Remittances and Macroeconomic Volatility in African Countries
Author: Ahmat Jidoud

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-Mail Address:ajidoud@imf.org

This paper investigates the channels through which remittances affect macroeconomic volatility in African countries using a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model augmented with financial frictions. Empirical results indicate that remittances—as a share of GDP—have a significant smoothing impact on output volatility but their impact on consumption volatility is somewhat small. Furthermore, remittances are found to absorb a substantial amount of GDP shocks in these countries. An investigation of the theoretical channels shows that the stabilization impact of remittances essentially hinges on two channels: (i) the size of the negative wealth effect on labor supply induced by remittances and, (ii) the strength of financial frictions and the ability of remittances to alleviate these frictions.

Abstract

This paper investigates the channels through which remittances affect macroeconomic volatility in African countries using a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model augmented with financial frictions. Empirical results indicate that remittances—as a share of GDP—have a significant smoothing impact on output volatility but their impact on consumption volatility is somewhat small. Furthermore, remittances are found to absorb a substantial amount of GDP shocks in these countries. An investigation of the theoretical channels shows that the stabilization impact of remittances essentially hinges on two channels: (i) the size of the negative wealth effect on labor supply induced by remittances and, (ii) the strength of financial frictions and the ability of remittances to alleviate these frictions.

I. Introduction

There has been widespread work done on the impact of remittances on African countries both from a microeconomic and macroeconomic perspective in recent years. The reason is that, though significantly underestimated, officially recorded remittance flows to Africa have increased from $9.1 billion in 1990 to nearly $40 billion in 2010 (World Bank, 2011 and Figure 1). An extensive empirical literature has recognized the microeconomic benefits of remittances, while a growing number of studies have looked at their macroeconomic effects. More precisely, recent research has examined the impact on growth (Adam Jr and Page, 2005; Gupta, Patillo and Vagh, 2009; Giuliano and Luis-Arranz, 2009) and their power to cushion aggregate fluctuations (Chami and others, 2008; Chami, Hakura and Montiel, 2009; Bugamelli and Paterno, 2009a; Combes and Ebeke, 2011; Ahamada and Coulibaly, 2011; among others). This capacity of remittances to act as shocks buffers hinges in their resilience to economic crises but also to their lower volatility compared to other financial flows (Figure 2).

Figure 1:
Figure 1:

Remittances and other financial flows in SSA

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

Figure 2:
Figure 2:

Volatility of financial flows to Africa 1980-2010

(Coefficient of variation)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

Source: Author calculations based on ADI World Bank data, 2011.

This paper’s main objective is to investigate the channels and mechanisms through which remittances affect macroeconomic volatility (output and private consumption volatilities) in African countries using a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model augmented with financial frictions. In order to motivate this question, the paper first (i) assesses the empirical correlation between remittances and business cycle volatility and (ii) the extent of risk-sharing through remittances. While the existing literature has brought evidence of the smoothing impact of remittances in recipient countries (Chami, Hakura, and Montiel, 2009; Combes and Ebeke, 2011; Craigwell, Jackman, and Moore, 2010), it has been silent at exploring the theoretical mechanisms at work.

The main contribution of this paper to the literature is to propose a theoretical explanation of the potential stabilizing impact of remittances in a context of a general equilibrium framework. The empirical results show that remittances have a significant smoothing impact on output volatility but their impact on consumption volatility is somewhat small. These findings fit perfectly with those in Craigwell, Jackman, and Moore (2010) for sub-Saharan African countries. Moreover, remittances absorb a significant fraction of output shocks, ranging between 3.8 and 22 percent. Quantitative simulations from the theoretical model show that the stabilization impact of remittances essentially hinges on two channels: (i) the size of the negative wealth effect on labor supply induced by remittances (ii) the strength of financial frictions and the ability of remittances to alleviate these frictions. The first channel implies that labor supply may decrease following an increase in remittances, lowering output and increasing its response to shocks. The second channel suggests remittances are more stabilizing in countries with a shallow financial and banking sector and when remittances induce financial sector development by providing a greater access to financial markets to their recipients (which can improve their creditworthiness scores). This later finding underscores the need for recipient countries to promote financial development so as to channel remittances through the financial system and help the poor have greater access to credit.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 1 briefly reviews the existing work on the macroeconomic effects of remittances in developing countries. Section 2 assesses the empirical correlation between business cycle volatility and the size of remittances in African economies. The theoretical model that is used to investigate the transmission channels is laid out in Section 3. In Section 4, we perform the quantitative analysis that simulates the implications of remittances on business cycle volatility along with the sensitivity analysis. Finally, Section 5 concludes.

II. Literature Review

In the last two decades, remittances toward African countries have increased, although at a lower speed than in Latin American and Asian countries. Officially recorded migrant transfers to Africa have been estimated to have increased from US$9.1 billion in 1990 to more than US$40 billion in 2010 (World Bank, 2011) as shown in Figure 1. Better data collection, lower transfer costs, and increasing migration are among the main factors driving the rise of recorded remittances in recent years. Remittances represent an important and stable source of funds for developing economies. As shown in Figure 1, remittances toward African countries have outweighed the other financial flows (FDI, and private debt and portfolio equity). Remittances reached a record high of US$ 40 billion in 2008, a level slightly higher than official aid (US$38 billion). Their effective management supposes a clear understanding of their potential benefits and consequences on the real economy.

The empirical literature on the economic consequences of these inflows in the recipient economies has become widespread and has gained interest in academic and policy decision-makers spheres over the recent decade. The existing work has essentially focused on their microeconomic effects on the recipient households. But the sizeable upward trend followed by remittances has shifted attention to the assessment of their impact at the macroeconomic level. This burgeoning work has covered an array of issues and brought insightful policy guidance in the macroeconomic management of these special financial flows. Among the most covered subjects in the literature are (1) the ability of remittances to promote growth, alleviate poverty, and reduce inequality, (2) their stabilizing effects on macroeconomic fluctuations, (3) their capacity to promote financial development and alleviate credit constraints, and (4) their possible negative effects on competitiveness through “Dutch Disease” effects.

About their poverty reduction virtues, Adams, Jr. and Page (2005) found that both international migration and remittances significantly reduce the level, depth, and severity of poverty in developing countries.2 Remittances reduce poverty through their positive impact on financial development by loosening borrowing constraints faced by households. Remittances give financially constrained households access to credit markets by collateralizing assets they build using the remittances they receive. Hence they can contribute to an increase in aggregate investment and savings.

