Is Islamic Banking Good for Growth?

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address: pimam@imf.orgkkpodar@imf.org

The rapid growth of Islamic banking has attracted much attention lately in the economic literature. At the same time, a mature body of the literature has shown that financial development is broadly conducive to economic growth, which raises the question as to whether a similar conclusion holds for Islamic banking. Against this backdrop, this paper investigates the relationship between Islamic banking development and economic growth in a sample of low and middle income countries, using data over the period 1990-2010. The results show that, notwithstanding its relatively small size compared to the economy and the overall size of the financial system, Islamic banking is positively associated with economic growth even after controlling for various determinants, including the level of financial depth. The results are robust across across different specifications, sample composition and time periods.

Abstract

The rapid growth of Islamic banking has attracted much attention lately in the economic literature. At the same time, a mature body of the literature has shown that financial development is broadly conducive to economic growth, which raises the question as to whether a similar conclusion holds for Islamic banking. Against this backdrop, this paper investigates the relationship between Islamic banking development and economic growth in a sample of low and middle income countries, using data over the period 1990-2010. The results show that, notwithstanding its relatively small size compared to the economy and the overall size of the financial system, Islamic banking is positively associated with economic growth even after controlling for various determinants, including the level of financial depth. The results are robust across across different specifications, sample composition and time periods.

I. Introduction

Since the modern birth of Islamic banking in the 1970s in Egypt, it has expanded rapidly across the globe. As illustrated by Imam and Kpodar (2013), such expansion has taken place, in particular—though not exclusively—in countries with larger Muslim populations. From an insignificant beginning, the industry has grown to over USD 1.6 trillion in assets in 2012, and is expected to reach USD 6.1 trillion by the end of this decade (Gewal, 2013). Not only have local banks in Muslim countries adopted Islamic banking principles, but large multinational banks have established Islamic windows. Islamic finance has spread beyond commercial banks, and now spans investment banks, insurance companies, as well as investment (e.g. asset management) and financial companies (e.g. leasing). The development of new products, such as sukuks (Islamic bonds), has also broadened the range of products available.

There is mounting evidence—at least for lower and middle income countries—that financial sector development is good for growth (see for instance the seminal paper of Levine, Loayza, and Beck, 2000). A developed financial sector helps mobilize savings, facilitates the allocation of capital to where returns are expected to be highest, monitors the use of capital once invested, and allows for diversification of risk. Moreover, there is a growing consensus among economists that it does not matter much for economic growth whether the financial system is more bank-based or market-based (Allen and Gale, 2000; Levine, 2002). The particular institutional arrangements that provide financial services to the economy are not so important; what matters is the level of overall financial development.

However, do these findings of financial sector deepening impacting growth also apply to systems where Islamic banking plays a significant role? This is an important question to answer, as with a few exceptions, countries with large Islamic populations are typically not highly developed (see Figure 1), and have often not performed well in economic terms, one of the reasons being an underdeveloped financial system.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Average GDP per Capita in Islamic and Other Countries (1990-2010)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 081; 10.5089/9781475569285.001.A001

Sources: IMF, Alesina, et al. (2003)Note: See Appendix table 4 for country names.

Growth in Islamic countries, while not spectacular, has not been dismal compared to other countries with a similar level of development. The widely held perception is that Islamic countries have performed poorly in economic terms since the 1950s, but this does not hold. After an initial strong growth spurt following independence—in sync with other low-income countries (LICs)—growth rates were sub-par following the lost decades of the 1980s and 1990s. While it is true that Islamic countries and sub-national regions with large Muslim populations are characterized by low incomes and a low level of social development, with the exception of oil-producing Gulf countries, they are in fact not much different from other emerging markets (EMs) and LICs (Figure 2). In fact, once adjustments for low education levels, poor institutions, commodity prices, etc., are made, evidence is mounting that Islam per se is not holding back these countries (Nolan, 2003).

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Average Real GDP Growth: How do Islamic Countries Compare to Others (1990-2010)?

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 081; 10.5089/9781475569285.001.A001

Sources: IMF, Alesina, et al. (2003)Note: See Appendix table 4 for country names.

Similarly, Islamic countries do not currently stand out in terms of private sector credit to GDP (Figure 3). However, as Islamic banking becomes more acceptable to a large swath of the population, it could expand faster, as it would not necessarily be a substitute for conventional banking, but it would provide financial products to a part of the population that otherwise would not use the financial system, potentially leading to higher financial inclusion and an acceleration of economic growth in these countries.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Average Private Sector Credit Ratio to GDP in Islamic and Other Countries (1990-2010)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 081; 10.5089/9781475569285.001.A001

Sources: Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, (2000), Alesina, et al. (2003)Note: See Appendix table 4 for country names.

