Debt Sustainability, Public Investment, and Natural Resources in Developing Countries: the DIGNAR Model*
Author:
Mr. Giovanni Melina
Search for other papers by Mr. Giovanni Melina in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Susan S. Yang
Search for other papers by Ms. Susan S. Yang in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Luis-Felipe Zanna
Search for other papers by Luis-Felipe Zanna in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Contributor Notes

This paper presents the DIGNAR (Debt, Investment, Growth, and Natural Resources) model, which can be used to analyze the debt sustainability and macroeconomic effects of public investment plans in resource-abundant developing countries. DIGNAR is a dynamic, stochastic model of a small open economy. It has two types of households, including poor households with no access to financial markets, and features traded and nontraded sectors as well as a natural resource sector. Public capital enters production technologies, while public investment is subject to inefficiencies and absorptive capacity constraints. The government has access to different types of debt (concessional, domestic and external commercial) and a resource fund, which can be used to finance public investment plans. The resource fund can also serve as a buffer to absorb fiscal balances for given projections of resource revenues and public investment plans. When the fund is drawn down to its minimal value, a combination of external and domestic borrowing can be used to cover the fiscal gap in the short to medium run. Fiscal adjustments through tax rates and government non-capital expenditures—which may be constrained by ceilings and floors, respectively—are then triggered to maintain debt sustainability. The paper illustrates how the model can be particularly useful to assess debt sustainability in countries that borrow against future resource revenues to scale up public investment.

Abstract

This paper presents the DIGNAR (Debt, Investment, Growth, and Natural Resources) model, which can be used to analyze the debt sustainability and macroeconomic effects of public investment plans in resource-abundant developing countries. DIGNAR is a dynamic, stochastic model of a small open economy. It has two types of households, including poor households with no access to financial markets, and features traded and nontraded sectors as well as a natural resource sector. Public capital enters production technologies, while public investment is subject to inefficiencies and absorptive capacity constraints. The government has access to different types of debt (concessional, domestic and external commercial) and a resource fund, which can be used to finance public investment plans. The resource fund can also serve as a buffer to absorb fiscal balances for given projections of resource revenues and public investment plans. When the fund is drawn down to its minimal value, a combination of external and domestic borrowing can be used to cover the fiscal gap in the short to medium run. Fiscal adjustments through tax rates and government non-capital expenditures—which may be constrained by ceilings and floors, respectively—are then triggered to maintain debt sustainability. The paper illustrates how the model can be particularly useful to assess debt sustainability in countries that borrow against future resource revenues to scale up public investment.

I. Introduction

Natural resource revenues are a significant source of fiscal revenues in many developing countries, especially in Africa. Given tremendous infrastructure needs and borrowing constraints in these countries, resource revenues are valuable to finance public investment, which has been claimed to be important for growth and economic development. For countries that expect future production, resource revenues can also serve as a collateral for accessing international financial markets, making it possible to build up public capital before revenues arrive. However, natural resource revenues may bring the infamous natural resource curse to the recipient economy—a negative relationship between resource abundance and growth.1

The positive growth effects of public investment have long been recognized in the theoretical literature. Agénor (2012) distinguishes several channels through which increases in public capital may affect growth, including the one associated with positive productivity and cost-saving effects—more public capital raises the productivity of labor and private capital and lowers the unit costs. The other channels correspond to (i) a complementary effect on private capital, where more public capital increases the rate of return on private capital; (ii) a crowding-out effect, when increases in public capital requires domestic financing and, therefore, displaces (or crowds out) private investment, and (iii) a “Dutch vigor” effect, where higher public capital can raise the total factor productivity through positive learning-by-doing externalities (see Berg et al. (2010)). These channels provide support to the “Big Push” proposal that Sachs (2005), among others, has advocated for many poor developing countries: a substantial increase in public infrastructure spending financed with more aid and debt relief to increase growth and reduce poverty. Scaling up public investment in developing countries, however, may not always enhance growth. Low public investment efficiency and absorptive capacity constraints are among them, as they can significantly discount the growth benefits of public investment (Berg et al. (2013) and van der Ploeg (2012a)). Also, in resource-rich countries, spending resource revenues domestically may lead to Dutch disease, hurting the competitiveness of traded good sectors and, hence, growth (e.g., van der Ploeg (2011a) and van der Ploeg and Venables (2013)).

History reveals that, during windfalls, resource-rich developing countries that plan to increase public investment together with external borrowing may bear substantial debt risks. Soaring oil prices in the 1970s promoted many oil-exporting countries (e.g., Algeria, Ecuador, Indonesia, Nigeria, Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela as documented in Gelb (1988)) to undertake ambitious investment projects, jointly financed by oil revenues and external borrowing. In the early 1980s, the increase in interest rates and the collapse of oil prices contributed to a sequence of debt crises in Latin America, resulting in the “lost decade” with little or negative economic growth—per capita income plummeted and poverty increased (Carrasco (1999)). In fact, Manzano and Rigobon (2007) argue that these countries used natural resources as collateral for debt, leading to excessive borrowing when commodity prices in the 1970’s were going up. But once prices plummeted in the 1980s, debt crises became inevitable. In theory, external commercial borrowing to scale up public investment in poor developing countries can bring some benefits but also involve significant risks, as suggested by Buffie et al. (2012): poor execution of projects, sluggish fiscal adjustments to service debt, or persistent negative economic shocks can easily threaten debt sustainability.

The previous discussion suggests that assessing the growth and debt sustainability effects of public investment plans in resource-rich developing countries is not an easy task. Nevertheless country teams at the Fund are frequently asked to provide such assessments. To do so, they can use the IMF-World Bank debt sustainability framework (IMF-WB DSF), but this framework can be subject to criticisms. Some suggest that IMF-WB DSF does not contain a fully consistent analytic framework to create projections that accounts for the public investment growth nexus.2 To address this criticism, Buffie et al. (2012) construct a consistent model-based framework that has been used at the Fund to provide debt sustainability and growth assessments of public investment surges in low-income countries (LICs).3 This framework, however, does not have a natural resource sector and, thus, it may not be suitable for resource-rich countries. On the other hand, the framework developed in Berg et al. (2013) contains a resource sector but abstracts from debt accumulation; thus, the model can only be used to evaluate the effects of a public investment increase financed by resource revenues.

To fill this modeling gap, in this paper, we present a DSGE model of a small open economy, which can be used for assessing debt sustainability and growth effects in a resource-rich developing country that combines resource revenues and borrowing to scale up public investment. We name the model the “Debt, Investment, Growth, and Natural Resources (DIGNAR)” model, and it basically merges the debt model of Buffie et al. (2012) with the natural resource model of Berg et al. (2013). DIGNAR differs from the Buffie et al. model by adding a natural resource sector—so it accounts for resource GDP—and distinguishing between the resource sector and non-resource traded good sector. DIGNAR differs from the Berg et al. model by including several debt instruments such as concessional debt, external commercial debt, and domestic debt. Other key features of DIGNAR include large share of poor households that do not have access to financial markets, learning-by-doing externalities in the traded good production to capture potential Dutch disease from spending resource revenues, inefficiency and absorptive capacity constraints for public investment, a time-varying depreciation rate of public capital that accelerates with the lack of maintenance of installed capital, and a relatively detailed fiscal specification, to be explained next.