One of the most positive effects of remittances emphasized by the literature is their capacity to reduce macroeconomic volatility. In this sense, remittances act as automatic stabilizers by cushioning aggregate fluctuations (Chami, Hakura, and Montiel, 2009; Bugamelli and Paterno, 2009b). Their insurance role allows households to smooth out negative income and consumption shocks (Combes and Ebeke, 2011; Bugamelli and Paterno, 2009b; Craigwell, Jackman, and Moore, 2010; among others). The stabilizing feature of remittances may however depend on the nature of the comovements between business cycles in the home countries of the migrants and the flow of remittances. Procyclical remittances tend to deepen business cycles while countercyclical remittances act as automatic stabilizers by dampening the effects of shocks (Durdu and Sayan, 2010; Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh, 2009). There is evidence that, at least for some African countries, remittances are driven by altruistic motives of the migrants because remittances tend to increase when the recipient economy undergoes negative macroeconomic shocks from natural disasters, financial crisis, conflict, or the like (Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh, 2009; Mohapatra and Ratha, 2011; among others). Remittances can also contribute to stability by lowering the probability of current account reversals, especially in countries where they exceed 3 percent of GDP (Bugamelli and Paterno, 2009a). They also contribute to stabilizing the current account by reducing the volatility of overall capital flows (Chami and others, 2008).

Another relevant channel through which remittances help in stabilizing recipient economies is their capacity to enhance sovereign creditworthiness by increasing the level and stability of foreign exchange receipts (Ratha, 2007; Ratha, De, and Mohapatra, 2011). Ratha, De, and Mohapatra (2011) have shown that the creditworthiness rating score of some developing countries would improve by one to three notches if these remittances are accounted in this rating. Although credit rating is widely used by African countries, this feature of remittances sounds very important as it can allow African countries easy access to international financial markets to raise the required funds at low cost and finance their development projects. Recently, several African countries have raised substantial international financing at lower interest rates and longer maturities through the securitization of future remittance flows (and other future receivables). Banks in these countries use future flows of remittances as collateral on international capital markets to lower borrowing costs and lengthen the maturity of the issued bonds.3 Given the lack of well-functioning domestic financial markets in developing economies and mostly in Africa, remittances are a direct source of funds and an asset for access to more funding on international capital markets at low costs.

Despite these obvious benefits, remittances may in some circumstances elicit undesirable side effects. “Dutch disease” (a real exchange rate appreciation) is the most feared consequence in remittances-dependent countries. Like other financial flows (development aid, natural resources revenues, etc.), large flows of migrant transfers into a country could result in an appreciation of the real exchange rate and loss of international competitiveness (Bourdet and Falck (2006) regarding Cape Verde).

III. Empirical Evidence of Stylized facts

This section briefly evaluates the empirical correlation between the size of remittances and macroeconomic volatility on a sample of African countries. Moreover it evaluates the risk-sharing power of remittances by quantifying the share of output shocks absorbed through the remittances channel. Its central role is to provide a motivating basis for the theoretical analysis undertaken in section 3.

A. Remittances and Macroeconomic Volatility

We assess the correlation between business cycle volatility and remittances on a sample of 27 African countries with yearly data in 1980-2005. Table 1 provides some insightful statistics about business cycle fluctuations and remittances in these economies. Consumption appears to be more volatile than output, a stylized fact established in developing countries literature on business cycle. The growth rate of households’ consumption is 1.6 more volatile than the growth rate of GDP (1.62 for HP filter variables). For all countries, consumption fluctuations are significantly much higher than output fluctuations.4 Figure 3 hints at the volatility-remittances nexus and indicates that output and consumption fluctuations are negatively correlated with the size of remittances. The following cross section model that captures the impact of remittances on macroeconomic volatility is estimated

Table 1:

Business cycle fluctuations and remittances

article image
Source: African Development Indicators and Author calculations.
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Macroeconomic volatility and Remittances in Africa

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

Source: Author calculations form African Development Indicators database, 2012.
log(σi,X)=c+γRi+βXi+ui(1)

where σi,X stands for the standard deviation of per capita GDP or consumption using HP filtered data or growth rates. Ri denotes the average ratio of remittances-to-GDP for country i over the sample period. Remittances are measured as the sum of workers’ remittances and compensation of employees in accordance with the World Bank definition. γ is the parameter of interest (the semi-elasticity) that captures the impact of remittances on macroeconomic volatility. Xi is the vector that stacks all the relevant determinants of volatility identified in the literature such as per capita income, financial development, government size, development aid and terms of trade volatility. Financial development is measured by the credit to the private sector to GDP while government size is measured as the ratio of government consumption to GDP. Development aid is an important source of funds for developing economies and particularly for a wide range of African economies. However, the strong variability of aid flows is likely to be harmful for these economies in terms of business cycles because it translates into a high macroeconomic volatility (Pallage and Robe, 2001; Pallage, Robe, and Berube, 2007; Bulir and Hamann, 2003; Arellano and others, 2009; among others). Thus we measure development aid in the regression by its volatility rather than its size. Finally, ui represents the error terms, assumed to be uncorrelated with the regressors.

A natural issue to account for in this analysis is the potential endogeneity of remittances. There are several reasons supporting the evidence that remittances are not endogenous in our sample of economies. First, correlation test between remittances and growth at leads and lags and at country levels have provided no evidence of a significant relationship. Second, another empirical test of endogeneity (Nakamura and Nakamura (1998)) test shows that remittances are not endogenous in our regressions.5 Third, micro studies in African countries have shown that (i) more than half of households in Burkina Faso, Ghana, and Nigeria, and 30 percent of households in Senegal receiving remittances from outside Africa are in the top two consumption quintiles; (ii) Africans also tend to remit more often, and African migrants from poorer African countries are more likely to remit than those from richer African countries. (World Bank, 2011); and (iii) a significant portion of international remittances are spent on land purchases, building a house, business, improving the farm, agricultural equipment, and other investments. These findings imply that remittances could be acyclical at the macro level though they appear to be procyclical (for the richer households) and contracyclical (for poor households) at the micro level. Finally, the endogeneity might have died off by taking country average values over time.

