expanding positions that Latin BIS reporting banks are taking in neighboring countries.6 It appears that the share of claims on other LA-7 countries has risen significantly in Chile and Brazil since 2005.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Intra-Regional Component of Global Integration: Portfolio and FDI Investments, 2014

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 001; 10.5089/9781475568684.001.A001

Sources: IMF, Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey (CDIS); IMF, Coordinated Direct Investment Survey (CDIS).1 Numbers in parenthesis reportthe share of intra-regional assets or liabilities in total assets or liabilities of the region.2 LA7 Includes: Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Panama, Peru, and Uruguay.3 Emerging Asia includes: Brunei, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia, Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam.4 Non-Euro Emerging Europe includes: Bulgaria, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Russia.5 Euro Emerging Europe includes: Cyprus, Estonia, Greece, Latvia, Malta, Slovak Republic, and Slovenia.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Evolution of Intra-Regional Integration

(Stocks outstanding in percent of group GDP)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2017, 001; 10.5089/9781475568684.001.A001

Source: IMF, Coordinated Direct Investment Survey (CDIS).1 LA-7 Includes: Brasil, Chile, Colombia, Mexcio, Panama, Peru, and Uruguary.2 Emerging Asia includes: Brunei, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia, Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam.3 Non-Euro Emerging Europe includes: Bulgaria, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Russia.4 Euro Emerging Europe includes: Cyprus, Estonia, Greece, Latvia, Malta, Slovak Republic, and Slovenia.
Table 2.

Consolidated Foreign Claims on the World by BIS Reporting Banks in Four Latin American Countries

(Percent of GDP)

article image
Source: BIS, Consolidated Banking Statistics.

Cross-border mergers and acquisitions provide anecdotal evidence of global fragmentation and increased regional integration after the global financial crisis (GFC). Although the trend in LA seems less pronounced than in Emerging Europe or Emerging Asia, several global banks have withdrawn from LA since the GFC to refocus on their core markets and activities, and regional or domestic banks have taken over their activities. For example, in 2015 Grupo Financiero Inbursa of Mexico purchased the banking operations of Standard Chartered in Brazil, and in 2012 Corpbanca (Chile) acquired Santander’s banks in Colombia. LA-7 institutions are also seizing the opportunity to expand into Central America such as when Grupo Aval, the largest conglomerate in Colombia, acquired BBVA activities in Panama in 2014, and when the Ficohsa group of Panama purchased Citibank’s operations in Honduras and Nicaragua in 2015. Non-bank financial institutions have also been subject to advanced country divestitures. One of the largest moves was BBVA’s sale of its pension fund management firms in Chile, Colombia, Mexico and Peru to regional and local buyers in 2012-14.

Another dimension of regional integration is the Integrated Market for LA (MILA) initiative that began in 2011. Unlike the Pacific Alliance (PA), whose agenda for integration is set by the political leadership of member countries (Chile, Colombia, Mexico and Peru), MILA is a private sector initiative of the four PA stock exchanges and custodians/depositories that seek to mutually increase trading volumes by facilitating cross-border trading. Early accomplishments include the cross-listing of share prices on all exchanges and the full cross-listing of initial public offers7. Furthering integration efforts will require agreement on facilities for direct trading across exchanges; payment and settlement facilities to mitigate counterparty risks; and broadening of securities to include fixed income instruments. Beyond the MILA framework, regional exchanges are also integrating through ownership agreements. In 2009, the Bolsa Mexicana purchased an ownership stake in Bolsa de Lima, and in 2015, BM&F Bovespa bought into the Santiago Exchange. Through cross ownership relationships, exchanges can explore synergies in trading platforms, settlement processes and the cross-listing of securities.

B. Measuring the Extent of Financial Integration of Latin American Countries

The measurement of financial integration can be refined further. Simple cross-country comparisons may paint a distorted picture of the degree of integration of Latin American markets relative to other regions—for instance, because countries that are less economically advanced often have shallower financial markets by nature. This section attempts to quantify the extent to which Latin American markets are under-integrated given their economic fundamentals, by controlling for factors such as the level of economic development (proxied by GDP per capita in PPP dollars), trade openness (exports plus imports divided by GDP), countries’ past history of financial crises (as compiled by Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009), the level of public debt as a ratio to GDP (which, as a stock variable, cannot be easily modified by the government), and the quality of the institutional framework (measured by the investment profile subcomponent of the PRS Group’s International Country Risk Guide Index8). Variables that are more directly and immediately affected by economic policy, such as the extent of capital controls, are not included, as the purpose of our econometric analysis is not to provide the best fit for the data but to control for exogenous factors.

