Can Property Taxes Reduce House Price Volatility? Evidence from U.S. Regions
Author:
Mr. Tigran Poghosyan
Search for other papers by Mr. Tigran Poghosyan in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: tpoghosyan@imf.org

We use a novel dataset on effective property tax rates in U.S. states and metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) over the 2005–2014 period to analyze the relationship between property tax rates and house price volatility. We find that property tax rates have a negative impact on house price volatility. The impact is causal, with increases in property tax rates leading to a reduction in house price volatility. The results are robust to different measures of house price volatility, estimation methodologies, and additional controls for housing demand and supply. The outcomes of the analysis have important policy implications and suggest that property taxation could be used as an important tool to dampen house price volatility.

Abstract

We use a novel dataset on effective property tax rates in U.S. states and metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) over the 2005–2014 period to analyze the relationship between property tax rates and house price volatility. We find that property tax rates have a negative impact on house price volatility. The impact is causal, with increases in property tax rates leading to a reduction in house price volatility. The results are robust to different measures of house price volatility, estimation methodologies, and additional controls for housing demand and supply. The outcomes of the analysis have important policy implications and suggest that property taxation could be used as an important tool to dampen house price volatility.

I. Introduction

Housing market has important implications for macroeconomic stability through its impact on aggregate demand and supply (OECD, 2011).2 On the demand side, housing wealth is an important part of the net worth of the private sector and housing-related expenses (e.g., mortgage payments, rents) represent a major part of household expenditure. Hence, changes in house prices may affect aggregate demand through various channels, including spending on residential construction and spending on non-residential consumption (wealth effect). On the supply side, house prices have implications for labor mobility and property assets of businesses contribute to the production process. Volatile housing market can also raise systemic risks due to the high mortgage exposure of the banking sector.

Developments in the housing market have been at the heart of the global crisis, prompting a debate on alternative policy responses. The discussion so far has mainly focused on employing monetary policy tools and macro prudential regulation to dampen house price volatility and prevent the buildup of housing bubbles. However, both have drawbacks (Crowe et al., 2013). Monetary policy is considered a too blunt instrument, as it affects the entire economy and may be too costly if the boom is limited to the housing market. Moreover, this tool is not available for members of a monetary union. Macro prudential regulation is more targeted and relatively more flexible,3 but it may be too invasive to the operation of markets and market participants may find ways to circumvent them. A natural question arises – can tax policy help?

In recent years, a number of countries used tax instruments to curb excessive house price fluctuations (Lim et al., 2011; He, 2014; Darbar and Wu, 2015). There has been also increased interest in using property taxation as an efficient tool to bolster public revenues (IMF, 2013; Norregaard, 2015). While there is large literature assessing the impact of macro prudential regulation on house prices (Kuttner and Shim, 2013; Claessens, 2014; Cerutti et al., 2016), evidence on the impact of property taxes is scant.

Van Den Noord (2005) develops a simple theoretical framework showing that demand shocks to house prices tend to amplify if property taxes are low, inducing excessive volatility. He supports the theoretical prediction of a negative association between property tax rates and house price volatility using a simple scatterplot analysis. Crowe et al. (2013) run cross-sectional regressions using a sample of 243 U.S. metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) and show that property taxes are negatively associated with house price volatility. However, the paper does not assess whether the causality runs from property tax rates to house price volatility. Using a panel of OECD countries over 1980-2005, Andrews (2010) also finds that more generous taxation of property (mortgage interest deductibility, recurrent property taxes) could lead to larger house price volatility. Similarly, OECD (2011) argues that reducing the tax relief on mortgage debt financing costs from the level observed in Netherlands to the level in Sweden can reduce house price volatility by 11 percent. By contrast, Aregger et al. (2013) study the impact of transaction and capital gains taxes in 21 Swiss cantons over 1985-2009 but find mixed evidence on their ability to deter speculation and reduce volatility. Keen et al. (2010) also argue that the ability of transaction taxes to deter housing speculation in the longer term is ambiguous. Ultimately, the extent to which house prices adjust to accommodate demand shocks driven by property tax changes is affected by the responsiveness of housing supply and regulatory arrangements (Saiz, 2010; Andrews et al., 2011; Gattini and Ganoulis, 2012; Hilber and Vermeulen, 2016).

