Abstract
Rollover risk imposes market discipline on banks’ risk-taking behavior but it can be socially costly. I present a two-sided model in which a bank simultaneously lends to a firm and borrows from the short-term funding market. When the bank is capital constrained, uncertainty in asset quality and rollover risk create a negative externality that spills over to the real economy by ex ante credit contraction. Macroprudential and monetary policies can be used to reduce the social cost of market discipline and improve efficiency.
I Introduction
The reliance on short-term debt by banks and other financial institutions was a prominent feature in the run up to the crisis of 2007 to 2009. Spikes in uncertainty about the quality of their assets caused freezes in the asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) and overnight sale and repurchase (repo) markets. From a systemic perspective, the inability to roll over short-term debt was a market failure that led to the demise of a substantial part of investment banking and the distress of other financial institutions in the United States, United Kingdom, and other countries. The financial sector distress was followed by the prolonged investment slowdown and economic decline of the Great Recession.
In this paper, I am interested in developing a model of investment contraction caused by uncertainty in the asset quality and rollover risk of banks and other financial intermediaries (hereafter, banks). While there is a growing literature that analyzes the implication of short-term credit market for banks, most existing theories treat investment and the capital structure of banks separately. However, many questions emerged during the crisis are related to banks as a transmission channel between credit and capital markets. For example, how do the investment and financing decisions of banks interact? How does asset quality uncertainty affect the supply of credit? What are the real effects of banks’ rollover risk?
These questions motivate a two-sided model of the balance sheet of banks. In the model, a bank separately contracts with a firm to invest in real projects (the asset side) and with investors in the wholesale funding market to finance its assets (the liability side). The investment is long term (e.g. a mortgage) but the financing is short term (e.g. a repo). The bank faces idiosyncratic uncertainty because the quality and rollover decision on an individual project is unknown ex ante. The bank may in addition face aggregate uncertainty because in a bad aggregate state, the quality of projects is more dispersed.
I analyze the interaction between a bank’s financing and investment decisions as a channel of uncertainty transmission. The economic mechanism is as follows. On the liability side, a short-term loan with limited debt capacity is the outcome of optimal contracting for a bank that faces a risk-shifting moral hazard problem. However, uncertainty in asset quality and the need to rollover short-term debt can lead to inefficient liquidation in some states of the world, which affects the bank’s investment surplus on the asset side. This inefficiency spills over to the real economy causing ex ante credit contraction and underinvestment.
From a social welfare perspective, the use of short-term debt is a mixed blessing. On the one hand, investors in the credit market can use rollover risk as a discipline device to limit the risk of the bank. By forcing the bank into liquidation with a debt run when the signaled project revenue is low, they prevent the bank from taking on riskier but less efficient projects. On the other hand, rollover risk is socially costly. In equilibrium, a debt run can lead to a loss of total surplus (i.e. a deadweight loss) and an ex ante contraction of the economy. This contractionary effect is aggravated by aggregate uncertainty.
The two-sided model has different welfare properties from a standard one-sided model of bank runs (Calomiris and Kahn (1991), Diamond and Rajan (2000)). Here the driving force of uncertainty transmission and welfare loss is the interaction between the bank’s investment and financing decisions. In the model, uncertainty in asset quality alone does not lead to inefficiency. If the bank has sufficient capital and all the bargaining power in contract renegotiation, a one-sided bank-firm contract can be renegotiated in a way to fully restore efficiency. In contrast, if the bank relies on short-term lending to finance its balance sheet, the equilibrium investment is inevitably lower than the first-best.
The welfare properties of the model provide a rationale for policy interventions. Ex ante policies such as capital requirements and liquidity requirements in the banking sector can lead to welfare improvement and restore efficiency. Ex post policies such as a monetary intervention can also improve efficiency in crisis time but has no effect on ex ante investment. A subtle point about capital requirement is that it may fully restore efficiency only if there is no equity premium. The reason is that imposing a minimum capital ratio addresses the problem of debt runs; however, it does not address why equity holders require higher returns. The model is not designed to address equity-side frictions.