Thus, the rapid diffusion of Islamic banking represents a growth opportunity for Islamic countries, as much of the empirical evidence suggests a strong link between financial sector development and growth (see Levine (2005) for a summary). However, the empirical literature has only looked at conventional banking, not Islamic banking. This paper aims to rectify this lacuna, by considering whether Islamic banking is also potent in raising growth. This paper aims to establish the positive relationship between Islamic banking and economic growth, and not to answer the question of whether the growth-enhancing effect of Islamic banking goes beyond that of conventional banking. Using a sample of low- and middle-income countries with data over the period 1990-2010, we investigate the impact of Islamic banking on growth and discuss the policy implications. The results show that, notwithstanding its relatively small size compared to the economy or the overall size of the financial system, Islamic banking is positively associated with economic growth even after controlling for various determinants, including the level of financial depth. The results are robust across different measures of Islamic banking development, econometric estimators (pooling, fixed effects and System GMM), and to the sample composition and time periods.

The paper is structured as follows. Section II reviews the literature, with a focus on how Islamic banking could help financial deepening, and ultimately growth. Section III presents the sample, the econometric model, and estimators, as well as the results. Section IV concludes with the policy implications.

II. Literature Review

Although the finance—growth nexus continues to be heavily debated in the literature, the main thrust is that financial development has, by and large, a favourable impact on economic growth. Financial intermediaries carry out five basic functions that serve growth: they (i) facilitate the trading, hedging, diversifying, and pooling of risk; (ii) allocate resources; (iii) monitor managers and exert corporate control; (iv) mobilize savings; and (v) facilitate the exchange of goods and services (see Levine, 1997). In performing their functions, financial intermediaries mitigate the effects of information and transaction costs, and improve the allocation of resources, thus influencing saving rates, investment decisions, technical innovation, and ultimately long-run growth rates. In turn, economic activity can also influence financial development. It is worth noting that this whole literature implicitly refers to conventional banking. An interesting question is: does this also apply to Islamic banks?

The literature has evolved overtime, however, and depicted alternating periods of optimism and scepticism on the benefits of finance for growth. It began early with the work of Schumpeter (1912), who highlighted the essential role of banks in financing innovative businesses and increasing productivity. Robinson (1952) challenges this view, arguing that financial development simply follows economic growth. Although Gurley and Shaw (1960) share Schumpeter’s view on the importance of finance for growth, they stress instead the role of financial innovation for economic development, as it facilitates better risk management and a reduction in intermediation costs.

However, following the work of McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973), mixed country experiences from the wave of financial liberalization policies in the 1970s and 1980s raised uncertainties on the potential benefits of finance for growth. The studies of King and Levine (1993a), (1993b) and (1993 c) and Levine (1997) gave a new impetus to the finance-growth literature. The authors thoroughly documented the channels through which financial development positively impacted economic growth and undertook convincing theoretical and empirical investigation to support their hypothesis. Subsequent studies confirmed their findings (e.g. Rajan and Zingales, 1998; Levine, Loayza, and Beck, 2000), although some more recent studies—especially since the global financial crisis—cast doubt on the strength of the positive relationship between financial development and growth (see for instance Andersen and Tarp, 2003, Arcand, Berkes and Panizza, 2012 and Panizza, 2014). There is also evidence that by increasing the likelihood of banking crisis, the positive relationship between financial sector development and growth may be conditional (see Guillaumont Jeanneney and Kpodar, 2006).

Following the Miller and Modigliani (1958) capital structure irrelevance theory, it is likely that Islamic banking and conventional banking will not have different impacts on growth per se, if they finance the same projects. Although the benefits/risks of the project are distributed differently for conventional banks than for Islamic banks, the overall return on the project is the same. On the other hand, while Islamic banks perform similar functions to conventional banks, they have distinct features. In fact, Islamic banking has many advantages, not only in Islamic countries, but also in low- and middle-income countries in general, that could explain why it is preferable in stimulating growth to conventional banking, under certain circumstances. What are these distinct advantages of Islamic banking?

  • Encourages lending (to individuals without assets). Conventional banks in most countries lend based on some form of guarantee/collateral. The risk-sharing characteristic of Islamic banking means that the borrower and the bank share the risk of any investment on agreed terms, and divide any profits or losses between them, without recourse to guarantees. Risk-sharing leads providers of financial capital and entrepreneurs to share business risks in return for a share of profits, suggesting that borrower liabilities are state-contingent, in contrast to conventional banks. This should in principle encourage more investment—notably by individuals who could not otherwise borrow because of a lack of assets that could act as a guarantee—and thereby growth.2 Ben Naceur et al. (2015) find that although physical access to financial services has grown more rapidly in member countries of the Organization for Islamic Cooperation, the use of these services has not increased as quickly. Through the prohibition of riba (interest rates), the incentives of lenders and borrowers are aligned, thus reducing moral hazard. At the same time, it helps to spur investment that would otherwise not take place, and thereby growth, and also acts as a shock absorber for countries subject to large shocks.