Results. The model in equation (1) is estimated under Generalized Least Squares (GLS) methods instead of standard Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) to overcome potential heteroskedascity in the errors terms. The results are reported in Table 2. Columns (1) and (2) display the results for output volatility (HP filtered and the growth rate of per capita GDP respectively) while columns (3) and (4) display the results for consumption volatility (HP filtered and the growth rate of per capita consumption respectively). We follow an eclectic approach by choosing the best model on the grounds of its fit (adjusted R-square) and report here only the relevant model. The results show a clear negative correlation between output fluctuations and the size of remittances for both measures of volatility. In our preferred regressions, an increase in workers’ remittances-to-GDP of 1 percentage point reduces the log of the standard deviation of GDP per the cyclical component of per capita GDP by 4 percent while the reduction in per capita output growth is 3.2 percent. While remittances reduce consumption volatility, the impact is somewhat small and statistically insignificant (columns (3) and (4)). This result goes at odds with some empirical papers on developing countries in general (Chami, Hakura, and Montiel, 2009; Combes and Ebeke, 2011; Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh, 2009; among others) but it lines up perfectly with the evidence presented by Craigwell, Jackman, and Moore (2010).

Table 2.

Macroeconomic Fluctuations and Remittances

(GLS Estimation)

article image
Note: t-student are in parenthesis. (*), (**), and (***) denote significance at 5,1, and 0.1 respectively. ŷ (respectively ĉ) is the cyclical component of the log of per capita GDP (respectively per capita consumption) using the HP filter with a smoothing parameter of 6.25. Δy (respectively Δc) is the growth rate of per capita GDP (respectively per capita consumption).6

The inability of remittances to significantly reduce consumption volatility though they decrease output fluctuations is puzzling. However, several explanations can be put forward to solve such a puzzle. First, households’ consumption in developing economies encompasses both consumption of durables and non-durables. It might be that remittances actually reduce the volatility of consumption of non-durables goods but not the volatility of durables. Thus the inability to disentangle these two components makes it harder to observe a significant impact on aggregate consumption fluctuations. Second, surveys at microeconomic levels in some African countries have shown evidence that more than half of households receiving remittances from outside Africa are in the top two consumption quintiles (Mohapatra and Ratha, 2011). In this case, the consumption smoothing effect of remittances may not show up because these households have access to alternative means (e.g., credit markets) to smooth their consumption and may use these remittances for investment instead. Third, remittances can fuel consumption volatility when they are used for other purposes than consumption (e.g., land purchase and housing). As argued by Combes and Ebeke (2011), this contributes to a boom in the real estate sector and then affects the consumption pattern on aggregate. Finally, because of the very limited development of financial and capital markets, consumption volatility may be so high that the increase in remittances would not be enough to alleviate these credit constraints.

B. Remittances and Risk Sharing

To complement the previous section findings, we evaluate the extent of risk sharing through remittances using a methodology developed in Asdrubali, Sorensen, and Yosha (1996). Econometric framework. Consider the following identity, holding for any period t:

yit=(yityit+Rit)(yit+Rit)=yity˜ity˜it(2)

where yit is GDP per capita and Rit denotes the remittances per capita of country i at period t, all in per capita real terms. The mechanism at work in equation (2) is that smoothing of domestic shocks takes place via remittances if the ratio yityit+Rit varies positively with yit. That is, an increase in yit entails a small increase in yit + Rit. To derive a simple quantitative measure of smoothing from identity (2), first take logs and then differences of both sides of equation (2), and multiply both sides by Δyit. Then taking expectations leads to:

Var(Δyit)=Cov(Δyit,ΔyitΔy˜it)+Cov(Δyit,Δy˜it)(3)

Finally dividing by Varyit) gives:

1=βR+βu(4)

where βR is the OLS coefficient from the regression of ΔyitΔy˜it on Δyit and βu the OLS coefficient of the regression of Δy˜it on Δyit. βR measures the incremental percentage of smoothing (when positive) or de-smoothing (when negative) achieved via remittances while βu accounts for the smoothing through other channels and the amount not smoothed at all.

To estimate the parameter βR, we run the following regression:

ΔyitΔy˜it=α1+λt+βRΔyit+uit(5)

where αi and λt are the individual fixed effects and the time effects respectively. Equation (5) shows how risk-sharing from remittances is achieved. The interpretation of this equation is that the smoothing virtues of remittances are stronger when they move countercyclically with the receiving country’s GDP, and remittances could be destabilizing when they are procyclical. In the later case, an increase in GDP elicits a positive reaction from remittances, inducing a stronger increase in Δy˜it than in Δyit, implying a negative βR.

The main results. The results are reported in Table 3. The Hausmann test and the variance decomposition of Δy˜ both show that the random effects model is an appropriate specification for our data. The model in equation (5) with random individual effects is estimated using different estimation methods: Ordinary Least Squares (OLS), Instrumental Variable (IV), and System-GMM of Arellano and Bond (2003). IV and GMM estimation techniques are used to account for potential endogeneity issues where the growth rate of per capita GDP is instrumented by its own first lag.

Table 3.

Remittances and Risk Sharing

article image
Note: Standard errors are in parenthesis.

The results in Table 3 confirm our cross-section evidence: remittances have a positive and significant risk-sharing power. They absorb a fraction worth 3.7 to 22 percent of GDP shocks. The extent to which this number is important depends on the contribution of the other channels (e.g., capital and credit markets) in absorbing GDP shocks in these economies. Yehoue (2005) found that remittances together with standard channels (capital and credit markets) absorbed only 15 percent and 13 percent of GDP shocks in the CEMAC and WAEMU CFA zones in 1980–2000 while development aid especially from France absorbed about 44 percent of shocks.7 Therefore, remittances appear to outweigh capital and credit markets channel in dampening the effects of macroeconomic shocks. In addition, given the potential effect of remittances on promoting financial development (Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh, 2009; Combes and Ebeke, 2011; World Bank, 2006, 2011), their cumulated direct and indirect stabilizing effects on business cycle fluctuations could be significantly higher than thought. Moreover, our quantitative findings represent the lower bound values of the effective impact of remittances in African countries as the quality and coverage of data in general and on remittances in particular leave much to be desired. Transfers through informal channels, misreporting in the receiving countries, and misclassification of remittances into other revenues (exports revenues, tourism receipts, nonresident deposits, or FDI, World Bank, 2011) are among the main reasons for the underestimation of remittances in developing countries, particularly African economies.

IV. A Small Open Economy Model with Remittances

The objective of this section is to provide a theory supporting the preceding empirical results (Section 2.1). In particular, we probe the theoretical transmission channels through remittances affect macroeconomic fluctuations consistent with the above empirical results. We argue that the absence of a reduction in consumption volatility in response to an increase in remittances stems from the excess volatility of consumption with respect to GDP, which itself results from underdeveloped financial and limited access to capital markets. We use the standard one-good neoclassical small open economy DSGE model developed in Garcia-Cicco, Pancrazi, and Uribe (2010) where financial frictions play a leading role in generating an excess consumption volatility.

