Experiences with Macroprudential Policy—Five Case Studies

Contributor Notes

Authors’ E-Mail Addresses: sdarbar@imf.org, dianyoua@hotmail.com

This paper presents case studies of macroprudential policy in five jurisdictions (Hong Kong SAR, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Singapore, and Sweden). The case studies describe the institutional framework, its evolution, the use of macroprudential tools, and the circumstances under which the tools have been used. The paper shows how macroprudential policy is conducted under a heterogeneous set of institutional frameworks. In all cases macroprudential tools have been used to address risks in the housing market. In addition, some of them have moved to enhance the resilience of their banks to more general cyclical and structural risks.

Abstract

This paper presents case studies of macroprudential policy in five jurisdictions (Hong Kong SAR, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Singapore, and Sweden). The case studies describe the institutional framework, its evolution, the use of macroprudential tools, and the circumstances under which the tools have been used. The paper shows how macroprudential policy is conducted under a heterogeneous set of institutional frameworks. In all cases macroprudential tools have been used to address risks in the housing market. In addition, some of them have moved to enhance the resilience of their banks to more general cyclical and structural risks.

I. Introduction

This paper presents five case studies of experiences with macroprudential policy. It complements the Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy (IMF, 2014a) issued recently by the IMF that provides a framework for staff’s advice on macroprudential policy in its bilateral surveillance.2 The studies describe the institutional framework and its evolution in the five cases, and provide examples of the types of macroprudential tools used and the circumstances under which they have been implemented. The five economies studied are Hong Kong SAR, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Singapore and Sweden.3 All of these economies have gained experience with implementing macroprudential policies, and most of these economies have large financial sectors relative to their GDP. The study focuses on the post global financial crisis period.

The institutional frameworks described in this paper resemble to a large extent the stylized institutional models identified in Nier et al. (2011). One size, however, does not fit all. For example, Singapore fits into the model where the central bank is the overall financial supervisor and also has the macroprudential mandate, but with active role of the government (e.g., (MOF)). New Zealand fits into the model where the integration of supervisory agencies is partial but the macroprudential mandate lies with the central bank and the government does not play an active role in macroprudential policy. Sweden is an example where the central bank does not have supervisory responsibilities and the macroprudential mandate lies with the integrated supervisory agency. In Hong Kong SAR the central bank is empowered to conduct macroprudential policy, whereas in the Netherlands the mandate to implement macroprudential policy is shared between the central bank and the government.

In all the cases reviewed, the macroprudential tools have been used primarily to address risks in the real estate sector. Partly for this reason, the loan-to-value (LTV) limit was the most popular macroprudential tool, used in the five cases. Some jurisdictions have used multiple tools to help the effectiveness of the measures. For instance, Hong Kong SAR and Singapore have used the debt service–to-income (DSTI) ratio and taxes applied to real estate transactions along with the LTV ratio. Sweden and Hong Kong SAR also have imposed additional capital requirements for mortgages.

To enhance the resilience of the banking system, some authorities in these five cases also have used, or plan to use, additional macroprudential tools to address risk in the time and structural dimensions (IMF, 2013a). Most of these measures were adopted in response to the global financial crisis. New Zealand, for instance, moved quite quickly compared to other countries and imposed liquidity requirements to contain bank funding risks, and gradually increased the requirement. Sweden did the same in 2013. Banks in both countries rely heavily on wholesale funding. Countercyclical capital buffers will take effect in Sweden in the Fall of 2015 and in Hong Kong SAR in phases beginning 2016, while the Netherlands intends to impose them too. Furthermore, systemically important institutions will have to hold additional capital buffers starting in 2015 in Sweden and 2016 in Hong Kong SAR and the Netherlands.

It is too early to gauge the full impact of the measures that have been undertaken. In addition, some measures will only take effect in the future. Nevertheless, there is some early evidence that the implementation of macroprudential measures have enhanced banking system resilience and helped reduce the build-up of housing sector leverage in the cases reviewed. For instance, LTV ratios declined in Hong Kong SAR, New Zealand, and Singapore following the adoption of LTV limits. House prices growth was also affected. For example, the rate of growth of house prices peaked in New Zealand following the imposition of a cap on LTVs. House prices also leveled off in Hong Kong SAR under the combined weight of macroprudential tools and taxes, with the taxes appearing to have a more immediate impact.

II. Case Studies4

A. Hong Kong SAR

Background

Hong Kong SAR’s financial sector is one of the largest in the world. The banking system, with assets equivalent to 750 percent of GDP, is highly capitalized, profitable, and liquid, and the securities markets are deep, liquid, and efficient. As of end 2014, the Hong Kong SAR financial system faced a number of risks from elevated property prices, spillovers from the impending exit from the low interest rate environment, and increasing economic and financial integration with mainland China.5

During 2014 property prices stood at near historical highs. Residential property prices resumed an upward trend in 2009 after a brief correction in 2008, rising by 130 percent by mid-2013, as unconventional monetary policy in the U.S. came into effect and interest rates fell to record lows.6 The increase in property prices was fuelled by increased mortgage lending while housing supply remained tight. Demand from buyers from mainland China appear to have also contributed to strong house price gains, which have been larger among non-luxury units.

Hong Kong SAR banks withstood well the impact of the global financial crisis. The increase in financial market volatility affected Hong Kong SAR markets in late 2008 as reflected by a spike in interbank rates due to rising concerns over counterparty risk, higher risk aversion, and some liquidity hoarding. The market for term interbank lending dried up with significant tiering among counterparties. In response, the monetary authorities expanded their liquidity facilities, provided a facility for foreign exchange swaps, and introduced a temporary blanket guarantee for all deposits (in line with other countries in the region). Hong Kong SAR banks managed to withstand the market turbulence, in part, because they were in general not exposed to the securitized products at the center of the crisis, had strong internal risk management systems, were highly liquid, and had low loan-to-deposit ratios (Figure 1).

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Hong Kong SAR: Selected Macroprudential Indicators, 1990–2014

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Sources: Bank for International Settlements (BIS), World Economic Outlook (WEO), International Financial Statistics (IFS), CEIC, Global Property Guide (GPG), Haver Analytics Inc., and Fund staff calculations.1 The “credit-to-GDP gap” is defined as the deviation of the ratio of credit to GDP from its long run trend. The long run trend is calculated from the credit-to-GDP series by using a one-sided Hodrick-Prescott filter. This calculation uses a high smoothing parameter (lamda equals 400,000) since the series is quarterly. See IMF (2014c) for further details. Credit-to-GDP gap is calculated from the earliest GDP data available.

Institutional framework

Hong Kong SAR has an effective institutional arrangement for macroprudential policy. The responsibility for maintaining financial stability is shared among multiple agencies, each of which has its own formal mandate. The Financial Secretary (FS), is responsible for determining the monetary policy objective and the structure of the monetary system, and plays an important role in maintaining the stability and integrity of the monetary and financial system. The Hong Kong Monetary Authority (HKMA), which is the regulator of deposit-taking institutions, shares the financial stability responsibility and plays a key role in the macroprudential framework.