The models relate financial integration to a set of control variables. In each specification, a measure of financial integration is regressed (either the baseline or alternative composite indices of financial integration presented in Section II.B or their subcomponents) on its macroeconomic determinants and fixed effects. The degree of under or over-integration is then calculated as the difference between the estimated country (or region) fixed effect and the sample average of all country (or region) fixed effects. As the purpose of the regressions is to filter out the effect of certain fundamentals and not to interpret a causal model, the endogeneity problem, inherent in this type of analysis, is less of a concern. The following equation is estimated over a sample of 67 countries between the mid-1980s and 2014:

FIit=β.Xit+αi+ɛit

where FIit denotes the financial integration indicator, Xit is a vector of control variables, and αi are the country fixed effects.

The econometric results (Tables 3 to 7) confirm that the LA-7 countries are under-integrated as a whole, although there are important differences between countries, and across the various dimensions of financial integration. In each model, the sign of the control variables is consistent with priors. The main result is that although the LA-7 countries do not appear under-integrated from the perspective of international cross-border capital flows, once broader measures of integration are used through the composite integration indexes, these countries do appear to be under-integrated on the whole, even after controlling for fundamentals. The extent of integration varies across the LA-7, with Panama appearing more integrated than the rest in most specifications, likely owing to its sizeable offshore financial sector and role as a regional hub for Central American countries.

  • Table 3 shows the outcomes of various models explaining the degree of global financial openness (measured either as the ratio of gross external assets and liabilities to GDP or as the liability ratio—both in logarithmic form). The results suggest that LA-7 countries are relatively well integrated from an openness perspective compared to the sample average, but this result is partly driven by Panama and Chile, which clearly show a greater degree of openness than the other countries.

  • Table 4 presents the results using the baseline consolidated index of financial integration (described in section II B). After combining the dimensions of financial openness and financial convergence, it appears that the LA-7 countries are indeed under-integrated, with the exception of Panama, which shows a level of integration in line with the sample average after controlling for fundamentals. This result suggests that the relatively high degree of global openness of countries such as Chile and Peru in Table 3, is more than offset by the lack of regional convergence exhibited by their financial markets.

  • Table 5 reports the results using the first alternative consolidated index of financial integration, which combines convergence and external liabilities-to-GDP, as a measure of openness. The results using this narrower measure of openness, which helps preclude cases where large external assets do not correspond to integration, corroborate the findings of the baseline index. With the exception of Panama, LA-7 countries show a degree of under-integration virtually identical to the baseline results presented in Table 4. In this case, Panama stands out as the only LA-7 country whose level of integration is not only in line with, but above the sample average.

  • Table 6 presents the findings using the second alternative consolidated index of integration, incorporating three components: openness, convergence and depth. The results support the outcomes of Tables 4 and 5, confirming that even with the added dimension of depth, the LA-7 countries—excluding Panama—are under-integrated relative to the sample average, after controlling for fundamentals. An interesting nuance of these results is that after adding depth, the integration outcomes for the LA-7 worsen relative to the two-component indexes, with the exception of Panama and Chile. Panama’s result is not only above the sample average but significantly stronger than its outcomes using the two-component indexes of integration. Regarding Chile, while the integration outcome is still negative indicating under-integration, the magnitude of under-integration is halved relative to previous results, suggesting a relatively deep market. Combined with Chile’s positive result in the openness models presented in Table 3, one could conjecture that Chile’s under-integration comes largely from a lack of convergence with the region rather than a lack of global openness or financial depth. For the remaining five LA-7 countries, only the results of Table 3—gauging global openness—were positive, putting the onus of their under-integration on the lack of regional convergence and depth of their financial markets.

  • Table 7 displays the findings of the third alternative consolidated index of integration, which includes a measure for relative regional openness, in addition to the measure for global financial openness and regional convergence. The results including the regional measure stand out from the previous findings in that all LA-7 countries, including Panama, exhibit under-integration relative to the sample average. That said, Panama still shows the lowest degree of under-integration among the LA-7 countries. This may suggest that Panama’s high degree of financial integration, demonstrated in the previous results, largely reflects extra- rather than intra-regional integration. Another interesting finding using this index is Brazil, Colombia, Peru and Uruguay are less under-integrated relative to the sample than Chile and Mexico. Mexico’s result may reflect its higher degree of integration with the United States (which is not included in the same regional grouping as Mexico for this exercise) compared with its integration with the region. In the case of Chile, which showed a relatively high degree of openness and depth compared to other LA-7 countries in the previous indexes, the results confirm our expectation that the interconnections of its relatively deep financial markets principally stem outside the region rather than within.