The main objective of DIGNAR is to help governments facing volatile and exhaustible resource revenues to make public investment decisions. A fast investment scaling-up pace may lead to fast accumulation of public capital and higher non-resource growth. However, as more resource revenues are devoted to public investment, less can be saved, leaving the economy vulnerable to future negative resource revenue shocks. Also, when determining the public investment scaling up magnitude, it is important to consider the financing needs of sustaining capital after resource revenues are exhausted, to ensure long-lasting growth benefits from more public capital. To highlight the important role of saving in maintaining macroeconomic stability, the resource fund introduced in the model plays the role of a fiscal buffer. Given exogenous paths of public investment, concessional borrowing, aid, resource production, prices, and revenues, a resource fund is drawn down if there is a revenue shortfall or accumulates higher savings if there is excessive revenue. When the fund reaches a chosen lower bound, a government can choose one or more fiscal instruments contemporaneously or resort to borrowing to close the fiscal gap. Debt accumulation then triggers fiscal adjustments. Debt dynamics are determined by the speed of fiscal adjustments, specified in the fiscal rules of the adjustment instruments. As a result, the resource fund in DIGNAR can maintain macroeconomic stability by stabilizing public and private consumption paths.4

There are four fiscal instruments to close the fiscal gap: the consumption and labor income tax rates, on the revenue side, and government consumption and transfers, on the expenditure side. These instruments can be constrained by corresponding ceilings or floors. In practice, raising tax rates beyond a certain level may not be feasible, due to weak institutions in enforcing revenue collection or lack of political support. To maintain minimal functions, government consumption cannot be lowered than the level required to cover its operating costs, and transfers cannot be lower than zero. Also, we assume that the resource fund can be subject to a minimal level of assets, so the fund can serve as a saving commitment device.5 Moreover, to model ambitious public investment plans, DIGNAR introduces a functional form that can be used to parameterize the degree of front-loading and the level of scaling-up magnitude in the longer horizon, convenient to construct an investment scaling-up path.

In this paper, we also illustrate how DIGNAR can be used for policy analysis. We calibrate the model to an average LIC and analyze various investment scaling-up paths. We consider two hypothetical scenarios of resource revenue inflows, similar to the qualitative patterns of a country that anticipates a future resource windfall. The simulated investment approaches include (i) the spend-as-you-go approach, which invests all resource windfall each period without saving, and (ii) the delinked approach, which combines investment and saving such that government spending is a-cyclical along with resource revenue flows. Simulations for different degrees of investment front-loading, investment efficiency, and return to public capital are also pursued to show their role in the debt sustainability analysis. Country applications of DIGNAR so far include Mozambique (Melina and Xiong, 2013) and Kazakhstan (Minasyan and Yang, 2013).

Like the models in Buffie et al. (2012) and Berg et al. (2013) that follow the approach of developing DSGE models for LICs, we see several advantages of using DIGNAR for policy analysis, as summarized in Berg et al. (2014). Models like DIGNAR offer a framework for organizing thinking and incorporating empirical evidence, such as returns to public capital and public investment efficiency. Also, they can be used to systematically produce alternative macroeconomic and policy scenarios, which make transparent the linkages of different assumptions and their effects on macroeconomic outcomes in an internally consistent framework.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section II, we present the structure of the model and discuss extensively all its features. We discuss our calibration to an average LIC in Section III. In Section IV, we present and discuss the policy scenarios. Finally, Section V concludes.

II. The DIGNAR Model

DIGNAR is a real three-sector model of a small open economy embellished with multiple types of public sector debt, multiple tax and spending variables, and a resource fund. The country produces a composite of traded good and a nontraded good using capital k, labor L, and government-supplied infrastructure kG. It is also endowed with natural resources whose production and prices are assumed to be exogenous. Since the time horizon is 20+ years, the model abstracts from money and all nominal rigidities.6 We lay out the model in stages, starting with the specification of households.

A. Households

There are two types of households who live infinitely and are distributed over the unit interval. A fraction ω own firms and have access to capital markets. They are referred to as intertemporal optimizing or Ricardian households and denoted by the superscript OPT. The remaining fraction 1 – ω are poor and financially constrained. They are referred to as rule-of-thumb or hand-to-mouth and do not have access to capital and financial markets. They consume all of their disposable income each period and are denoted by the superscript ROT.

Both types consume a consumption basket cti which is described as a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) aggregate of traded goods cT,ti and nontraded goods cN,ti. Thus, the consumption basket is

c t i = [ φ 1 χ ( C N , t i ) χ 1 χ + ( 1 φ ) 1 χ ( c T , t i ) χ 1 χ ] χ χ 1 , for i = O P T , R O T , ( 1 )

where φ indicates the nontraded good bias and χ > 0 is the intra-temporal elasticity of substitution.

The consumption basket is the numeraire of the economy, and pN,t represents the relative price of nontraded goods, and st corresponds to the relative price of traded goods to the consumption basket. Assuming that the law of one price holds for traded goods implies that st also corresponds to the real exchange rate, defined as the price of one unit of foreign consumption basket in units of domestic basket.

Minimizing total consumption expenditures subject to the consumption basket (1) yields the following demand functions for each good:

c N , t i = φ p N , t χ c t i , i = O P T , R O T , ( 2 )

and

c T , t i = ( 1 φ ) s t χ c t , i i = O P T , R O T . ( 3 )

The unit price of the consumption basket is

1 = [ φ p N 1 χ + ( 1 φ ) s t 1 χ ] 1 1 χ . ( 4 )

Both types of households provide labor service (LT,ti and LN,ti,i=OPT,ROT) to the traded and the nontraded good sectors, denoted by subscripts T and N, respectively. Total labor Lti has the following CES specification to capture imperfect sustitutability between the labor amounts supplied to the two sectors:

L t i = [ δ 1 ρ ( L N , t i ) 1 + ρ ρ + ( 1 δ ) 1 ρ ( L N , t i ) 1 + ρ ρ ] ρ 1 + ρ , for i = O P T , R O T , ( 5 )

where δ is the steady-state share of labor in the nontraded good sector, and ρ > 0 is the intra-temporal elasticity of substitution. Let wT,t and wN,t be the real wage rates paid in each sector, and wt be the real wage index. Maximizing the household’s total labor income (wtLti=wT,tLT,ti+wN,tLN,ti) subject to aggregate labor (5) yields the following labor supply schedules for each sector:

L N , t i = δ ( ω N , t ω t ) ρ L t i , for i = O P T , R O T , ( 6 )

and

L T , t i = ( 1 δ ) ( ω T , t ω t ) ρ L t i , for i = O P T , R O T . ( 7 )

The real wage index is

ω t = [ δ ω N , t 1 + ρ + ( 1 δ ) ω T , t 1 + ρ ] 1 1 + ρ . ( 8 )

1. Intertemporal Optimizing Households

A representative intertemporal optimizing household maximizes its utility

E 0 Σ t = 0 β t U ( c t O P T , L t O P T ) = E 0 { Σ t = 0 β t [ 1 1 σ ( c t O P T ) 1 σ k O P T 1 + ψ ( L t O P T ) 1 + ψ ] } , ( 9 )

subject to the following budget constraint:

( 1 + τ t C ) c t O P T + b t O P T s t b t O P T * = ( 1 τ t L ) ω t L t O P T + R t 1 b t 1 O P T R t 1 * s t b t 1 O P T * + Ω T , t + Ω N , t + ϑ K τ K ( r T , t K k T , t 1 + r N , t K k N , t 1 ) + s t r m t * + z t μ k G , t 1 Θ t O P T * . ( 10 )

E0 is the expectation operator at time 0;β[(1+ϱ)]1 is the subjective discount factor; and ϱ is the pure rate of time preference. σ is the inverse of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of consumption, while ψ is the inverse of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of the labor supply. kOPT is the disutility weight of labor and τtC and τtL are the tax rates on consumption and labor income, respectively. The intertemporal optimizing households have access to government bonds btOPT that pay a (gross) real interest rate Rt. They can also borrow from abroad—so btOPT* is liabilities to the rest of the world—by paying an interest rate Rt*. These households also receive profits, ΩT,t and ΩN,t, from firms that are in the traded and nontraded good sector. The term ϑKτK(rT,tKkT,t1+rN,tKkN,t1) is a tax rebate that optimizing households receive on the tax levied on the firms’ return on capital.7 rmt* denotes remittances from abroad and zt corresponds to government transfers. μ is the user fees charged for public capital kG,t services, and ΘtOPT*η2(btOPT*bOPT*)2 are portfolio adjustment costs associated to foreign liabilities, where η controls the degree of capital account openness and bOPT* is the initial steady-state value of private foreign debt.8 Note that a variable without a time subscript refers to the steady-state value of such variable.