The HKMA is empowered to implement macroprudential policy. The mandate for the HKMA to promote the general stability and effective working of the banking system is set out in the Banking Ordinance, which stipulates the principal functions of the HKMA and provides it with the legal basis for regulating and supervising banks and other deposit-taking businesses.7 The HKMA determines prudential policies, standards, and guidelines relating to the regulation of banks and other deposit-taking institutions, and designs macroprudential instruments to address systemic risks.

Coordination for financial stability is under the auspices of the Council of Financial Regulators. Chaired by the FS, the Council comprises representatives from the HKMA, the Securities and Futures Commission (SFC), the Office of the Commissioner of Insurance (OCI), the Mandatory Provident Fund Schemes Authority, and the Financial Services and the Treasury Bureau. A smaller Financial Stability Committee, chaired by Secretary for Financial Services and the Treasury Bureau and composed of representatives of the HKMA, SFC and OCI, is responsible for monitoring the functioning of the financial system on a regular basis. The division of functions and responsibilities between the HKMA and FS was set out in June 2003.

Use of macroprudential policy instruments

The HKMA has made extensive use of macroprudential instruments to address risks in the property sector since the 1990s. The most frequently used instruments have been the LTV cap and the cap on the DSTI. Both instruments have been adjusted at different phases of the credit cycle to achieve a countercyclical effect. The LTV cap is differentiated, with a lower cap on higher-valued properties and on investment properties.

Increased risks in the property sector prompted a progressive tightening of the macroprudential instruments starting in 2009. To strengthen the resilience of banks to potential house price corrections, and to the eventual increase in interest rates in advanced economies, the HKMA undertook a gradual tightening of macroprudential policy measures (Box 1).

Hong Kong SAR—Macroprudential Measures, 2009–13

article image
article image

The imposition of the risk weight floor reflect concerns that the risk weights generated by banks’ internal models are too low.

There is some evidence that the tightening of macroprudential policy enhanced the resilience of Hong Kong SAR’s banking system and limited household leverage.8 For instance, the average LTV ratio at origination declined from 64 percent in 2009 to 55 percent in mid-2013. Mortgage lending growth also slowed following the measures, although it has rebounded since mid-2014 (Figure 1). The impact of tightening macroprudential policy on property prices is less clear; property prices leveled off briefly following the measures but resumed their upward trend in mid-2014.

Taxes on property transactions seem to have had a larger impact on the housing market.9 On several occasions, the government raised taxes on property transactions in conjunction with the macroprudential measures. A Special Stamp Duty (SSD) of up to 15 percent on residential properties resold within 24 months of purchase was introduced in November 2010. In October 2012, the SSD was raised to up to 20 percent on re-sales within 36 months, when a Buyer’s Stamp Duty of 15 percent was also introduced for buyers of residential properties that are not Hong Kong SAR permanent residents. This was followed by a doubling of the existing ad valorem stamp duty rates across the board to a maximum of 8.5 percent in February 2013.10 The across-the-board hike in the stamp duty, in particular, seems to have had a significant short-term impact on property prices and transactions (Figure 2).

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Hong Kong SAR: Housing Units Purchased, 2002–14

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Source: HKMA.

In early 2015, the authorities announced new macroprudential measures to safeguard financial stability.11 Renewed concerns about the above-trend credit-to-GDP ratio and housing price growth prompted the authorities to announce a countercyclical capital buffer of 0.625 percent that will be activated at the beginning of 2016. This will be accompanied by a capital conservation buffer of 0.625 percent and higher loss absorbency surcharges of 0.25 percent to 0.625 percent for domestic systemically important banks implemented under Basel III. While these measures go beyond the property sector, their implementation should enhance banks’ overall resilience and reduce their vulnerability to property sector shocks. Over the longer term, though, structural policies that ensure adequate housing supply will be key to preventing imbalances in the property sector.12

B. The Netherlands

Background

The Netherlands was hit hard by the global financial crisis. The Netherlands has a very large financial sector (assets amounting to about 600 percent of GDP at end-2013) and includes large and complex global financial firms.13 Dutch banks were exposed to the U.S. mortgage market and were also affected by the lack of liquidity in the inter-bank market when the crisis unfolded. Pension and insurance firms were also affected.

Sizeable government funds were required to support the financial sector during the crisis. These took the form of equity injections, liquidity support, and guarantees. While these interventions helped stabilize the situation, it led to extensive state ownership or participation, including in four of the five largest financial groups. Following a divestment strategy state ownership has wound down to only two institutions by late 2014.

The measures taken helped restore financial soundness. By end-2013 all large banks had capital buffers well above the minimum requirements. The capital adequacy ratio (CAR) stood at 14.9 percent at end-2013, and comprised mostly of core Tier 1 capital. In addition, the nonperforming loan (NPL) ratio was at manageable levels.

Notwithstanding these improvements banks balance sheet risks remain, on account of the large exposure to the real estate sector, the slow economic recovery, and the continued reliance on wholesale funding.14 As of end-2013 residential real estate loans represented about 30 percent of total bank loans and the process of household and bank deleveraging continued. The 34 percent share of underwater mortgages remains an important vulnerability.15 Although mortgage defaults have remained low (in part because the Dutch personal bankruptcy system is creditor friendly with full recourse to borrower’s assets), the large debt overhang in a context of low inflation is likely to continue holding back private consumption. Moreover, funding risk remains a challenge, owing to banks’ high reliance on wholesale funding (Figure 3).

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

The Netherlands: Selected Macroprudential Indicators, 1989–2013

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Sources: BIS, WEO, IFS, CEIC, Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), and IMF staff calculations.1 The “credit-to-GDP gap” is defined as the deviation of the ratio of credit to GDP from its long run trend. The long run trend is calculated from the credit-to-GDP series by using a one-sided Hodrick-Prescott filter. This calculation uses a high smoothing parameter (lamda equals 400,000) since the series is quarterly. See IMF (2014c) for further details. Credit-to-GDP gap is calculated from the earliest GDP data available.

Household balance sheets also remain vulnerable. Prior to the crisis, in the context of ample global liquidity, a favorable macroeconomic environment, and supportive tax and regulatory incentives, households accumulated substantial mortgage debt at generous LTV ratios, spurred in part by advantageous mortgage interest deductibility (MID). Mortgage debt as a share of GDP increased steadily until 2012 (Figure 4), while household debt as a share of disposable income doubled from 2000 to 2012—to the highest in the euro area. The expansion in credit activity led to the sharp increases in the credit gap during 2000–06 and 2009–10.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

The Netherlands: Household Debt Indicators, 2000–13

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Since their 2008 peak, house prices have fallen by about 20 percent in nominal terms (about 25 percent in real terms) (Figure 3). House prices rose on average by 60 percent in nominal terms from 2000 to the third quarter 2008.16 The rate of decline from the peak was severe compared to previous downturns. Prices have since stabilized and recently there has been a pick-up in demand for residential mortgage loans.17

Institutional framework

Netherlands was one of the early adopters (in 2002) of the so called “twin-peaks” model of supervision. The central bank (DNB) became a single prudential supervisor of all financial institutions (banks, insurance companies, investment firms, pension funds, and securities firms). And the Authority for Financial Markets (AFM) was created as a supervisor responsible for conduct-of-business supervision including supervision of security market activities.