A. The Theoretical Model

We briefly review the main features of the model. A more detailed description of this model can be found in Jidoud (2012) and references mentioned above.

Preferences. The economy is populated by a representative household whose objective is to maximize its discounted lifetime utility:

EtΣt=1βtU(ct,Nt)(6)

where β ϵ [0, 1) is the discount factor, ct is current consumption, U(.) is a period utility function, and Et (.) is the conditional expectation operator on the information available to the household up to period t. The objective of the household is to maximize the above utility subject to the sequence of per period budget constraints given in (11).

Two utility specifications are called to compete in this setup. The first is the KPR preferences (King, Plosser, and Rebelo, 1988) given by

U(ct,Nt)=(ct(1Nt))1σ11σ(7)

and the second is the so called GHH preferences following Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Huffman (1988)

U(ct,Nt)=(ctNtωω)1σ11σ(8)

ω > 1 governs the intertemporal substitution of labor supply while σ ≥ 1 stands for the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of consumption.

The motivation behind confronting the two preferences specifications is the size of the wealth effect they generate. They indeed represent different levels of constant wealth effect for a given elasticity of labor supply. GHH preferences (8) have the property that labor supply is independent of wealth and is accordingly determined independently from the consumption level of the household. Thus the wealth effect is zero. On the other hand KPR preferences generate a sizeable wealth effect which, everything else equal, would reduce the labor supply of the households in response to a shock that induces an increase in the marginal utility of wealth. In addition, GHH preferences are widely used in the business cycles analysis of developing countries on the grounds that they help the small open economy models reproduce the stylized business cycle facts of open economies, in particular, countercyclical trade balances (Mendoza, 1991; and Garcia-Cicco, Pancrazi, and Uribe, 2010; among others). Therefore comparing the performances of these two specifications is of particular interest for this literature.

Technology. The economy produces one single good using a Cobb–Douglass production function with constant return to scale as follows:

Yt=atA¯KtαNt1α(9)

where Yt denotes output in period t, Kt denotes capital in period t, Nt denotes labor input in period t, A>0 is a scale parameter that pins down the level of output. We assume that fluctuations in output are solely driven by a transitory productivity shock at which follows a first-order autoregressive process, that is,

ln(at)=(1ρa)ln(A¯)+ρaln(at1)+ɛta,ɛtaN(0,σa2).(10)

where |ρa| < 1 denotes the persistence of the shock.

The resource constraint of the economy is given by

Yt+qtDt+1+Ret=Ct+It+Dt+Gt+Φ(Kt+1,Kt)Kt(11)

Ct, It, and Ret denote private consumption, private investment, and migrants’ transfers from abroad (remittances) respectively. Dt accounts for the stock of foreign debt (international bonds) held by the country, inherited from the previous period, and qt the price of one unit of bonds (see next subsection).

The law of motion of capital is given by

Kt+1=It+(1δ)Kt(12)

with δ ϵ (0, 1] being the depreciation rate of capital, and the function Φ(.) represents the capital adjustment function which takes the form

Φ(Kt+1,Kt)=φ2(Kt+1Kt1)2(13)

φ ≥ 0 is the elasticity of the capital adjustment costs function. Capital adjustment costs are added in DSGE models because the latter cannot generate realistic moments of investment had these costs being ignored (Koze and Riezman, 2001; among others). Their formulation in equation (13) indicates that changing the stock of capital by a given amount increases with the speed of the desired adjustment and thus gives incentives to the firm to spread out this change over several periods. In addition, capital adjustment costs are zero at the steady state.

B. International Financial Markets and the Role of Remittances

The representative agent has access to international capital markets for non-contingent debt. Then Dt in equation (11) represents the debt or the number of promises from the previous period the agent pays and qt is the price at which he can sell a promise to a unit of goods to be delivered at t+1. Given that the international traded assets are non-contingent bonds, our economy has an incomplete asset markets structure. Furthermore, these markets are assumed to be competitive, and accordingly the gross interest rate, denoted Qt, on foreign borrowing is given by the inverse of the price of bonds:

1qtRt=R*+ψ(Dt,Yt,Ret)(14)

where R* accounts for the fixed (common) international interest rate. The second component of the bond price is the risk-premium or spread paid by the economy on top of the fixed interest rate on international financial markets. While in the standard SOEM this premium nests on technical necessities, in our setup it acts as a reduced form of a financial friction governing the dynamic effects of aggregate fluctuations and the transmission of financial shocks.8 Therefore the parameter ψ reflects the tightness or the sensitivity of these financial frictions to different macroeconomic variables (GDP, debt, remittances). In dealing with this friction, we adopt two modeling assumptions. First we assume the country risk premium is determined by the indebtedness of the economy with respect to its output. So that (14) is given by

Rt=R*+ψ(exp(DtYtD¯Y¯)1)(15)

where variables with bars are the steady state values. In this specification, the level of the country’s indebtedness has a positive effect on the borrowing cost. The higher the debt relative to GDP the higher is the interest rate paid by the country because investors will fear the probability of default of the country (Garcia–Cicco, Pancrazi, and Uribe, 2010; Ozbilgin, 2010; for a closer formulation). In a second specification we assume the flow of remittances has some impact on the country’s borrowing costs. Formally (14) become

Rt=R*+ψ(exp(DtYt+RetD¯Y¯+R¯e)1)(16)

This modeling assumption is underpinned by the empirical evidence that remittances lessen the remittances-dependent countries’ borrowing cost on international capital markets and enhance their creditworthiness. Furthermore, some African countries have used remittances as securitized assets to raise funds on international financial markets at low cost and longer maturities (Ratha, De, and Mohapatra, 2011; Afreximbank, 2005). Evidence about the ability of remittances to ease access to financial markets is a well-established fact in most African economies.

V. Quantitative Analysis

The model is log-linearized around the deterministic stationary steady state. The structural parameters of the model are calibrated following the business cycle literature on developing economies and mostly African countries whenever possible.