This paper is related to a growing literature on the effects of aggregate uncertainty on the real economy by driving business cycles (Bloom (2009), Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng (2013)), affecting credit spreads (Gilchrist, Sim and Zakrajsek (2013)), increasing labor wedge (Arellano, Bai and Kehoe (2012)), or deducing credit supply (Valencia (2013)). Like in the last three studies, uncertainty negatively affects investment through the bank’s lending decision. But unlike there, the bank’s credit supply is a constrained outcome of market discipline. The use of short-term debt is necessary to discipline the bank’s risk taking behavior.
The role of deposit or short-run debt runs as a discipline device has been discussed in classical bank run models such as Calomiris and Kahn (1991) and Diamond and Rajan (2000). The difference is that in their models, investment is not affected by bank runs. In Calomiris and Kahn (1991), investment is fixed and welfare loss is ex post. In Diamond and Rajan (2000), bank runs occurs of the equilibrium.
The work in the paper also contributes to the literature on the rollover risk of short-term debt, which is well documented for the ABCP market (Covitz, Liang and Suarez (2013), Kacperczyk and Schnabl (2010)) and the repo market (Martin, Skeie and von Thadden (2014), Gorton and Metrick (2012)). Previous theoretical work focuses on the debt capacity of collateralized assets (Acharya, Gale and Yorulmazer (2011), Adrian and Shin (2013)), separating liquidity and solvency risks (Morris and Shin (2003)), and the interaction between risk-taking behavior and fire sale (Eisenbach (2013)). This literature commonly abstracts away from the equilibrium level of real investment.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II introduces the model. Section III presents equilibrium financing and investment solutions. Section IV examines several extensions. Section V describes policy options. Section VI concludes.
II Model
Consider an economy with two risky investment projects and three parties. A firm invests in projects and finances its investment through a bank. The bank funds projects and finances its operation through collateralized borrowing. An investor serves as an uninsured wholesale creditor to the bank. All parties are risk neutral. There are three dates t = 0, 1, 2. The two-period opportunity cost of capital is R = 1 + r > 1.
The firm can invest in one of two projects, a good project (g) and a bad project (b). Each project is represented by a stochastic production technology that transforms A units of capital at date t = 0 into zY (A) units of revenue at date t = 2, where z ∈ {zg, zb} is a random variable with distribution Fg for the good project and Fb for the bad project. The bad project has lower expected revenue
but has higher upside risk relative to the good project in the sense of second order stochastic dominance (SOSD). Formally, there is a z* such that Fg(Z*) = Fb(Z*) and
for all z. At date t = 1, a public signal is observed. The signal can be thought of as a leading economic indicator. It predicts with perfect accuracy the value of z that will be realized at date t = 2. After the signal is observed at t = 1, a liquidation process can be initiated, in which case the capital is sold at a discount price of α ∈ [0, R) per unit at date t = 2. The timing is summarized in Figure 1.
I refer to idiosyncratic uncertainty as the stochastic outcome of an individual project given the project type. It is idiosyncratic in the sense that if the economy is to be replicated by identical projects, their outcomes are independent draws from the same distribution. I use aggregate uncertainty to refer to the circumstance in which the distribution may be changed by an exogenous shock. I leave the formal definition of to Section A.
The following assumptions are maintained throughout the paper to ensure interior solutions.
In addition, Y′ (A) is convex.
As is standard, the assumption on concavity and Inada conditions ensure that (absent any frictions) there is positive investment for any positive cost of capital. The additional assumption requires that the production technology has diminishing marginal return at an increasing rate. Assumption 1 is satisfied by commonly used production functions including Aα and ln A.
Assumption 2 For F ∈ {Fg, Fb}, the survival function 1 − F is log-concave; that is, the hazard rate h (z) = f (z) / (1 − F (z)) is continuous and increasing.
Assumption 2 is satisfied by commonly used distributions including normal, logistic, exponential, chi-squared and certain parameterization of gamma and beta.