The twin-peaks model worked well during the 2008–09 crisis.18 Laws that permitted information sharing between the two peaks and the MOF were particularly useful. The pre-crisis institutional set up also helped. For example, the coordination group on financial stability used to meet a few times per year began to meet weekly during the crisis. The crisis showed that having both micro and macro prudential supervision consolidated within the DNB, allowed the central bank to take a systemic view across the financial sector and act quickly and decisively. The clear division of powers and responsibilities across key institutions (DNB, AFM, and MOF) were also instrumental in achieving coordination.

Nevertheless, the report on the 2011 Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) identified areas that could be strengthened.19 In particular, the crisis had underlined the importance of macroprudential regulation and supervision. It noted that there was scope for further integration of its macroprudential and microprudential supervision and for increasing the number of macroprudential policy instruments. The FSAP report also recommended that the DNB be given a greater role in the rule-making process and have some discretion to adjust levels of designated macroprudential instruments. At the time of the 2011 FSAP, most regulatory requirements were directly contained in the Act for Financial Supervision or in Decrees that were issued by the MOF (for example, the decree setting mortgage LTV ratios). The FSAP suggested instead that the DNB be allowed to change the LTV, perhaps within a range agreed with the MOF.

In recent years, the Netherlands has taken steps to strengthen macroprudential oversight. In 2012, the authorities established, through a Ministerial Decree, a macroprudential body—the Financial Stability Committee (FSC).20 The FSC consists of seven representatives: three from the DNB (including the Chair), and two each from the MOF and the AFM. The FSC is responsible for identifying risks to financial stability, issue warnings and recommendations, and monitor the implementation of European Systemic Risk Board recommendations. While the FSC discusses the main risks and coordinates policy, the use of instruments remains the responsibility of the individual authority.21 The FSC is useful for coordination beyond the use of prudential tools, such as the MID regime. More importantly, staring in January 2014, the division of labor between the MOF and DNB was changed by law, with responsibility of financial stability being entrusted to the DNB and some macroprudential instruments being explicitly assigned to it. In particular, the DNB was designated as the relevant authority for macroprudential instruments forming part of the European Union capital requirements for banks,22 such as capital buffers for systemic banks and counter cyclical capital requirements, and risk weights for property loan exposures. The MOF remains responsible for other instruments (for example limits on LTV and loan-to-income (LTI) ratios).23, 24

Use of macroprudential policy instruments

During the upswing in housing prices average mortgage LTV ratios were well over 100 percent. For example, LTV ratios on new mortgages averaged 114 percent in 2007, and over 120 percent in 2010. The authorities did not set a formal LTV requirement on mortgage lending, but instead adopted a voluntary mortgage lenders’ code of conduct in the Fall of 2006. The code restricted mortgage service cost to 30 percent of gross annual income (in effect a voluntary DSTI ratio), and did not set maximum LTV ratios. Compliance with the voluntary code was less than perfect in 2007/08.25 One of the reasons attributed to the growing indebtedness of households was the generous MID regime, which allowed for unlimited deductions of interest payments on mortgages of primary residences. Against this background, household debt-to-disposable income continued to grow, and exceeded 270 percent in 2010.

Comfort with the existing buffers and vulnerability indicators less worrisome than in some peers led the authorities to not adopt stricter measures to arrest the growth of household debt. Mortgages were not deemed risky as systemic risk was seen as being reduced by collateral in mortgage-linked insurance and savings accounts; while a sharp correction in house prices was seen as unlikely given the limited land supply and the generous MID regime. Moreover, indicators of vulnerabilities in the housing/mortgage market were mixed, especially when compared with other European peers. Netherlands was not an outlier in the region in terms of growth in house prices and indicators of affordability. During 2002:Q1–2006:Q3 house prices in European countries rose by 56 percent on average, where as house prices in the Netherlands rose by 22 percent.26 As no action was taken the rising house prices and household debt continued unabated until mid 2008.

Following the crisis macroprudential instruments started to be used more proactively. In January 2013, a cap on LTV was introduced. New legislation mandated a gradual reduction in LTV ratios. The reason for the gradual approach was to not destabilize the housing market in an environment of weak domestic demand and falling house prices. Starting 2013 all new loans could not exceed a threshold LTV ratio of 105 percent. The limit was lowered to 104 percent on January 1, 2014, and to 103 percent on January 1, 2015, and is set to be reduced by one percentage point per year until January 2018. These limits have been introduced through primary legislation, based on a proposal by the DNB. An LTV ratio of 100 percent however, would still be high compared internationally,27 and it would thus, seem appropriate to set a more ambitious timetable after 2018.

Maximum LTI ratios at about the same time (January 2013) were imposed on mortgage loans (through a MOF regulation).28 The LTI ratios are based on gross household income, and the maximum financing cost allowed as a percentage of gross income. The financing cost limits were provided by the National Institute for Family Finance Information (Nationaal Instituut voor Budgetvoorlichting), and are expected to be updated annually.

The MID regime was also reformed in January 2013. Since then the tax benefit is applicable only if the new mortgage is fully amortized within 30 years (at least on an annuity basis). New interest only mortgages no longer qualify for tax deductibility. As existing mortgages have been grandfathered, the impact of this change on the housing market will only show over time.

In April 2014, the DNB announced additional capital buffer requirements for systemic banks. The additional capital buffer requirements will be imposed on four systemic banks and will be phased in during 2016–19. The systemic buffer will be three percent of risk weighted assets for ING Bank, Rabobank, and ABN Amro Bank, and one percent for SNS Bank.29

The DNB is also considering the adoption of counter cyclical capital buffers and leverage ratios. This would be in line with Basel III (and EU wide implementation). In particular, the DNB plans to assess (four times a year) whether credit growth calls for the imposition of counter cyclical buffers.30 The authorities have announced their intention to impose a higher minimum leverage ratio of four percent for systemically important financial institutions (compared with three percent recommended under Basel III).31 In this context, DNB has asked the four largest banks to submit capital migration plans showing compliance with the new requirement by 2018.

C. New Zealand

Background

New Zealand banks weathered the global financial crisis relatively well. The New Zealand banking system is dominated by four large subsidiaries of Australian banks, which had withstood the crisis without major problems. Since the crisis those subsidiary banks have taken steps to strengthen their balance sheets. Capital adequacy has improved since 2007, with Tier 1 capital ratio reaching 12.4 percent in 2013. The rise in nonperforming loans peaked at around two percent in 2011. Profitability returned to pre-crisis levels in 2011.

