From Natural Resource Boom to Sustainable Economic Growth
Lessons for Mongolia*
Author:
Pranav Gupta
Search for other papers by Pranav Gupta in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Grace B Li
Search for other papers by Ms. Grace B Li in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Jiangyan Yu
Search for other papers by Jiangyan Yu in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

Authors’ E-Mail Addresses: pgupta@imf.org; bli2@imf.org; jyu@imf.org

Some resource-rich developing countries are in the process of harnessing immense mining resources towards inclusive growth and prosperity. Nevertheless, tapping into natural resources could be challenging given the large front-loaded investment, volatile capital flows and exposure to global commodity markets. Public investment is needed to remove the often-large infrastructure gap and unlock the economic potential. However, too rapid fiscal outlays could push the economy to its limit of absorptive capacity and increase macro-financial vulnerabilities. This paper utilizes a structural model-based approach to analyze macroeconomic impacts of different public investment strategies on key fiscal and non-fiscal variables such as debt, consumption, sovereign wealth fund, and real exchange rates. We apply the model to Mongolia and draw policy recommendations from the analysis. We find that fiscal policy adjustment, particularly moderating infrastructure investment and optimizing investment efficiency is needed to maintain macroeconomic and external stability, as well as to boost the long-term sustainable growth for Mongolia.

Abstract

Some resource-rich developing countries are in the process of harnessing immense mining resources towards inclusive growth and prosperity. Nevertheless, tapping into natural resources could be challenging given the large front-loaded investment, volatile capital flows and exposure to global commodity markets. Public investment is needed to remove the often-large infrastructure gap and unlock the economic potential. However, too rapid fiscal outlays could push the economy to its limit of absorptive capacity and increase macro-financial vulnerabilities. This paper utilizes a structural model-based approach to analyze macroeconomic impacts of different public investment strategies on key fiscal and non-fiscal variables such as debt, consumption, sovereign wealth fund, and real exchange rates. We apply the model to Mongolia and draw policy recommendations from the analysis. We find that fiscal policy adjustment, particularly moderating infrastructure investment and optimizing investment efficiency is needed to maintain macroeconomic and external stability, as well as to boost the long-term sustainable growth for Mongolia.

I. Introduction

For resource-rich developing countries, resource wealth offers major opportunities to accelerate economic development and raise living standards. However, resource-rich developing countries also face the challenges of achieving sustained growth, while avoiding boom-bust cycles that stem from volatility, and sometimes exhaustibility in natural resource revenues. Meanwhile, these countries often suffer from the lack of access to international capital markets and domestic capital scarcity. Resource exhaustibility gives rise to inter-temporal decisions of how much of the resource wealth to consume and how much to save, and revenue volatility calls for appropriate fiscal rules and precautionary savings to prevent expenditure volatility and procyclicality. (see IMF, 2012, Collier et al, 2010, Sachs and Warner, 1995, van der Ploeg, 2011 and van der Ploeg and Venables, 2011).

The objective of this paper is to assess macroeconomic developments, e.g. growth and debt sustainability, under different public investment strategies, for a natural resource-rich developing country – Mongolia, and presents relevant considerations for the policymakers. Notably leveraging natural resources wealth for Mongolia has also encountered opportunities and challenges. It has been a long term goal for the authorities of Mongolia to well manage the natural resource revenues, speed up development and diversify the economy. This paper utilizes a structural model-based approach to analyze macroeconomic implications of alternative scenarios of public investment for Mongolia and presents its policy implications.

In this paper, we use Mongolia as an example to shed lights on the issues for many natural resource rich developing countries in a general perspective. We assess the growth and debt sustainability of the economy under alternative public investment path and different commodity price and production trajectories. Especially, we introduce the features such as physical capital scarcity and limited absorptive capacity to these countries, which usually pose common policy challenges in defining the balance between scaling up investment and safeguarding debt sustainability and macroeconomic stability.

We first present the country background of Mongolia, and its current development condition. Then we analyze the dynamics of key macroeconomic variables under different public investment paths. In particular, we compare the results of an aggressive investment path and a smoothed path with fiscal consolidation. The aggressive investment path maintains aggressive status-quo investment levels to develop infrastructure and boost growth at the cost of higher deficit and public debt. Under a fiscal consolidation path, the government instead restrains public investment so as to improve debt sustainability and avoid economic overheating. Our results show that front-loaded fiscal consolidation is needed alongside a comprehensive approach to enhance absorptive capacity, manage natural resources wealth in a way to avoid the Dutch disease, and sustain the longer-term diversification of growth. While the ambitious scaling up of public investment can generate higher nonmineral growth, it can also pose substantial challenges to debt sustainability and macroeconomic stability.

Furthermore, we also find out that, without fiscal consolidation, when natural resource revenues reduced owing to an adverse commodity price and production shock, public debt would grow exponentially and become unsustainable in our simulation.

The paper is organized as follows: Section II discusses Mongolia’s economic background. Section III described the model and the key assumptions that we used for the assessment. Section IV presents the results derived from the analysis for alternative scenarios, and explains the policy implications. Section V summarizes the main findings and concludes.

II. Country Background

Natural Resource Sector: Mongolia embraces huge mineral resource wealth estimated at US$1-3 trillion, with coal, copper, and gold being the principal reserves. Mongolia hosts 10% of the world’s known coal reserves, and the Tavan Tolgoi coal mine (TT) is one of the world’s largest untapped coking and thermal coal deposits.

In 2009, the government established a joint venture with Turquoise Hill Resources (a majority owned subsidiary of Rio Tinto) to develop the Oyu Tolgoi copper and gold deposit (OT), which is the biggest foreign-investment project ever in Mongolia and has attracted more than $6 billion (50 percent of GDP) in FDI for the first phase development (OT-1)with another $5 billion in the pipeline for the second phase (OT-2). OT-1, which exploits the open pit of the deposit, has completed construction and started commercial production in 2013. Nevertheless, the second phase, which exploits the underground deposit and appears crucial to recover the cost of the project, has been stalled by disputes between Mongolian government and Rio Tinto. OT-2 at best could start production only from 2020 onwards should the dispute be solved soon.

Growth and Outlook: On the back of large stock of resources and immense FDI inflows to the mining sector, Mongolia has been one of the fastest growing economies in the past decade. Real GDP growth averaged 9 percent over the past decade, and per capita income has more than quadrupled, to more than $4,000. Mining accounts directly for 20 percent of the economy, while the total share, including indirect impacts, is likely much higher—mineral exports account for over 40 percent of GDP.