  • Raises savings. Islamic banking can raise the savings of pious individuals who refrain from using conventional banks, as they do not satisfy the needs of devout Muslims, who are not willing to put their savings into a financial system that is not based on religious principles. This could thereby increase financial intermediation. Demirguc-Kunt et al. (2013) explore the difference between Muslims and non-Muslims within the same country, and find that in the 64 countries they cover, 24 percent of Muslim adults report having a bank account, in contrast to 44 percent of non-Muslims who have one. This under-banking of an important segment of the population leads to savings not being channeled to the formal sector, and therefore not being used efficiently, leading to sub-optimal financial intermediation.3 Bringing Muslims into the formal sector, by providing them with suitable products, would increase access to finance, with savings increasing commensurately.

  • Enhances financial stability. Most boom-bust cycles witnessed across the world in recent decades have exposed several underlying factors that highlight the vulnerability of conventional banking, namely high leveraging, wholesale financing, and utilization of complex instruments.4 In Islamic finance, balance sheet mismatches are absent, as banks do not have asset-liability mismatches, given that short-term deposits finance short-term trading, while for longer-term investments, longer-term deposits are used (Mirakhor, 2010). There is also consistent evidence of higher capitalization of Islamic banks, and this capital cushion combined with higher liquidity reserves explains the relatively better performance of Islamic banks during the recent crisis. Derivatives and other non-transparent products are also disallowed.5 This, combined with the sharing of profits and losses, creates a less crisis prone system (Cihak and Hesse, 2008; Hassan and Dridi, 2010). It is probably fair to say that banking systems that are diversified, through including Islamic banks as a complement to conventional banks, are likely to contribute to financial stability (Imam and Kpodar, 2013)6.

  • Finances morally acceptable projects. Islamic banking is based on a moral system of Islam, which only allows for the financing of assets that are not harmful to society. Islamic banks are not allowed to finance casinos and other activities that are deemed harmful to society and the poor in particular. While the standard of ‘morally’ acceptable projects might seem subjective to some outsiders, the gray areas are few, and an Islamic scholar will in case of doubt be able to provide an answer. This aspect is difficult to quantify, but could be growth enhancing by reducing negative externalities imposed on society by undesirable projects. If conventional banking and Islamic banking co-exist, this aspect is unlikely to matter much, as ‘haram’ activities can be financed by conventional banking.

All these factors are, in principle, conducive to higher growth and poverty alleviation. Moreover, if Islamic banking is more likely to develop in Islamic countries because it is more acceptable to pious Muslims, growth is likely to accelerate more rapidly in these countries than it would if only conventional banking were available. However, Islamic banks have certain structural weaknesses that counterbalance the positive aspects:

  • Lack of Economies of Scale. Islamic banks are often newer, and therefore smaller, than conventional banks. This means that they are often still below optimal scales and thus have higher cost structures (Hasan and Dridi, 2010).7 We should expect that, with continued growth, the disadvantage of scale will disappear over time as the industry grows. Comparing conventional and Islamic banks and controlling for other bank and country characteristics, Beck et al. (2010) find few significant differences in business orientation, efficiency, asset quality, or stability. While Islamic banks seem more cost-effective than conventional banks in a broad cross-country sample, this finding reverses in a sample of countries with both Islamic and conventional banks. However, conventional banks that operate in countries with a higher market share of Islamic banks are more cost-effective but less stable.

  • Lack of Liquid Instruments. There is no secondary market for Islamic fixed-income products, forcing Islamic banks to have large liquidity buffers, putting them at a disadvantage relative to conventional banks (Moody’s, 2009). This is because Islamic banks are prohibited from engaging in activities that include interest, but the way central banks function is through a repo that includes interest bearing assets. The establishment in 2010 of the “International Islamic Liquidity Management Corporation” (IILM), whose objective is to issue Shariah-compliant financial instruments that facilitate more efficient and effective liquidity management solutions for institutions offering Islamic financial services, should help address this problem8. However, this is still a work in progress.

Thus, Islamic banks have features that can promote growth, but at the same time are disadvantaged by the lack of economies of scale and liquid instruments—though work is ongoing to address these shortcomings. This suggests that the answer to the question as to whether Islamic banking promotes growth lies in the empirical evidence. While there is a plethora of empirical studies on the impact of financial development on growth,9 studies on how Islamic banking development affects growth are nonexistent, a void this paper attempts to fill in the next section.