However, the crisis exposed key vulnerabilities in the New Zealand banking system. Banks relied heavily on short-term, offshore wholesale funding for their normal operations and the disruption of interbank lending following the collapse of Lehman Brothers gave rise to severe funding pressures. In response, the Reserve Bank of New Zealand (RBNZ, the central bank) provided liquidity support (e.g., by expanding the list of eligible collateral, extending the reverse repo facility to 30 days, and introducing a term auction facility), and the government introduced wholesale funding guarantees in 2008. Following the crisis the banks improved their funding structures; banks’ reliance on short-term wholesale funding for example, declined from 53 percent of total funding in 2007 to 42 percent in late 2010. Nonetheless, reliance on offshore wholesale funding remains substantial (reflected in high loan-to-deposit ratios, Figure 5), and banks remain vulnerable to disruptions in wholesale funding and foreign exchange swaps.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

New Zealand: Selected Macroprudential Indicators, 1988–2013

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Sources: Haver Analytics Inc., IFS, CEIC, OECD, and IMF staff calculations.1 The “credit-to-GDP gap” is defined as the deviation of the ratio of credit to GDP from its long run trend. The long run trend is calculated from the credit-to-GDP series by using a one-sided Hodrick-Prescott filter. This calculation uses a high smoothing parameter (lamda equals to 400,000) since the series is quarterly. See IMF (2014c) for further details. Credit-to-GDP gap is calculated from the earliest domestic credit data available.

Banks are also significantly exposed to highly indebted households and farmers. The largest exposure is to households (Figure 6), with over 50 percent of bank lending accounted for by residential mortgages (Figure 5). Affordability metrics show a significant deterioration in the last two decades. As of third quarter 2012 house prices were estimated to be about 25 percent above equilibrium and are beginning to rise again, particularly in Auckland and Christchurch.32 While mortgage lending is seen as a better risk than agriculture lending (a key sector in New Zealand), a sharp decline in house prices could force many borrowers into negative equity, and a sharp increase in unemployment could increase potential of defaults. Risks to lending in agriculture arise from the potential for droughts or a sharp decline in commodity prices, especially since access to insurance vehicles to mitigate such risks is limited.

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

New Zealand: Bank Lending and Household Debt, 1999–2012

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Institutional framework

The RBNZ draws its macroprudential powers from the Central Bank Act, which gives it the responsibility for “promoting the maintenance of a sound and efficient financial system.” Following the global financial crisis the RBNZ began evaluating the use of macroprudential policy. In 2013 the authorities formalized the macroprudential framework with a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) on macroprudential policy signed by the Governor of the RBNZ and the Minister of Finance that provides the RBNZ with a framework to implement macroprudential policy.33 Concretely the MoU authorizes the RBNZ to use four tools: (i) core funding ratio (CFR); (ii) countercyclical capital buffer; (iii) sectoral capital requirements; and (iv) LTV ratios on loans to the residential property sector. The MoU requires that the RBNZ informs the Minister of Finance when it is contemplating using the macroprudential tools, but the final decision on implementation resides with the RBNZ. As per the RBNZ Act the banks would be given an opportunity to comment on the tools being considered. The MoU covers the application of macroprudential policy only on banks (which account for the majority of lending). Any extension of macroprudential instruments to nonbanks or involvement of other agencies would require consultation with the Minister of Finance.34

The RBNZ announced its macroprudential policy framework shortly after the signing of the MoU. In a policy position paper, published in May 2013 the RBNZ outlined the objective of macroprudential policy, identified the instruments that could be used, and detailed the process of assessing and implementing macroprudential policy.35 It explained that the RBNZ would inform the public about its assessments and decisions on macroprudential policy primarily through its regular six-monthly financial stability reports. The framework also contemplates giving banks notice periods to implement changes in the macroprudential instrument (i.e., up to twelve months for counter cyclical buffer; up to three months for sectoral capital requirements; up to six month for adjustments to the CFR; and at least two weeks for LTV ratios). The RBNZ also identified a set of macroprudential indicators that it plans to review periodically to help guide implementation of macroprudential policy (Table 1).36

Table 1.

New Zealand: Macroprudential Indicators

article image
Source: Wolken (2013, pp. 27–30).

Use of macroprudential policy instruments

Before the macroprudential framework had been formalized New Zealand had started to adopt liquidity rules to contain/address banks’ dependence on short-term wholesale funding. In April 2010, the RBNZ introduced two quantitative requirements: liquidity mismatch ratios and a CFR (similar in spirit to the Basel Committee’s proposed liquidity standards—the liquidity coverage ratio and net stable funding ratio). The liquidity mismatch ratios compares a bank’s likely cash inflows to its likely outflows over a period of one week and one month, while the CFR aims to ensure that banks hold sufficient stable retail and long-term wholesale funding. The CFR is based on a comparison between an estimate of the funding of the bank that is stable and can be assumed to stay in place for at least one year (‘core funding’), and the core lending business of the bank that needs to be funded on a continuing basis.37 The RBNZ foreshadowed the adoption of these requirements through a Consultation Paper issued in October 2008.38 Following a consultation period, regulations were issued on October 22, 2009 with implementation beginning in April 2010. The minimum CFR was initially set at 65 percent and it was estimated that at the time all the banks’ CFR would be just slightly above the required minimum.39 The RBNZ also indicated at that time that it planned to increase the minimum CFR to 75 percent in stages to allow sufficient time for banks to adjust to meet the new requirements. The minimum CFR was increased to 70 percent from July 1, 2011; and to 75 percent from January 1, 2013 (Figure 7).

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

New Zealand: Banking System Core Funding Ratio, 2000–13

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Sources: SSR, RBNZ liquidity statistics.Note: The dotted section of the core funding ratio is an approximation based on SSR data.

After the formalization of the macroprudential framework, the RBNZ introduced a cap on the share of new high-LTV housing loans. Noting that debt-to-disposable income was high by historical standards and house prices were rising, beginning October 2013, housing loans with LTV ratios above 80 percent were restricted to ten percent of all new housing loans made by a bank. Interestingly New Zealand introduced this cap on LTVs at a time when the credit gap was negative (Figure 5). The RBNZ argued that the credit gap was not a useful metric in the aftermath of a large credit boom, such as the one experienced by New Zealand during 2002–07. It explained that the decision to impose caps on LTVs was influenced by two factors—rising house prices (which brought house prices relative to income or rents to very high levels); and the rise in lending to borrowers with less than 20 percent equity.40 Analysis by RBNZ showed that loss rates of high-LTV loans increased more than those of lower-LTV loans following a sharp fall in house prices. Prior to the introduction of the minimum LTV ratios on new lending the RBNZ undertook a consultative process and conducted an impact analysis.41 The RBNZ decided to impose temporary restrictions on high-LTV residential mortgage lending instead of a sectoral capital requirement because it concluded that the former measure would be more effective in dampening excessive house price growth and to building up resilience. The RBNZ also concluded that it would be administratively complex to target LTV restriction to particular regions.

Following the imposition of the caps there was a sharp fall in loans with high LTVs. Housing loans with high LTVs made up 5.2 percent of total new commitments in February 2014 compared with 25.1 percent in September 2013 (Table 2). In addition, the slowdown was accompanied by lower house sales and a lower growth in house prices.42

Table 2.