The purpose of our analysis is to contribute to this literature by providing a more detailed assessment of the relationship between property tax rates and house price volatility.4 Similar to Crowe et al. (2013), the analysis employs data on property tax rates from U.S. regions (states and MSAs),5 but extends it for the period 2005-14. Another difference is that we are trying to establish a causality in the relationship between property tax rates and house price volatility.

Estimation results support the theoretical prediction of Van Den Noord (2005) on the negative impact of property tax rates on house price volatility. A 0.5 percent increase in property tax rates (one standard deviation in the total sample) leads to 0.5-5.5 percent decline in house price volatility depending on the empirical specification and the measure of volatility. Instrumental variable and GMM regressions suggest that this relationship is causal, which increases in property tax rates leading to a reduction in house price volatility. The results are supported by the difference-in-difference regressions exploring the exogenous variation in housing supply due to the geographical location and regulatory constraints and are are robust to different measures of house price volatility and estimation methodologies. The key policy implication is that property taxation could usefully complement other tools, including monetary and macro prudential, in reducing house price volatility.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section II outlines the theoretical framework underpinning the empirical analysis. Section III describes the data and provides descriptive statistics. Section IV presents estimation results. The last section concludes.

II. Theoretical Framework

Tax policy tools can influence housing markets through affecting demand for housing. There is a wide range of property taxes and subsidies, with the main being: mortgage rate deductibility, tax on imputed rents, capital gains tax, recurrent taxes on land and buildings, wealth tax, inheritance tax, VAT, and stamp duties (or acquisition taxes). These could be grouped into three broad categories: (i) transaction taxes, (ii) recurrent property taxes, and (iii) mortgage interest deductibility.

The starting point of the theoretical framework of Van Den Noord (2005) that underpins our empirical analysis is the assumption of an equilibrium relationship between homeowners’ return on housing investment and on other assets (see also Poterba, 1992; Poterba and Sinai, 2008). This requires an equality between the marginal value of rental services from owner-occupied housing and marginal user cost of housing capital:

R t ( H ) = P t [ r ( 1 τ m ) + τ p π e ( 1 τ c ) + δ ] ( 1 )

where R is the marginal value of rental services, H is the housing stock, r is the nominal interest rate, τm is the marginal effective tax rate on interest income (normally, marginal income tax rate), τP is the property tax rate, τc is the capital gains (transaction) tax rate, δ is the property depreciation rate, P is the price of owner-occupied housing, and πe is the expected rate of house price inflation (E[dPt/dt]/Pt). As shown in (1), the user cost of owning a house is distorted by the favorable tax treatment of owner-occupied housing (transaction taxes, recurrent property taxes, and mortgage interest deductibility). Given that the marginal value of rental services is a negative function of the total housing stock H (dR/dH<0), equation (1) can be interpreted as a downward-slopping demand function for housing.

The supply function relates the total stock of housing to the flow of net construction, which depends on the ratio of house prices and construction costs (C):

H t = ( 1 δ ) H t 1 + φ ( P t C t ) ( 2 )

where φ is the positive short-run price sensitivity of supply. This sensitivity is typically small and short-run supply tends to be steep. However, the long-run price sensitivity (φ/δ) is considerably larger than the short-run sensitivity for relatively small values of δ.

Figure 1 provides graphical illustration of how demand shock affects house prices in the presence of different property tax systems. Panel I shows the results for less generous tax treatment of housing (flatter demand curve), while Panel II depicts the case of a more generous tax treatment (steeper demand curve). Given the inelastic short-term supply curve (horizontal line SSR), the equilibrium initially moves from A to B. Over time, the supply would expand (upward-slopping line SLR) and equilibrium would be set at C. Overall, prices first go up and then come down, settling at a higher level than that prior to the shock. The key implication is that the volatility of house prices (or overshooting) during this transition is larger in the presence of a more generous tax treatment.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Graphical Illustration: Demand Shock and House Prices

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2016, 216; 10.5089/9781475552799.001.A001

Assuming that the expected house price inflation is a linear function of the observed price change in the previous period (E[dPt/dt]=a*[Pt-1-Pt-2], with a>0)6 and abstracting away from capital gains taxes (τc=0), equation (1) can be rewritten as:

P t = a r ( 1 τ m ) + τ p + δ ( P t 1 P t 2 ) + R t r ( 1 τ m ) + τ p + δ ( 3 )

where r. (l-τm)+ τP + δ > 0 and a>0.