Table 3.

Determinants of Global Financial Openness

article image
Notes: Time dummies have been incorporated in all specifications.

The OLS regressions are ordinary least squares regressions with standard errors adjusted for clustering at the country level for a panel of 67 countries from 1986-2011. Selected country and/or regional dummies are included.

The FE regressions estimate country fixed effects for all countries in the sample, but only the LA7 results are reported in this table.

The investment profile subcomponent of the International Country Risk Guide political risk index is used to gauge institutional quality.

Reinhart and Rogoff indicator of past banking crises.

Demeaned estimates: fixed effect estimates minus a sample average of fixed effects. Robust T-statistics are in italics. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 4.

Baseline Financial Integration Index with Two Components 1/

article image
Notes: Time dummies have been incorporated in all specifications.

Dependent variable is a principle component from 2 variables: openness (external assets+liabilities as a ratio to GDP) and convergence. This is the baseline indicator described in Table 1.

The OLS regressions are ordinary least squares regressions with standard errors adjusted for clustering at the country level for a panel of 67 countries from 1986-2011. Selected country and/or regional dummies are included.

The FE regression estimates country fixed effects for all countries in the sample; only LA7 results are reported.

The investment profile subcomponent of the International Country Risk Guide political risk index is used to gauge institutional quality.

Reinhart and Rogoff indicator of past banking crises.

Demeaned estimates: fixed effect estimates minus a sample average of fixed effects. Robust T-statistics are in italics. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 5.

Alternative Financial Integration Index with Two Components 1/

article image
Notes: Time dummies have been incorporated in all specifications.

Dependent variable is the principle component from 2 variables: external liabilities as a ratio to GDP and convergence. This is financial integration, alternate 1 described in table 1.

The OLS regressions are ordinary least squares regressions with standard errors adjusted for clustering at the country level for a panel of 67 countries from 1986-2011. Selected country and/or regional dummies are included.

The FE regression estimates country fixed effects for all countries in the sample; only LA7 results are reported.

The investment profile subcomponent of the International Country Risk Guide political risk index is used to gauge institutional quality.

Reinhart and Rogoff indicator of past banking crises.

Demeaned estimates: fixed effect estimates minus a sample average of fixed effects. Robust T-statistics are in italics. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 6.

Alternative Financial Integration Index with Three Components, including Financial Depth 1/

article image
Notes: Time dummies have been incorporated in all specifications.

Dependent variable is the principle component from 3 variables: openness, convergence and depth. This is the financial integration alternate 2 described in table 1.

The OLS regressions are ordinary least squares regressions with standard errors adjusted for clustering at the country level for a panel of 66 countries from 1986-2011. Selected country and/or regional dummies are included.

The FE regression estimates country fixed effects for all countries in the sample; only LA7 results are reported.

The investment profile subcomponent of the International Country Risk Guide political risk index is used to gauge institutional quality.

Reinhart and Rogoff indicator of past banking crises.

Demeaned estimates: fixed effect estimates minus a sample average of fixed effects. Robust T-statistics are in italics. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 7.

Alternative Financial Integration Index with Three Components, including Regional Openness 1/

article image
Notes: Time dummies have been incorporated in all specifications.

Dependent variable is the principle component from 3 variables: global openness, regional convergence and regional integration based on 8 regions. This is the finanical integration alternate 3.1 described in table 1.

The OLS regressions are ordinary least squares regressions with standard errors adjusted for clustering at the country level for a panel of 66 countries from 1986-2011. Selected country and/or regional dummies are included.

The FE regression estimates country fixed effects for all countries in the sample; only LA7 results are reported.

The investment profile subcomponent of the International Country Risk Guide political risk index is used to gauge institutional quality.

Demeaned estimates: fixed effect estimates minus a sample average of fixed effects. Robust T-statistics are in italics. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

IV. Benefits of Further Integration in Latin America

This section describes the benefits of greater financial integration (IV A), and provides a quantitative estimate of these benefits on growth using econometric analysis (IV B).