A First-Best Investment
I begin the analysis with a characterization of the first-best investment level and composition as a benchmark for the rest of the paper. Suppose there is a hypothetical social planner who can directly allocate funds and operate projects. The planner prefers the good project over the bad project because it generate higher expected revenue for any given level of investment. The planner chooses the capital size A at date t = 0 and decides whether to liquidate the project at date t = 1 when the signal is observed. Using backward induction, for any given level of investment, the planner liquidates the project if the project revenue is less than liquidation value. In other words, the planner liquidates the project if
In what follows, I refer to
The social planner’s problem is given by
with first order condition
This condition simply says that the expected marginal return on investment is equal to the marginal cost R. As a approaches zero, Assumption 1 guarantees that there exists a unique solution. When α ∈ (0, R), the expected return falls but there is a gain from liquidation because
Proposition 1 There exists a unique first-best investment level Afb ∈ (0, ∞).
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
B Contracting Framework
Bank-Firm Contract
Suppose the firm lacks internal funds and has to finance investment from the bank. Let (A, B) characterize the bank-firm contract, where A is the loan amount and B is the face value of the debt. The contract is implemented as follows. At date t = 0, the bank chooses from one of the two projects-good (g) or bad (b)–and invest A in the firm. The firm pays B at t = 2 if the project is complete. If the project is terminated at date t = 1, the bank takes the full liquidation value of the project αA. I implicitly assume that the debt payment cannot be contingent on z because, perhaps, z is not verifiable in a court. As a benchmark for later analysis on the bank’s financing problem, suppose for now that the bank has an arbitrarily large size of capital with opportunity cost R.
The firm has a reservation payoff C. If C is too large, the project may not generate sufficient revenue to be worth the firm’s effort. I assume this is not the case, that is,
This assumption guarantees that the first-best investment is feasible. If the firm receives the first best loan and the entire surplus, it strictly prefers to participate in the contract.
Because investment is determined at date t = 0 and there are only two outcomes at date t = 1, continuation or liquidation. The firm follows a simple rule. It liquidates the project if the signaled revenue is less than its debt. The liquidation threshold
For productivity levels
Taking into account the liquidation threshold with contract renegotiation, the optimal contract at date t = 0 can be solved by backward induction:
subject to firm’s participation constraint (PCF)
The next result shows that allowing contract renegotiation recovers the first-best solution, provided the bank has all the bargaining power.
Proposition 2 The bank gives the first-best loan Afb to the firm and the corresponding debt value Bfb is set to satisfy the firm’s reservation payoff.
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
The conclusion from this section is that absent financing constraints, the bank can assume the role of a social planner and choose the first-best investment as long as it can capture the entire surplus in contract renegotiation. Even though the contract cannot be contingent on project outcome, renegotiation can remedy this ex post inefficiency caused by idiosyncratic uncertainty. This is not the case if the bank cannot capture the entire surplus. In the next section, I explore one such case with frictions on the bank’s liability side.
Bank-Creditor Contract
I start by relaxing the previous assumption that the bank has arbitrarily large capital. Suppose the bank starts with limited equity and finances its operation through a collateralized debt arrangement, such as a repo. At t = 0, the bank sells its assets A for a price D and agrees to repurchase the asset at t = 2 for price
Given the bank’s capital structure, I analyze the ex ante contracting problem between the bank and the investor at t = 0. The bank-creditor contract faces a moral hazard problem because the creditor cannot observe the project type chosen by the bank. As I shall show momentarily, without proper incentive, the bank may choose the riskier and less inefficient project. The optimal financing contract needs to specify the value of debt subject to the bank’s incentive constraint. Specifically, for any contract (A, B) the bank might give to the firm, the optimal contract solves the face value
Let
Given the form of bank-firm contracts derived previously, the firm’s payoff from the good project is
The bank’s payoff from the good project
where
To make the contract incentive compatible so that the bank chooses the good project, the bank’s expected payoff from the bad project should not exceed that from the good project:
which gives the incentive compatibility constraint of the bank (ICB)
where
Lemma 1 If the liquidation value α is sufficiently small, the bank’s incentive compatibility constraint (ICB) binds and there exists a unique solution for the bank’s debt value
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
This result implies that the bank’s debt capacity is limited by the collateral requirement set by the creditor. The next result shows how this financing constraint affects the liquidation rule.