Specification (3) indicates that after an initial demand shock to R, the accelerator mechanism sets in assuming unchanged supply. This mechanism will be stronger for lower property tax rates (smaller τm). The equation will produce an oscillating development of the price level and its rate of change, with the amplitude greater for higher values of the ratio a/[r ˙ (l-τm)+ τP + θ+δ].

In sum, this simple theoretical model suggests that lower property tax rates will lead to higher volatility of house prices following an exogenous demand shock. In the long-run (equilibrium), the property tax rate itself does not induce the price volatility, but can exacerbate or dampen the impact of shocks. In the short-run, property tax rate changes can contribute to house price volatility directly as prices adjust to the new equilibrium.

Figure 2 illustrates the dynamics of house prices in response to a permanent demand shock. As expected, the volatility of house prices in response to a shock is higher for lower levels of property taxes. We test the empirical validity of this theoretical prediction below.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

The Impact of Exogenous Demand Shock on House Prices

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2016, 216; 10.5089/9781475552799.001.A001

III. Data and Descriptive Statistics

A. Data

Our database covers the period 2005-2014. We employ separately data on 51 U.S. states and 77 MSAs in two sets of regressions. Table 1 lists variables and their sources.

Table 1.

Variables and Data Sources

article image

House price data are taken from the Federal Housing Finance Agency. Annual house prices are estimated as averages of four quarters within a year. Macroeconomic variables, including nominal and real GDP, GDP deflator, per capita GDP, and population are taken from the Bureau of Economic Analysis. Effective property tax rates are measured as the ratio of the median annual property tax payment to the median property value for owner-occupied housing units. Both series are taken from the American Community Survey maintained by the Census. The advantage of this measure is that it accounts for differences in property tax rates across counties within the state and property tax exemptions/adjustments.

Unfortunately, the survey data do not extend back beyond 2005, so the series are restricted to the 2005-2014 period.

The volatility of house prices is estimated using 5-year backward moving window. We use the following alternative measures of real house prices for estimating volatility: (i) annual growth rates, and (ii) percentage deviations from the HP-filtered value.7

B. Descriptive Statistics

Table 2 presents descriptive statistics of all variables used in the analysis. The panel is balanced, with 510 state-year and 770 MSA-year observations. The average effective property tax rate in the sample is 1 percent, with standard deviation of 0.5 percent. The average volatility of house prices is 5-6 percent, depending on the measure.

Table 2.

Descriptive Statistics

article image

Figure 3 presents the dynamics of house price growth rates and property taxes across 51 U.S. states over 1995-2014. Two observations are worth noting. First, the median house price growth rate has switched from positive to negative during the crisis period (2007-11). For each year, the real growth rates varied widely across states, with 25-75 interquartile range of up to 8 percent depending on the year. The variation across states was largest at the height of the crisis in 2009, when some states have experienced positive growth rates despite the negative median. This suggests that some states managed to weather the demand shock better than others and property tax rates could have played a role here. Second, the median effective property tax rate has increased from 0.8 percent before the crisis to 1 percent now. This was in part driven by the large deficits run by local governments requiring them to look for alternative revenue sources to meet their balanced budget targets (Gracia et al., 2014). Similar to house prices, effective property tax rates vary widely across states and this variation did not change following the crisis. In some states, property tax rates are approaching 2.5 percent level, with the 25-75 interquartile range reaching up to 1 percent depending on the year.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

House Prices and Property Tax Rates

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2016, 216; 10.5089/9781475552799.001.A001

Note: Reported are variation ranges of variables across 51 U.S. states. Real house prices are estimated using state GDP deflators. The whiskers of the plot denote the minimum and maximum values of variables for each year. The edges of the box denote 25th and 75th percentiles of the distribution across states. The line splitting the box denotes the state median.