A. What Are the Pros and Cons of Greater Financial Integration?

By expanding possible financing options and vehicles for savings in a country, global financial integration can enhance financial development, which in turn is linked to higher economic growth (Sahay and others, 2015). There are at least three key channels of transmission to growth. First, integration may stimulate capital accumulation through financial deepening in the host country. If capital is brought from outside, competition among financial institutions can be enhanced, particularly when the domestic financial sector contains few institutions and maintains high spreads between borrowing and lending rates; and economies of scale can be exploited by pooling larger amounts of savings. The monetary transmission mechanism can also be enhanced if the banking sector becomes more competitive. All these factors are likely to lower borrowing costs, and stimulate investment. Second, better resource allocation and importation of technology and knowledge may create opportunities for efficiency gains, and boost productivity, which is another source of growth. Third, financial integration can also promote growth indirectly by exposing policy decisions and corporate actions to greater financial market scrutiny.

In addition to raising the growth trend, financial integration may foster economic resilience and reduce volatility around this trend. Output volatility can be mitigated through two main factors. First, financial integration is likely to increase the depth of financial markets leading to greater market liquidity: possibilities to buy and sell securities increase with the emergence of new players and new instruments. Second, financial integration offers new opportunities for risk-sharing and inter-temporal consumption smoothing through the diversification of portfolios across asset classes, sectors and countries. Overall, this stabilization effect should be particularly beneficial in LA countries, where production bases are concentrated, and there is a heavy dependence on agricultural activities or the extraction of natural resources (IMF, 2015a).9

On top of these overarching advantages, regional financial integration can bring a number of additional benefits for both the home and host countries:

  • Cross-border financial activity (bank and nonbank) both follows and can be followed by cross-border trade, and thus could help foster wider regional economic integration. A larger common market creates new growth opportunities, which may be important in LA in a context of lower commodity prices and tighter global financial conditions.

  • Regional banks (robustly supervised with sufficient high quality capital to support their cross border operations) and regional markets may have a better understanding of regional needs than global institutions. They may be able to provide expertise particularly suited to the host country, such as in the area of improving financial inclusion. The importance of commodity exports across the region is also fertile ground for transplanting expertise in trade and industrial credit.

  • At the regional level, capital market integration creates scope for economies of scale, especially when individual markets are relatively small. In many LA countries, the small size of national markets, in some cases due to domestic regulatory factors, constrains financial sector growth and efficiency, contributing to higher costs, a narrower range of financial products, and the exclusion of many from formal financial services. Addressing regulatory limitations and facilitating regional integration could help loosen these constraints by allowing governments, financial intermediaries, and corporations to access a regional market with greater depth and liquidity. In addition, larger inflows of foreign capital to the region may follow, as a larger and more liquid regional market may be more attractive to international investors.

  • Regional banks can fill the hole left by retrenching global banks. Since the global financial crisis, financial pressures and increased regulatory oversight have led some global institutions to reduce their cross-border activities and pull back into their core markets (IMF, 2015a). Responding to the withdrawal of these banks, intra-regional acquisition activity has been growing rapidly in a number of emerging markets, particularly in Asia and emerging Europe (BIS, 2014). This trend has so far been less pronounced in LA, where it has been more common for domestic institutions to absorb the assets of departing global banks. Regional integration could help avoid increased consolidation of domestic financial sector activity and mitigate a possible credit squeeze if North-American and Spanish banks were to continue reducing their presence in the region. While this strategy could lead to the emergence of large regional banks, and raise the risk of concentrated regional markets, it would promote greater competition and diversification of risks within domestic markets.

  • Regional integration can also alleviate the pressure on domestic markets arising from the significant growth of the non-bank financial sector (particularly pension funds) in LA countries in recent years. Current regulations governing pension fund investments in LA countries compel the funds to invest the vast majority of their portfolios in domestic assets. Given the relatively small size of many LA financial markets, the investment options available to these pension funds are severely limited, and most end up overweight in domestic government securities. Although the motivation driving these investment restrictions is likely the preservation of savings and financial stability, the development of domestic financial markets in most LA countries has not kept up with the growth of their pension funds, and these restrictions may therefore paradoxically lead to the creation of bubbles and instability. If regional integration, through the harmonization of regulations and more coordinated supervision, were to widen pension funds’ permissible investment options to include other countries in the region, this could be part of the solution.

  • Almost all LA countries currently face the urgent need to improve their physical infrastructure. However, upgrades to logistics and transport infrastructure typically require sizeable investments, necessitating deep and well-developed financial markets. While pension funds in some LA countries have invested in domestic infrastructure, the caps on their permissible investments in such projects are dwarfed by the size of these projects. Thus, given the absence of deep domestic markets, the need for economies of scale for investment is yet another reason to assess the possibility of advancing regional financial integration in LA. Investment vehicles could then be established at a regional level to pool resources for infrastructure projects around the region.