New Zealand: New Residential Mortgage Lending, August 2013 – February 2014

article image
Source: RBNZ.

Figures do not include the construction lending exemption announced in December 2013.

High-LTV is where the LTV is above 80 percent. Percentages are calculated from non-rounded figures.

The ‘high-LTV share after exemptions’ is calculated by subtracting exempt lending (with LTV above 80 percent) from new commitments then dividing by total new commitments less exempt lending (with LTV above 80 percent). Though similar, it is not the same as the high LTV “speed limit.” Banks’ compliance with the “high-LTV” speed limit will initially be measured against the average ‘high-LTV share after exemptions,’ for October 1, 2013 to March 31, 2014. Thereafter, it will be measured against the three-month rolling average for the larger banks (ANZ, ASB, BNZ, Kiwibank and Westpac) and the six-month rolling average for the smaller banks.

D. Singapore

Background

Singapore’s financial system is very sophisticated/advanced. Singapore is one of the world’s largest financial centers, built around a core of domestic and international banks, which offer a wide range of financial services. Singapore’s financial system is exposed to a broad array of domestic and global risks (as a consequence of its interconnectedness) ranging from possible spillovers from changes in global interest rate to a deterioration of economic conditions in Europe or in China.43 Its most pressing vulnerability, however, stems from the rapid growth of credit and real estate prices in recent years.

Singapore’s real estate market is dominated by public housing, which accounts for almost 80 percent of the housing stock. The government’s Housing and Development Board (HDB) builds apartments (flats) on government-allocated land and sells them at subsidized prices to eligible Singapore citizens. Apartments can be resold after a minimum occupancy period of five years to other eligible citizens or Singapore permanent residents. While the program has helped increase home ownership to about 90 percent of the eligible population, supply seems to have fallen short of demand in recent years. Since 2003, house prices have almost doubled, accompanied by strong growth in mortgages, and total credit growth of 15 percent, on average, during 2010–13. The growth in mortgages has fueled an increase in household debt as a percent of disposable income posing an increasing risk to the banking sector. Mortgages account for 35 percent of credit to the private sector, the bulk of which is provided for private housing purchases (Figure 8).

Figure 8.
Figure 8.

Singapore: Selected Macroprudential Indicators, 1990–2013

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Sources: BIS, WEO, IFS, CEIC, OECD, GPG, Haver Analytics Inc., and IMF staff calculations.1 The “credit-to-GDP gap” is defined as the deviation of the ratio of credit to GDP from its long run trend. The long run trend is calculated from the credit-to-GDP series by using a one-sided Hodrick-Prescott filter. This calculation uses a high smoothing parameter (lamda equals to 400,000) since the series is quarterly. See IMF (2014c) for further details. Credit-to-GDP gap is calculated from the earliest domestic credit data available.

Singapore’s financial sector emerged largely unscathed from the global financial crisis. Domestic financial markets were tested but continued to operate in an orderly fashion. Singapore money market experienced liquidity pressures in the Fall of 2008 and interbank rates spiked with rising counterparty risk, but markets never seized up. Liquidity pressures eased by January 2009, following coordinated actions by central banks around the globe. The Singapore authorities implemented a range of measures to support the stability of Singapore’s financial system. In particular, in 2008, the Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS) (i) adopted a temporary blanket deposit guarantee (as was done by others in the region); (ii) agreed to a currency swap arrangement with the U.S. Fed.; and (iii) broadened access to its liquidity facility. Activity in Singapore financial sector recovered quickly, and by 2010, credit to non bank sector was above pre-Lehman levels.

Institutional framework

The MAS is responsible for conducting macroprudential policy. MAS is both a central bank and an integrated financial supervisor overseeing all financial institutions and is mandated to promote financial stability.44 Under the current institutional arrangement, the Deputy Prime Minister and Minister of Finance serves as the Chairman of the Board of MAS, who presides over the Board level Chairman’s Meeting (CM) where microprudential and macroprudential policies as well as monetary policy are decided.45 At the level of the CM, the MAS holds meetings with the MOF to discuss macroeconomic and financial stability issues and seek agreement on policies that can have broad ramifications.

The CM’s role in macroprudential policy is supported by the MAS Management Financial Stability Committee (FSC). The FSC is chaired by the Managing Director of MAS and comprises other MAS senior managers. It coordinates policies aimed at maintaining financial stability as well as the stability of asset and consumer prices and collaborates with all relevant government agencies. For instance, the MAS collaborates with the Urban Redevelopment Authority, HDB, and MOF on policies that affect the housing sector. The FSC receives inputs from MAS staff in financial supervision departments, including the macroeconomic surveillance department, drawing both on bottom-up assessments of risks in individual financial institutions and on a top-down assessment of the system as a whole.

Use of macroprudential policy instruments

In the aftermath of the global financial crisis the Singapore authorities started to tighten macroprudential policy to cool the housing market. The tightening was incremental and targeted, and the instruments used included caps on the LTV and DSTI ratios, and loan tenor rules (often accompanied by stamp duties and increased government land sales; Box 2). In addition, to limit excessive increases in household leverage the authorities introduced measures on auto loans and unsecured credit (including credit cards).

Singapore—Macroprudential Measures, 2009–13

article image
article image

In February 2014, MAS refined the TDSR framework with broader exemptions. Borrowers refinancing owner-occupied housing loans borrowed before the TDSR’s June 2013 introduction would be exempt from the 60 percent limits, and those refinancing public housing loans from limits on the mortgage servicing ratio. Similarly, borrowers were allowed to maintain the remaining loan tenors when refinancing owner-occupied housing loans taken before the loan tenor limits were introduced.

The combination of macroprudential and fiscal measures was effective in building buffers and moderating price appreciation in Singapore. The recent macroprudential measures lowered the average LTV ratio on new housing loans, and increased the share of borrowers with single mortgages. As of 2013:Q1, over 90 percent of outstanding housing loans had an LTV ratio below 80 percent. The rise in housing prices has abated. The HDB Resale Price Index declined eight percent from its peak in mid-2013 to the end of 2014 following a rise of almost 50 percent since end-2008. Similarly, the Private Residential Property Price Index declined by five percent from its peak in the third quarter of 2013 to the end of 2014. The decline in housing prices was accompanied by a sharp drop in transaction volumes. Annual new home sales in the private residential market declined by ⅓ in 2013 and by 50 percent in 2014.46 Sales of HDB units also declined (by 28 percent in 2013 and a further four percent in 2014). While the macroprudential measures have had a cooling effect on the housing market, continued vigilance is warranted as the prospective rise in interest rates could make it difficult for households to service their debt given the large proportion of mortgages with floating interest rates. Over the medium term, maintaining adequate land supply for housing would be key to the healthy development of the housing market.47

E. Sweden

Background

Sweden’s banking system is large, concentrated and regionally interconnected. Bank assets amount to over 400 percent of GDP and the four biggest banks account for about 85 percent of the system’s assets. More than 80 percent of the lending activities of the four largest banks are to households and firms in Sweden, Denmark, Finland, and Norway.