Calibration. We consider our panel of countries to form a representative African economy. The parameters of the model are calibrated following the existing work and according to the annual frequency of the data. But their choice is evaluated with respect to the model’s ability to mimic some features of this economy as observed in 1980–2005. It is worth noting that the calibration for some of the parameters entails great uncertainty because we lack thorough, reliable studies on African countries on these parameters. To overcome this problem, we later provide some sensitivity analysis on these parameters. We set the discount factor β = 0.98, which implies an interest rate level equal to 2.04 percent. The share of capital income to total income of the economy α is set to 0.33. The inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of consumption, σ, is set to 5 following Arellano and others (2009). All these values are pretty standard in the literature of business cycles. The persistence and the standard deviation of the total factor productivity (TFP) are to 0.9271 and 0.0126 respectively. The annual depreciation rate of capital δ is equal to 0.15, while the capital adjustment cost parameter φ = 5. The depreciation rate is set to 0.15 and its relatively high value reflects the higher depreciation of capital stock in developing countries (Bu, 2006). The relatively high value of the capital adjustment cost parameter φ reflects the difficulty of adjusting capital in developing economies (Tybout, 2000; Bigsten and others, 2005). We set ω (one plus the labor supply elasticity) equal to 1.5, a value close to that chosen by Mendoza (1991) for a small open economy case.9 The debt-to-GDP ratio is equal to 0.80, a value fairly consistent with the indebtedness size of African economies.

The model is finally simulated for different values of the elasticity of the risk premium. We specifically consider three values for this parameter: 1, 2.5, and 7.5, with a higher value reflecting tight borrowing constraints or the sensitivity of bond prices to the different arguments in the risk-premium function. Table 3 summarizes this calibration.

The model is solved by varying the steady state level of workers’ remittances-to-GDP ratio over three values: 0, 0.0378 and 0.0756. The empirical mean (of the countries included in the regression) which we consider, the steady state value is 3.78 percent. The performances of the model with respect to the data are evaluated by computing the semi-elasticity, εσx of the generated volatilities around the steady state value of the remittances-to-GDP ratio. Formally speaking this semi-elasticity (consistent with the empirical model) is given by

ɛσx=Δlog(σx)ΔRe(17)

A. The Role of Wealth Effect on Labor Supply

The model is simulated under the world interest rate specification (15) in which we assume the size of remittances have no direct effects on the country’s risk premium. Table 5 reports the results. Column (1) displays all the characteristics of the data for comparison while columns (2)–(4) report the results using KPR preferences. Columns (5)–(7) deal with GHH preferences. It is worth noting that the model replicates well the business cycle facts in these economies. In particular, the consumption to output volatility predicted by the model is the actual one especially with GHH preferences and tight borrowing constraints.

Table 4.

Calibrated Parameters

article image
Table 5.

Model Predictions and the Wealth Effect

article image
Note: ŷ and ĉ account for the cyclical component of the HP filtered logs of per capita GDP and private consumption while Δy and Δc are the growth rates of the same variables. The model is simulated with completely exogenous remittances. That is, Ȓt = 0. The steady-state level of remittances takes the values 0, 0.0378 and 0.0756. The autocorrelations and the relative volatilities from the model are taken when the model is simulated at the empirical average of the steady state size of remittances to GDP ratio: 0.0378.

How does the model perform in terms of the effects of remittances on macroeconomic fluctuations? In columns (2)–(4), consumption volatility decreases, but output volatility increases as the size of remittances increases. Hence remittances have stabilizing effects on consumption and destabilizing effects on output. Unlike KPR preferences, GHH preferences give negative elasticities for both consumption and output. The stabilizing impact of remittances on output becomes stronger (higher elasticity in absolute value) as the risk-premium sensitivity ψ increases but the elasticity of consumption volatility decreases (in absolute value) though it remains negative for all degree of financial tightness. For example, when ψ = 1, a 1 percent increase in the remittances-to-GDP ratio increases (decreases) output (consumption) volatility by 0.39 (0.59) percentage point with KPR preferences. These numbers are 0.03 and 0.80 in the case of GHH preferences. But when the risk premium strongly responds to the indebtedness ratio, an increase of 1 percent in the remittances size reduces both output and consumption volatility by 0.3 and 0.24 percentage points. In summary, besides their ability to generate plausible business cycle facts, GHH preferences are more consistent with our empirical finding: increasing the size of remittances cushions both output and consumption instabilities with the effect on output fluctuations being much more pronounced.

The key channel driving the difference between the two cases is the wealth effect generated by the two preferences. In the GHH preferences, the wealth effect on labor supply is nil whereas it is strictly positive for KPR for a given level of labor elasticity. Because of this wealth effect, labor supply decreases in the case of KPR preferences following an increase in the size of remittances. Households consume more leisure and then the steady state level of employment is reduced. The reduction in the steady state employment increases the elasticity of labor supply and deepens the response of hours and output following a positive TFP shock.10 This is why output volatility increases following a positive TFP shock for example (see Chami and others, 2008, for a graphical illustration of this effect: technology shocks plus income effect). When households’ preferences are for GHH, their labor supply decision is no longer affected by their income level but only by their wages. In response to a positive TFP shock labor supply increases but does not affect the elasticity of labor supply contrary to the case with KPR preferences. The constant elasticity of labor supply avoids output to respond strongly to TFP shocks. The observed decline in output volatility, although small, comes from a composition effect. Because consumption becomes less and less volatile, GDP fluctuations are moderated as the size of remittances becomes larger.

Figures 4 and 6 plot the impulse responses of different aggregates after a TFP shock for different levels of remittances-to-GDP ratio for KPR and GHH preferences, respectively. It turns out that an increase in remittances does not significantly affect the reaction of output, nor of consumption, in response to a TFP shock in KPR. However, it makes both output and consumption responses less strong for GHH.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

IRF to TFP Shocks with KPR Preferences, Without Remittances–Credit Frictions Interaction

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

IRF with KPR Preferences and Remittances-Credit Frictions Interaction

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

IRF to TFP Shocks with GHH Preferences Without Remittances–Credit Frictions Interaction

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

Why does consumption volatility decrease in both cases? Such a result stems from the reduction of the private consumption multiplier. Indeed an increase of remittances increases the steady state consumption-output ratio. This decouples consumption from output dynamics as consumption responds less to TFP shocks and income fluctuations. Yet this mechanism is not the only one at work. An additional channel driving the reduction of consumption volatility is the composition effect. Because remittances are not volatile themselves, and we are increasing the size of the non-volatile component of consumption, the volatility of consumption decreases. The above investigation has shed light on the wealth effect on labor supply as the main mechanism through which remittances deepen or dampen macroeconomic fluctuations. Furthermore, these effects are stronger in economies in which households have very limited access to financial markets. Unfortunately, this channel fails to generate a strong reduction in macroeconomic volatility as observed in our empirical investigation. For such a channel to generate sizeable smoothing effects, the model needs a strong propagation mechanism.