Financial integration has its fair share of critics, and the aforementioned advantages of global and regional integration are not assured unless accompanying safeguards are in place, particularly enhanced supervision. Cross-border financial activity also brings risks, including adverse spillovers if there is insufficient official capacity to exercise necessary oversight. Critics of financial integration point to financial crises following capital account liberalizations in Mexico (1994), east Asia (1997) and Russia (1998). In fact, efforts to identify empirically positive results from financial integration often struggle to generalize results and must narrow the findings to selected forms of integration (FDI and equity are statistically favored over debt instruments), or acknowledge necessary preconditions such as high levels of economic development, institutional quality, or financial development. Greater integration could also render countries’ macro-prudential policies easier to circumvent, through cross-border leakages and provision of credit (IMF, 2014).

One particular concern is that increased cross-border banking sector integration may adversely impact financial stability through the transmission of international shocks. Giannetti and Laeven (2012) and Jeon, Olivero, and Wu (2013) describe how stresses in the home country of parent banks widen the funding spreads in subsidiary and branch markets and even pit operations in different emerging market countries against each other for liquidity from parent banks.10 Degryse and others (2009) find that foreign banks tend to reinforce credit segmentation whether they enter via greenfield investments and target the most transparent and credit worthy borrowers, or via mergers/acquisitions in which case the composition of loan portfolio credit quality changes little. Furthermore, evidence on financial integration and foreign bank presence leading to enhanced financial inclusion and depth is mixed: several studies including Detragiache, Gupta, and Tressel (2008) and Claessens and van Horen (2014) associate the prominence of foreign banks with lower credit-to-GDP ratios in developing countries.

Nonetheless, proponents of integration maintain that although integration does bring costs and benefits, the latter outweigh the former, particularly when pre-conditions for successful integration, such as consolidated supervision and enhanced cross-border information-sharing, are in place. For example, Rancière, Tornell, and Westermann (2006, 2008) show that the direct positive effects of financial liberalization on growth outweigh the negative indirect effect of increasing the propensity for crises. In their analysis of financial globalization, Kose and others (2006, pp1) also recognize the existence of conflicting results but conclude that the empirical literature “lends some qualified support to the view that developing countries can benefit from financial globalization, but with many nuances. On the other hand, there is little systematic evidence to support widely-cited claims that financial globalization by itself leads to deeper and costlier developing country growth crises.”

B. How Large Could Be the Macroeconomic Gains from Greater Financial Integration in Latin America?

To quantify the benefits of further integration in LA, a model relating financial integration to economic growth is estimated. The specification, which follows Beck and Levine (2004) and Sahay and others (2015), includes the standard control variables of growth equations: initial income per capita, trade openness, inflation, the government expenditure-to-GDP ratio, the investment-to-GDP ratio, population growth, and several measures of institutional framework quality (proxied by the ICRG indicators of country risk). The sample is similar to the one used in section III.B, and includes 76 countries between the mid-1980s and 2014.

In light of the endogeneity of the integration variable with respect to growth, the baseline model uses an instrumental variable (IV) panel estimator with the following instruments: the first lag of the integration variable; the capital controls indicator by Fernández and others (2015); the occurrence of a banking crisis 10 years earlier; and a subcomponent of the ICRG political risk index, which describes the extent to which profits can be transferred or repatriated out of a country. All the instruments are assumed to impact integration directly but affect growth indirectly. Admittedly, it is very difficult to find fully exogenous instruments in a macroeconomic setting. This paper assumes that the institutional framework (capital controls, profit repatriation rules) is exogenous with respect to growth, which may be justified by the fact that these variables are slow-moving.

The estimated equation is therefore:

yit=αit+β1*FIit+β2*Xit+ɛit

where yit denotes GDP growth, FIit the financial integration indicator defined earlier in section II.B, Xit the control variables, and αi is the fixed effect. Time dummies are also included in some specifications.