III. Econometric Estimation

A. The data and model

In this section, we empirically attempt to assess the impact of Islamic banking on growth. We construct a panel of 52 developing economies, of which 29 belong to the Organization of Islamic Countries (OIC), with data spanning the period 1990-2010, and averaged over 3-year intervals. The sample size is constrained by data availability, in particular on variables capturing Islamic banking expansion and the quality of the institutional environment. In addition, we restricted the sample to low and middle income countries as the macroeconomic variables included in the growth model are more relevant to them, and also because this helps reduce sample heterogeneity. With regard to the length of the time period, the 3-year average represents a good balance between the need to smooth business cycle fluctuations and that of ensuring an adequate number of observations for the regressions.

We rely on a standard growth model, with a set of variables of interest measuring broad financial development and Islamic banking development, and control variables conventionally utilized in the growth literature. The data sources for the variables are found in Appendix Table 1. The variables of interest consist of:

  • Development of Islamic banking. As discussed above, there are theoretical grounds for expecting a positive impact of Islamic banking development on growth. This makes Islamic banking indicators good candidates for explaining cross-country growth. We measure Islamic banking development by the amount of loans extended by these banks to the private sector divided by nominal GDP. While this indicator gives an idea on the size of the Islamic banking sector, it may not accurately measure the indirect channels through which Islamic banks could ignite growth (facilitate risk sharing, enhance financial stability, and mobilize savings). However, it is reasonable to assume that the larger the Islamic banking sector, the better it can perform its functions, a common hypothesis also made for conventional banking in past studies. We also use two alternative indicators of Islamic banking development: the ratio of Islamic banking assets to GDP and the ratio of deposits in Islamic banks to GDP, the latter being a useful indicator to gauge the ability of Islamic banks to mobilize savings.10 As a robustness check we also used an indicator of capitalization (the capital-to-asset ratio), and the standard ratios of Return on Equity (ROE) and Return on Assets (ROA) to measure the financial strength and profitability of Islamic banks.

  • Development of the overall banking system. There is a general acceptance in the economic literature that financial deepening stimulates growth (for a literature review, see Levine, 2005 and 2007). As a result, we include in the model the ratio of private sector credit by commercial banks in percent of GDP as a measure of the development of the banking sector. Since both conventional and Islamic banking coexist in many countries and evolve together, it is important to control growth for the overall size of the banking system in order to properly isolate the growth impact of Islamic banking. Alternative measures of financial development considered include the ratio of private sector credit by bank and nonbank financial institutions in percent of GDP, the total assets of financial institutions as a ratio of GDP and finally the total financial system deposits as a ratio to GDP.

The control variables include:

  • Initial real GDP per capita. This variable is intended to control for growth convergence as the neoclassical model points out that lower income countries, with lower initial levels of technology and capital, will tend to grow faster than more advanced countries.

  • Inflation: It has long been argued that inflation uncertainty lowers real output growth. Inflation uncertainty increases the variability of prices, which distorts the price signal and thereby harms economic efficiency and productivity. In addition, high inflation is likely to be associated with weaker growth as it is often a reflection of weak quality and unsustainable macroeconomic policies.

  • Government consumption. The issue of government spending and its effect on economic growth is still widely debated in the economic literature. While government spending is necessary, and has a growth-enhancing impact when it finances public goods such as infrastructure, it can deter growth when excessively dominated by current spending. The hypothesis is that rising government consumption (as a percent of GDP) encourages poor quality spending, leads to an oversized government and often results in a waste of public resources, which crowd out private investment when government relies on domestic resources to finance growing deficits.

  • Education: Human capital accumulation, as proxied by the primary school enrolment rate, is expected to have a positive impact on growth through improved labor productivity.

  • Trade Openness: It is to be expected that countries that are more open will experience higher economic growth, as they can take better advantage of economies of scale in production, benefit from technological transfer, promote efficient allocation of resources, and encourage competition in domestic markets. At the same time, trade openness can make countries more vulnerable to exogenous shocks when export concentration is high, making growth more volatile, which ultimately can result in lower long-term growth.

  • Terms of Trade: Improvements in terms of trade are often associated with economic growth. Conversely, deteriorating terms of trade would hamper growth, especially in developing countries where financial markets are shallow.

  • Quality of Institutions: Institutional quality matters for long-term growth, as it determines the incentives of and the constraints on economic actors, fosters better policy choices, and shapes economic outcomes (Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2004). However, measuring accurately institutional development remains a challenge. While, no perfect or comprehensive indicator exists, we opted for the indicator of rule of law as a proxy for the quality of institutions, as compiled by the International Risk Country Guide (ICRG), which is widely used in the literature.