B. Remittances and Financial Frictions

In the previous subsection, increasing the size of remittances buffered macroeconomic fluctuations in an environment where households’ preferences exhibit no wealth effect and they face strong financial frictions. To improve the model’s performances in generating a sizeable reduction in macroeconomic volatility, we now allow remittances to have negative effects on the risk premium. We thus simulate the model using the specification (16) for the risk premium, which entails a loosening effect of remittances on financial constraints. The results are displayed in Table 6. The predictions of the model are qualitatively identical to those of the baseline setup. Remittances have a negative effect on both output and consumption volatility when the wealth effect in the preferences is killed off (GHH case) while they deepen output volatility when the income effect is allowed (KPR case). However, unlike the previous case, the semi-elasticities in Table 5 are higher in absolute value. That is, the reduction in both output and consumption fluctuations is more substantial. For example, when the risk-premium sensitivity is 7.5, a 1 percent increase in the size of remittances reduces output (consumption) instability by 1.66(1.56) percentage point when preferences are GHH type. In addition, the impact on volatility is stronger as financial constraints become tighter. The labor supply mechanism at work in the previous case still prevails. But the mechanism is much stronger now as more remittances imply greater possibilities to accumulate debt and decouple both consumption and output from TFP shocks. As can be seen in Figures 5 and 7, an increase in remittances entails a smaller response of output and consumption after a TFP shock. The dampening in these reactions is much stronger in GHH preferences. Moreover, the increase in output after a shock lasts longer in this case, affording households more income over time. Topping up the risk premium with remittances proves to be a powerful propagation mechanism, inducing the smoothing effect of remittances. In this new setup, an increase in the size of remittances implies a reduction in the costs of borrowing on international financial markets. This effect transmits into a more stable debt level and accordingly a reduction in the trade balance fluctuations. Hence reducing the risk premium remittances contribute to the stabilization of output and consumption as households get easier access to financial markets.

Table 6.

Model Predictions and Financial Development

article image
Note: ŷ and ĉ account for the cyclical component of the HP filtered logs of per capita GDP and private consumption while Δy and Δc are the growth rates of the same variables. The model is simulated with completely exogenous remittances. That is, Ȓt = 0. The steady-state level of remittances takes the values 0, 0.0378, and 0.0756. The autocorrelations and the relative volatilities from the model are taken when the model is simulated at the empirical average of the steady-state size of remittances to GDP ratio: 0.0378.
Figure 7.
Figure 7.

IRF to TFP shocks with GHH Preferences and Remittances–Credit Frictions Interaction

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2015, 049; 10.5089/9781498300940.001.A001

The bottom line of this analysis is that the stabilizing effect of remittances is stronger in an environment where financial frictions are tight, that is, borrowing constraints are permanently binding. This finding is quite intuitive. In an economy in which individuals can easily save and/or borrow, the marginal value of a unit of remittances is small; and remittances may have no effect on macroeconomic volatility. However, in an economy in which the options for saving and borrowing are limited, remittances constitute a direct source of income but also an asset that helps alleviate these borrowing constraints. This finding has some empirical support in the papers of Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh (2009) and Combes and Ebeke (2011), among others. This result also lines up with Ahamada and Coulibaly (2011) who find the smoothing effect of remittances in sub-Saharan African countries to be nonlinear and higher depending on the level of financial development.

VI. Sensitivity Analysis

We assess the robustness of the previous results alongside the following dimensions: the discount factor, the degree of risk aversion, and the capital adjustment cost parameter. All the following results are obtained by simulating the model under specification (16) of the world interest rate.

The elasticity of labor supply. In the baseline setup, the parameter ω, which governs the labor supply elasticity, was taken to be equal to 1.5, equal to a labor elasticity of 2. This parameter is subject to an endless debate in developing countries as the study of labor markets in these countries is at its infancy on account of the unavailability of adequate household data and the attention being more focused on surplus labor and underemployment. We check the robustness of our results along different values (1.2 and 2) of this parameter but only for GHH preferences because these are the only ones concerned with this parameter. The results are presented in Table 6. We see that the higher the elasticity of labor supply (low ω), the stronger is the stabilizing effect of remittances on output and consumption. Furthermore, in such a setting, the results are more qualitatively consistent with the empirical facts, that is, the stabilizing role of remittances is more pronounced on output than on consumption. When the labor supply elasticity is low, the semi-elasticities of output and consumption are negative, but the effect is less pronounced for output. Clearly this analysis brings out the role of labor market characteristics in shaping the impact of remittances in business cycles in developing countries. In countries where workers strongly adjusted their labor supply in response to wage variations, remittances are expected to significantly cushion the resulting fluctuations in output and consumption. On the contrary, when the labor supply elasticity is relatively low, the stabilizing effect of remittances is limited.

The discounting dimension. In the benchmark setup we assume the representative household discounts time at a rate 0.98, which corresponds to an annual real interest rate of 2.04 percent. While this corresponds to commonly practiced world interest rate for developing countries, we are greatly interested in assessing the validity of our results in the hypothesis the household is more or less patient compared to the baseline setup. The degree of patience of households may undermine the effects of remittances because it determines the consumption/savings decisions of households.

Table 7 shows the results for two values of the discount rate. The figures are quantitatively and qualitatively in line with those of the benchmark model. Remittances have a negative effect on macroeconomic fluctuations when they are poured into economies with low financial development. The more impatient are the households (a lower discount factor) the stronger is the smoothing effect of remittances. The impatience of households (β = 0.92) results in an important smoothing behavior because of the higher interest rates faced by the households. A higher fixed interest rate is an additional financial constraint and thus fuels the effect of remittances on macroeconomic fluctuations.

Table 7.

Model Predictions as ω Changes

article image

Intertemporal substitution. It is well known that the strength of the intertemporal substitution (the curvature of the utility function) carries the consumption-smoothing objective of the households. The higher the substitution is, the more intense is the consumption-smoothing objective and thus the greater will be the intertemporal reallocation of resources in the face of a productivity shock. In our benchmark analysis the risk-aversion parameter was set to 5, a value widely used in standard RBC analysis for developing countries (Arellano and others, 2009). Nevertheless, when it comes to developing countries, scarcity of reliable empirical studies on this issue makes it difficult to stick to specific values for these parameters. We thus assess the sensitivity of our results along this intertemporal substitution dimension. We choose a small value (σ = 1) and a higher one (σ = 10).

The results shown in Table 8 are in line with the baseline ones. The stabilizing effect of remittances is higher for a higher degree of intertemporal substitution because of households’ desire to smooth the consumption path. A higher degree of intertemporal substitution pushes the households to reallocate the additional resources from remittances for future consumption. In so doing, households opt for smoother income and consumption paths. When the intertemporal substitution is small, households’ desire to postpone present consumption to future periods is low, and this lessens the power of remittances to reduce consumption fluctuations.