Since the mid 1990s house prices and household indebtedness have risen steadily. Prices rose by about 40 percent during 1995–2010, and only suffered a mild correction during the global financial crisis. Since 2012 house prices have rallied, growing by 7½ percent per year for single-family homes and by nearly 13 percent for tenant-owned apartments in the first half of 2014.48 Household debt has almost doubled since 1995; the ratio of household debt to personal disposable income reached 174 percent in 2013, driven largely by increases in mortgage debt (Figure 9). The share of variable interest rate debt also increased to over 65 percent in 2013 from below ten percent in 1996. Banks’ mortgage lending is largely funded through the covered bond market.49 Housing and real estate developers’ loans account for 60 percent of total lending.

Figure 9.
Figure 9.

Sweden: Household Debt, 1971–2014

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Several factors contributed to the increase in house prices and household debt. The main ones include: a low interest rate environment and strong economic growth; a tax regime that provides a 30 percent mortgage interest deduction; a stagnant supply of new houses; and financial innovation (such as “interest only” loans or “amortization-free” mortgages). Mortgages and the share of mortgage loans to total credit increased rapidly in 2008–09, pushing the credit gap measure to positive territory in 2005 (Figure 10).

Figure 10.
Figure 10.

Sweden: Selected Macroprudential Indicators, 1980–2013

(In percent)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Sources: WEO, IFS, Riksbank, OECD, Statistics Sweden, and IMF staff calculations.1 The “credit-to-GDP gap” is defined as the deviation of the ratio of credit to GDP from its long run trend. The long run trend is calculated from the credit-to-GDP series by using a one-sided Hodrick-Prescott filter. This calculation uses a high smoothing parameter (lamda equals 400,000) since the series is quarterly. See IMF (2014c) for further details. Credit-to-GDP gap is calculated from the earliest GDP data available.

Swedish banks are highly dependent on wholesale funding. The loan-to-deposit ratio for the sector is well over 200 percent (Figure 10). About half of the wholesale funding is short-term and in foreign currency. The rest of the funding comes in the form of long-term covered and senior unsecured bonds, a significant share of which is denominated in foreign currency. The banks’ mortgage lending is largely funded through the covered bond market (mostly in local currency). Even though covered bond funding is a more stable source of funding than other wholesale funding instruments, this funding structure renders banks vulnerable to a drying up of wholesale markets or sharp increases in funding costs.

The global financial crisis had a significant impact on Sweden’s financial sector. Several Swedish banks faced funding pressures as wholesale funding markets dried up. The authorities took rapid steps to help restore confidence in the system, including increasing central bank liquidity and approving legislation enabling the government to intervene, for example, with guarantees and capital injections.

Institutional framework

Financial stability responsibilities fall on many institutions.50 The Swedish Financial Supervisory Authority (FSA), established in 1991, is a single integrated regulator responsible for the supervision and regulation of banking, securities, and insurance industries and has a statutory mandate for financial stability and consumer protection. The Riksbank (central bank) is responsible for promoting a safe and efficient payments system but does not have an explicit mandate for financial stability. However, it has control over instruments related to financial stability such as provision of emergency lending and systemic liquidity. The Swedish National Debt Office (SNDO) manages the stability fund (along with the MOF) and the deposit insurance and investor protection systems, and is the support authority when public funds are allocated to credit institutions.51 The MOF is responsible for legislation concerning the financial sector and plays a role in crisis management especially when public funds are required to support failing institutions.

In 2011 the government formed a Financial Crisis Committee (FCC) to propose improvements in the regulatory framework. In an interim report, in January 2013, the FCC proposed the creation of a macroprudential council chaired by the governor of the Riksbank and including the Director General of FSA, one additional official each from Riksbank and FSA and two independent members appointed by the government. 52 The FCC recommended that responsibility for macroprudential policy be shared by FSA and Riksbank. Both the Riksbank and the FSA disagreed with the FCC proposal.

In August 2013, the government decided that the FSA would be responsible for macroprudential policy.53 The Riksbank was not given any mandate on macroprudential issues. A Financial Stability Council was also established, which replaced a council for cooperation on macroprudential policy.54 The Financial Stability Council consists of the Minister for Financial Markets, the Director General of FSA, the Director General of the SNDO and the Governor of the Riksbank. The purpose of the council is to discuss issues relating to financial stability and the need for measures to prevent the build-up of financial imbalances. In the event of a financial crisis, it would also discuss the need for measures to manage the crisis. The Council is a forum for discussion and not a decision-making body. In particular, the Council does not have any formal powers of recommendation, thereby reducing the Riksbank’s influence on macroprudential policy.

Use of macroprudential policy instruments

In October 2010 the FSA introduced an LTV ratio on mortgages. An LTV cap of 85 percent was applied to all new mortgages or extensions to existing mortgages that used the home as collateral. Prior to October 2010, no LTV ratios on mortgages existed. At the time of the measure, the average LTV ratio had risen to 55 percent at end-2010 (from ten percent in 1995), and the average LTV ratios on new-lending had risen to about 71 percent. Twelve percent of new borrowers had an LTV ratio above 90 percent and one third above 85 percent.55 The FSA expected that the new LTV limit would help curb mortgage loans and at the same time not have a major adverse impact on mortgage practices and the housing market.56 Following the cap, the share of households with loans exceeding LTV ratio of 85 percent dropped and the average LTV ratio of new loans in 2013 stayed at about 70 percent (Figure 11).57

Figure 11.
Figure 11.

Sweden: Loan-to-Value Ratio, 2002–13

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Two and a half years later, in May 2013, the FSA introduced a risk-weight floor of 15 percent for mortgages.58 This measure applies to firms that use the internal ratings based approach to calculate the capital requirement for credit risk on Swedish mortgages. The risk weight floor of 15 percent is set on an aggregated portfolio level for each bank and relates to the exposure-weighted average risk weight. This measure was implemented through the framework of Pillar 2 as part of FSA’s ongoing supervisory review and evaluation process. This approach was adopted as FSA concluded that regulatory changes on risk weights through the adoption of CRR and CRD4 would not be possible. The FSA recently increased the risk weight floor to 25 percent.59

In November 2014, the FSA announced plans to introduce mandatory amortization of mortgages. The proposed regulation would ensure that new loans are to be repaid in two steps. New mortgages with an LTV higher than 70 percent will repay at least two percent of their original loan each year until the LTV ratio is 70 percent. Thereafter, households will repay at least one percent of the loan each year until the LTV ratio is 50 percent.60

A liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) requirement was adopted on January 1, 2013. 61 Following the financial crisis the FSA introduced enhanced reporting requirements for credit institutions and investment firms, which enabled it to monitor Basel III-type liquidity indicators starting in 2011. The LCR requirement adopted in 2013 is based on the Basel III guidelines and was introduced ahead of the international schedule. This requirement is applied to large firms and financial groups and currently eight firms have to comply. The LCR measures the amount of liquid assets a bank can rely on for a stress period lasting 30 days assuming no other source of funding is available. The ratio is designed as a single ratio covering all currencies as well as separately for the U.S. dollar and euro in view of substantial foreign exchange funding liquidity risk that Swedish banks face. A ratio of one or 100 percent implies that the bank is in compliance with the regulation (Figure 12).