The baseline regression looks as follows:

Git = α + βIslBankit + δFDit + φXit + Ui + εit + vt

where: G is the growth rate of real GDP per capita; IslBank is the indicator of Islamic banking development (ratio of loans, assets, or deposits in Islamic banks to GDP); FD is the measure of overall financial development (ratio of private sector credit by commercial banks to GDP); X is the set of control variables described above; u is the country-specific effect, ε the error term and v is the time-specific effect (see Appendix table 1 for the source and description of data).

B. The methodology

Estimating the growth impact of Islamic banking poses several econometric challenges. First, while Islamic banking is fast growing, the size of Islamic banking development in relation to GDP or banking assets is often zero, or very small in the majority of countries, including Islamic ones. This makes it challenging to identify any statistically significant impact. Second, like for conventional banking, there may be a reverse causality from growth to Islamic finance, raising an endogeneity issue that needs to be addressed in the regressions. Third, the indicators of Islamic bank development are subject to measurement errors as only pure Islamic banks are covered by statistics while Islamic windows (of conventional banks) are not included, due to lack of data. This is because conventional banks often do not separate in their balance sheets and financial reports activities related to Islamic finance from those of conventional banking. The underestimation of Islamic banking development would lead to a downward bias of the estimated coefficient.

In light of the challenges outlined above, we use a range of econometric techniques which include pooling and fixed effects estimator to control for country-specific effects, and the System GMM estimator to control for endogeneity bias. In the following section, we will provide the rationale behind each econometric estimator, as well as what issues they address and what they don’t. Before that, we look at the two-way relationship between real GDP per capita growth and each of the three indicators of Islamic banking development. This simple illustration suggests a positive correlation between Islamic banking development and economic growth (Figure 4 and Appendix table 2). This result holds for the whole sample as well as for the sub-sample of countries with Islamic banks (Figure 4).

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Islamic Banking Development and Economic Growth (1990-2010)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 081; 10.5089/9781475569285.001.A001

Notes: Data are 3-year average over the period 1990-2010Sources: IMF, Bankscope, authors’ calculations

C. Main results

Pooling and Fixed-effects

Table 1 presents the results from the estimations using a pooling and fixed-effect estimator. The pooling estimator runs ordinary least squares (OLS) with the panel data, without regard to which countries they belong. Unlike the pooling estimator, a fixed-effect estimator allows to control for unobservable country-specific effects invariant over time, and which affect a country’s economic growth. The results from the pooling estimation are presented in columns 1 to 6, while those of the fixed-effect estimator are shown in columns 7 to 12. For each series of regressions, the first specification runs the baseline model only with the control variables (columns 1 and 7), while the second specification controls for overall financial development (columns 2 and 8) measured by the ratio of private sector credit by commercial banks in percent of GDP. Subsequent specifications (column 3 to 6, 9 to 12) add in turn the 3 indicators of Islamic banking development, as well as a composite indicator constructed as the first principal component of the above 3 indicators of Islamic banking development using the principal component analysis (PCA).

Table 1.

Islamic Banking and Growth: Pooling and Fixed Effect Regressions

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

The findings confirm the well-known result found in the economic literature that financial deepening matters for growth. The coefficient is positive and significant in all specifications at least at the 5 percent significance level. More interestingly, for a given level of financial development, Islamic banking is found to stimulate growth. The coefficients for all the indicators of Islamic banking development, including the composite index, are positive and enter the regressions in a statistically significant way, confirming the theoretical predictions, despite the fact that Islamic banking has been small relative to GDP.11 This result suggests that Islamic banking responds to the specific needs of households and firms, which would have been otherwise unmet and the associated incremental growth would have been forgone. This result also provides evidence that Islamic banking does not appear to crowd out traditional finance—it complements, rather than substitutes for conventional banking—as for a given level of financial development, more Islamic banking raises economic growth.

Regarding the control variables, as expected, accumulation of human capital stimulates economic growth, with the coefficient for primary school enrollment rate highly significant in all regressions. We also tested the secondary school enrollment rate, which gives similar results but missing values on this variable reduce the sample size. Countries with sound macro-economic policies, characterized by low inflation and subdued government current spending, tend to grow faster. This also seems to be the case for countries with positive terms of trade changes and good institutional quality. Further, the hypothesis of economic convergence is supported by the negative and significant sign of the variable initial GDP per capita. In contrast, trade openness seems to have an ambiguous effect on growth, often with a counterintuitive sign, which is not surprising given the contrasting results in previous studies focusing on the growth dividend of trade openness (see Winters, 2004, for an overview). Overall, the model helps explain 33 to 38 percent of the variability in economic growth rates

Although the pooling and fixed effect estimators provide interesting results, the coefficients may be biased in the presence of the endogeneity of the right-hand side variables, in particular with regard to the financial sector indicators. This is particularly relevant for Islamic banking indicators, as their potential endogeneity does not only result from the reverse causality to growth, but also from measurement errors when the full size of Islamic banking development is not captured in the data12.