Figure 4 presents the dynamics of house price volatility using both definitions. Both measures provide a qualitatively similar picture. The median state standard deviation has increased from below 5 percent to above 5 percent during the crisis. There is wide variation across states, exceeding 15 percent in some years. The standard deviation has declined back to pre-crisis levels recently.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Volatility of House Prices

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2016, 216; 10.5089/9781475552799.001.A001

Note: Reported are volatilities measures using 5-year backward moving window.

Figure 5 presents simple scatterplots of house price volatility and property tax rates. The slopes are negative for both definitions of house price volatility, suggesting a lower volatility in state-years characterized by high property tax rates. There is also some evidence of heteroscedasticity, with distribution of house price volatility being larger in state-years with low property tax rates. The latter suggests that robust standard errors should be used in the regressions to improve inference.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

House Price Volatility and Property Tax

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2016, 216; 10.5089/9781475552799.001.A001

Note: The sample covers 51 U.S. states for the period 2005-14.

IV. Empirical Analysis

In this section, we test the theoretical prediction of the Van Den Noord (2005) model suggesting a negative association between house price volatility and the level of property tax rates. We test this prediction using several alternative empirical specifications.

A. Baseline Specification

The baseline specification takes the following form:

V O L i t = α + β T A X i t + γ X i t + u i + ω t + ϵ i t ( 4 )

where i denotes state, t denotes time, VOL is the house price volatility, TAX is the property tax rate, X is a vector of control variables, u is the unobserved state-specific heterogeneity (state fixed effect), ω is the unobserved time-specific heterogeneity (time fixed effect), and ε is the i.i.d. error term. The Van Den Noord model predicts a negative slope coefficient on the property tax rate variable (β<0).

Table 3 presents estimation results from the baseline specification. Columns (I)-(IV) show results for volatility based on house price real growth rates, while columns (V)-(VIII) show results for volatility based on detrended house prices. In all specifications the slope coefficient of the property tax variable is negative (and in most cases significant), supporting the theoretical prediction of the negative association between house price volatility and property tax rates. The economic significance of the coefficients is large: a 1 standard deviation increase in property tax rates (0.48 percent) leads to 1.3-1.7 percent reduction in volatility based on the growth rate measure and 0.5-0.6 percent reduction in volatility based on the detrended measure. Figure 6 provides further evidence on the economic significance of the impact assuming a normal distribution of house price growth rates.

Table 3.

Baseline Regressions

article image
Figure 6.
Figure 6.

The Impact of Property Taxes on House Price Volatility

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2016, 216; 10.5089/9781475552799.001.A001

Note: The exercise assumes that house price growth rates have normal distribution. The blue line represents the distribution of house price growth rates using the mean and standard deviation from the sample. The red line represents the distribution of house price growth rates assuming 0.48 percent higher property tax rates, which would translate into lower volatility/standard deviation. The latter is calculated as 7.4-0.48*3, where 3 is the average economic significance of the property tax rate impact across all regressions.

B. Instrumental Variables

The baseline specification assumes that the causality goes from property tax rates to house price volatility, but in practice the causality may go in both directions. Specifically, states experiencing high house price volatility may react by increasing property tax rates. This reaction will lead to a downward bias in the slope coefficient on the property tax rate variable.

To control for this endogeneity, we run two sets of instrumental variable regressions. First, we instrument the property tax rate variable by the average property tax rates of neighboring states. This instrument is motivated by the large literature showing existence of a strategic interaction in property tax setting by local governments competing for property tax base (see, e.g., Brueckner and Saavedra, 2001; Brueckner, 2003). Second, we use panel GMM estimator, using lagged values of explanatory variables as instruments.

Table 4 presents estimation results from the instrumental variable specification. F-statistics from first stage regressions are high (exceeding 10 in most cases), supporting the instrument validity. The coefficient on the property tax rate variable remains negative and significant. As expected, its magnitude increases, suggesting a stronger impact of property tax rates on volatility: a 1 standard deviation increase in property tax rates (0.48 percent) leads to 2.3-5.5 percent reduction in volatility based on the growth rate measure and 1.0-3.2 percent reduction in volatility based on the detrended measure.

Table 4.

Instrumental Variable Regressions

article image
Note: Coefficients are obtained from panel IV regressions with state fixed effects. The dependent variable is the house price volatility, measured as a 5-year backward moving window standard deviation of: (i) house price real growth rates (columns I-IV), and (ii) deviation of real house prices from their HP-filtered values (columns V-VIII). The instrument for the property tax rate variable is the average property tax rate of neighboring states. Economic significance measures the response of house price volatility to a 1 standard deviation (0.48%) increase in property tax rates. Robust standard errors are in brackets. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.