Lemma 2 If the liquidation value a is sufficiently small, there exists a unique
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
Because the bank’s debt value is
Competitive lending in the repo market holds down the creditor’s payoff so the optimal market value of debt D* solves
where
where
A direct implication of Lemma 1 is a limit on the bank’s leverage.
Lemma 3 There is a unique solution to the bank’s debt to asset ratio for given asset size A:
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
The result that the bank has to be partially financed by equity is very intuitive. Limited leverage is a device to contain risks to the creditor. Because the creditor is a senior claimant in case of a default, equity buffers the loss of the creditor. If the bank cannot raise enough equity to make up the gap between debt and asset values, no projects will be funded which leads to a trivial equilibrium solution. I assume this is not the case. I also assume for now that equity requires the same return as debt Re = R. This assumption will be relaxed later.
III Equilibrium Financing and Investment
In this section, I describe the banking equilibrium and discuss its implications.
A banking equilibrium is a quadruplet of values
subject to (6), (7), and (10)
Previous results simplify this problem. The argument in Section B goes through because it holds for any contract (A, B) the bank might give to the firm. In particular, Lemma 1 shows that choosing
The following result is the first main implication of the model.
Proposition 3 If the liquidation value a is sufficiently small, there exists a unique banking equilibrium
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
This proposition shows that in the constrained equilibrium, investment is below its first-best level. I leave the technical proof to the Appendix, but discuss the intuition for this result by comparing the planner’s problem (2) and the bank’s problem (12). The last term of (12) represents surplus loss resulting from the bank-creditor contract. This is illustrated in Figure 2. Recall that if the bank has sufficient capital, idiosyncratic uncertainty can be remedied by contract renegotiation, which fully restores efficiency because the bank can capture the entire surplus after renegotiation. This is not possible when the bank has insufficient capital. The roll-over risk on short-term debt forces some projects into inefficient liquidation, resulting in a loss of surplus. The bank anticipates that the loss will reduce its marginal return from the investment and reduces investment ex ante. This analysis highlights the channel through which uncertainty is transmitted to real investment decision: It is the interaction between the bank’s asset quality and debt capacity that leads to the contraction of credit supply and investment.
Equilibrium Payoffs and Welfare Loss
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 065; 10.5089/9781475593167.001.A001
Equilibrium Payoffs and Welfare Loss
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 065; 10.5089/9781475593167.001.A001
Equilibrium Payoffs and Welfare Loss
Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 065; 10.5089/9781475593167.001.A001
IV Extensions and Discussions
A Aggregate Uncertainty
Consider an exogenous aggregate shock that leads to higher uncertainty in the economy. How would it affect the equilibrium financing and investment decision? To answer this question, I adopt a simple definition of aggregate uncertainty in terms of a mean-preserving spread of the distribution of project productivity. In particular, suppose the distribution of the bad project is unchanged but the good project follows a new distribution Fm such that
and there is z* such that
Fg(z*) = Fm(z*) and
Because both Fm delivers the same expected revenue as Fg, it is still desirable even though it becomes riskier.
The definitions of aggregate uncertainty and idiosyncratic uncertainty (recall Section II) have simple interpretations in the context of my model. Idiosyncratic uncertainty refers to individual project outcome and aggregate uncertainty refers to the aggregate outcome of all projects. Higher uncertainty here resembles a shock to the variance of future productivity as in Bloom (2009) and Jurado et al. (2013). In my model, a representative bank invests in the market portfolio. The model can be easily recasted as a continuum of banks each matched to one project. In this case, idiosyncratic uncertainty shocks can refer to shocks to a bank and aggregate uncertainty shocks can refer to shocks to the banking sector.