System-GMM

To address the endogeneity issue, not only for the banking indicators, but also for some other explanatory variables, we rely on the System-GMM estimator (dynamic panel Generalized Method-of-Moment) developed by Blundell and Bond (1998). They show that the System-GMM estimator, which simultaneously uses both the difference in the panel data and the data from the original levels specification, produces dramatic increases in both consistency and efficiency relative to the first-differenced GMM developed by Arellano and Bond (1991)13. We use the one-step System GMM estimator while controlling for sample heterogeneity14. Further, to minimize over-fitting of the model, careful attention is paid to the selection of the instruments. For variables considered as predetermined or endogenous, only the first relevant lag is used15. To test the validity of the lagged variables as instruments, we use the standard Hansen test of over-identifying restrictions, where the null hypothesis is that the instrumental variables are not correlated with the residual, and the serial correlation test, where the null hypothesis is that the errors exhibit no second-order serial correlation.

The results from the System GMM estimator presented in Table 2 are comparable to those from the fixed-effect estimator16. Once again, both overall financial system development and Islamic banking development appear to have a meaningful positive impact on economic growth. The coefficients on financial variables should be interpreted with caution, however, given the relatively small size of Islamic banking compared to the overall financial development, which makes them not directly comparable. One way to make the coefficients more informative by taking into account the scale effect is to estimate the coefficients for the standardized financial variables17.

Table 2.

Islamic Banking and Growth: Dynamic Panel System GMM estimations

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. AR(2): Arellano and Bond test of second order autocorrelation

The results (in Annex 1) suggest that a one standard deviation increase in the overall financial development would lead to about 3.4 percent increase in real GDP per capita growth. For a one standard deviation increase in the ratio of loans by Islamic banks to GDP, the impact on growth would be of 0.5 percent compared to about 0.8 percent for the ratios of assets and deposits of Islamic banks to GDP. However, even with the standardized variables, the regressions do not allow for reliable inference on the magnitude of the growth impact of Islamic banking, although they provide strong evidence on the positive effect of Islamic banking on growth. From that perspective, the fixed effects and GMM System results are quite encouraging, especially given the concern that a significant number of countries in the sample are reported as not having Islamic banking activities (although they might have banks with Islamic finance windows), while in countries where Islamic banks are present, their relative importance in the economy or the banking system is still far from significant.

Robustness analysis and Alternative specifications

Table 3 presents additional regressions to test the robustness of the relationship between Islamic banking development and economic growth using alternative indicators of Islamic Banking. In column 1, we use a step dummy taking 1 for strictly positive values of the composite indicator if Islamic banking and zero otherwise to measure the presence of Islamic banking in a given country. The associated coefficient is positive and significant confirming the above results that for countries with similar level of financial development, those with Islamic banking would experience faster economic growth.

Table 3.

Dynamic Panel System GMM Estimations with Alternative Indicators of Islamic Banking Development

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. AR(2): Arellano and Bond test of second order autocorrelation

In the subsequent regressions, we test the impact of variables related to the soundness and profitability of Islamic banks on economic growth (columns 2 to 5). It emerges that well-capitalized Islamic banks may have a favorable impact on economic growth, probably because healthy banks are less prone to crisis. With profitability measured by the standard ratios of Return on Equity (ROE) and Return on Assets (ROA), we find that Islamic banks’ profitability also benefit economic growth.

Using alternative measures of overall financial development does not change the conclusion that Islamic banking matters for growth. The coefficient for Islamic banking indicators retains its sign and statistical significance when bank and nonbank private credit ratio, a broader measure of financial development, is controlled for (Table 4, column 1 to 3).

Table 4.

Use of Different Indicators of Overall Financial Development (System GMM Estimations)

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. AR(2): Arellano and Bond test of second order autocorrelation

In addition, we introduce as a measure of overall financial development the ratio of total financial sector assets to GDP and the ratio of total financial sector deposit to GDP respectively in the specification using the corresponding measure for Islamic banking (Table 4, column 4 and 5). Both the indicators of overall financial development and Islamic banking continue to be positively and significantly correlated with economic growth.

To test the robustness of the results it is worthwhile to assess their sensitivity to sample composition and the time period. As Islamic banks are likely to emerge and expand in countries with large Muslim population, we restricted the sample to countries with more than 50 percent Muslim population share (column 1 to 3, Table 5). In subsequent regressions, this threshold is increased to 75 percent (column 4 to 6, Table 5). The results are broadly in line with those obtained for the whole sample and the magnitudes of the coefficients are also comparable,18 suggesting that countries with smaller share of Muslim population can potentially benefit from Islamic banking. The regressions are rerun with a sample restricted to net oil importer countries (column 7 to 9, Table 5) in order to exclude potential outlier countries where Islamic banking development might have been fuelled by oil money. While the three indicators of Islamic banking remain positively correlated with economic growth, the asset and deposit ratios are significant but not the loan ratio. This probably is a reflection that Islamic banks in net oil importer countries may not enjoy the benefits of large oil money deposits that could be used to scale-up loans compared to net oil exporting countries.