Let λt be the Lagrange multiplier to the budget constraint (10). The first-order conditions with respect to ctOPT,LtOPT,btOPT, and btOPT* are

λ t ( 1 + τ t C ) = ( c t O P T ) σ , ( 11 )
k O P T ( L t O P T ) ψ = λ t ( 1 τ t L ) ω t , ( 12 )
λ t = β E t ( λ t + 1 R t ) , ( 13 )

and

λ t = β E t [ λ t + 1 s t + 1 R t * s t η ( b t O P T * b O P T * ) ] . ( 14 )

We assume that the private sector pays a constant premium u over the interest rate that the government pays on external commercial debt Rdc,t, such that

R t * = R d c , t + u . ( 15 )

2. Rule-of-thumb Households

Rule-of-thumb households have the same utility function as that of intertemporal optimizing households, so

U ( c t R O T , L t R O T ) = 1 1 σ ( c t R O T ) 1 σ k R O T 1 + ψ ( L t R O T ) 1 + ψ . ( 16 )

Their consumption is determined by the budget constraint

( 1 + τ t C ) c t R O T = ( 1 τ t L ) ω t L t R O T + s t r m t * + z t μ k G , t 1 , ( 17 )

while static maximization of the utility function gives the following labor supply function:

L t R O T = [ 1 k R O T 1 τ t L 1 + τ t C ( c t R O T ) σ ω t ] 1 ψ . ( 18 )

3. Aggregation

With two types of households, aggregate consumption, labor, privately-owned government bonds, and foreign liabilities are computed as follows.

c t = ω c t O P T + ( 1 ω ) c t R O T , ( 19 )
L t = ω L t O P T + ( 1 ω ) L t R O T , ( 20 )

and

b t = ω b t O P T ; b t * = ω b t O P T * . ( 21 )

B. Firms

The economy has three production sectors: (i) a nontraded good sector indexed by N; (ii) a (non-resource) traded good sector indexed by T; and (iii) a natural resource sector indexed by O. Since resource-rich developing countries tend to export most resource output, we assume that the whole resource output is exported for simplicity.

1. Nontraded Good Sector

Nontraded good firms produce output yN,t with the following Cobb-Douglas technology:

y N , t = z N ( k N , t 1 ) 1 α N ( L N , t ) α N ( k G , t 1 ) α G , ( 22 )

where zN is total factor productivity, kN,t is end-of-period private capital, kG,t is the end-of-period public capital, αN is the labor share of sectoral income, and αG is the output elasticity respect to public capital.

Capital installed in the nontraded good sector evolves according to

k N , t = ( 1 δ N ) k N , t 1 + [ 1 k N 2 ( i N , t i N , t 1 1 ) 2 ] i N , t , ( 23 )

where iN,t represents investment expenditure, δN is the capital depreciation rate, and kN is the investment adjustment cost parameter. The investment adjustment costs follow the representation suggested by Christiano et al. (2005).

The representative nontraded good firm maximizes its discounted lifetime profits weighted by the marginal utility of consumption of the intertemporal optimizing households λt. These profits are given by

Ω T , 0 = E 0 Σ t = 0 β t λ t [ p N , t y N , t w N , t L N , t i N , t τ K r N , t K k N , t 1 ] , ( 24 )

where rN,tK=(1αN)pN,tyN,tkN,t1 is the (gross) return to capital. Let λtqN,t be the Lagrange multiplier associated with the law of motion of capital, where qN,t is the sectoral Tobin’s q. Then, the first-order conditions with respect to LN,t, kN,t, and iN,t are given by

w N , t = α N p N , t y N , t L N , t , ( 25 )
q N , t = E t [ β λ t + 1 λ t ( ( 1 δ N ) q N , t + 1 + ( 1 τ K ) ( 1 α N ) p N , t + 1 y N , t + 1 k N , t ) ] , ( 26 )

and

1 q N , t = [ 1 k N 2 ( i N , t i N , t 1 1 ) 2 k N ( i N , t i N , t 1 1 ) i N , t i N , t 1 ] + E t [ β λ t 1 λ t k N q N , t + 1 q N , t ( i N , t + 1 i N , t 1 ) ( i N , t + 1 i N , t ) 2 ] . ( 27 )

2. Traded Good Sector

Analogously to the nontraded good sector, firms in the traded good sector produce traded output with the following technology

y T , t = z T , t ( k T , t 1 ) 1 α N ( L T , t ) α N ( k G , t 1 ) α G . ( 28 )

To capture the common Dutch disease effects associated with spending resource revenues, we assume that the total factor productivity in this sector, zT,t, is subject to learning-by-doing externalities:

z T , t z T = ( z T , t 1 z T ) ρ z T + ( y T , t 1 y T ) ρ y T , ( 29 )

where ρzT, ρyT ∈ [0,1] control the severity of Dutch disease. This specification is a variation of the one in Matsuyama (1992) and Krugman (1987).9 It implies that there are no permanent effects of learning by doing on output or productivity. But deviations of traded sector output from the trend do imply persistent productivity effects.

Private capital in the traded sectors is accumulated according to

k T , t = ( 1 δ T ) k T , t 1 + [ 1 k T 2 ( i T , t i T , t 1 1 ) 2 ] i T , t . ( 30 )

Like nontraded good firms, a representative traded good firm maximizes the following discounted lifetime profits:

Ω T , 0 = E 0 Σ t = 0 β t λ t [ y T , t w T , t L T , t i T , t τ K r T , t K k T , t 1 ] . ( 31 )

The first-order conditions with respect to LT,t, kT,t, and iT,t are given by

w T , t = α s t y T , t L T , t , ( 32 )
q T , t = E t [ β λ t + 1 λ t ( ( 1 δ T ) q T , t + 1 + ( 1 τ K ) ( 1 α T ) s t + 1 y T , t + 1 k T , t ) ] , ( 33 )

and

1 q T , t = [ 1 κ T 2 ( i T , t i T , t 1 1 ) 2 κ T ( i T , t i T , t 1 1 ) i T , t i T , t 1 ] + E t [ β λ t + 1 λ t κ T q T , t + 1 q T , t ( i T , t + 1 i T , t 1 ) ( i T , t + 1 i T , t ) 2 ] . ( 34 )

3. Natural Resource Sector

Since often most natural resource production in resource-rich developing countries is capital intensive, and much of the investment in the resource sector is financed by foreign direct investment in LICs, natural resource production is simplified in the model as follows. Resource production follows an exogenous process

y ˜ O , t y ˜ O = ( y ˜ O , t 1 y ˜ O ) ρ y o exp ( ɛ t y o ) , ( 35 )

where ρyo ∈ (0,1) is an auto-regressive coefficient and ɛtyoiidN(0,σyo2) is the resource production shock. We assume that resource production is small relative to world production; hence, the international commodity price (relative to the foreign consumption basket), pO,t*, is taken as given and evolves as

p O , t * p O * = ( p O , t 1 * p O * ) ρ p o exp ( ɛ t p o ) , ( 36 )

where ρpo ∈ (0,1] is an auto-regressive coefficient and ɛtpoiidN(0,σpo2) is the resource price shock. Resource GDP in units of the domestic consumption basket corresponds to

y O , t = s t p O , t * y ˜ O , t . ( 37 )

and therefore total real GDP yt in this economy can be defined as

y t = p N , t y N , t + s t y T , t + y O , t . ( 38 )

C. The Government

The government flow budget constraint is given by

τ t C c t + τ t L w t L t + ( 1 ϑ K ) τ K ( r T , t K k T , t 1 + r T , t K k T , t 1 ) + s t g r t * + μ k G , t 1 + t O , t + b t + s t d c , t + s t R R F f t 1 * = p t G ( g t C + g t I ) + z t + R t 1 b t 1 + s t R d d t 1 + s t R d c , t 1 d c , t 1 + s t f t * , ( 39 )

where besides the tax revenues from consumption, labor income and capital income—τtCct,τtLwtLt,, and Σj=T,N(1ϑK)τKrj,tKkj,t1—the government also receives international grants, grt*, user fees, μkG,t-1, and resources-related royalties, tO, t. As in Buffie et al. (2012), the user fee charged on public capital is computed as a fraction f of recurrent costs: μfptGδG. The resource revenues collected each period, on the other hand, correspond to

t t O = τ O s t p O , t * y ˜ O , t , ( 40 )

where τO is a constant royalty rate that can be made time-varying, if necessary. The government has three debt instruments: external concessional debt, dt, external commercial debt, dc,t, and domestic debt, bt. Concessional loans extended by official creditors are taken as exogenous in the model and charge a constant (gross) real interest rate Rd. On the other hand, the gross real interest rates paid on external commercial debt incorporates a risk premium depending on the deviations of total external public debt to GDP ratio from its initial steady state. That is

R d c , t 1 = R f + v d c exp [ η d c ( d t + d c , t y t d t + d c y ) ] , ( 41 )

where Rf is a (constant) risk-free world interest rate, yt is total GDP and udc and ηdc are structural parameters. We now proceed to describe the spending variables and the resource fund that also appear in the budget constraint (39).