The next result presents the second main implication of the model.
Proposition 4 Conditional on the existence of a banking equilibrium
This result highlights how the contractionary effect of uncertainty is aggravated by an aggregate shock. When uncertainty is high, banks are forced to shed their debt and reduce their balance sheet size. This is consistent with behavior of balance sheet management in financial intermediaries during the 2007-2009 crisis. Adrian and Shin (2010) and Adrian and Shin (2013) document evidence of banks reducing leverage and shrinking balance sheet when uncertainty about the quality of their assets increases. The model implies that this is a market-based mechanism to contain risks of financial intermediaries; however it is socially costly because it investment contraction in the real economy.
B Multiple Assets
In the preceding analysis I assumed that the bank can only invest in one project, thus holds only one (type of) asset. In practice, however, a bank’s portfolio consists of multiple assets, whose characteristics jointly affect the bank’s financing and investment positions. Allowing the bank to hold multiple assets does not affect the qualitative nature of my results, but does yield some additional implications concerning the transmission of uncertainty on the bank’s asset side. A simple way to model this is to introduce two types of good assets. I assume that both assets have the same expected revenue and same variance. This is important to ensure that the bank holds a nondegenerated portfolio of both assets because in equilibrium, the bank only invests in the asset with the higher expected revenue. Other than that, the exact portfolio allocation does not matter for the analysis.
Now consider a shock that increases the correlation of the two types of assets ρ. It is straightforward to establish that all else equal, an increase in ρ increases the variance of the return from the asset portfolio. The same line of argument in Section A applies and I obtain the following result.
Corollary 1 All else equal, an increase in the return correlation of the bank’s asset portfolio leads to lower credit supply and lower investment.
This inefficient result follows because market discipline is non-discriminative, that is, the short-term creditor funds the bank without discriminating against a certain type of asset.
C Endogenous Default
So far I have assumed that liquidation is involuntary because the short-term creditor is not willing to rolled over the debt. This assumption can be relaxed to allow for debt renegotiation between the bank and the creditor. In this section, I show that all previous results follow by simply allowing the bank to default endogenously. In particular, when the signaled project revenue at t = 1 is lower than the bank’s debt value (i.e. when
It is also worth noting that the possibility of endogenous default also rules out financing with long-term debt. The intuition is simple. A long-term creditor does not have the power to influence liquidation and payment decisions at t = 1. By issuing long-term debt, the creditor forgoes the opportunity to demand payment on her own terms and runs the risk of endogenous default by equity holders.
To see more formally the role of endogenous default in the choice of debt maturity, keep all elements in the model as in previous sections but replace the bank-creditor contract with one that does not need to be rolled over at t = 1. I shall leave formal proof on properties of the long-term debt contract to the Appendix and provide a sketch of the argument here. Denote the market value of the long-term debt by Dlong to distinguish it from the short-term debt value D in the main model. Let
V Policy Options
When considering policy options, it is important to note that the banking equilibrium described in the last section is constrained optimal. Policy interventions that aim to improve macro efficiency needs to preserve market discipline at the micro level. I first derive an efficiency condition. I then discuss policy options that improves efficiency.
Proposition 3 imply that the source of welfare loss is inefficient runs of short-term debt. The threshold productivity
In other words, for the banking equilibrium (3) to be efficient, the bank’s debt value cannot be too high. This result reflects the trade-off between the cost of market discipline and social efficiency. When the moral hazard problem is severe, the cost of discipline is too high and efficiency has to be sacrificed.
A Ex Ante Policy
Capital Requirement
One way to reduce the cost of market discipline is to impose an ex ante capital requirement. The bank needs to hold sufficient equity to buffer the loss of the creditor in all states of the world. It is straightforward to show that setting (14) to equality implies a minimum equity to asset ratio:
The next result shows that although imposing a debt to equity ratio can eliminate welfare loss, it is not sufficient to fully restore efficiency if there is an equity premium.