After correcting for endogeneity, financial integration—proxied with the baseline index of Table 1—is found to be positively correlated with growth. In models without this correction, integration is either statistically insignificant or negatively correlated to growth. With the IV correction, the elasticity is clearly positive, regardless of the number of control variables (Table 8, columns 1–3), or if the equation is saturated with time dummies (column 4), or whether real growth or real growth per capita are used as a dependent variable (column 5). Results are also robust to removing the banking crisis instrument, the inclusion of which presents the disadvantage of reducing the sample size as the variable denotes the existence of a crisis 10 years earlier and is not available for some countries (column 6). The results of a dynamic model estimated by Arellano–Bond GMM with lagged GDP growth as the explanatory variable are also presented, and the financial integration variable coefficient is broadly unchanged (column 7).11

Table 8.

Impact of Financial Integration on GDP Growth (Baseline Results)

article image
Notes: all specification estimated with panel IV estimator except for specifications 7 and 9 that use GMM.

Principle component of 2 variables: global openness and regional asset price convergence. This is the baseline described in Table 1.

Exports plus imports, ratio to GDP.

Private and public investment, ratio to GDP.

Current and capital expenditures of the general government, ratio to GDP.

ICRG composite index of political, economic and financial country risks.

This specification is saturated with time dummies, which are not reproduced in the table.

Another potential issue is that the lagged GDP-per-capita level is generally endogenous in growth equations (Bond, Hoeffler, and Temple, 2001). To circumvent this problem, an equation is presented that excludes the variable and finds that the integration coefficient is broadly unchanged (column 8). The endogeneity of both the integration variable and the lagged GDP level is corrected by rewriting the growth regression as a dynamic model in levels12 and estimating it with the first-differenced Arellano-Bond (2001) GMM estimator; alongside the lagged (first-differenced) variables, the additional instruments mentioned above (capital controls indicator, occurrence of a banking crisis 10 years earlier, and profit repatriation rule) are included. The effect of financial integration is again positive and significant (column 9), but the regression suffers from the traditional GMM shortcomings, including a high sensitivity to the number of lags used for the instruments. Finally, the possibility of non-linear relationships was accounted for through interaction terms and a quadratic form of the integration indicator. However, the non-linear models did not produce robust results.

Table 9 reports the results of specifications with the alternative measures of integration. The following indicators described in Section II.B and Table 1 are used: a two-component index with the ratio of external liabilities-to-GDP (column 1); a three-component index that adds a measure of financial depth (column 2); and variants of the three-component index including regional openness (columns 3-6). Column 3 measures regional integration as the ratio of a country’s regional assets and liabilities to total foreign assets and liabilities in an eight-region framework. Column 4 replicates the indicator with a four-region split. Column 5 measures regional integration by weighting the sum of assets and liabilities with the distance between countries. Column 6 measures regional integration by weighting only liabilities with the distance between countries. In all these specifications, the effect of financial integration remains positive and significant.

Table 9.

Impact of Financial Integration on GDP Growth (Using Alternative Financial Integration Indicators)

article image
Note: All equations are estimated with instrumented variable estimation.

Principle component of 2 variables: global integration of external liabilities and asset price convergence within an 8 region world.

Principle component of 3 variables: global integration of external assets and liabilities, banking system credit to the private sector, and asset price convergence within an 8 region world.

Principle component of 3 variables: global integration of external assets and liabilities, asset price convergence, and in tegration of external assets and liabilities within an 8 region world.

Principle component of 3 variables: global integration of external assets and liabilities, asset price convergence, and in tegration of external assets and liabilities within a 4 region world.

Principle component of 3 variables: global integration of external assets and liabilities, asset price convergence within an 8 region world, and average proximity of external asset and liability partners.

Principle component of 3 variables: global integration of external liabilities, asset price convergence within an 8 region world, and average proximity of external liability partners.

Global openness is measured as the log of external assets plus liabilities in percent of GDP.

Regional openness (8 regions) is measured as the log of external regional assets plus liabilities (vis-à-vis narrow regional partners) as a ratio to GDP.

Regional openness (4 regions) is measured as the log of external regional assets plus liabilities (vis-à-vis broad regional partners) as a ratio to GDP.

Exports plus imports, ratio to GDP.

Private and public investment, ratio to GDP.

Current and capital expenditures of the general government, ratio to GDP.

ICRG composite index of political, economic, and financial risks.

As a final sensitivity exercise, we conduct regressions with simpler measures of financial integration. The last three columns show that simple financial openness ratios are positively related to growth. Column 7 reports the results of a regression with global openness measured as financial assets plus financial liabilities in percent of GDP. Columns 8 and 9 replicate the results with regional openness indicators—defined in a similar way (regional assets plus regional liabilities as a ratio to GDP), with an eight or a four region split.