Figure 12.
Figure 12.

Sweden: Major Banks’ Liquidity Coverage Ratio, 2013–14

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 123; 10.5089/9781513500812.001.A001

Capital requirements higher than those stipulated in Basel III have been proposed for the four largest banks. The MOF, FSA and Riksbank proposed that the largest four Swedish banks have capital requirements equivalent to ten percent on January 1, 2013, rising to 12 percent on January 1, 2015. These thresholds include a capital conservation buffer of 2.5 percent but not a countercyclical buffer. In May 2014, the FSA decided that the systemically important banks will hold additional capital buffer of three percent and a further two percent within the framework of Pillar 2, as of January 1, 2015.62

In May 2014, the FSA announced the intention to implement a countercyclical capital buffer requirement.63 The level of the counter cyclical buffer was set at one percent of risk weighted assets and was decided in consultation with the other authorities that make up the Financial Stability Council. To give time to banks to meet the additional capital requirement the countercyclical buffer will be applied as of September 2015.64

III. Concluding Remarks

Increasing attention has been given to the field of macroprudential policy following the global financial crisis. This paper reviews the use of macroprudential policy in five economies (Hong Kong SAR, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Singapore, and Sweden). All these jurisdictions actively implemented macroprudential policy measures following the global financial crisis. The analysis shows that each jurisdiction reviewed adopted an institutional framework for macroprudential policy suited to their own circumstances. The evidence reviewed confirms that “one size does not fit all,” and that it is possible to conduct macroprudential policy with a heterogenous set of institutional frameworks. In all cases, most of the macroprudential tools used were directed at containing risks arising from a booming housing market (for e.g., LTV and DSTI ratio limits). Some of the cases studied also took steps to enhance the resilience of the banking system to more general cyclical and structural risks (for e.g., liquidity requirements and additional capital requirement for systemically important institutions). While there is some early evidence that the measures taken have enhanced banking system resilience, it is still early to determine their full impact.

References

  • De Nederlandsche Bank, 2013, “New Macroprudential Instruments for DNB,” DNBulletin, June 25, 2013 (De Nederlandsche Bank, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Nederlandsche Bank, 2014a, “First Signs of Recovery in Credit Demand for Residential Mortgages,” Statistical News Release, May 20, 2014 (De Nederlandsche Bank, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Nederlandsche Bank, 2014b, “Overview of Financial Stability Spring 2014,” (De Nederlandsche Bank, Netherlands).

  • De Nederlandsche Bank, 2014c, “DNB Imposes Additional Capital Buffer Requirement on Dutch Systemic Banks,” Press Release, April 29, 2014 (De Nederlandsche Bank, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Financial Crisis Committee, 2013, “Summary—Preventing and Managing Financial Crises,” (Ministry of Finance, Sweden).

  • Financial Stability Board, 2014, “Peer Review of the Netherlands: Review Report,” November 11, 2014 (Financial Stability Board: Switzerland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finansinspektionen, 2010, “Referral Memorandum—Draft General Council on the Restriction of Loans Secured by Residential,” (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finansinspektionen, 2012, “Finansinspektionen’s Regulations Regarding Requirements for a Liquidity Coverage Ratio and Reporting of Liquid Assets and Cash Flows,” FFFS 2012:6 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finansinspektionen, 2014a, “The Swedish Mortgage Market 2014,” (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

  • Finansinspektionen, 2014b, “Capital Requirements for Swedish Banks,” Memorandum September 8, 2014 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

  • Finansinspektionen, 2014c, “New mortgages to be repaid down to 50 percent,” Press Release November 11, 2014 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finansinspektionen, 2014d, “Forthcoming Capital Requirements for Swedish Banks,” Press Release May 8, 2014 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finansinspektionen, 2014e, “Capital Requirements for Swedish Banks,” Memorandum May 8, 2014 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

  • Finansinspektionen, 2014f, “Finansinspektionen’s Regulatory Code,” September 12, 2014 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

  • Finansinspektionen, 2014g, “Regulations Regarding the Countercyclical Buffer Rate,” Decision Memorandum September 8, 2014 (Finansinspektionen, Sweden).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • He, Dong 2014, “The Effects of Macroprudential Policies on Housing Market Risks: Evidence from Hong Kong,” Banque De France Financial Stability Review, No. 18, April 2014.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hong Kong Monetary Authority, 2006, “Mandate & Governance of the Hong Kong Monetary Authority,” HKMA Background Brief No. 3, December 2006 (Hong Kong SAR: Hong Kong Monetary Authority).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hong Kong Monetary Authority, 2013, “Half-Yearly Monetary and Financial Stability Report, September 2013,” (Hong Kong SAR: Hong Kong Monetary Authority).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hong Kong Monetary Authority, 2015, “Announcement by the Monetary Authority of Applicable Jurisdictional Countercyclical Capital Buffer Ratio for Hong Kong - 27 January 2015,” (Hong Kong SAR: Hong Kong Monetary Authority).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hoskin, Kevin, Ian Nield and Jeremy Richardson, 2009, “The Reserve Bank’s new liquidity policy for banks,” RBNZ Bulletin, Vol. 72, No. 4, December 2009 (Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2011a, “Kingdom of the Netherlands—Netherlands: Financial Sector Assessment Program Update—Technical Note on Financial Sector Supervision: The Twin Peaks Model,” IMF Country Report No. 11/208 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2011b, “Kingdom of the Netherlands—Netherlands: Financial System Stability Assessment,” IMF Country Report No. 11/144 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2011c, “Kingdom of the Netherlands—Netherlands: Selected Issues and Analytical Notes,” IMF Country Report No. 11/143 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2011d, “Sweden: Financial Sector Stability Assessment,” IMF Country Report No. 11/172 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2011e, “Sweden: Financial Sector Assessment Program Update—Technical Note on Household Indebtedness: Implications for Financial Stability,” IMF Country Report No. 11/289 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2013a, “Key Aspects of Macroprudential Policy,” IMF Policy Paper, June (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2013b, “Kingdom of the Netherlands—Netherlands: Staff Report for the 2013 Article IV Consultation,” IMF Country Report No. 13/115 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2013c, “New Zealand: Staff Report for the 2013 Article IV Consultation,” IMF Country Report No. 13/117 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2013d, “Singapore: Staff Report for the 2013 Article IV Consultation,” IMF Country Report No. 13/328 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2013e, “Singapore: Financial System Stability Assessment,” IMF Country Report No. 13/325 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2014a, “Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy,” IMF Policy Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2014b, “People’s Republic of China-Hong Kong Special Administrative Region: Financial System Stability Assessment,” IMF Country Report No. 14/130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2014c, “Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy—Detailed Guidance on Instruments,” IMF Policy Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2014d, “Kingdom of the Netherlands: Concluding Statement of the 2014 Article IV Mission,” October 6, 2014 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2014e, “Sweden: Staff Report for the 2014 Article IV Consultation,” IMF Country Report No. 14/261 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leeuwen, Ruben van, and Philip Bokeloh, 2012, “Mortgage Market in the Netherlands,” (ABN-AMRO: Netherlands).