1. Government Purchases

Government purchases comprise government consumption (gtC) and public investment (gtI). Like private consumption, government expenditure, gtgtC+gtI, is also a CES aggregate of domestic traded goods, gT,t and domestic nontraded goods, gN,t. Thus,

g t = [ ν t 1 χ ( g N , t ) χ 1 χ + ( 1 ν t ) 1 χ ( g T , t ) χ 1 χ ] χ χ 1 , ( 42 )

where νt is the weight given to nontraded goods in government purchases. We assume that government purchases have the same intra-temporal elasticity of substitution χ > 0 as that of private consumption.

Minimizing total government expenditures ptGgt=pN,tgN,t+stgT,t, subject to the government consumption basket (42), yields the following public demand functions for each good:

g N , t = ν t ( p N , t p t G ) χ g t , j = N , T , ( 43 )

and

g T , t = ( 1 ν t ) ( s t p t G ) χ g t , j = N , T , ( 44 )

where ptG is the government consumption price index in terms of units of the consumption basket, defined as

p t G = [ ν t p N 1 χ + ( 1 ν t ) s t 1 χ ] 1 1 χ . ( 45 )

Note that νt is time-varying. As we focus on the effects of additional government spending in the form of government investment, the weight given to nontraded goods for the additional government spending, νg, can differ from its steady state value, ν, i.e.,

ν t = ( p G g ) ν + ( p t G g t P G g ) ν g p t G g t . ( 46 )

2. Public Investment Efficiency, Absorptive Capacity Constraints, and Public Capital Depreciation

Public investment features inefficiency and absorptive capacity constraints. Hulten (1996) and Pritchett (2000) argue that often high productivity of infrastructure can coexist with very low returns on public investment in developing countries, because of inefficiencies in investing. As a result, public investment spending does not necessarily increase the stock of productive capital and, therefore, growth. Similarly, absorptive capacity constraints related to technical capacity and waste and leakage of resources in the investment process—which impact project selection, management, and implementation—can have long lasting negative effects on growth, as suggested by Esfahani and Ramirez (2003), among others.

To reflect these inefficiencies and constraints, we assume that effective investment g˜tI(γ¯tGI) is a function of the public investment growth rate (γ¯tGI) relative to its steady state value, and γ¯tGIgtIgI1. Specifically,

g ˜ t I = { ε ¯ g t I , ε ¯ ( 1 + γ ¯ G I ) g I + ε ( γ ¯ t G I ) [ 1 + γ ¯ t G I γ ¯ t G I ] g I , if  γ ¯ t G I γ ¯ t G I if γ ¯ t G I > γ ¯ t G I } , ( 47 )

where ε¯[0,1] represents steady-state efficiency and ε(γ¯tGI)(0,1] governs the efficiency of the portion of public investment exceeding a threshold γ¯GI, in percent deviation from the initial steady state. We assume that ε(γ¯tGI) takes the following specification:

ε ( γ ¯ t G I ) = exp [ ζ ε ( γ ¯ t G I γ ¯ t G I ) ] ε ¯ . ( 48 )

In other words, if the growth rate of government investment expenditure from the initial steady state exceeds γ¯GI, then the efficiency of the additional investment decreases, reflecting the presence of absorptive capacity constraints. The severity of these constraints is governed by the parameter ςε ∈ [0, ∞).

The law of motion of public capital is described as

k G , t = ( 1 δ G , t ) k G , t 1 + g ˜ t I , ( 49 )

where δG,t is a time-varying depreciation rate of public capital in the spirit of Rioja (2003). Since insufficient maintenance can shorten the life of existing capital, we assume that the depreciation rate increases proportionally to the extent to which effective investment fails to maintain existing capital.10 Therefore

δ G , t = { ϕ δ G δ G k G , t 1 g ˜ t I , if  g ˜ t I < δ G k G , t 1 ρ δ δ G , t 1 + ( 1 ρ δ ) δ G , if  g ˜ t I δ G k G , t 1 } , ( 50 )

where δG is the steady-state depreciation rate, ϕ ≥ 0 determines the extent to which poor maintenance produces additional depreciation, and ρδ ∈ [0,1) controls its persistence.

3. The Resource Fund

We introduce a resource fund in the model along the lines of Berg et al. (2013). A resource windfall is defined as resource revenues that are above their initial steady-state level, i.e., ttOtO. Let ft* be the foreign financial asset value in a resource fund. Each period, the resource fund earns interest income st(Rrf1)ft1*, with a constant gross real interest rate Rrf. The resource fund evolves by the process

f t * f * = max { f f l o o r f * , ( f t 1 * f * ) + f i n , t s t f o u t , t s t } , ( 51 )

where fin,t represents the total fiscal inflow, fout,t represents the total fiscal outflow, and ffloor ≥ 0 is a lower bound for the fund that the government chooses to maintain. If no minimum savings are required in a resource fund, the lower bound can be set at zero. At each point in time, if the fiscal inflow exceeds the fiscal outflow, the value of the resource fund increases.11 Instead, if the resource fund is above ffloor, any fiscal outflow that exceeds the fiscal inflow is absorbed by a withdrawal from the fund. Whenever the floor of a resource fund binds, the fiscal gap is covered via borrowing and/or increases in taxes (on consumption and factor incomes) or cuts in government non-capital expenditures (government consumption and transfers). Later we explicitly define fin,t and fout,t and explain in detail the mechanism to close a fiscal gap.

One of the purposes of the model is to analyze the effects of investing a resource windfall. The simulations presented in this paper focus on two investing approaches: the spend-as-you-go approach and the delinked investing approach. These approaches are formulated as follows.

  • Spend-as-you-go approach (SAYG). With spend-as-you-go, the resource fund stays at its initial level (ft*=f*,t), and the entire windfall is spent in public investment projects:

    p t G g t I p G g I = ( t t O s t t O s ) . ( 52 )
  • A delinked investment approach. With delinked investing, a scaling-up path of public investment is specified as a second-order delay function,

    g t I g I = 1 + [ 1 + exp ( k 1 t ) 2 exp ( k 2 t ) ] g n s s I , ( 53 )

    where gnssI is the scaling-up investment target expressed as percentage deviation from the initial steady state, k1 > 0 represents the speed of adjustment of public investment to the new level, and k2k1 represents the degree of investment frontloading. In particular, if k1 = k2 = 0, public investment stays at its original steady-state level, i.e., gtI=gIt. If instead k1 → ∞, public investment jumps to the new steady-state level immediately. Lastly, if k2 = k1, public investment increases gradually and is not frontloaded. The mechanics of this functional form on public investment trajectories are illustrated in Figures 1 and 2.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Different speeds of investment scaling-ups. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Different degrees of frontloading in investment scaling-ups. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

In addition to the above two approaches, the MATLAB code associated with the model allows for analyzing an exogenously specified public investment path, either proposed by authorities or recommended by a country team.