Overall, financial integration and economic performance are found to be positively correlated. The various specifications return elasticities of 0.01-0.02 for the financial integration variable. Using the measure of under-integration calculated in Section III.B, it is possible to estimate the effect of closing the integration gap in the LA-7 countries. Specifically, combining the two steps, the analysis predicts a growth effect in the range of ¼ to ¾ percentage point on average, if the gap were to be fully closed.13 The growth dividend would be lower if progress were partial. These results should be treated with caution, as most variables in growth regressions are endogenous, creating potential estimation biases that IV and GMM estimators cannot always correct.

V. Conclusion

There has seldom been a better moment to advance regional financial integration in LA. The aftermath of the global financial crisis has brought significantly tighter banking regulations and a trend of de-risking. Consequently, global banks have been withdrawing from LA and other emerging markets to return home. At the same time, the commodity boom is over, and with slower growth foreseen in China over the medium term, commodity producers will face hard times unless they are able to establish alternative avenues of growth. These avenues would require investment and deep capital markets. Put simply, this is not a juncture where LA countries can comfortably afford to see their financial markets contract. Enhanced financial integration within the region provides one possible solution. Providentially, initiatives to promote regional financial integration, such as the MILA initiative of the Pacific Alliance, are currently enjoying political support.

The analysis in this paper finds strong evidence of financial under-integration in the LA-7, from both a descriptive and an econometric perspective. Moreover, this integration gap applies to both global and regional financial integration. Other emerging market regions, such as east Asia and eastern Europe, seem more integrated with each other and with the outside world, compared to our LA sample. Furthermore, the LA-7 countries appear to be under-integrated given their own macro- and socioeconomic fundamentals. There would be great benefits to LA from reducing this degree of financial under-integration. Our econometric results suggest that the positive impact on growth of closing the integration gap could be ¼ to ¾ percentage point, on average. Of course, given the traditional challenges in estimating causal effects with macroeconomic data, our results, although robust to alternative specifications, should be treated with caution.

In order to advance regional financial integration, and thus realize the macroeconomic benefits therein, IMF (2016) suggests a number of concrete steps that could be taken by the LA countries in question. While there has been considerable political traction for projects such as MILA, to get the process effectively rolling would require the logistical and economic nuts and bolts to be firmly in place. In particular, the countries would need to harmonize their accounting and regulatory practices, and taxation schemes, as well as establish coordinated and consolidated supervision, enhanced cross-border information sharing, and macro-prudential policies. All of this would require substantial investment, but without it, the risks of integration could outweigh the benefits by undermining the resilience and stability of financial systems. The case for enhanced regional financial integration in LA is clear. If all stakeholders are brought on board, and the requisite regulatory and supervisory innovations instituted, success is well within grasp.

References

  • Baele, L., A. Ferrando, P. Hördahl, E. Krylova, and C. Monnet. 2004. “Measuring European Financial Integration.European Central Bank (ECB) Occasional Paper 14, Frankfurt, Germany.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS). 2014. “EME Banking Systems and Regional Financial Integration.Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS) Publication 51, Basel, Switzerland.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., and R. Levine. 2004. “Stock Markets, Banks and Growth: Panel Evidence.Journal of Banking and Finance 28 (3): 42342.

  • Bond, S., A. Hoeffler, and J. Temple. 2001. “GMM Estimation of Empirical Growth Models.Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR) Discussion Paper 3048, Washington.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, S., and N. van Horen. 2014. “Foreign Banks: Trends and Impact.Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46: 1: 295326.

  • Degryse, H., O. Havrylchyk, E. M. Jurzyk, and S. J. Kozak. 2009. “Foreign Bank Entry and Credit Allocation in Emerging Markets.IMF Working Paper WP/09/270, Washington.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Detragiache E., P. Gupta, and T. Tressel. 2008. “Foreign Banks in Poor Countries: Theory and Evidence.Journal of Finance 63 (5, October): 212360.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fernández A., M. W. Klein, A. Rebucci, M. Schindler, and M. Uribe. 2015. “Capital Control Measures: A New Dataset.NBER Working Paper 20970, Cambridge, United States.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galindo, A., A. Izquierdo, and L. Rojas-Suárez. 2010. “Financial Integration and Foreign Banks in Latin America. How Do They Impact the Transmission of External Financial Shocks?Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) Working Paper IDB-WP-116, Washington.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giannetti, M., and L. Laeven. 2012. “Flight Home, Flight Abroad and International Credit Cycles.American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings., 102: 3: 21924

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2008. “Reaping the Benefits of Financial Globalization,IMF Policy Paper, Washington.