Notwithstanding promising long-term prospects, managing the resource boom could be challenging in the near term. It is expected that over time the country is going to generate a large stream of resource earnings, accumulate its sovereign wealth fund, and move solidly into the upper-middle income range. But for any of that to happen, Mongolia must maintain macro-financial stability and cast a sustainable policy path. Nevertheless, Mongolia’s narrow economic base has left the country highly vulnerable to external shocks—minerals account for 90 percent of all exports, and 90 percent of these are bound for China. This lack of diversification has made the economy prone to repeated boom-bust cycles—the latest balance-of-payments crisis took place in 2009, and renewed shocks to FDI and coal exports against the backdrop of loose macro policies have led to sharp reserve losses and exchange rate depreciation since early 2013.

Debt Sustainability: The Fiscal Stability Law (FSL) provides an extremely useful framework for governing fiscal policy, but the presence of substantial off-budget spending makes the FSL incomplete. The FSL, which absorbs successful experiences of a few resource-rich countries, stipulates that the structural fiscal deficit should be kept below 2 percent of GDP. Nevertheless, the Development Bank of Mongolia (DBM) was established in 2012 and has since served virtually as a vehicle of off-budget capital spending. As a consequence, although on-budget deficit has been kept within 2 percent of GDP in line with the FSL, large off-budget spending pushed the consolidated deficit to around 10 percent of GDP in 2012 and 2013; and public debt has surged dramatically from below 40 percent of GDP in 2011 to more than 60 percent of GDP in end-2013.

Meanwhile, investment efficiency is worrisome. Public investment suffers from weak project selection and implementation, inadequate coordination between government agencies, and excessive power of the parliament to insert poorly designed projects in the capital budget. Moreover, lack of transparency and capacity in public procurement, and politically motivated contracts also result in a low efficiency of infrastructure projects.2 World Bank (2013) report highlights poor project selection and weak government policies in Mongolia as major impediments to public investment efficiency in recent years.

A sovereign wealth fund (SWF) can be an integral part of a coherent fiscal framework, but achieving its goals requires strong discipline. A legal framework for the SWF is being developed, where authorities expect to start depositing a large share of mineral revenue into the SWF from 2018 and refrain from drawing down the fund in the next few decades—after that the drawing of SWF would be targeted to support social spending and capacity building. The SWF could provide a useful vehicle to save mineral revenues for the future. However, if the large fiscal deficit persists, building up SWF could be achieved only via borrowing rather than saving, which is not an appropriate strategy. Going forward, with the fiscal policy fully complying with the FSL or even running a surplus, there would be conditions to build up savings under the SWF framework.

Clearly, the key to achieving fiscal sustainability is to make the fiscal policy fully comply with the FSL. The consolidated fiscal balance should aim for a deficit of 2 percent of GDP as prescribed by the FSL in the near term, and over time should target a surplus in favor of accumulating savings under the SWF framework. Rather than following an aggressive investment strategy, a moderate path of public investment appears appropriate as it would allow the authorities to gradually build up capacity and refrain from wasting resources as investment capacity is overly stretched.

External Sustainability: The exhaustibility of these resources and the uncertainty of resource revenues also raise complex economic issues concerning external sustainability. In Mongolia, real exchange rates appreciated substantially in the period of 2009 to mid-2013 when large FDI flew into the mining sector, while the noncommodity exports have performed anemically. Despite dramatic front-loaded investments in some large mining projects, revenue streams could gather their strength only gradually, leaving large current account deficit in the interim period, which has to be financed by substantial external borrowing, both public and private. More importantly, the heavy reliance on mineral exports leaves the country vastly exposed to global market shocks. These developments make it all the more important for Mongolia to follow a prudent and sustainable policy path towards prosperity.

A01ufig1

Exchange rates of the togrog

(Index, 2005=100, Jan. 2005-Aug. 2014; an increase is an appreciation)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 090; 10.5089/9781475570632.001.A001

Sources: Mongolian authorities; and IMF staff estimates.
A01ufig2

Coal Export Price and FDI

(Jan.2011-July 2014)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 090; 10.5089/9781475570632.001.A001

Sources: Mogolian authorities, and IMF staff estimates.

Nevertheless, the recent macroeconomic policy has been loose and compounded with unfavorable commodity price shocks to adversely intensify balance of payments pressure. The authorities have committed to unleash economic growth by shoring up investment to fill a substantial infrastructure gap. In light of an adverse shock to FDI and commodity prices, aggressive monetary stimulus was introduced in 2013 with the hope that a loose monetary condition would help overcome the temporary difficulties, leading to a spike of credit growth to 54 percent y/y. As a consequence, current account deficit has remained wide despite the decline of equipment and machinery imports associated with the completed construction of OT-1, and capital and financial account deteriorated sharply reflecting a contraction of FDI. In the period of 2013-14, nominal exchange rate depreciated by more than 40 percent, driving inflation to double digits; and reserves dropped by two thirds despite aggressive external borrowing.

External sector assessment points to a significant current account gap induced by unsustainable macroeconomic policy mix. To restore external viability, a package of adjustment policy needs to be implemented. Most importantly, fiscal deficit should be compressed, monetary policy stance tightened, and exchange rate depreciated in real terms.

III. A Model-based Analysis of Mongolia’s Natural Resource Revenues

In this section we describe a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with natural resource wealth in a small open economy. The model combines elements of frameworks developed in Araujo et al (2013), Buffie et al (2012), Berg et al. (2013), and Melina et al. (2014) in analyzing natural resource management for developing countries. In particular, we utilize the model of Melina et al. (2014) and apply its model to Mongolia.

We analyze the debt sustainability and macroeconomic impact of various public investment plans in Mongolia, which model is based on a DSGE model of a small open economy that captures the investment-growth nexus in presence of given natural resource revenue, as well as investment efficiencies and absorptive capacity constraints. It helps to inform the authorities about the various policy decisions on investing resource revenues to boost growth while maintaining fiscal sustainability and macroeconomic stability.

The model follows Melina et al. (2014) closely. It is a three-sector model of a small open economy which comprises household, firms and government. The country produces a composite of non-resource traded and traded sector good using capital k, labor L and government-supplied infrastructure kg. The model incorporates various multiple types of public debt instruments, multiple taxes and spending variables and resource fund.