4. The Fiscal Gap

We borrow the structure of the fiscal gap and the mechanisms to cover it, from Buffie et al. (2012). But here we increase the number of fiscal instruments and take into account the dynamics of the fund. Given the paths of public investment, concessional borrowing, and foreign grants, algebraic manipulation of the budget constraint of the government (39) allows us to rewrite it as follows:

g a p t = f o u t , t f i n , t + s t ( f t * f t 1 * ) , ( 54 )

where

g a p t = Δ b t + s t Δ d c , t + ( τ t C τ C ) c t + ( τ t L τ L ) w t L t p t G ( g t C g C ) ( z t z ) , ( 55 )
f i n , t = τ C c t + τ L w t L t + ( 1 ϑ K ) τ K ( r T , t K k T , t 1 + r N , t K k N , t 1 ) + t O , t + μ k G , t 1 + s t a t * + s t g r t * + s t ( R R F 1 ) f t 1 * + s t Δ d t , ( 56 )

and

f o u t , t = p t G g t I + p t G g C + z + ( s t R d 1 ) d t 1 + ( R d c , t 1 1 ) s t d c , t 1 + ( R t 1 1 ) b t 1 . ( 57 )

Equation (55) says that covering the fiscal gap entails domestic and/or external commercial borrowing or adjustments in various fiscal instruments. By combining equations (51) and (54), we can see that if ft*>ffloor, then gapt = 0; i.e., the resource fund absorbs any fiscal gap and no fiscal policy adjustments are needed. On the other hand, when ft*=ffloor, the gap satisfies gapt > 0 and it needs to be covered by the fiscal adjustments to be explained next.

5. Covering the Fiscal Gap

The split of government borrowing between domestic and external commercial debt, to help cover the gap, occurs according to the following simple rule:

ϰ Δ b t = ( 1 ϰ ) s t Δ d c , t , ( 58 )

where ϰ ∈ [0,1]. Given concessional borrowing and grants, this rule accommodates the limiting cases of (i) supplementing this concessional borrowing with borrowing exclusively in domestic markets (ϰ = 0) and (ii) supplementing concessional borrowing with accumulating more external commercial debt (ϰ = 1).

Debt sustainability, however, requires that eventually revenues have to increase and/or expenditures have to be cut in order to cover the entire gap. To calculate the debt stabilizing (target) values of (i) the consumption tax rate, (ii) the labor income tax rate, (iii) government consumption, and (iv) transfers, the following equations are used:

τ target , t C = τ C + λ 1 g a p t c t , ( 59 )
τ target , t L = τ L + λ 2 g a p t w t L t , ( 60 )
g target, t C = g + λ 3 g a p t p t G , ( 61 )

and

z target , t = z + λ 4 g a p t , ( 62 )

where λi, i = 1, …, 4 split the fiscal burden across the different fiscal instruments, satisfying Σi=14λi=1. Tax rates and expenditure items are then determined according to the policy reaction functions

τ t C = min { τ rule , t C , τ ceiling C } , ( 63 )
τ t L = min { τ rule , t L , τ ceiling L } , ( 64 )
g t C g C = max { g rule , t C g C , g floor C } , ( 65 )

and

z t z = max { z rule , t z , z floor } , ( 66 )

where τceilingC and τceilingL are the maximum levels of the tax rates that can be implemented, and gfloorC and zfloor are minimum deviations of government consumption and transfer from their initial steady-state values. All these ceilings and floors are determined exogenously and reflect policy adjustment constraints that governments may face. In turn, τrule,tC,τrule,tL,grule,tC, and zrule,t are determined by the following fiscal rules,

τ rule , t C = τ t 1 C + ζ 1 ( τ target , t C τ t 1 C ) + ζ 2 ( x t 1 x ) , with  ζ 1 , ζ 2 > 0 , ( 67 )
τ rule , t L = τ t 1 L + ζ 3 ( τ target , t L τ t 1 L ) + ζ 4 ( x t 1 x ) , with  ζ 3 , ζ 4 > 0 , ( 68 )
g rule , t C g C = g t 1 C g C + ζ 5 ( g target , t C g t 1 C ) g C ζ 6 ( x t 1 x ) , with  ζ 5 , ζ 6 > 0 , ( 69 )

and

z rule , t z = z t 1 z + ζ 7 ( z target , t z t 1 ) z ζ 8 ( x t 1 x ) , with  ζ 7 , ζ 8 > 0 , ( 70 )

where ζ‘s control the speed of fiscal adjustments, and xtbt+stdc,tyt is the sum of domestic and external commercial debt as a share of GDP.

D. Identities and Market Clearing Conditions

To close the model, the goods market clearing condition and the balance of payment conditions are imposed. The market clearing condition for nontradaed goods is

y N , t = φ p N , t x ( c t + i N , t + i T , t ) + v t ( p N , t p t G ) x g t . ( 71 )

The balance of payment condition corresponds to

c a t d S t = g r t * Δ f t * + Δ d t + Δ d c , t + Δ b t * , ( 72 )

where catd is the current account deficit

c a t d = c t + i N , t + i T , t + p t G g t + Θ t O P T * y t s t r m t * + ( R d 1 ) s t d t 1 + ( R d c , t 1 1 ) s t d c , t 1 + ( R t 1 * 1 ) s t b t 1 * ( R R F 1 ) s t f t 1 * . ( 73 )

III. Calibration

The model is calibrated to an average LIC, which is a assumed to start its exploitation on liquefied natural gas (LNG). Other types of commodities and other stages of exploitations can be accommodated by imposing an exogenous path of resource quantities and prices. The model is at the annual frequency. Table 1 summarizes the baseline calibration, which is explained as follows.

Table 1.

Baseline calibration

article image
  • National accounting. To reflect LIC averages of the last decade in the IMF World Economic Outlook database, trade balance is set at 6 percent of GDP, government consumption and public investment are set at 14 and 6 percent of GDP, respectively, and private investment is set at 15 percent of GDP. We choose the shares of traded goods to be 50 percent in private consumption and 40 percent in government purchases, as government consumption typically have a larger component of nontraded goods than private consumption. Since the economy is at the early stages of exploitation, the share of natural resources is assumed to be only 1 percent of GDP at the initial steady state.

  • Assets, debt and grants. We assume that government savings are small initially, only 1 percent of GDP (RFshare = 0.01). For government domestic debt, concessional debt and grants, we rely on LIC averages of the last decade as in Buffie et al. (2012). This implies bshare = 0.20, dshare = 0.50, and grshare = 0.04. To highlight the financial constraints faced by LICs in international capital markets, we set bshare*=0 and dc, share = 0.

  • Interest rates. We set the subjective discount rate ϱ such that the real annual interest rate on domestic debt (R – 1) is 10 percent. Consistent with stylized facts, domestic debt is assumed to be more costly than external commercial debt. We fix the real annual risk-free interest rate (Rf – 1) at 4 percent. The premium parameter vdc is chosen such that the real interest rate on external commercial debt (Rdc – 1) is 6 percent, and the real interest rate paid on concessional loans (Rd – 1) is 0 percent, as in Buffie et al. (2012). We assume no additional risk premium in the baseline calibration, implying ηdc = 0. The parameter u is chosen to have R = R* in the steady state, required by (13) and (14). Based on the average real return of the Norwegian Government Pension Fund from 1997 to 2011 (Gros and Mayer (2012)), the annual real return on international financial assets in the resource fund (RRF – 1) is set at 2.7 percent.

  • Private production. Consistent with the evidence on Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) surveyed in Buffie et al. (2012), the labor income shares in the nontraded and traded good sectors correspond to αN = 0.45 and αT = 0.60. In both sectors private capital depreciates at an annual rate of 10 percent (δN = δT = 0.10). Following Berg et al. (2013), we assume a minor degree of learning-by-doing externality in the traded good sector (ρYT = ρZT = 0.10). Also as in Berg et al. (2010), investment adjustment costs are set to κN = κT = 25.

  • Households preferences. The coefficient of risk aversion σ = 2.94 implies an inter-temporal elasticity of substitution of 0.34, which is the average LIC estimate according to Ogaki et al. (1996). We assume a low Frisch labor elasticity of 0.10 (ψ = 10), similar to the estimate of wage elasticity of working in rural Malawi (Goldberg, 2011). The labor mobility parameter ρ is set to 1 (Horvarth, 2000), and the elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods is χ = 0.44, following Stockman and Tesar (1995). To capture limited access to international capital markets, we set η = 1 as in Buffie et al. (2012).