Table 5 shows the dynamic panel system GMM estimation results following Blundell and Bond (1998), which allow controlling for the endogeneity of the lagged dependent and other potentially endogenous variables. Similar to the instrumental variable regressions, the negative coefficient on the tax variable remains: a 1 standard deviation increase in property tax rates (0.48 percent) leads to 0.7-4.0 percent reduction in volatility based on the growth rate measure and 0.6-1.4 percent reduction in volatility based on the detrended measure. We also assess the validity of the GMM results by: (i) running the Arellano-Bond test of no second-order autocorrelation on the residuals, and (ii) using Sargan test to check for the misspecification of our instruments. Both statistics are reported at the bottom of the table and confirm the validity of model specification.

Table 5.

Dynamic Panel GMM Regressions

article image
Note: Coefficients are obtained from system GMM regressions with state fixed effect (Arellano-Bover). The dependent variable is the house price volatility, measured as a 5-year backward moving window standard deviation of: (i) house price real growth rates (columns I-IV), and (ii) deviation of real house prices from their HP-filtered values (columns V-VIII). Economic significance measures the response of house price volatility to a 1 standard deviation (0.48%) increase in property tax rates. Robust standard errors are in brackets. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.

C. Difference-in-Difference Regressions

To provide further insights on the relationship between property tax rates and house price volatility, we adopt a difference-in-difference approach proposed by Rajan and Zingales (1998). We exploit variation in house price volatility across metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) within states by using an interaction of state tax rates with MSA-specific supply restriction indicators. The empirical specification takes the following form:

V O L m t = α + β T A X i t + λ ( T A X i t * S U P P L Y m ) + γ X i t + u m + ω t + ϵ m t ( 5 )

where i denotes state, m denotes MSA, t denotes time, and SUPPLY is the supply restriction indicator. The dataset covers 77 MSAs located in 29 U.S. states.

We use two supply-restriction indicators: (i) geographical - the share of undevelopable land area as of percent total (Saiz, 2010), and (ii) regulatory - the index of property regulation (Wharton Regulation Index) (Gyourko et al., 2008). Higher level of both variables indicates less responsive supply of housing to demand shocks. The interaction term of each supply-restriction indicator with effective property tax rates at the state level shows the extent to which the difference in house price volatility in MSAs with varying degrees of supply restrictions and located within the same state responds to differences in property tax rates across states (difference-in-difference effect). The null hypothesis is λ < 0, which implies that a higher property tax at the state level would reduce house price volatility in MSAs with more rigid housing supply at a faster rate compared to states with less rigid supply.

Tables 6-7 present estimation results for each supply-restriction indicator. The results support the null hypothesis, as the coefficient on the interaction term is negative and significant. The economic significance measured for the 25-75 interquartile range of property tax rates and supply restriction indices results in a difference-in-difference effect of 1.1-2.0 percent for the geographical supply restriction indicator, and 2.6-3.2 percent for the regulatory supply restriction indicator.

Table 6.

Difference-in-Difference Regressions: Geographical Supply Restrictions Index

article image
Note: Coefficients are obtained from panel OLS regressions with MSA fixed effects. The dependent variable is the house price volatility, measured as a 5-year backward moving window standard deviation of: (i) house price real growth rates (columns I-IV), and (ii) deviation of real house prices from their HP-filtered values (columns V-VIII). The geographical supply restrictions index is taken from Saiz (2010) — it measures the share of land area that is not subject to property development. Economic significance measures the response of house price volatility to 25-75 interquartile increases in supply restrictions index and property tax rates. Robust standard errors are in brackets. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 7.

Difference-in-Difference Regressions: Regulatory Restrictions Index

article image
Note: Coefficients are obtained from panel OLS regressions with MSA fixed effects. The dependent variable is the house price volatility, measured as a 5-year backward moving window standard deviation of: (i) house price real growth rates (columns I-IV), and (ii) deviation of real house prices from their HP-filtered values (columns V-VIII). The regulatory restriction index is taken from Gyourko et al. (2008) — it measures zoning regulations or project approval practices that constrain new residential real estate development. Economic significance measures the response of house price volatility to 25-75 interquartile increases in regulatory restrictions index and property tax rates. Robust standard errors are in brackets. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.