A. Model

The economy features two types of households, including poor households with no access to financial markets, and features traded and non-traded sectors as well as a natural resource sector. Public capital enters production technologies, while public investment is subject to inefficiencies and absorptive capacity constraints. The government has access to different types of debt (concessional, domestic and external commercial) and a resource fund, which can be used to finance public investment plans. The resource fund can also serve as a buffer to absorb fiscal balances for given projections of resource revenues and public investment plans. When the fund is drawn down to its minimal value, a combination of external and domestic borrowing can be used to cover the fiscal gap in the short to medium run. Fiscal adjustments through tax rates and government non-capital expenditures—which may be constrained by ceilings and floors, respectively—are then triggered to maintain debt sustainability.

Households: There is continuum of two types of households—optimizing households and hand-to-mouth households—who live for infinite horizon. A fraction ω of the households have access to capital markets, where they can trade contingent securities and own firms. These types of households are often referred to as optimizing or Ricardian households and are denoted by subscript OPT. The remaining fraction 1- ω are poor or financially constrained also referred as rule-of thumb or hand-to-mouth households and are denoted by subscript HTM. Hand-to-mouth households have no access to capital and financial market and consume all of the disposable income each period.

Both types consume a consumption basket, Cti, a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) aggregate of traded goods CT,ti and nontraded goods CN,ti. Thus, the consumption basket is

C t i = [ φ 1 x ( C N , t i ) x 1 x + ( 1 φ ) 1 x ( C T , t i ) x 1 x ] x x 1 , i = O P T , H T M ( 1 )

where φ is the degree of non-traded goods bias in the consumption basket, and x > 0 is the intra-temporal elasticity of substitution.

Let pN,t and st be the relative prices of nontraded and traded goods with respect to the consumption basket. Assuming the law of one price holds for traded goods, st is also the real exchange rate, defined as the price of one unit of foreign consumption basket in units of domestic basket. The unit price of the consumption basket is

1 = [ φ p N 1 x + ( 1 φ ) S t 1 x ] 1 1 x . ( 2 )

Both types of households provide labor service (LT,ti and LN,ti, i = OPT, HTM) to the traded and the nontraded good sectors, denoted by subscripts T and N. Total labor Lti has a CES specification to capture that labor supplied to the two sectors are not perfect substitutes,

L t i = [ δ 1 ρ ( L N , t i ) 1 + ρ ρ + ( 1 δ ) 1 ρ ( L T , t i ) 1 + ρ ρ ] ρ 1 + ρ , i = O P T , H T M , ( 3 )

where δ is the steady-state share of labor in the nontraded good sector, and ρ > 0 is the intra-temporal elasticity of substitution. Let wT,t and wN,t be the real wage rate paid in each sector. The real wage index is

w t = [ δ w N , t 1 + ρ + ( 1 δ ) w T , t 1 + ρ ] 1 1 + ρ ( 4 )

A representative optimizing household (OPT) maximizes its utility

E 0 Σ t = 1 β t U ( C t O P T , L t O P T ) = E 0 { Σ t = 1 β t [ 1 1 σ ( C t O P T ) 1 σ k O P T 1 + ψ ( L t O P T ) 1 + ψ ] } , ( 5 )

subject to the budget constraint expressed in units of composite consumption

( 1 + τ t C ) C t O P T + b t O P T s t b t O P T * = ( 1 τ t L ) w t L t O P T + R t 1 b t 1 O P T R t 1 * s b t 1 O P T * + Ω T , t + Ω N , t + υ K τ K ( r T , t K K T , t 1 + r N , t K k N , t 1 ) + s t r m t * + z t μ k G , t 1 Θ t O P T * . ( 6 )

β is the discount factor. σ and ψ are the inverse of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of consumption and of labor supply. KOPT is the disutility weight of labor. τtC and τtL are the effective tax rates on consumption and labor income. btOPT is domestic government bonds that pay RtbtOPT units of the consumption basket at time t+1,btOPT* is liabilities to the rest of the world that entail repayment of Rt*btOPT* units of the foreign consumption basket. ΩT,t and ΩN,t are firms’ profits in the traded and nontraded good sector. The term ϑKτK(rT,tKkT,t1+rN,tKkN,t1) is a tax rebate that optimizing households receive on the tax levied on the firms’ return on capital.3 rmt* is remittance from abroad, zt are government transfers. μ is user fees of public capital kG,t, and ΘtOPT*η2(btOPT*bOPT*)2 are portfolio adjustment costs associated to foreign liabilities, where η controls the degree of capital account openness and bOPT* (a variable without a time subscript) is the initial the steady-state value.

We assume that the private sector pays a constant premium u over the interest rate that the government pays on external commercial debt Rdc,t, such that

R t * = R d c , t + u . ( 7 )

Hand-to-mouth households (HTM) have the same utility function as optimizing households

U ( C t H T M , L t H T M ) = 1 1 σ ( C t H T M ) 1 σ k H T M 1 + ψ ( L t H T M ) 1 + ψ . ( 8 )

Their consumption is determined by the budget constraint

( 1 + τ t C ) C t H T M = ( 1 τ t L ) w t L t H T M + s t r m t * + z t μ k G , t 1 . ( 9 )

Static maximization of the utility function gives the labor supply function:

L t H T M = [ k 1 H T M 1 τ t L 1 + τ t C ( C t H T M ) σ w t ] 1 ψ . ( 10 )

In aggregation, with two types of households, aggregate consumption, labor, privately owned government bonds, and foreign liabilities are computed as follows.

c t = ω c t O P T + ( 1 ω ) c t H T M , ( 11 )
L t = ω L t O P T + ( 1 ω ) L t H T M , ( 12 )
b t = ω b t O P T ; b t * = ω b t O P T * . ( 13 )

Firms: The economy has three production sectors: (i) a nontraded good sector indexed by N; (ii) a (non-resource) traded good sector indexed by T; and a natural resource sector indexed by O. Since resource rich developing countries tend to export most resource output, we assume that the whole resource output is exported for simplicity.

Nontraded good firms produce output yN,t with technology

y N , t = z N ( k N , t 1 ) 1 α N ( L N , t ) α N ( k G , t 1 ) α G , ( 14 )

where zN is total factor productivity, kN,t is end-of-period private capital, kG,t is the end of period public capital, αN is the labor share of sectoral income, and αG is the output elasticity respect to public capital.

Capital installed in the nontraded good sector evolves by

k N , t = ( 1 δ N ) k N , t 1 + [ 1 k N 2 ( i N , t i N , t 1 1 ) 2 ] i n , t , ( 15 )

where iN,t represents investment expenditure, δN is the capital depreciation rate, and kN is the investment adjustment cost parameter.