  • Measure of intertempotal optimizing households. Since a large proportion of households in LICs are liquidity constrained, we pick ω = 0.40, implying that 60 percent of households are rule-of-thumb. Depending on the degree of financial development of a country, the measure of intertemporal optimizing households can be lower than 40 percent in some SSA countries. Based on data collected in 2011, Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper (2012) report that on average only 24 percent of the adults in SSA countries have an account in a formal financial institution.

  • Mining. Resource production shocks are assumed to be persistent with ρyo = 0.90. Based on Hamilton’s (2009) estimates, we assume resource prices follow a random walk so ρpo = 1. The royalty tax rate τO is set such that the ratio of natural resource revenue to total revenue at the peak of natural resource production is substantial, almost 50 percent of total revenues. In this case τO = 0.65. When applying the model to individual countries, the resource tax rate should be calibrated to match the share of resource revenue in total revenues in the data.

  • Tax rates. Consistently with data collected by the International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation in 2005-06, the steady-state taxes on consumption, labor and capital are chosen so that τC = 0.10, τL = 0.15, and τK = 0.20, respectively. This combination of tax rates and the implied inefficiency in revenue mobilization implies a non-resource revenue of around 18 percent of GDP at the initial steady state.

  • Fiscal rules. We impose a non-negativity constraint for the stabilization fund by setting ffloor = 0. In the baseline calibration, fiscal instruments do not have floors or ceilings. This translates in setting, for instance, gfloorC=zfloor=100000 and τceilingC=τceilingL=100000. The baseline calibration also implies that the whole fiscal adjustment takes place through changes in external commercial borrowing and consumption taxes. This is achieved by setting κ = λ1 = 1, λ2 = λ3 = λ4 = 0, ζ3 = ζ5 = ζ7 = 1, and ζ4 = ζ6 = ζ8 = 0 in the fiscal rules. To smooth tax changes, we choose an intermediate adjustment of the consumption tax rate relative to its target (ζ1 = 0.5) and a low responsiveness of the consumption tax rate to the debt-to-GDP ratio (ζ2 = 0.001). The selection of values for these policy parameters should be guided by the policy scenario that the team wants to simulate as well as by what they consider feasible as a fiscal adjustment.

  • Public investment. Public investment efficiency is set to 50 percent (ε¯ = 0.5), following Pritchett’s (2000) estimates for SSA countries. The annual depreciation rate for public capital is 7 percent (δG = 0.07). The home bias for government purchases ν and for investment spending above the initial steady-state level νg are 0.6 and 0.4, respectively. The smaller degree of home bias in additional spending reflects that most of the investment goods are imported in LICs. The output elasticity to public capital αG is set at 0.15, implying a marginal net return of public capital of 28 percent at the initial steady state. This is in the high end of the range of returns reported by Buffie et al. (2012). The severity of public capital depreciation corresponds to ϕ = 1 and the change in the depreciation rate of public capital is assumed to be a persistent process by setting ρδ = 0.8. In the baseline, absorptive capacity constraints start binding when public investment rises above 75 percent from its initial steady state (γ¯GI=0.75). The calibration of absorptive capacity constraints with ς = 25 implies that the average investment efficiency approximately halves to around 25 percent when public investment spikes to around 200 percent from its initial steady state. For illustrative purposes, in the delinked investment approach, we set the planned long-term scaling up of investment such that public investment at the new steady state is 80 percent higher than at the initial steady state (gnssI=0.80).

IV. Scaling up Public Investment with a Resource Windfall

The hypothetical scenarios we analyze assume that the economy discovers a sizable reserve of natural gas, and that production will reach full capacity several years later. With formidable development needs, the government plans to start investment before resource exploitation is fully in place. To do this, we assume the government uses the prospected natural resource revenues as a collateral to borrow commercially, creating challenges to ensure fiscal sustainability and macroeconomic stability.

In the baseline scenario, the production of LNG increases gradually to reach full capacity by 2021 and then starts to decline after 2035. At peak, we assume a production of about 1500 millions of cubic feet per year. For the initial years of simulations, we use the oil price forecast per barrel available in the World Economic Outlook of the IMF, multiplied by the conversion factor for full oil parity (0.1724), which yields the price in dollars per million of BTUs. The projection of the LNG price in the baseline scenario assumes a non-volatile path, fluctuating around the mean price. The adverse scenario assumes that from 2025 onwards, the resource revenue quickly declines, due to both reduced production quantity and large negative shocks to LNG prices.

A. The Spend-As-You-Go Approach versus the Delinked Investment Approach

We begin the analysis of policy scenarios by considering two investment approaches and assuming there is no commercial or domestic borrowing to finance public investment increases. With the spend-as-you-go (SAYG) approach, the government spends all of its resource windfall in public investment each period and the stabilization fund remains at its initial steady state, as analyzed in Richmond et al. (2013) for Angola. Policymakers faced with impoverished and demanding populations could easily find the SAYG approach appealing because of its related immediate increase in consumption and investment. With the delinked investment approach, the government combines investment spending with savings in a resource fund, consistent with the sustainable investing approach analyzed in Berg et al. (2013). We assume both approaches resort only to the consumption tax rate to close any fiscal gap by setting λ1 = 1,: λ2 = λ3 = λ4 = 0, ζ1 = ζ3 = ζ5 = ζ7 = 1, and ζ2 = ζ4 = ζ6 = ζ8 = 0 in the fiscal rules.

Figures 3 and 4 compare the two investment approaches under two resource revenue scenarios: the dotted-dashed lines refer to the SAYG approach and the solid lines correspond to the delinked investment approach. With SAYG, public investment does not increase much because of the initial low LNG production. With the delinked approach, public investment scales up gradually with no overshooting (k1 = 0.20, k2 = 0.20). Since the scaling-up is deliberately chosen to be commensurate with the magnitudes of resource revenues, the investment path does not require a large increase in tax rates.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Spend-as-you-go vs. delinked investment approach: no additional commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Spend-as-you-go vs. delinked investment approach (continued): no additional commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

The main difference between the two investment approaches is that the SAYG approach results in a volatile path for public investment, mirroring the volatility of resource revenue flows. Fiscal volatility is translated into macroeconomic instability as shown by fluctuations in macro variables. In contrast, the delinked approach can build up a fiscal buffer and maintain a stable spending path without major fiscal adjustments. Comparing the two scenarios of resource revenues, the economy can build a bigger stabilization fund (of around 150 percent of GDP) under the baseline scenario than under the adverse scenario of rapidly declining resource revenues—it only peaks at around 25 percent of GDP.

Another concern with the SAYG approach is the reduced public investment efficiency during the years when resource revenue flows accelerate. Sudden accelerations in public investment expenditures make the economy more prone to bumping into absorptive capacity constraints, translating into lower efficiency. As shown in Figure 3, with the SAYG approach, public investment accelerates to an extent that average investment efficiency drops from a baseline value of 50 percent down to almost 25 percent. Also, when public investment significantly drops (due to a sharp decline in the natural resource revenue), failure to maintain public capital leads to a higher depreciation rate than the steady-state level.

In the baseline scenario without negative shocks, SAYG can perform reasonably well as it leads to a higher accumulation of public capital than the delinked approach. As a result, non-resource output, private consumption and investment may reach a higher level than that with a delinked approach. However, in the presence of negative shocks to the resource revenue, as captured under the adverse scenario, the delinked approach performs much better, leading to overall more public capital, real non-resource output, private consumption, and investment. Moreover, in both scenarios, a delinked approach delivers a more resilient and stable growth in non-resource GDP and a less volatile real exchange rate. The greater real exchange appreciation induced by SAYG (in periods of particularly high resource revenue) leads to greater negative learning-by-doing externalities and thus a larger decline in traded output, and thus more severe Dutch disease effects.