V. Conclusions

House price volatility is important contributor to macro financial stability. Following the global crisis, the discussion of policy tools to dampen house price volatility ranks high on the policy agenda. While the effectiveness of macro prudential measures to curb house price volatility has been analyzed extensively (Kuttner and Shim, 2013; Claessens, 2014; Cerutti et al., 2016), evidence on the effectiveness of property taxes is scant.

In this paper, we assess the relationship between property tax rates and house price volatility using U.S. state and MSA level panel data for the period 2005-2014. Drawing on a novel dataset on effective property tax rates, we show that property taxes have a negative impact on house price volatility, which is consistent with the theoretical prediction of Van Den Noord (2005). The impact is causal, with increases in property tax rates leading to a reduction in house price volatility. Specifically, a 0.5 percent increase in property tax rates (one standard deviation in the total sample) leads to 0.5-5.5 percent decline in house price volatility depending on the empirical specification and the measure of volatility. The results are supported by the difference-in-difference regressions exploring the exogenous variation in housing supply due to the geographical location and regulatory constraints and are robust to different measures of house price volatility and estimation methodologies.

The key policy implication is that property taxation could be used as an effective tool to dampen house price volatility. However, using transaction taxes in a countercyclical fashion may not be the best option given that they tend to thin the markets and discourage transactions that would allocate properties more efficiently. In addition, unlike macroprudential tools, transaction taxes cannot be changed very frequently and implementation lags can be too long given the need to amend legislation. Finally, they could adversely impact labor mobility by increasing the cost of changing property.

Instead, reforms could target recurrent property taxation and mortgage interest deductibility, with the objective of ensuring tax neutrality between investment in housing and other types of capital. The objective is to reduce incentives for debt-financed home ownership permanently. One possibility is to tax imputed rents (Linden and Gayer, 2010; OECD, 2011). The practical issue with this approach is that these rents are difficult to measure. Hence, increasing recurrent and transaction property taxes could be used as an alternative. Another possibility is: (i) not to allow mortgage interest deductibility, and (ii) to levy a lower recurrent tax on property. In this way, housing investment would still be taxed and the tax system would not favor debt. Both options would reduce incentives for debt-favored house financing.

References

  • Andrews, D., 2010, “Real House Prices in OECD Countries: The Role of Demand Shocks and Structural and Policy Factors,” OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 831 (Paris: OECD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrews, D., A. Caldera Sanchez, and A. Johansson, 2011, “Housing markets and structural policies in OECD countries”, OECD Economics Department Working papers, No. 836 (Paris: OECD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aregger, N., M. Brown and E. Ross, 2013, “Transaction Taxes, Capital Gains Taxes, and House Prices,” Swiss National Bank Working Paper No. 2 (Zurich: Swiss National Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brueckner, J., 2003, “Strategic Interaction among Governments: An Overview of Empirical Studies,” International Regional Science Review, 26: pp. 175188.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brueckner, J. and L. Saavedra, 2001, “Do Local Governments Engage in Strategic Property-Tax Competition,” National Tax Journal, 54 (2): pp. 20330.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cerutti, E., S. Claessens, and L. Laeven, 2016, “The Use and Effectiveness of Macroprudential Policies: New Evidence,” Journal of Financial Stability (forthcoming, also IMF WP 15/61).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, S., 2015, “An Overview of Macroprudential Policy Tools,” IMF Working Paper WP/14/214 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crowe, C., G. Dell’Ariccia, D. Igan, and P. Rabanal, 2013, “How to Deal with Real Estate Booms: Lessons from Country Experiences,” Journal of Financial Stability, 9: pp. 300319.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Darbar, S., and X. Wu, 2015, “Experiences with Macroeconomic Policy – Five Case Studies,” IMF Working Paper WP/15/123 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gattini, L., and I. Ganoulis, 2012, “House Price Responsiveness of Housing Investments Across Major European Economies,” ECB Working Paper No. 1461 (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gracia, B., J. McHugh, and T. Poghosyan, 2014, “Impact of the Crisis and Policy Response at the Sub-National Level,” in: Cottarelli, C., P. Gerson, and A. Senhadji (eds.), Post-Crisis Fiscal Policy, (Cambridge: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gyourko, J., A. Saiz, and A. Summers, 2008, “A New Measure of the Local Regulatory Environment for Housing Markets: The Wharton Residential Land Use Regulatory Index,” Urban Studies, 45: pp. 693729.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • He, D. 2014. “The Effects of Macroprudential Policies on Housing Market Risks: Evidence from Hong Kong.” Banque de France, Financial Stability Review No. 18 (April).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hilber, C. and W. Vermeulen, 2016, “The Impact of Supply Constraints on House Prices in England,” The Economic Journal (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • IMF. 2013. “Fiscal Monitor: Taxing Times”, October.