The representative nontraded good firm chooses labor (LN,t), capital (kN,t), and investment (iN,t) to maximize its discounted lifetime profits weighted by the marginal utility of consumption of optimizing households λt,

Ω T , 0 = E 0 Σ t = 0 β t λ t [ p N , t y N , t w N , t L N , t i N , t τ K r N , t K k N , t 1 ] , ( 16 )

where rN,tK=(1αN)pN,tyN,tkN,t1 is the return to capital.

Analogously to the nontraded good sector, firms in the traded good sector produce with technology

y T , t = z T , t ( k T , t 1 ) 1 α N ( L T , t ) α N ( k G , t 1 ) α N . ( 17 )

To capture the common Dutch disease associated with spending resource revenues, we assume total factor productivity, zT,t, is subject to learning-by-doing externalities:

z T , t z T = ( z T , t 1 z T ) ρ z T + ( y T , t 1 y T ) ρ y T , ( 18 )

where ρzT, ρyT ϵ [0,1] control the severity of Dutch disease. The law of motion of private capital is

k T , t = ( 1 δ T ) k T , t 1 + [ 1 k T 2 ( i T , t i T , t 1 1 ) 2 ] i T , t . ( 19 )

Like nontraded good firms, a representative traded good firm chooses labor (LT,t), capital (kT,t), and investment (iT,t) to maximize its discounted lifetime profits,

Ω T , 0 = E 0 Σ t = 1 β t λ t [ y T , t w T , t L T , t i T , t τ K r T , t K k T , t 1 ] . ( 20 )

As most natural resource production is capital intensive and much of investment in the natural resource sector is financed by foreign direct investment in developing countries, natural resource production is simplified in the model.

Resource production follows an exogenous process

y ˜ o , t y ˜ o = ( y ˜ o , t 1 y ˜ o ) ρ y o exp ( ɛ t y o ) , ( 21 )

where ρyo(0,1) is an auto-regressive coefficient and ɛtyoiidN(0,σyo2) is the resource production shock. We assume that resource production is small relative to world production; hence, the international commodity price (relative to the foreign consumption basket),

pO,t*, is taken as given. It is assumed to evolve following the process:

p O , t * p O * = ( p O , t 1 * p O * ) ρ y o exp ( ɛ t p o ) , ( 22 )

where ρpo(0,1] is an auto-regressive coefficient and ɛtpoiidN(0,σpo2) is the resource price shock. Resource GDP in units of the domestic consumption basket is

y o , t = s t p o , t * y ˜ o , t . ( 23 )

Government: Let τto be the royalty rate on production. Then, the resource revenue collected each period is

t t o = s t τ t o p 0 , t * y ˜ o , t . ( 24 )

The government flow budget constraint is

τ t C C t + τ t L w t L t + t o , t + ( 1 υ K ) τ K ( r T , t K k T , t 1 + r N , t K k N , t 1 ) + b t + s t d t + s t d c , t + s t R R F f t 1 * + μ k G , t 1 = p t G ( g t c + g t I ) + z t s t g r t * + R t 1 b t 1 + s t R d c , t 1 d c , t 1 + s t f t * , ( 25 )

where grt* is international grants. The user fee paid on public capital is computed as a fraction f of recurrent costs: μfptGδG.

The government has three debt instruments: external concessional debt (dt), external commercial debt (dc,t), and domestic debt (bt). Concessional loans extended by official creditors are taken as exogenous in the model. Rd and Rdc,t are the gross real interest rates paid on concessional debt and external commercial debt. The latter incorporates a risk premium depending on the deviations of total external public debt to GDP ratio from its initial steady state,

R d c , t 1 = R f + υ d c exp [ η d c ( d t + d c , t y t d + d c y ) ] , ( 26 )

where Rf is a (constant) risk-free world interest rate, yt is total GDP and υdc and ηdc are structural parameters.

Public investment paths (as a share of GDP) are computed outside the model and taken as exogenous. Except for the fiscal approach that increases transfers, all other approaches assume constant transfers as a share of GDP. Throughout all simulations, government consumption is kept constant as the level in a trend-growth path.

Government purchases comprise government consumption gtC and public investment gtI. Like private consumption, government expenditure, gtgtC+gtI, is also a CES aggregate of domestic traded goods, gT,t and domestic nontraded goods, gN,t. Thus,

g t = [ υ t 1 x ( g N , t ) x 1 x + ( 1 υ t ) 1 x ( g T , t ) x 1 x ] x x 1 , ( 27 )

where υt is the weight given to nontraded goods in government purchases. Government purchases have the same intra-temporal elasticity of substitution χ > 0 as private consumption. ptG is the government consumption price index in terms of units of the consumption basket,

p t G = [ υ t p N 1 x + ( 1 υ t ) s t 1 x ] 1 1 x . ( 28 )

Note that υt is time-varying. As we focus on the effects of additional government spending in public investment, the weight given to nontraded goods for the additional government spending, υg, can differ from its steady state value, υ.

Public investment features inefficiency and absorptive capacity constraints. To reflect this, we assume that investment efficiency on additional investment above a threshold level drops from the steady-state efficiency value ϵ to a lower value ε˜. Let g˜tI denote the effect public investment, and StGIgtIyt be the public investment-to-output ratio with yt being the real GDP. Then,

g ˜ t I = { g t I , when  s t G I < s ¯ G I ( s ¯ G I y t ) + ˜ ( g t I s ¯ G I y t ) , when  s t G I s ¯ G I } , ( 29 )

where s¯GI is the threshold value that triggers efficiency costs associated with absorptive capacity constraints.

The law of motion of public capital is

k G , t = ( 1 δ G ) k G , t 1 + g ˜ t I , ( 30 )

where δG is the depreciation rate of public capital.

Resource fund and fiscal gap: Let ft* be the foreign financial asset value in a resource fund, and it serves as a fiscal buffer to absorb fiscal surplus or deficits. Each period, the resource fund earns interest income St(Rrf1)ft1*, with a constant gross real interest rate Rrf.

When the resource fund reaches zero, a government has to resort to borrowing to cover the revenue shortfall, which then triggers fiscal adjustments to maintain debt sustainability.