Lastly, the two revenue scenarios assume that the reserve of natural gas will deplete after 2040, and this has important consequences for public capital under SAYG. If the public investment level cannot be maintained (like with SAYG), public capital built with the resource windfall eventually declines back to the initial steady-state level. Consequently, the growth benefits of more public capital also diminish. Thus, when determining a scaling-up magnitude, financing needs to sustain capital should be accounted for to ensure long-lasting growth benefits from a resource windfall.

B. Front Loading Public Investment with Commercial Borrowing

Under the constraints of no additional borrowing, any front-loading of public investment is not fiscally feasible unless the government chooses to sharply increase taxes (or significantly cut non-capital expenditures). In this section, we analyze the effects of a front-loaded investment path financed jointly by resource revenues and commercial borrowing.

Figures 5 to 7 compare the public investment effects under different degrees of frontloading. All three investment paths eventually reach a long-run investment level 80 percent higher than the level in the initial steady state (k1 = 0.20). The dotted lines represent a conservative path (k2 = 0.10), in which public investment is scaled up slowly enough, so it does not require significant debt accumulation when LNG production is low initially. The solid lines represent a gradual path (k2 = 0.20) with a small degree of frontloading. The dashed lines correspond to an aggressive path (k2 = 0.70), which generates a pronounced overshooting of public investment. During the two peak years, public investment is around 100 percent from the initial steady-state level.

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Various degrees of investment frontloading: external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

Figure 6.
Figure 6.

Various degrees of investment frontloading (continued): external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

Figure 7.
Figure 7.

Various degrees of investment frontloading (concluded): external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

In terms of fiscal adjustment, we assume that the government makes use of external commercial borrowing (ϰ = 1) to close the fiscal gap when the stabilization fund reaches its lower bound. Also, the consumption tax rate is used as the adjustment instrument that stabilizes debt in the long run (λ1 = 1).12 Since tax collection in LICs is generally weak, we assume there exists a ceiling for the consumption tax rate at 12.5 percent and it is difficult to increase the tax rate by more that 2.5 percentage points in the short run.

In both resource revenue scenarios (baseline and adverse), front loading investment results in no savings in the stabilization fund and rising public debt. As expected, the debt increase is most pronounced with the aggressive investment path under the adverse scenario. In contrast, with either the conservative or gradual path, public debt as a share of GDP does not increase significantly. Also, the increase in the consumption tax rate is smaller than that with the aggressive path. Moreover, the conservative path is able to accumulate some savings in the resource fund even under the adverse scenario.

When the economy can resort to external commercial borrowing, front-loading public investment can advance the benefits of expected resource windfalls, relative to the case with no borrowing. If the degree of front-loading is not excessive and/or the economy does not experience particularly bad shocks, public debt can be stabilized despite taxing constraints. In this respect, the model can serve as a tool to determine a proper front-loading degree under various assumptions on the rate of return to public capital, fiscal policy, and projections of resource revenues. Among the three investment paths analyzed here, the aggressive path signals a likely unfeasible path, since government debt appears to be on an explosive path under the adverse scenario.

C. Domestic versus External Commercial Borrowing

Instead of using external commercial borrowing, the government can use domestic borrowing to finance an investment scaling-up. Figure 8 compares the macroeconomic effects of the two borrowing strategies (domestic versus external commercial borrowing). The solid lines refer to domestic borrowing (ϰ = 0), and the dotted-dashed lines reflect external borrowing (ϰ = 1). The public investment path is the same as the aggressive frontloading path depicted in Figure 5.

Figure 8.
Figure 8.

Domestic vs. external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

The most important difference is that external borrowing brings in additional financial resources, while domestic borrowing shifts domestic resources away from the private sector into the public sector. Because of this and the fact that the real interest rate rises more with domestic borrowing, private investment is crowded out more with domestic borrowing. And since the amount of domestic borrowing is higher under the adverse scenario, the crowding-out effect is more pronounced than that under the baseline scenario. The higher interest rate associated with domestic borrowing also feeds into higher interest payments, more accumulation of public debt, and on average higher consumption tax rates to stabilize debt. This has important consequences for debt sustainability under the adverse scenario: with external commercial borrowing, public debt remains stable; while with domestic borrowing, public debt becomes unsustainable.13

D. Public Investment Efficiency, Return on Public Capital, and Debt Sustainability

Among various aspects of the model, the public investment efficiency and the return to public capital are particularly important in shaping the macroeconomic effects of public investment. Figure 9 reports the effects of improving the investment efficiency () and the output elasticity with respect to public capital (αG). It considers three different assumptions. The solid lines reflect the baseline calibration ( = 0.5 and αG = 0.15); the dotted-dashed lines assume efficiency increases from 0.5 to 0.7 over time; and the dotted lines correspond to improving efficiency together with αG = 0.18. The figure is depicted for the case of external commercial borrowing and the adverse natural resource scenario.

Figure 9.
Figure 9.

Increasing public investment efficiency and/or higher return to public capital: external commercial borrowing and adverse natural resource scenario. X-axis is in years.

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2014, 050; 10.5089/9781475515459.001.A001

As shown in Figure 9, improving efficiency and/or raising the return on public capital deliver better macroeconomic outcomes than those from the baseline calibration. Higher efficiency generates more public capital for a given investment level, which then helps produce more non-resource output, leading to higher income and, therefore, more consumption. If public capital also becomes more productive, these positive macroeconomic effects are further amplified. In the example provided for the combined changes (dotted lines), the additional growth rate in non-resource GDP is doubled in the long run.

On the fiscal side, government debt is on an explosive path with the baseline calibration, given the adverse natural resource path. However, with the efficiency improvement, the same investment path turns out to be fiscally sustainable as the additional positive effect on non-resource GDP growth is capable of generating enough non-resource revenues that close the fiscal gap. Thus, we can see that for the same resource revenue flows and same investment paths, different investment efficiencies and returns to public capital can easily change the outlook of debt sustainability.

V. Conclusions

This paper presents the DIGNAR model that can be used to assess debt sustainability and growth effects of public investment scaling-ups in resource-abundant developing countries. The model has most of the relevant developing country features of the frameworks developed in Buffie et al. (2012) and Berg et al. (2013), including public investment inefficiencies, absorptive capacity constraints, and learning-by-doing externalities that can deliver Dutch disease effects. But it also introduces novel features especially in the fiscal policy structure. DIGNAR can accommodate flexible fiscal arrangements, with domestic and external commercial borrowing as options to close the fiscal gap in the short-to-medium run, and several fiscal instruments (taxes and expenditures rules) to maintain debt sustainability in the long run. The model also has a resource fund that can be used as a fiscal buffer as well as a saving device—a minimal level of savings greater than zero can be imposed.

To illustrate how to use DIGNAR in policy analysis, the paper calibrates the model to an average LIC and constructs some hypothetical and stylized resource revenue scenarios, including an adverse scenario of declining revenues. It then discusses the macroeconomic effects of different investment approaches (spend-as-you-go and delinked investment) under different borrowing schemes as well as different frontloading degrees of public investment. The simulation exercises show how DIGNAR can serve as an analytical tool to search for the scaling-up magnitude of public investment that can sustain public capital—financed with both resource windfalls and borrowing—while still being consistent with debt sustainability.

The analysis reveals the importance of considering country-specific information that can be mapped into parameter values of the model. When this is not possible for some parameters, sensitivity analysis can be conducted for these parameters, as the paper shows for the public investment efficiency and the return to public capital under a negative resource revenue scenario. Also, the analysis only focuses on two resource revenue scenarios, but in reality the degree of resource revenue uncertainty can be greater than what is depicted here. One way to address this issue is to conduct simulations under a wide range of resource revenue scenarios that account for the historical resource price volatility and likely production profiles. The probability of an unfavored outcome associated with an investment path can then serve as an indicator whether a proposed investment path is overly aggressive (see the analysis for Angola in Richmond et al. (2013)).14

DIGNAR is an integrated macroeconomic framework that may be useful in constructing the scenarios necessary for debt sustainability analysis of resource-rich developing countries. Judgment is still critical to calibrate, construct and interpret these scenarios. But DIGNAR can help make explicit the assumptions underlying the projections, organize policy discussions based on different simulated scenarios, apply empirical information, and allow more systematic risk assessments. In this regard, DIGNAR can be used to complement the IMF-WB DSF, when applied to natural resource-rich developing countries.