Proposition 6 If there is no equity premium (i.e. Re = R), imposing a debt to equity ratio α/(R − α) achieves the first-best investment. If there is equity premium (i.e. Re > R), investment under such capital requirement is still lower than the first-best level.
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
Although capital requirement leads to a new equilibrium that does not incur welfare loss (and therefore is “ex post efficient”), it nevertheless distorts ex ante investment by increasing its marginal cost if there is an equity premium. The reason is that capital requirement only buffers creditor from default risks. It does not address why shareholders require a higher return. It is likely that the equity premium captures other types of risks not related to the bank’s capital structure, for example, agency conflict between shareholders and the manager.
It is worth noting that to eliminate welfare loss in the model, it is not necessary to regulate total debt. Limiting the size of short-term debt would be necessary. This is because short-term debt is the key disciplinary device, while all sources of long-term funding have a similar role as equity in buffering the loss of the short-term creditor. This suggests that an efficient level of long-term funding to asset ratio is also equal to (R − α)/R. One way to implement this policy is to impose a net stable funding ratio (NSFR) as proposed in the Third Basel Accord (Basel III), in which case net stable funding includes customer deposits, long-term wholesale funding from the interbank lending market and equity.
Liquidity Requirement
Capital requirements regulate the liability side of the balance sheet. An alternative is to regulate the asset side by imposing liquidity requirements. Suppose the bank is required to hold an amount L of liquid assets funded by equity. If the bank’s liquidation value is sufficient to pay back the short-term creditor, inefficient debt run and liquidation can be avoided. An equivalent condition to (14) is
Because no surplus is lost, one can use similar argument as Proposition 6 to show that the first best investment can be achieved in the absence of an equity premium. Given A = Afb, the debt value can be derived using the creditor’s required return because payment to the creditor is guaranteed. Thus
To achieve the efficiency condition (16), the regulator can impose a minimum level of liquid assets to cover the bank’s liquidity needs:
Contingent Debt
The model points to the lack of state contingency to the bank’s liability as a source of inefficiency. This naturally suggests using contingent debt as a potential remedy but there is a more subtle point. Whether contingent debt can be used as a policy tool to improve efficiency crucially depends on the design of conversion triggers. In order to preserve the bank’s incentive, conversion triggers should be based on an aggregate state variable, rather than an individual state variable. The intuition is simple. In the model, idiosyncratic risk is directly linked to debt runs so the bank has the incentive to contain the risk. If individual outcomes are used as conversion triggers to prevent bank runs, this linkage will be eliminated and the bank’s incentive to choose the good project will be weakened. Using aggregate outcomes as conversion triggers does not affect the bank’s incentive as long as the bank’s decision does not influence aggregate outcomes or debt conversions. A simple way to model this is to consider an aggregate shock to productivity z after investment was made and contracts were signed. The shock is unexpected so characterizations of the bank’s asset and liability at t = 0 remain unaffected as in previous sections. After the aggregate signal is observed at t = 1, the regulator can trigger a debt conversion in which the bank-creditor contract is converted to a contingent payment scheme. The bank pays the creditor
The above argument lends support to using regulatory-based trigger to reduce the risk of systemic debt run. It is worth noting that when the banking sector is highly concentrated, the distinction between aggregate state and individual state becomes blurry. In this case, even a policy based on a systemic trigger will violate the incentive of a bank that is “too big to fail”.
B Ex Post Policy
Monetary Policy
When there is no ex ante policy to eliminate a debt run, is there still a role for ex post policy? Suppose after the investment is made and financing contracts are signed, the productivity signal at t = 1 is lower than the creditor’s liquidation threshold in the banking equilibrium (3). One way to prevent a debt run is to reduce the creditor’s required return. Recall that the creditor’s required return on D satisfies
which is based on the opportunity cost of capital R at t = 0. If at t = 1, the monetary authority announces a new interest rate, which effectively reduces the cost of capital from R to Rm < R, the creditor will be willing to roll over the short-term debt for a lower payments of RmD payable at t = 2. The next proposition shows that given asset and debt values committed at t = 0, an interest rate can be set to eliminate welfare loss.