To formalize the function of the resource fund, we assume that the resource fund evolves by the process

f t * f * = max { f * , ( f t 1 * f * ) + f int,t s t f o u t,t s t } , ( 31 )

where fint,t represents the total fiscal inflow, fout,t represents the total fiscal outflow. Every period, if the fiscal inflow exceeds the outflow, a resource fund increases its value.4 Instead, if the fiscal inflow falls short of the outflow, the fund is drawn down to support government spending. We assume that the resource fund cannot accumulate liabilities. Thus, when ft1*+fint,tstfout,tst<0 (i.e., the fund does not have sufficient assets to be drawn down to cover the difference between the fiscal inflow and outflow), ft* is set to zero. Later we explicitly define fint,t and fout,t and explain in detail the mechanism of closing the fiscal gap.

Given the paths of public investment, concessional borrowing, foreign aids and grants, algebraic manipulation of (25) allows the government budget constraint to be rewritten as

g a p t f o u t , t f int , t + s t ( f t * f t 1 * ) , ( 32 )

where

g a p t = Δ b t + s t Δ d c , t + ( τ t C τ C ) C t + ( τ t L τ L ) w t l t , 5 ( 33 )
f int , t = τ C c t + τ L w t L t + ( 1 ϑ K ) τ K ( r T , t K k T , t 1 + r N , t K k N , t 1 ) + t o , t + μ k G , t 1 + s t a t * + s t g r t * + s t ( R R F 1 ) f t 1 * + s t Δ d t , 34
f o u t , t = p t G g t I + p t G g t C + z t + ( s t R d 1 ) d t 1 + ( R d c , t 1 1 ) s t d c , t 1 + ( R t 1 1 ) b t 1 . ( 35 )

Equation (33) says that covering the fiscal gap entails domestic and/or external commercial borrowing or adjustments in various fiscal instruments.

When the government has to borrow, we assume that only external debt can be accessed. Thus, bt=bt. Debt sustainability requires that eventually revenues have to increase and/or expenditures have to be cut in order to cover the entire gap. In this analysis, we focus on two fiscal adjustment instruments: the consumption and labor income tax rates.6 To calculate debt stabilizing (target) values of the two tax rates, the following equations are used.

τ target, t C = τ C + λ 1 g a p t c t , ( 36 )
τ target, t L = τ L + λ 2 g a p t w t L t , ( 37 )

where λ1 + λ2 = 1. Tax rates are then determined according to the following policy rules:

τ t C = min { τ rule, t C , τ ceiling C } , ( 38 )
τ t L = min { τ rule, t L , τ ceiling L } , ( 39 )

where τceilingC and τceilingL are the maximum level of the tax rates can be implemented. Also,

τ rule, t C = τ t 1 C + ζ 1 ( τ target, t C τ t 1 C ) + ζ 2 ( x t 1 x ) , ζ 1 , ζ 2 > 0 , ( 40 )
τ rule, t L = τ t 1 L + ζ 3 ( τ target, t L τ t 1 L ) + ζ 4 ( x t 1 x ) , ζ 3 , ζ 4 > 0 , ( 41 )

where ζ’s control the speed of fiscal adjustments, and xtbt+stdc,tyt is the sum of domestic and external commercial debt as a share of GDP.

To close the model, the goods market clearing condition and the balance of payment conditions are imposed. The market clearing condition for nontradaed goods is

y N , t = φ p N , t x ( c t + i N , t + i T , t ) + ν t ( p N , t p t G ) x g t . ( 42 )

The balance of payment condition is

c a t d s t = g r t * Δ f t * + Δ d t + Δ d c , t + Δ b t * Ω t o * , ( 43 )

where Ωto*=yo,tto,tst is the dividend from resource production,7 and catd is the current account deficit:

c a t d = c t + i N , t + i T , t + p t G g t + Θ t O P T * y t s t r m t * + ( R d 1 ) s t d t 1 + ( R d c , t 1 1 ) s t d c , t 1 + ( R t 1 * 1 ) s t b t 1 * ( R R F 1 ) s t f t 1 * . ( 44 )

Finally, total real GDP, yt is given by

y t = p N , t y N , t + s t y T , t + y o , t . ( 45 )

B. Calibration: Applying to Mongolia

The equilibrium system of the model consists of first-order conditions for all optimization problems of the households and firms, market clearing conditions, the balance of payment condition, and exogenous paths of resource variables (resource production quantities, prices, and revenues as a share of GDP), public investment and transfers to households, and concessional debt. We solve for a perfect foresight solution, using Dynare’s nonlinear package.

Departing from Melina et al. (2014), we applied the model to Mongolia in particular, who has been facing a high risk of debt distress because of its aggressive government spending in recent years. The initial steady states are calibrated to the recent macroeconomic conditions of Mongolian economy in year 2014, based on national accounts and fiscal data gathered from the World Economic Outlook (WEO) and International Finance Statistics (IFS) databases. Calibrating the model in this way captures the key features of the economy using wide range of data on income share of GDP, cost shares, tax rates, debt and asset stocks etc. The frequency of model is annual and the simulation horizon runs till 2025. Table 1 summarizes the calibration while rationale for important parameters choice is discussed below.

  • - National accounting. The national accounts data is taken from the WEO/IFS database for the last 15 years. The share of export to GDP and import to GDP are calibrated by taking average of past few years and are 40% and 57% respectively. The share of government spending is taken as 19.6% of GDP, 13.7% of which is government consumption whereas 5.9% is government investment expenditure.

  • - Assets, debt and grants. Stock of assets, grants and debt reflects the 2013 values for Mongolia. The government domestic level is much higher than the government’s FSL debt limit of 40% and was at around 60% of GDP (14.7% domestic debt, 20% concessional debt and 26% government external borrowing). Private foreign borrowing stands at 87% of GDP, whereas sovereign welfare fund is much below the government desired level of 5%.

  • - Private production. Consistent with the evidence on Low and middle income countries in Buffie et al. (2012), the labor income shares in the nontraded and traded good sectors correspond to αN = 0.45 and αT = 0.60. In both sectors private capital depreciates at an annual rate of 10 percent (δN = δT = 0.10). Following Berg et al.(2013), we assume a minor degree of learning-by-doing externality in the traded good sector (ρYT = ρzT = 0.10). Also as in Berg et al. (2010), investment adjustment costs are set to kN = kT = 25.

  • - Households’ preferences. The coefficient of risk aversion σ = 2.94 implies an inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of 0.34, which is the average LIC estimate according to Ogaki et al. (1996). We assume a low Frisch labor elasticity of 0.10 (Ψ = 10), similar to the estimate of wage elasticity of working in rural Malawi (Goldberg, 2011). The labor mobility parameter ρ is set to 1 (Horvarth, 2000), and the elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods is χ = 0.44, following Stockman and Tesar (1995). To capture limited access to international capital markets, we set η = 1 as in Buffie et al. (2012).