Table 5.

Sensitivity to Sample Composition (System GMM Estimations)

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. AR(2): Arellano and Bond test of second order autocorrelation

We also run the regressions over different time periods to see if the results hold. First, we considered the period 1996-2010, leaving out the first half of the 1990s where Islamic banks were at the nascent stage. Second, we choose to run the regressions over 1990-2007, excluding the 2008-2010 period which might be affected by structural breaks associated with the 2008 global financial crisis. The conclusion that Islamic banking is favorable to economic growth holds regardless of the period considered (Table 6). The regressions over the period 1996-2007 yield similar results.

Table 6.

Sensitivity to Time Periods (System GMM Estimations)

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. AR(2): Arellano and Bond test of second order autocorrelation

IV. Conclusion

The objective of this paper was to assess the impact of Islamic banking on economic growth. This is the first paper, to our knowledge, that comprehensively assesses this question using robust empirical techniques. We find that, holding constant the level of financial development and other growth determinants, countries where Islamic banking is present and hence its impact on growth is measurable, experience faster economic growth than others. This is a powerful result, and robust to various specifications: we use different measures of Islamic banking development, econometric estimators (pooling, fixed effects and System GMM), and control for country and time-specific dummies. This finding is also encouraging as, despite its rapid growth, Islamic banking still represents a relatively small share of the economy and of the overall size of the financial system, and it has yet to reap the benefits from economies of scale. Although our study does not suggest that Islamic banking provides more “bang for the buck” compared to conventional banks; it does, however, establish the positive impact on growth. As indicated, there are uncertainties on the magnitude of the growth effect of Islamic banking, which calls for further research as Islamic banks diffuse further and become larger. Should future studies confirm this finding, the policy implications would be significant.

As the global crisis has illustrated, conventional banking has many weaknesses—its excessive dependence on leverage being one of them. However, Islamic banking, which is one of the fastest growing segments of global finance, has unique features that are highly appropriate for developing countries. In particular, it is based on risk-sharing, making its activities more closely related to the real economy than conventional finance; it is also more flexible against shocks and more inclusive with regards to growth. Not only does Islamic finance help to stimulate growth, but it also appears less prone to risks such as bubbles (Dridi and Maher, 2011).

This means that many countries that currently suffer from low growth—a feature often present in Muslim countries—may want to further develop this segment of finance. As an initial step, it is essential to develop proper legislation and regulation, as well as the supporting infrastructure, including the necessary skill set. Future areas of research include measuring better Islamic banking development and assessing the impact of Islamic banking on inequality and social development.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson, 2004, “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth,National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 10481.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, A., A. Devleeschauwer, W. Easterly, S. Kurlat, and R. Wacziarg, 2003, “Fractionalization,Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 15594.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Allen, F. and D. Gale, 2000, Comparing Financial Systems (Boston: MIT Press)

  • Amin Gutiérrez de Piñeres, S., and M. Ferrantino 2000, Export Dynamics and Economic Growth in Latin America: A Comparative Perspective (UK: Ashgate).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andersen, T., and F. Tarp (2003), “Financial Liberalization, Financial Development and Economic Growth in LDCs”, Journal of International Development 15 (2), pp. 189209.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arcand, J.-L., E. Berkes and U. Panizza (2012), “Too Much Finance?”, IMF Working Paper No. 12/161.

  • Arellano, M. and S. Bond, 1991, “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, pp. 277297.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arellano, M. and O. Bover, 1995, “Another Look at the Instrumental-Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models,Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 68, No. 1, pp. 2952.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt and R. Levine, 2000, “A New Database on Financial Development and Structure,World Bank Economic Review, No 14, pp. 597605

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt and O. Merrouche, 2010, “Islamic vs. conventional banking: business model, efficiency and stability,World Bank Working Paper No.5, 446

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel, 1994. “The role of human capital in economic development: evidence from aggregate cross-country data,Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 34, pp. 143174.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ben Naceur, S., A. Barajas and A. Massara, 2015Can Islamic Banking Increase Financial Inclusion?IMF Working Paper No. 31

  • Blundell, R., and S. Bond, 1998, “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models,Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 87, No. 1, pp. 11543.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bond, S., A. Hoeffler, and J. Temple, 2001, “GMM Estimation of Empirical Growth Models,Economics Papers 2001-W21 (Oxford: Economics Group, Nuffield College, University of Oxford).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cleveland, W. S, 1979, “Robust Locally Weighted Regression and Smoothing Scatterplots,Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74, pp. 829836.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirguc-Kunt, A. and R. Levine, 2009, “Finance and Inequality: Theory and Evidence,NBER Working Paper No. 15275.