Table 8.

Model Predictions as β Changes

article image

Capital Adjustment Costs. Capital adjustment costs are generally included in SOEM to avoid important swings in investment. The baseline value of 5 is reasonable given the arguments exposed in the previous section. As such, higher adjustment costs may by themselves reduce the volatility of investment and accordingly reduce output volatility through a composition effect. To see the extent to which our results rely on choice of the value of this parameter, we reevaluate the model’s performances with two values around the baseline value: 2 and 10.

The results in Table 9 show that our central findings are not challenged by the capital adjustment costs parameter. Higher remittances induce a decrease in both volatilities of output and consumption although the decrease is now more pronounced for consumption. Surprisingly, the reduction in macroeconomic volatility is more substantial when the adjustment costs are low. The mechanism might be that lower adjustment costs allow households to easily invest their remittances, which increases income over time and affords more possibilities to cushion macroeconomic shocks.

Table 9.

Model Predictions as σ Changes

article image
Table 10.

Model Predictions as φ Changes

article image

In light of what precedes, it is worth noting that our central finding, that is, the stabilizing effects of remittances are more pronounced in economies with fewer options for savings/borrowing and no wealth effect on labor supply, is robust to various alterations of different structural parameters.

VII. Conclusion

How effective are remittances in stabilizing aggregate fluctuations? How much of shocks is absorbed through migrants’ transfers? What are the mechanisms and channels through which remittances affect business cycle volatility? These are questions at the forefront of public and policy debate on the role of migration and remittances in developing countries. This paper responds to these questions by focusing on African economies. Consistent with the existing similar work on other countries, our empirical analysis suggests that larger remittances tend to reduce consumption and output volatility, that is, countries with higher remittances-to-GDP ratio display lower business cycle fluctuations. Nevertheless, the puzzling result is that the reduction in consumption volatility is less pronounced than for output volatility. Our interpretation of this finding is that given the relatively high volatility of consumption with respect to output, the level of remittances falls short of significantly reducing consumption volatility. Moreover, a portion worth 3.7 to 22 percent of GDP shocks is absorbed via remittances, suggesting the risk-sharing power of these transfers.

The main contribution of the paper to literature is the investigation of the theoretical channels and mechanisms through which remittances affect macroeconomic volatility using a general equilibrium framework. This theoretical analysis shows that the stabilization impact of remittances essentially hinges on two channels: (i) the size of the negative wealth effect on labor supply induced by remittances and, (ii) the strength of financial frictions and the ability of remittances to alleviate these frictions. The first channel implies that labor supply may decrease following an increase in remittances, lowering output and increasing its response to shocks. The second channel suggests remittances are more stabilizing in countries with a shallow financial and banking sector and when remittances induce financial sector development by providing a greater access to financial markets to their recipients (which can improve their creditworthiness scores). This later finding underscores the need for recipient countries to promote financial development so as to channel remittances through the financial system and help the poor have greater access to credit. This paper is among the first attempts to bring about a clear understanding of the transmission mechanism of remittances into the real economy. It bridges the gap between the burgeoning empirical work on the issue and the underlying theoretical mechanism. The paper points to the direction of labor markets and financial frictions as the two channels through which remittances exert their effects on business cycles in developing countries. Labor markets modeling issues and international financial frictions in developing countries have to be seriously considered when trying to understand the macroeconomic effect of remittances. This should be part of our future research agenda.

Appendix

Table 11.

Summary Statistics

article image
Note: σŷ and σĉ denote the standard deviations of HP filtered per GDP and consumption, respectively. σΔy and σΔc are the standard deviations of per capita GDP and consumption growth rates, respectively. All numbers in the table are percentages.

References

  • Adams, Jr., R.H., and J. Page (2005) “Do international migration and remittance reduce poverty in developing countries?”, World Development, 33, pp. 16451669.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Afreximbank (2005), Annual Report, http://www.afreximbank.com.

  • Agénor, P., McDermott, C., and Prasad, E. (2000)Macroeconomic fluctuations in developing countries: some stylized facts”, World Bank Economic Review, 14, pp. 251285.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aguiar, M., and G. Gopinath, (2007)Emerging markets business cycles: the cycle is the trend”, Journal of Political Economy, 115, pp. 69102.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ahamada, I., and Coulibaly, D. (2011), “How does financial development influence the impact of remittances on growth volatility?”, Economic Modelling, 28, pp. 27482760.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ahmed, A., and Suardi, S. (2009)Macroeconomic volatility, trade and financial liberalization in Africa,World Development, 37, pp. 16231636.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrès, J., R. Domènech and A. Fatas (2008)The stabilizing role of government size,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32, pp. 571593.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arellano, C., A. Bulir, T. Lane and L. Lipschitz, (2009)The dynamic implications of foreign aid and its variabilityJournal of Development Economics, 88, pp. 87102.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Asdrubali, P., B. E. Sorensen, and O. Yosha (1996), “Channels of Interstate Risk Sharing: United States 1963-1990”, Quaterly Journal of Economics, 111, pp. 10811110

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Azam, J-P., and F. Gubert (2005)Those in Kayes: the effects of remittances on their recipients in Africa”, Revue Economique, 56, pp. 13311358.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bekaert, G., Harvey, C., and Lundblad, C. (2006)Growth volatility and financial liberalization”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 25, pp. 370403.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bigsten, A., P. Collier, S. Dercon, M. Fafchamps, B. Gauthier, J.W. Gunning, R. Oostendorp, C. Patillo, M. Soderbom and F. Teal (2005)Adjustment costs and irreversibility as determinants of investment: evidence from African manufacturing”, Contribution to Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol 4.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourdet, Y., and H. Falck (2006)Emigrants remittances and Dutch Disease in Cape Verde”, International Economic Journal, 20, pp. 26784.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bu, Y. (2006)Fixed capital stock depreciation in developing countries: some evidence from firm level data”, Journal of Development Studies, 42, pp. 881901.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bugamelli, M., and F. Paterno (2009a)Do workers’ remittances reduce the probability of current account reversals”, World Development, 37 (12), pp. 18211838.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bugamelli, M., and F. Paterno (2009b)Output growth volatility and remittances”, Economica, pp. 121.

  • Bulir, A., and A.J. Hamann (2003)Aid volatility: an empirical assessment”, IMF Staff Papers, 50, 6489.