  • - Tax rates. The steady state value of consumption and labor tax rate are kept as 10% each which is consistent with the observed data whereas the tax rate on the return on capital is calibrated at 24% such that the steady state share of government tax revenue to GDP calculated by combination of tax rates and the implied inefficiency in revenue mobilization matches with the average of past years (around 28% of GDP). Considering that Mongolia has limited space for tax adjustment, we assume that the government will not adjust tax rates to finance public spending. Additional public debt will be financed by non-concessional external debt.

C. Assumptions: Natural Resource Revenue and Investment Paths

This paper utilizes the model described above to illustrate the policy implications from two alternative public investment paths of Mongolia. This approach is essential to analyze the current internal and external balances of Mongolia and impact of various policy decisions on Mongolia’s macroeconomic outlook. In the previous section, we calibrate the model using the historical data of Mongolia and parameters widely used in the literature. In particular, the initial steady state values are set using the country’s medium-term averages of relevant aggregate variables. Details on the calibration and parameterization for the model are given in Table 1.

When applying to Mongolia, our analysis investigates two alternative public investment paths in particular:

  1. Fiscal consolidation: In this plan government starts fiscal consolidation to reduce fiscal debt by cutting its public investment.

  2. Aggressive Investment: In this plan, the government maintains its current public investment level for infrastructure development and growth.

Given the uncertainty in the resource sector production and prices, specifically in copper mining, the above mentioned public investment approaches are analyzed under two scenarios—baseline and adverse scenarios—with different mining revenue profiles down the road. Both the public investment paths and resource sector scenarios are shown in Figure 1. Under both the scenarios, we assume that the government resorts to only external commercial borrowing to balance its financial deficit and fiscal adjustment in terms of increasing consumption tax or labor tax is not feasible due to political constraints. In the baseline scenario, the mining revenues follow the no-adverse-shock projections; in the adverse scenario, the revenues would be hit by a reduced mining production shock and lower international copper prices. To be specific, the two scenarios are summarized as below:

  • Baseline scenario: In this scenario the mining revenue projections are obtained using the FARI model8. According to these projections, copper concentrate production is estimated to increase from its current level of about ½ million tons in 2013 to more than 1 million tons by 2020. The rapid growth in copper mining production is expected to occur around 2020, when the major mining company Oyu Tolgio LLC. plans to start its second round of copper mining (phase II).

  • Adverse scenario: In this scenario, we introduce a negative copper production shock by delaying the Phase II of mining by Oyu Tolgio LLC. Apart from this we also introduce a copper price shock of the same size as observed during 2009.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Assumptions: Resource Output and Public Investment Paths

(Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 090; 10.5089/9781475570632.001.A001

D. Efficiency and Absorptive Capacity

Empirical studies suggest that investment inefficiencies (poor planning, higher-than-expected costs, bad governance, corruption, supply bottlenecks, lack of complementary infrastructure, etc.) are pervasive in developing countries. According to the literature on public investment efficiency level for low income countries (Berg et al. 2013 and van der Ploeg, 2012), only around half of public investment expenditure translates into effective public investment (i.e. investment that enhances the public capital stock). This means that $1 spent on public investment will translate into $0.5 worth of public capital formulation. We assumed slightly higher level of public investment efficiency level for Mongolia at 65%, considering relatively higher public investment efficiency index of Mongolia as compared to several developing countries. (See Dabla-Norris, 2011).

If public investment level remains high, the degree of inefficiency is likely to increase. Namely, it is more likely to bump into absorptive capacity constraints in the short run. These are limits on the level of public investment that the economy is able to retain and hence a bigger part of investment expenditure will be wasted. As shown in Figure 3, investment efficiency decreases more in short run in case of aggressive public investment than fiscal consolidation.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Projection of Public Debt and Sovereign Welfare Fund

(Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 090; 10.5089/9781475570632.001.A001

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Paths of Other Variables

(Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 090; 10.5089/9781475570632.001.A001

If, over time, institutions, governance, management practices are improved, public investment becomes, on average, more efficient and absorptive capacity constraints become less binding. If investment projects are better designed, selected, and implemented, the average real return of investment increases. This will increase productivity of private factors for production with a more positive impact on capital stock accumulation, growth and incomes without causing high debt distress level. In Figure 4, we show a robustness check with a different efficiency of investment. For instance, a difference of average public investment efficiency for about 1 percentage points will point to one percent change of public capital accumulation over ten years9. Combined with a better project selection, an improved efficiency can lead to same growth and public capital formulation as in the case of aggressive public investment but without any negative consequences in terms of higher public debt or worsen balance of payment. Thus increasing investment efficiency can lead to higher growth and faster buildup of capital with fiscal macroeconomic stability in Mongolia.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Robustness Check: Different Efficiency

(Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 090; 10.5089/9781475570632.001.A001

IV. Simulation Results and Policy Implication

In this section, we present the simulation results with different scenarios of natural resource revenues. In the first set of simulations, we consider the baseline natural resource output and revenue with different public investment paths. Then, we explore the implications with the adverse resource shocks. Last, we show a robustness check with different efficiency of public investment.

A. Baseline Scenario

Under the baseline scenario (left columns in Figures 13), as Figure 1 shows, the baseline envisages an increase of natural resource output and revenue starting from year 2020 as shown in the left column of the panel, reflecting the start of production by OT-2. The copper output, measured in millions of tons, is expected to double in 2020. Resource revenues from copper as percent of total revenue increase from 20 percent to about 40 percent in 10 years. With fiscal consolidation, we assume that the government will cut its public investment from 15 percent of GDP in 2014 to around 10 percent of GDP in 2015 and onward.

The baseline scenario with fiscal consolidation delivers more favorable outcomes in terms of debt sustainability and financial assets accumulation in the SWF. As Figures 23 shows, fiscal consolidation (solid blue lines) deliver sustainable and sizeable accumulations of public capital. The public capital will rise by 60 percent from the level of the steady states. Given the projected resource revenues in the baseline, it allows for a moderate amount of savings in the SWF starting from 2019, and the SWF will increase to about 12 percent of GDP in 2025. The investment path with fiscal consolidation will not require additional borrowing. The path of total public debt will reduce and be stabilized at about 45 percent of GDP eventually. There is about 10 percent overvaluation of the real exchange rate in 2014; the gap will diminish by 5 percentage points with the fiscal actions.