  • Demirguc-Kunt, A., L. Klapper and D. Randall, YEAR?, “Islamic Finance and Financial Inclusion: Measuring Use of and Demand for Formal Financial Services among Muslim Adults,World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 6642

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • DiNardo, J and J. L. Tobias, 2001, “Nonparametric Density and Regression Estimation,Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 15 (4), pp. 1128.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, W., and A. Kraay, 2000, “Small States, Small Problems? Income, Growth, and Volatility in Small States,World Development Vol. 28, pp. 201327.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, W. and A. Reshef, 2009, “Big Hits in Manufacturing Exports and Development,NYU Working Paper mimeo.

  • Gewal, B., 2013, “Overview of the Islamic Financial Landscape: Globally and in Europe,Kuwait Finance House mimeo

  • Greenwood, J. and B. Jovanovic, 1990. “Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98(5), pp. 10761107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guillaumont Jeanneney, S. and K. Kpodar, 2006, “Développement financier, instabilité financière et croissance économique,Économie et Prévision, Vol. 174 (3), pp. 87111.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gurley, J.G. and E.S. Shaw, (1960), Money in a Theory of Finance, (Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution).

  • Hassan, M. and J. Dridi, 2010, “The Effects of the Global Crisis on Islamic and Conventional Banks: A Comparative Study,IMF Working Paper No. 201

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Honohan, P., 2001Islamic Financial Intermediation: Economic and Prudential Considerations,Development Research Group and Financial Sector Strategy Department mimeo, (Washington DC: World Bank)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ichimura, H. and P. Todd, 2007, “Implementing Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimators,Handbook of Econometrics, J.J. Heckman & E.E. Leamer (ed.), Vol. 6, Chap. 74.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Imam, P. and K. Kpodar, 2013, “Islamic Banking: How has it Expanded?Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, Vol. 49, pp. 112137

  • Jansen, M. (2004), “Income Volatility in Small and Developing Economies: Export Concentration Matters,Discussion Paper 3. World Trade Organization, Geneva.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King R. and R. Levine (1993a) “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, pp. 717738.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King R. and R. Levine (1993b) “Finance, Entrepreneurship, and Growth: Theory and Evidence,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 513542.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King R. and R. Levine (1993c) “Financial Intermediation and Economic Development,” in Financial Intermediation in the Construction of Europe, Eds: Mayer C. and Vives X., London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, pp. 156189.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, R., 1997, “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 688726.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine R., N. Loayza and T. Beck, 2000, “Financial Intermediation and Growth: Causality and Causes,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 46, no. 1, August, pp. 3177.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine R., 2002, “Bank-based or Market-based Financial Systems: Which is Better?NBER Working Paper no. 9138.

  • Levine R.,, 2005, “Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence” pp. 865934 in Aghion, Philippe and Steven Durlauf, “Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1a (Amsterdam: North-Holland Elsevier)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon R. I., 1973, “Money and Capital in Economic Development,” (Washington D.C.: The Brooking Institution).

  • Modigliani, F and M. Miller, 1958The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment”. American Economic Review, Vol. 48, pp. 261297

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moody’s, 2009, ‘The Liquidity/Leverage Trade-Off for Islamic Banks—and its Impact on Their Ratings” (Moody’s Investors Service)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nolan, M., 2003, “Religion, Culture, and Economic PerformancePeterson Institute Working Paper Series WP03-8, Peterson Institute for International Economics

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Panizza, U., 2014, “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Known Knowns, Known Unknowns, and Unknown Unknowns,Revue d’économie du développement, Vol. 22(2), pp. 3366.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pritchett, L., 1997, “Where Has All the Education Gone?Working Paper No. 1581 (Washington D.C: World Bank).

  • Rajan, R. and L. Zingales, 1998. “Financial Dependence and Growth,American Economic Review, Vol. 88(3), pp. 55986.

  • Robinson, J., 1952, “The Generalization of the General Theory,” in The Rate of Interest and Other Essays, (London: Macmillan).

  • Schumpeter J., 1912, “The Theory of Economic Development,” (Leipzig: Dunker & Humblot, translated by Redvers Opie, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1934).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Winters, A., 2004, “Trade Liberalisation and Economic Performance: An Overview,Economic Journal, Vol. 114, pp. 421.

Annex 1. Islamic Banking and Growth: Dynamic Panel System GMM estimations with Standardized Coefficients for the Financial Variables

article image
Note: Robust standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. AR(2): Arellano and Bond test of second order autocorrelation
Appendix Table 1.

Variable Definition and Sources

article image
Appendix Table 2.

Correlation Matrix

article image