  • Chami, R., A. Barajas, T. Cosimano, C. Fullenkamp, M. Gapen and P. Montiel and Hakura (2008)Macroeconomic consequences of remittances”, IMF occasional paper, 259.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chami, R., Hakura, D., and Montiel, P. (2009), “Remittances: An automatic output stabilizer?IMF working paper no. 09/91.

  • Combes, J-L., and C. Ebeke, (2011)Remittances and households consumption volatility in developing countries”, World Development Issues, 9, pp. 10761089.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Craigwell, R., M. Jackman and W. Moore, (2010)Economic volatility and remittances”, International Journal of Development Issues, 9, pp. 2542.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Durdu and Sayan (2010)Emerging Market Business Cycles with Remittance Fluctuations,IMF Staff Papers, Palgrave Macmillan, vol. 57, pp. 303325.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freund, C., and C. Spatafora (2005)Remittances: transaction costs, determinants, and infor- mal Flows”, World Bank policy research working paper no. 3704, Wasgington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia-Cicco, J., Pancrazi, R. and Uribe, M., (2010)Real business cycles in emerging economies?”, American Economic Review, 100, pp. 25102531.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greenwood, J., Hercovitz, Z. and Huffman, G.W., (1988)Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle”, American Economic Review, 78, pp. 402417.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, S., Patillo, C., and Wagh, S. (2009)Effect of remittances on Poverty and finacial development in subsahran africa”, World Development, 37, pp. 104115.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, R., C.I. Plosser and S.T. Rebelo (1988)Production, growth and the business cycles: The basic neoclassical model”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, pp. 195232.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kose, M. A. and Riezman, R., (2001)Trade shocks and macroeconomic fluctuations in Africa”, Journal of Development Economics, 65, pp. 5580.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loayza, N.V., R. Rancière, L. Servén and J. Vantura, (2007)Macroeconomic volatility and welfare in developing economies”, World Bank Economic Review, 21, pp. 343357.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, E.G., (1991)Real business cycles in a small open economy”, American Economic Review 81, pp. 797818.

  • Mohapatra, S. and D. Ratha (2011)Remittances markets in Africa”, The World bank, Washington D.C, pp. 388.

  • Ozbilgin, H.M (2010)Financial market participation and the developing country business cycle”, Journal of Develoment Economics, 92, pp. 125137.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pallage, S. and M. Robe (2001)Foreign aid and the business cycle”, Review of International Economics, 9, pp. 641675.

  • Pallage, S., M. Robe and C. Bérubé (2007)The potential of foreign aid as insurance”, IMF Staff Papers, 53, pp. 453475.

  • Ratha, D., (2007), “Leveraging remittances for development, Policy Brief (June), Migration Policy Institute, Washington, DC.

  • Ratha, D., P.K. De and S. Mohapatra (2011)Shadow sovereign ratings for unrated developing dountries”, World Development, 39, pp. 295307.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M., (2003)Closing small open economy modelsJournal of International Economics, 61, pp. 163185.

  • Tybout, J. (2000)Manufacturing firms in developing countries: how well do they do, and why?”, American Economic Review, 38, pp. 1144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank (2006), “Global Economic Prospects 2006: economic implications of remittances and Migration”, Washington, DC, World Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank (2011), “Migration and remittances Factbook 2011”, Washington, DC, World Bank.

  • Yehoue, E.B., (2005)International risk–sharing and currency unions: The CFA zones”, IMF working paper no. 05/95.

1

Address: African Department, International Monetary Fund, 700 19th street N.W, Washington D.C, 20431. Email: ajidoud@imf.org. I would like to thank Patrick Feve for his permanent and invaluable support during my thesis, during which this paper started. I also thank Montfort Mlachila, Martial Dupaigne, Jean-Paul Azam and participants at the TSE Macroeconomic Workshop, ADRES conference 2013 (Strasbourg), Paris X Nanterre Job Market Seminar 2013, T2M conference 2013 (Lyon), CSAE Conference 2014 (Oxford) and the AFR External Sector Network seminar for their helpful comments and discussions. The views contained in the paper are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of IMF or IMF policy.

2

See also Anyanwu and Erhijakpor (2010) and Gupta, Patillo, and Wagh (2009) for a similar results.

3

In 1996, the African Export-Import Bank coarranged the first future flow securitization by a sub-Saharan African country: a $40 million medium-term loan in favor of a development bank in Ghana, backed by its Western Union remittance receivables (Afreximbank, 2005). In 2001, it arranged a $50 million remittance-backed syndicated note issuance facility for a Nigerian entity using Moneygram receivables. In 2004, it coarranged a $40 million remittance-backed syndicated term loan facility to an Ethiopian bank using its Western Union receivables (Afreximbank, 2005).

4

A higher relative volatility of consumption is the main feature of business cycles in developing economies. But this can be attributed to a measurement problem. Actually this consumption includes both consumption of durables and non-durables. It might as well originate from limited financial markets participation (strong financial frictions) in these countries, which hampers the consumption smoothing of the households. We favor this last explanation in what follows.

5

The test has two steps. First, regress the potentially endogenous variable on all the exogenous and the instruments. Then recover the residuals from this regression and include them in the baseline model as an exogenous variable. If the coefficient associated with the residuals is not significantly different from zero then we cannot reject the exogeneity hypothesis in the null.

6

Using HP filtered data with a smoothing parameter of 100 does not qualitatively affect the results.

7

CEMAC stands for Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa and WAEMU is the West African Economic and Monetary Union.

8

In standard SOEM, this trick is introduced to have a stationary model (see Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2003).

9

Empirical work is scarce on labor markets in African economies capable of allowing us to have a clear cut value on labor elasticity. However the value set here could be justified the existence of a sizeable informal sector in these economies and high unemployment rate.

10

The elasticity of labor supply is given by ɛGHH=1ω1 in the GHH case and by ɛKPR=N¯1N¯ in the KPR case.

Remittances and Macroeconomic Volatility in African Countries
Author: Ahmat Jidoud
  • View in gallery

    Remittances and other financial flows in SSA

  • View in gallery

    Volatility of financial flows to Africa 1980-2010

    (Coefficient of variation)

  • View in gallery

    Macroeconomic volatility and Remittances in Africa

  • View in gallery

    IRF to TFP Shocks with KPR Preferences, Without Remittances–Credit Frictions Interaction

  • View in gallery

    IRF with KPR Preferences and Remittances-Credit Frictions Interaction

  • View in gallery

    IRF to TFP Shocks with GHH Preferences Without Remittances–Credit Frictions Interaction

  • View in gallery

    IRF to TFP shocks with GHH Preferences and Remittances–Credit Frictions Interaction