  • Lim, C., F. Columba, A. Costa, P. Kongsamut, A. Otani, M. Saiyid, T. Wezel, and X. Wu. 2011. “Macroprudential Policy: What Instruments and How to Use Them?IMF Working Paper WP/11/238 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Linden, A. J. and C. Gayer. 2012. “Possible Reforms of Real Estate Taxation: Criteria for Successful Policies.” European Economy, Occasional Paper No 119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Norregaard, J., 2015, “Taxing Immovable Property: Revenue Potential and Implementation Challenges,” IMF Working Paper WP/13/129 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • OECD, 2011, “Housing and the Economy: Policies for Renovation,” Chapter 4 in Economic Policy Reforms 2011: Going for Growth (Paris: OECD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poterba, J., 1992, “Taxation and Housing: Old Questions, New Answers,” American Economic Review, 82 (2): 237242.

  • Poterba, J. and T. Sinai, 2008, “Tax Expenditures for Owner Occupied Housing: Deduction for Property Taxes and Mortgage Interest and the Exclusion of Imputed Rental Income,” American Economic Review P&P, 98 (2): 8489.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, M., A. Klemm, and V. Perry. 2010. “Tax and the Crisis.” Fiscal Studies, 31 (1), pp. 4379.

  • Kuttner, K. and I. Shim, 2013, “Can Non-Interest Rate Policies Stabilize Housing Markets? Evidence from a Panel of 57 Economies,” BIS Working Papers No. 433 (Basel: BIS).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajan, R., and L. Zingales, 1998, “Financial Dependence and Growth,” American Economic Review, 88 (3): pp. 559586.

  • Saiz, A., 2010, “The Geographic Determinants of Housing Supply,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125 (3): pp. 125396.

  • Van Den Noord, P., 2005, “Tax Incentives and House Price Volatility in the Euro Area: Theory and Evidence,” Economie Internationale, 101: pp. 2945.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

I would like to thank Michael Keen and Ruud De Mooij for suggesting the topic, as well as Ali Alichi, Ravi Balakrishnan, Marialuz Moreno Badia, Vitor Gaspar, Shafik Hebous, Philippe Wingender and seminar participants at IMF’s Fiscal Affairs Department and De Nederlandsche Bank for useful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

2

Some empirical studies suggest that a significant fall in housing prices is even more important for the economy than an equivalent fall in stock prices (Case et al., 2001).

3

For instance, the recently created European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) will be in charge of providing macro prudential policy recommendations in Europe.

4

The paper does not attempt to assess the extent to which higher house price volatility induced by property taxation can ultimately result in financial instability.

5

An MSA is a geographical region with a relatively high population density and close economic ties throughout area. Such regions are not legally incorporated (like a city or a town) and not considered legal administrative divisions (like counties). Some MSAs contain more than one large city (e.g., Norfolk-Virginia Beach, Minneapolis-Saint Paul). MSAs are used by the Census Bureau and other federal government agencies for statistical purposes and their definition can vary over time. As of 2014, there have been close to 400 MSAs in the U.S.

6

This assumption suggests that after a positive demand shock has produced first-round effect on house prices, households may anticipate further price increases. It also implies that property taxes do not directly affect expected house price changes.

7

Following the established practice for annual series, the smoothing parameter of the HP filter is set to 100.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Can Property Taxes Reduce House Price Volatility? Evidence from U.S. Regions
Author:
Mr. Tigran Poghosyan