Proof. See Appendix. ▘
This policy is ex post efficient because it lowers the creditor’s liquidation threshold and eliminates inefficient debt run. In other words, in the absence of an adequate ex ante policy, monetary intervention can be used to (partially) remedy the inefficiency caused by undercapitalized banks. To see how ex post monetary intervention is complementary to ex ante capital requirements, note that if the minimum capital requirement (15) is not met, the optimal interest rate (17) at t = 1 is indeed higher than ex ante rate R. Proposition 7 says that lowering the interest rate can effectively eliminate welfare loss. Similar to the use of contingent debt, ex post monetary interventions have no impact on ex ante investment decisions. To the extent that capital requirements achieve an ex ante investment level that is strictly higher than the laissez-faire level A*, it is preferable to monetary interventions.
VI Conclusion
This paper provides a theoretical foundation for the channel of uncertainty transmission through the balance sheet of financial intermediaries. On the liability side, short-term debt contracts are optimal instruments for banks that seek debt financing. But uncertainty and roll over risk can lead to inefficient liquidation and affect investment surplus on the asset side. This interaction between the bank’s investment and financing positions leads to lower credit and ex ante underinvestment. From a social welfare perspective, there is an important trade-off between the positive role of short-term debt in limiting excess risk-taking by banks and the cost of this market discipline.
The model lends support to direct interventions in the short-term funding markets. The success of policy intervention depends on the regulators’ability to extract surplus while preserving market discipline at the micro level. Imposing capital and liquidity requirements, and reducing interest rate at crisis times can be welfare-improving. Adding contingent debt can also improve efficiency but may create a moral hazard problem for banks that are “too big to fail”.
Appendix
Proof. Under Assumption 2, the survival function is log-concave. The result follows directly from Theorem 6 of Bagnoli and Bergstrom (2005). ▘
where the term
Taking the limit as A approaches infinity gives
Because all the terms are continuous in A, (19) is satisfied at least once following the Intermediate Value Theorem, proving existence. Define Afb such that MR (Afb) = MC (Afb).
hence
Proof of Proposition 2. I first use local variational arguments to show that debt renegotiation guarantees a binding PCF. Suppose PCF slacks under the optimal contract. For any given A, the bank can raise B by a small amount B′ = B + ε without violating PCF. By (4), the firm’s liquidation threshold
This is the same as the planner’s problem (2) except the reservation payoff C. Because C does not depend on A, the solution to (20) is the same as the first-best solution Afb chosen by the planner. ▘
where Gg (x, A) and Gb (x, A) are the density of revenue from the portfolios of good and bad projects respectively for given A. For ease of notation, I suppress the argument A in Gg (.) and Gb (.) in what follows.
for all x > αA. Since Gg (x) cuts Gb (x) precisely once from below, ΔΠ (x, A) is equal to
where the second line follows from integration by parts and the fourth line follows from binding PCF. This result says that ΔΠ (x, A) approaches ΔUB (A) from above as x approaches Ā. It is easy to rule out
I refer to α being sufficiently small when α ≤ ā. ▘
Proof of Lemma 2 Because the function z → zY (A) is continuous, it suffices to show that
▘
The first three terms correspond to the first order condition of the planner’s problem (3). The last two terms are the marginal welfare loss.
I first show that the left-hand side of (25) is negative when evaluated at the first best solution A = Afb. By (3), the first three terms are zero. Evaluate the first term of marginal welfare loss at Afb. Define
where hg (z) ≡ fg (z) / (1 − Fg (z)) is the hazard rate. The sign of
As shown in the proof of Proposition 1, the first three terms of (25) approach ∞ as A approaches 0. Following Assumption 1, both
Combined with (30), this implies the first two terms of (29) are negative.