However, if we assume that the government keeps its high public spending plans and only gradually reduces it to 10 percent of GDP, the results and the impacts (shown in red dashed lines) will be less favorable. In the long run, the economy might produce higher non-oil GDP and private investment because of the crowding-in effect from higher public capital accumulation. Although the public capital accrues more aggressively, the financing costs are not trivial and the national debt burden becomes significant. The economy will accumulate less saving in the stabilization fund. Also, with limited space for tax adjustment and low sovereign wealth fund, we show that the total public debt will increase to 80 percent of GDP in 2018 and stabilize at 65 percent in the long term, which is about 20 percentage points higher compared to the results with the fiscal consolidation. The appreciation of real exchange rate, however, will persist for a longer term in the high investment scenario than in the fiscal consolidation scenario. A Dutch disease (a decline in traded output) will last longer with the high investment government spending than otherwise. As most resource revenues are invested in external financial assets, the current account deficit will be more than 5 percent of GDP higher, comparing the aggressive investment to the fiscal consolidation.

B. Adverse Scenario: Negative Resource Shock

Turning to the adverse resource revenue scenario (right columns in Figures 13), we introduce a negative copper production shock by vastly delaying the OT-2 production, and we also introduce a copper price shock of the same size as observed during the 2009 global crisis. The resource revenues from copper will stay flat in the range of 20-25 percent out of the total government revenue.

With limited resource revenues, both projected paths of public investment deliver more challenges to the economy. Still, public capital has accumulated sizably under both paths. However, with relatively paltry resource revenues, the SWF will not have any savings in either of the adverse scenarios. The ratio of public debt to GDP increases by 10 percentage points to about 70 percent with fiscal consolidation (solid blue lines), reflecting higher levels of external non-concessional debt (rising for about 20 percent of GDP). Even worse, if the government keeps rapid spending plans (red dashed lines), the public debt path will be explosive. Moreover, aggressive investments would put pressure on real exchange rate. The exchange rate is currently overvalued by more than 10 percent and should be allowed to depreciate. As a result, current account deficit would widen—we estimate an additional 5 percent of GDP in current account deficit as compared to the baseline projection with fiscal consolidation path.

Under the aggressive investment path total, public debt sustainability is at high risk of distress and may require large fiscal adjustment. Even if OT-2 is implemented and substantially increases revenue, total public debt would remain significantly above the FSL limit. In case of any major adverse shock as simulated in the model, the public debt level will become unsustainable and the government would need to resort to undesirable increase in taxes or sharp spending cuts. High levels of external borrowing will also lead to an increase in country risk premium and higher cost of borrowing.

These flaws of aggressive investment call for fiscal consolidation. Although fiscal consolidation is contractionary in the short run, output losses would be limited over the medium term given the small fiscal multiplier. In the short run, the impact is driven by a contraction of aggregate demand as a result of lower government spending. Moreover, lower infrastructure investments tend to reduce medium-term growth and lead to slower growth of public capital. Nevertheless, fiscal consolidation would boost growth prospects over the medium and long run by lowering interest rates and spreads, putting debt on a sustainable trajectory, and ultimately enhance the sustainability of the economy. In addition, lower public expenditure would facilitate real exchange rate depreciation, which enhances external competitiveness and helps avoid the Dutch disease. Finally, fiscal consolidation in the near term would ease the constraints of absorptive capacity, give rise to investment efficiency in the near term and allow for capacity building over time.

In the case of Mongolia, fiscal consolidation leads to reduction in total public debt to 40% target over time (Figure 2). However, total public debt could increase by 10 percent of GDP from the current level in case of adverse shock to the economy (such as delays OT-2 or a negative international commodity price shock) even when fiscal consolidation is implemented. The authorities should be alert to such risks and manage to build up sovereign welfare fund that can be utilized to smooth out investment in case of negative shocks.

C. Robustness Check

Public investment efficiency and absorptive capacity (Figures 34). In the long run, fiscal consolidation and large resource sector revenues would put Mongolia on a sustainable growth path. This would also be highly dependent on efficient implementation of projects and sound absorptive capacity in the economy. In Figure 3, we show that under baseline scenario, the efficiency of public investment remains lower in case of aggressive scaling up as compared to fiscal consolidation. Fiscal consolidation instead will improve the measured efficiency of public investment. This follows from our assumption that aggressive scaling up can be bound by constraints like weak management capacity, supply bottlenecks, and institutional quality issues. In Figure 4, we also show a robustness check for different efficiency in the economy. If we assume the investment efficiency is lower by 2 percentage points, which implies that the efficiency is about 63 percent at the steady state, the public capital accumulation and the non-resource output production will be dampened mildly.

V. Conclusions

In sum, this paper employs a structural model-based analysis and helps answer various questions pertaining to fiscal sustainability and macroeconomic stability of Mongolia. We illustrate the policy tradeoffs faced by a natural resource-rich country that has large social and infrastructure gaps, faces absorptive and implementation capacity constraints, and is also subject to resource production and price uncertainty.

The outcomes are reflected in three areas. First, the model exhibits under two different public investment strategies—baseline and fiscal consolidation—the development of key macro-financial variables such as traded/non-traded sector growth rate, public capital formulation, investment efficiency, consumption, real exchange rate, balance of payments, public debt, etc. Second, the study explores how these variables would evolve in the presence of an adverse scenario such as a negative resource sector shock. Our results highlight the sensitivity of budgetary revenues to commodity production and price shocks, which could affect both government spending and potential non-oil output growth. Third, the model-based toolkit is also used to study the impact of enhanced institutional efficiency (in terms of governance, project selection, etc) on public capital formulation and overall growth. We show the positive impact of improving public investment efficiency, which can contribute to a higher-level of public capital without adversely affecting fiscal sustainability.

The analysis stresses the benefits of adopting a comprehensive approach to managing natural resources wealth and to sustaining the longer-term diversification of growth. In Mongolia, given the large share of the natural resources sector, it is particularly important to look beyond traditional metrics of the investment- growth nexus. While ambitious scaling up of public investment can generate higher non-mineral growth, the challenges on debt sustainability and external viability can be high and the associated macro-financial risks would outweigh the benefit of higher investment and growth, calling for fiscal consolidation and more moderate pace of public investment. Particularly, even without an adverse shock to the mining sector, public debt under the baseline investment path would reach more than 80 percent of GDP over the medium term and stay above 60 percent of GDP in outer years, signaling a high risk of debt distress. The buildup of sovereign wealth fund would be far delayed if the baseline path (without fiscal consoilidation) is adopted. Meanwhile, there is a wide gap of investment efficiency between the baseline and fiscal consolidation scenarios, suggesting substantial ineffective investment in the near term under the baseline. The baseline also entails immediate macroeconomic risk given the elevated balance of payments pressure. These risks would increase substantially given an adverse shock to the mining sector.