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2014. “Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy.Washington. http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2014/110614.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015a. “International Banking after the Crisis: Increasingly Local and Safer?Global Financial Stability Report. Washington, April.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015b. “Long-Run Growth in Latin America and the Caribbean: The Role of Economic Diversification and Complexity.Regional Economic Outlook: Western Hemisphere. Washington, April.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2016. “Financial Integration in Latin America.IMF Policy Paper. Washington. https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2016/030416.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jeon, B. N., M. P. Olivero, and J. Wu. 2013. “Multinational Banking and the International Transmission of Financial Shocks: Evidence from Foreign Bank Subsidiaries.Journal of Banking & Finance 37: 3: 952972.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamil, H., and K. Rai. 2010. “The Global Credit Crunch and Foreign Banks’ Lending to Emerging Markets: Why Did Latin America Fare Better?IMF Working Paper WP/10/102, Washington.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kose, A., E. Prasad, K. S. Rogoff, and S. Wei. 2006. “Financial Globalization: A Reappraisal.NBER Working Paper 12484, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff, 2009, This Time It’s Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (Princeton: Princeton University Press). Data available at http://www.reinhartandrogoff.com/data/

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rancière, R., A. Tornell, and F. Westermann. 2006. “Decomposing the Effects of Financial Liberalization: Crises vs. Growth.Journal of Banking & Finance 30: 333148.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rancière, R., A. Tornell, and F. Westermann. 2008. “Systemic Crises and Growth.Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (1): 359406.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sahay, R., M. Čihák, P. N’Diaye, A. Barajas, R. Bi, D. Ayala, Y. Gao, A. Kyobe, L. Nguyen, C. Saborowski, K. Svirydzenka, and S. R. Yousefi. 2015. “Rethinking Financial Deepening: Stability and Growth in Emerging Markets.IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/15/08, Washington.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

We greatly appreciate comments from Roberto Cardarelli, Charles Enoch, Chikako Baba, Jose Giancarlo Gasha, Maria Soledad Martinez Peria, Camelia Minoiu, Sumiko Ogawa, Marco Pinon, Sabine Tuzik and Claudio Visconti, as well as those received from colleagues during the preparation of IMF (2016). This Working Paper expands on some analytical sections of the aforementioned policy paper.

2

For instance, the discussion on financial fragmentation in the euro area (and its implications for the transmission of the European Central Bank’s (ECB) monetary policy) has focused at least as much on the absence of common firewalls (resolution and deposit insurance funds and supervisory mechanisms) as on the need to revive bilateral financial flows.

3

The objective of the PCA is to reduce the number of variables of interest into a single factor, which captures most of their variances (for the indices constructed in this exercise, the first component explains more than 50 percent of the total variance).

4

In principle the best measures of financial integration should be price based. However, in light of the difficulties to adequately identify homogenous assets across countries, this section relies on quantity-based indicators.

6

BIS bank lending data are only available for four LA countries.

7

Share prices on the secondary market are quoted for all firms listed on all MILA exchanges in the currency of the home exchange, but this is not considered full cross-listing as cross-border trades are conducted via correspondent brokers and settlement is often conducted via the back offices. An intermediary achievement in pursuit of full integration is the treatment of initial public offerings (IPOs) which are simultaneously and fully listed on all exchanges and therefore do not require correspondent brokers for trading.

9

It should be noted that the scope for mutual benefits from regional risk-sharing may be limited by the synchronization of economic cycles in commodity exporting countries.

10

Dependence on local funding and lending in local currency, as is common in Latin America, can insulate domestic credit by subsidiaries from crises in the home countries of parent banks (Kamil and Rai, 2010).

11

In this specification, the elasticity of the financial integration variable cannot be directly compared to the other specifications because of the lagged dependent variable term. This coefficient should first be multiplied by one divided by one minus the coefficient of the lagged GDP growth to get the long-term elasticity.

12

See Bond, Hoeffler, and Temple (2001), equation 16. By rewriting a growth model as a dynamic model in level (with the GDP level on the left-hand side), the control variable on the right-hand side becomes the lagged level of GDP rather than the lagged level of GDP per capita.

13

In the first step (Section III.B), the difference between the country fixed effect and the sample average is used to estimate the degree of under-integration. In the fixed effect models, this gap averages 0.3-0.4 in LA-7 countries. With an elasticity of 0.01–0.02, the growth effect is therefore 0.3-0.8 percentage points.