  • Ministry of Finance, 2012a, “Decree Establishing the Financial Stability Committee,” FM2012/1193M, November 2, 2012 (Ministry of Finance, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ministry of Finance, 2012b, “Setting Out the Income Criteria for the Granting of Mortgage Loans and Rules for Determining the Maximum Amount of a Mortgage Loan Based on the Value of the Dwelling (Temporary Mortgage Loan Regulation),” Ministry of Finance Regulation FM/2012/1887 M, December 12, 2012 (Ministry of Finance, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ministry of Finance, 2013a, “Banking vision paper: towards a robust, ethical and competitive banking sector,” Ministry of Finance News Item, August 23, 2013 (Ministry of Finance, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ministry of Finance, 2013b, “New Measures for Tighter Framework and Stable Financial System,” Press Release, August 26, 2013, Ministry of Finance, Sweden.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ministry of Finance and Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 2013, “Memorandum of Understanding between the Minister of Finance and the Governor of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand,” (Ministry of Finance and Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Monetary Authority of Singapore, 2013, “Financial Stability Review December 2013,” (Monetary Authority of Singapore: Singapore).

  • Monetary Authority of Singapore, 2013/14, “Annual Report 2013/14,” (Monetary Authority of Singapore: Singapore).

  • Nederlandse Vereniging van Banken, 2011, “The Code of Conduct for Mortgage Loans,” (Nederlandse Vereniging van Banken, Netherlands).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nier, Erlend W., Jacek Osiñski, Luis I. Jácome, and Pamela Madrid, 2011, “Institutional Models for Macroprudential Policy,” IMF Staff Discussion Note 11/18 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Onselen, Leith van, 2014, “NZ Mortgage Demand Continues to Soften,” January 28, 2014, Macrobusiness.com.au.

  • Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 2008, “Liquidity Policy Consultation Paper—31 October 2008,” (Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 2013a, “A New Macro-prudential Policy Framework for New Zealand – Final Policy Position,” (Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 2013b, “Regulatory Impact Assessment: Restrictions on High-LVR Residential Mortgage Lending,” August 2013 (Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 2014, “Liquidity Policy,” Prudential Supervision Department Document BS13, July 2014 (Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Statistics Netherlands, “House Price Index,” (Statistics Netherlands, Netherlands).

  • Statistics Netherlands, 2014, “Large Increase in Underwater Mortgages,” (Statistics Netherlands, Netherlands).

  • Wolken, Tony, 2013, “Measuring Systemic Risk: The Role of Macro-prudential Indicators,” RBNZ Bulletin, Vol. 76, No. 4, December 2013 (Reserve Bank of New Zealand: New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wong, Eric, Tom Fong, Ka-fai Li and Henry Choi, 2011, “Loan-to-Value Ratio as a Macro-Prudential Tool—Hong Kong’s Experience and Cross-Country Evidence,” February 17, 2011 (Hong Kong SAR: Hong Kong Monetary Authority).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

We would like to thank Miguel Savastano, Dong He, Karl Habermeier, Erlend Nier, Nicolas Arregui, Chikako Baba, Heedon Kang, Ivo Krznar, Hideyuki Tanimoto, Jack Chen, Francesco Columba, Nombulelo Duma, Michelle Hassine, and staff in the Advanced Europe Unit of the European Department for valuable comments; Jessica Allison and Sonia Echeverri for editorial assistance, and Ricardo Cervantes for research assistance. Xiaoyong Wu was a staff member of the International Monetary Fund when he worked on this paper.

2

The Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policies comprises of (i) a main paper; (ii) a combined instrument specific note; and (iii) considerations for low income countries.

3

The paper aims to serve as a complement to the Staff Guidance Note by providing examples of how a sample of jurisdictions used macroprudential tools. It is not intended to provide an assessment of supervisory practices in these jurisdictions.

4

The cutoff for information in all cases is end January 2015.

10

Hong Kong SAR permanent residents who do not own any other residential property in Hong Kong SAR at the time of acquisition are exempted.

13

Includes assets of banks, insurers, and pension funds.

16

Statistics Netherlands.

22

The European Union (EU) capital requirement is made up of the Capital Requirements Directive (CRD; 2013/36/EU) and the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR; 575/2013).

24

The recent peer review report by the Financial Stability Board provides recommendations to further strengthen the macroprudential policy institutional framework (Financial Stability Board (2014)).

25

By 2010, the compliance with the code of conduct had improved with non-compliance estimated at about 5 percent (see Leeuwen and Bokeloh (2012)). In addition, in August 2011 a revised voluntary code of conduct was introduced. It set a LTV ratio of 104 percent plus applicable transfer taxes, so in effect the recommended limit was 106 percent (see Nederlandse Vereniging van Banken (2011)). Transfer taxes were temporarily reduced from six percent to two percent in June 2011, a reduction that was made permanent in June 2012.

26

Simple average of nine EU countries (Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, and Spain); see page 47 of IMF (2011c).

32

See Annex 2 in IMF (2013c).

34

The RBNZ supervises banks and insurance companies and non-bank deposit takers (including finance companies that take deposits from the public, building societies and credit unions).

37

The CFR = 100 x (core funding/total loans and advances), where core funding equals the sum of: (i) all funding with residual maturity longer than one year, including subordinated debt and related party funding; (ii) 50 percent of any tradable debt securities issued by the bank with original maturity of two years or more and with residual maturity at the reporting date of more than six months and not more than one year; (iii) non-market funding that is withdrawable at sight or with residual maturity less than or equal to one year, where the percentage to be included decreases with size of funding; and (iv) Tier 1 capital (RBNZ (2014)).

47

During 2011–13 the authorities increased new (build-to-order) flat supply to more than 25,000 units annually.

49

The Swedish Covered Bond Act took effect in 2004. One of the main features of a covered bond is that investors have a claim both on the issuer and on the underlying cover pool (mostly mortgages). This dual nature of protection reduces the investors’ risk of losses compared to when investors only have a claim on the issuer.

51

In 2008, a stability fund was established that will finance future government measures to support the financial system. Banks and other credit institutions pay an annual stability fee to the fund.

54

In January 2012, the Riksbank and FSA established a council for cooperation on macroprudential policy. The council discusses and shares information on the assessment of risks to the financial system as a whole, including analyses and the development of tools and methods in the area of macroprudential policy.

58

As per the response to the 2013 IMF survey on Macroprudential Instruments.

62

Finansinspektionen (2014d). The FSA undertook a cost benefit analysis to determine the level of the additional capital buffers. The increase in capital requirement involves a clear tightening of capital requirements that would increase the resilience. At the same time the FSA estimated that banks would be able to meet the new requirement (see Finansinspektionen (2014e)).

Experiences with Macroprudential Policy—Five Case Studies
Author: Mr. Salim M. Darbar and Mr. Xiaoyong Wu