Going forward, the top priority is to safeguard macroeconomic stability and fiscal sustainability via fiscal consolidation and complementary structural reforms on the basis of a transparent institutional framework. From our analysis, we show that key measures could be the deficit reduction—for example, reducing public expenditure while maintaining well-targeted transfers and subsidies for inclusiveness—and a moderate investment strategy based on improved efficiency to facilitate economic diversification and growth potential, alongside the establishment of a coherent fiscal framework that addresses medium-term fiscal sustainability and makes savings under the sovereign wealth fund in the long run. In light of the lessons for Mongolia, we recommend to other similar natural resource rich and capital scarce economies that a long-term optimal fiscal framework should account for both the growth- or revenue-enhancing impact of investment and the fiscal distortions gauging its debt sustainability.

VI. Appendix

Table 1.

Calibration of Key Parameters

article image

VII. References

  • Araujo, J., Li, B., Poplawski-Ribeiro, M. and L.-F. Zanna, 2013, “Current Account Norms in Natural Resource Rich and Capital Scarce Economies.” IMF Working Paper 13/80, International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arestoff, F. and C. Hurlin, 2006, “Estimates of Government Net Capital Stocks for 26 Developing Countries, 1970-2002.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3858, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., J. Gottschalk, R. Portillo, and L.-F. Zanna, 2010. “The Macroeconomics of Medium-term Aid Scaling-up Scenarios.” IMF Working Paper 10/160, International Washington Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., R. Portillo, S.-C. S. Yang, L.-F. Zanna, 2013, “Public Investment in Resource-Abundant Developing Countries,” IMF Economic Review, 61(1), 92129.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buffie, E. F., A. Berg, C. Pattillo, R. Portillo, and L.-F. Zanna, 2012, “Public Investment, Growth, and Debt Sustainability: Putting together the Pieces,” IMF Working Paper 12/144, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Collier, P., R. van der Ploeg, M. Spence, and A. J. Venables, 2010, “Managing Resource Revenues in Developing Economies,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Palgrave Macmillan, Vol. 57(1), pp. 84118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dabla-Norris, E., J. Brumby, A. Kyobe, Z. Mills, and C. Papageorgiou, 2011. “Investing in Public Investment: An Index of Public Investment Efficiency.” IMF Working Paper 11/37, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, J., 2011, “Kwacha Gonna Do? Experimental Evidence about Labor Supply in Rural Malawi,” Manuscript, Economics Department, University of Maryland.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, S., A. Kangur, C. Papageorgiou, and A. Wane, 2014, “Efficiency-Adjusted Public Capital and Growth,” World Development, 57, 164178.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2012, Macroeconomic Frameworks for Resource-Rich Developing Countries, Washington, D.C. Available at: www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2012/082412a.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Melina, G., S.-C. S. Yang, and L.-F. Zanna, 2014, “Debt Sustainability, Public Investment, and Natural Resources in Developing Countries: the DIGNAR Model,” IMF Working Paper 14/50, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogaki, M., J. Ostry, and C. Reinhart, 1996, “Saving behavior in low- and middle-income developing countries: A comparison,” IMF Staff Papers 43 (1), 3871.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pritchett, L., 2000, “The Tyranny of Concepts: CUDIE (Cumulated, Depreciated, Investment Effort) is Not Capital,” Journal of Economic Growth vol. 5, 361384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, J.D. and A. M. Warner, 1995, revised 1997, 1999, “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working paper No. 5398, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stockman, A.C. and Tesar, L.L., 1995, “Tastes and Technology in a Two-Country Model of the Business Cycle: Explaining International Comovements,” American Economic Review, vol. 85(1), pp. 16885.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • van der Ploeg, F., 2011. “Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?Journal of Economic Literature, 49(2): 366420.

  • van der Ploeg, F., and A.J. Venables, 2011, “Harnessing Windfall Revenues: Optimal Policies for Resource Rich Developing Economies,” Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, Vol. 121(551), pp. 130.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2013, “Mongolia: Improving Public Investments to Meet the Challenge of Scaling Up InfrastructureJanuary, available at http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2013/02/27/mongolia-improving-public-investments-to-meet-the-challenge-of-scaling-up-infrastructure

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

We are grateful to Andy Berg, Koshy Mathai, Cathy Pattillo, Markus Rodlauer, Susan Yang, Felipe Zanna and seminar participants at the IMF, the Central Bank and the Ministry of Finance of Mongolia for comments and suggestions. This working paper is part of a research project on macroeconomic policy in low-income countries supported by U.K.’s Department for International Development. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF, IMF policy, or of DFID.

3

Because of the common wedge between tax burden imposed and tax revenues accrued to the government in developing countries, we assume that a fraction ϑK of the tax revenue related to capital income does not enter the government budget constraint.

4

To guarantee that the resource fund is not an explosive process, we assume that in the very long run, a small autoregressive coefficient ρfϵ(0, 1) is attached to. The model is typically solved at a yearly frequency for a 1000-period horizon. The coefficient ρf is activated after the first 100 years of simulations.

5

In addition tax rates, government consumption and transfers can also be used as fiscal adjustment instruments.

6

The DIGNAR model can also use government consumption and transfers as fiscal adjustment instruments.

7

For simplicity, we assume there is no cost in resource production, and the dividends are received by foreigners.

8

FARI model is developed by the FAD department of the International Monetary Fund.

9

Such an increase in efficiency has to be taken just as an example. In fact it can be very challenging for a developing country to achieve such an efficiency improvement over ten years. This ultimately depends on policy choices and individual country experiences.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
From Natural Resource Boom to Sustainable Economic Growth: Lessons for Mongolia
Author:
Pranav Gupta
,
Ms. Grace B Li
, and
Jiangyan Yu
  • Exchange rates of the togrog

    (Index, 2005=100, Jan. 2005-Aug. 2014; an increase is an appreciation)

  • Coal Export Price and FDI

    (Jan.2011-July 2014)

  • Figure 1.

    Assumptions: Resource Output and Public Investment Paths

    (Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

  • Figure 2.

    Projection of Public Debt and Sovereign Welfare Fund

    (Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

  • Figure 3.

    Paths of Other Variables

    (Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)

  • Figure 4.

    Robustness Check: Different Efficiency

    (Left column: Baseline Scenario; Right column: Adverse Scenario)