Define the third term of (29) as
Proof (long-term contract) I shall prove long-term contract properties summarized in Section C. To distinguish the long-term debt value from the short term debt value, let Dlong and
This is the same as the planner’s problem (2) except for the firm’s reservation payoff C. Because C does not depend on A, the solution to this problem is the same as the first-best solution Afb.
Note that this is identical to the PCC of a short-term contract (10). It is straightforward to show that the bank’s problem is also identical to the case of a short-term contract (11). It follows from the uniqueness of the equilibrium (3) that the value of a long-term contract is identical to that of a short-term debt. ▘
The maximal debt to asset ratio follows directly. ▘
The only difference between (32) and the planner’s problem (20) is the higher marginal cost of investment when Re > R, in which case lower investment level follows directly from the convexity of the its marginal revenue. ▘
▘
I thank Charles Calomiris, Stijn Claessens, Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, Daniela Fabbri (discussant), and conference and seminar participants at Cass Business School, City University of London, International Banking, Economics and Finance Association (IBEFA) Annual Meetings, IMF, New Economic School for helpful comments.
Here I implicitly assume that this is the only available debt maturity structure. I relax this assumption In Section C and show that long-term debt is not preferable to short-term debt if endogenous default is allowed. In other words, short-short debt is optimal.
Acharya, Viral V., Douglas Gale, and Tanju Yorulmazer (2011) “Rollover Risk and Market Freezes,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 66, No. 4, pp. 1177–1209.
Adrian, Tobias and Hyun Song Shin (2010) “Liquidity and leverage,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 418–437.
Adrian, Tobias (2013) “Procyclical Leverage and Value-at-Risk,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 27, No. 2, pp. 373–403.
Arellano, Cristina, Yan Bai, and Patrick Kehoe (2012) “Financial Markets and Fluctuations in Uncertainty,” Technical report.
Bagnoli, Mark and Ted Bergstrom (2005) “Log-concave probability and its applications,” Economic Theory, Vol. 26, No. 2, pp. 445–469.
Bloom, Nicholas (2009) “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks,” Econometrica, Vol. 77, No. 3, pp. 623–685.
Breeden, Douglas T. and Robert H. Litzenberger (1978) “Prices of State-Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices,” The Journal of Business, Vol. 51, No. 4, pp. 621–651.
Calomiris, Charles W and Charles M Kahn (1991) “The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrangements,” American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 3, pp. 497–513.
Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang, and Gustavo A. Suarez (2013) “The Evolution of a Financial Crisis: Collapse of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Market,” June.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan (2000) “A Theory of Bank Capital,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 55, No. 6, pp. 2431–2465.
Eisenbach, Thomas M. (2013) “Rollover Risk as Market Discipline: A Two-Sided Inefficiency,” staff reports, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Gilchrist, Simon, Jae Sim, and Egon Zakrajsek (2013) “Uncertainty, Financial Frictions, and Investment Dynamics,” Technical report.
Gorton, Gary and Andrew Metrick (2012) “Securitized banking and the run on repo,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 104, No. 3, pp. 425–451.
Holmstrom, Bengt and Jean Tirole (1997) “Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 3, pp. 663–691.
Jurado, Kyle, Sydney C. Ludvigson, and Serena Ng (2013) “Measuring Uncertainty,” NBER Working Papers 19456, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Kacperczyk, Marcin and Philipp Schnabl (2010) “When Safe Proved Risky: Commercial Paper during the Financial Crisis of 2007-2009,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 24, No. 1, pp. 29–50.
Martin, Antoine, David Skeie, and Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden (2014) “Repo Runs,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 957–989.
Merton, Robert C (1974) “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 29, No. 2, pp. 449–70.
Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin (2003) “Global Games: Theory and Applications,” in L. Hansen M. Dewatripont and S. Turnovsky eds. Advances in Economics and Econometrics, Vol. 1: Cambridge University Press, Chap. 3, pp. 57–114.
Valencia, Fabian (2013) “Aggregate Uncertainty and the Supply of Credit,” IMF Working Paper, No. 13/241.