VI. References

  • Adam, C. and D. Bevan, 2006, “Aid and the Supply Side: Public Investment, Export Performance, and Dutch Disease in Low-Income Countries,The World Bank Economic Review, vol. 20(2), pp. 261290.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adam, C. and D. Bevan, 2013, “Public Investment, Public Finance, and Growth: The Impact of Distortionary Taxation, Recurrent Costs, and Incomplete Appropriability,Manuscript, University of Oxford.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agénor, P. R., 2012, Public Capital, Growth and Welfare: Analytical Foundations for Public Policy, 1st edition, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., J. Gottschalk, R. Portillo, and L.-F. Zanna, 2010, “The Macroeconomics of Medium-Term Aid Scaling-Up Scenario,IMF Working Paper 10/160, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., R, Portillo, S.-C. Yang, and L.-F. Zanna, 2013, “Public Investment in Resource-Abundant Developing Countries,IMF Economic Review, vol. 61(1), pp. 92129.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., S.-C. Yang, and L.-F. Zanna, 2014, “Modeling African Economies: A DSGE Approach,forthcoming in The Oxford Handbook of Africa and Economics, edited by C. Mongo and J. Y. Lin, Oxford U.K.: Oxford University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buffie, E. F., A. Berg, C. Pattillo, R. Portillo, and L.-F. Zanna, 2012, “Public Investment, Growth, and Debt Sustainability: Putting Together the Pieces,IMF Working Paper 12/144, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carrasco, E. R., 1999, “The 1980’s: The Debt Crisis and the Lost Decade9 Transntl L. & Contemp. Probs. 119.

  • Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C.L. Evans, 2005, “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy,Journal of Political Economy, vol. 113, pp. 145.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Klapper, L., 2012, “Measuring Financial Inclusion: The Global Findex,World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6025, the World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eaton, J., 2002, “The HIPC Initiative: The Goals, Additionality, Eligibility, and Debt Sustainability,Manuscript, Operations Evaluation Department, the World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Esfahani, H. S. and M. T. Ramirez, 2003, “Institutions, Infrastructure, and Economic Growth,Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 70(2), pp. 443477.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gelb, A. H., 1988, Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse? A World Bank Research Publication, Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

  • Goldberg, J., 2011, “Kwacha Gonna Do? Experimental Evidence about Labor Supply in Rural Malawi,Manuscript, Economics Department, University of Maryland.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gros, D. and T. Mayer, 2012, “A Sovereign Wealth Fund to Lift Germany’s Curse of Excess Savings,CEPS Policy Brief No. 280, August 29, Center for European Policy Studies.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hamilton, J. D., 2009, “Understanding Crude Oil Prices,Energy Journal, vol. 30(2), pp. 179206.

  • Hjertholm, P., 2003, “Theoretical and Empirical Foundations of HIPC Debt Sustainability Targets,Journal of Development Studies, vol.39(6), pp. 67100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Horvath, M., 2000, “Sectoral Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations,Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 45(1), pp. 69106.

  • Hulten, C., 1996, “Infrastructure Capital and Economic Growth: How Well You Use It May Be More Important Than How Much You Have,NBER Working Paper, No. 5847.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2012a, “Macroeconomic Policy Frameworks for Resource-Rich Developing Countries,IMF Policy Paper No. SM/12/224, August International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, P., 1987, “The Narrow Moving Band, the Dutch Disease, and the Competitive Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on Trade in the Presence of Dynamic Scale Economies,Journal of Development Economics, vol. 27(1-2), pp. 4155.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Manzano, O. and R. Rigobon, 2007, “Resource Curse or Debt Overhang. In Natural Resources: Neither Curse nor Destiny,” ed. D. Lederman, W. F. Maloney. The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Matsuyama, K., 1992, “Agricultural Productivity, Comparative Advantage and Economic Growth,Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 58(2), pp. 317334.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Melina, G. and Xiong, Y., 2013, “Natural Gas, Public Investment and Debt Sustainability in Mozambique,IMF Working Paper 13/261, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Minasyan, Gohar and Yang, S.-C. S., 2013, “Leveraging Oil Wealth for Development in Kazakhstan: Opportunities and Challenges,Selected Isses, IMF Country Report No. 13/291, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogaki, M., Ostry, J., and Reinhart, C., 1996, “Saving Behavior in Low- and Middle-Income Developing Countries,IMF Staff Papers vol. 43, pp. 3871.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pritchett, L., 2000, “The Tyranny of Concepts: CUDIE (Cumulated, Depreciated, Investment Effort) is Not Capital,Journal of Economic Growth vol. 5, 361384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Richmond, C., Yackovlev, I., Yang, S.-C., 2013, “Investing Volatile Oil Revenues in Capital-Scarce Economies: An Application to Angola,IMF Working Paper 13/147, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rioja, F., 2003, “Filling Potholes: Macroeconomic Effects of Maintenance versus New Investments in Public Infrastructure,Journal of Public Economics, vol. 87(9-10), pp. 22812304.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, J., 2005, The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time, 1st edition, New York: Penguin Press.

  • Sachs, J.D. and A. M. Warner, 1995, revised 1997, 1999, “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth,National Bureau of Economic Research Working paper No. 5398, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, J.D. and A.M. Warner, 1999, “The Big Push, Natural Resource Booms and Growth,Journal of Development Economics, vol. 59, 4376.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schmitt-Grohe, S. and M. Uribe, 2003, “Closing Small Open Economy Models,Journal of International Economics, vol. 61(1), pp. 163185.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stockman, A.C. and Tesar, L.L., 1995, “Tastes and Technology in a Two-Country Model of the Business Cycle: Explaining International Comovements,American Economic Review, vol. 85(1), pp. 16885.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Torvik, R., 2001, “Learning by Doing and the Dutch Disease,European Economic Review, vol. 45(2), pp. 285306.

  • van der Ploeg, F., 2011a, “Fiscal Policy and Dutch Disease,International Economics and Economic Policy, vol. 8, pp. 121131.

  • van der Ploeg, F., 2011b, “Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?,Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 49(2), pp. 366420.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • van der Ploeg, F. 2012, “Bottlenecks in Ramping up Public Investment,International Tax and Public Finance, vol. 19(4), pp. 509538.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • van der Ploeg, F. and A. J. Venables, 2013, “Absorbing a Windfall of Foreign Exchange: Dutch Disease Dynamics,Journal of Development Economics, vol. 103, pp. 229243.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • van der Ploeg, F. and S. Poelhekke, 2009, “Volatility and the Natural Resource Curse,Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 61(4), pp. 727760.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wyplosz, C., 2007, “Debt Sustainability Assessment: The IMF Approach and Alternatives,HEI Working Paper, No. 03/2007, Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
*

We are grateful to Andrew Berg, Martin Cerisola, Kamil Dybczak, Luc Moers, Catherine Pattillo, and participants in the 2013 CSAE conference at the University of Oxford for comments and suggestions. This working paper is part of a research project on macroeconomic policy in low-income countries supported by U.K.’s Department for International Development (DFID). This working paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF or of DFID. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy, or of DFID. Working Papers describe research in progress by the authors and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.

1

Sachs and Warner (1995) show that resource rich countries grow on average one percent less during the period of 1970-89 after controlling for initial income per capita, investment, openness and rule of law. In spite of many later studies supporting the existence of a natural resource curse (Sachs and Warner, 1995, 1999; van der Ploeg and Poelhekke, 2009), the empirical literature that followed pointed to mixed results, suggesting also the possibility of a natural resource “blessing” (van der Ploeg, 2011b).

2

Eaton (2002) and Hjertholm’s (2003) have raised concerns that IMF-WB’s debt projections are not derived from an integrated, internally consistent macroeconomic framework. For instance they generally do not make an explicit linkage between the public investment that the proposed nonconcessional borrowing is meant to finance and the resulting growth that should make the operation self-financing. This inflates debt indicators, such as debt-to-GDP ratios, creates a bias toward conservative borrowing limits, and can amount “to sacrificing growth to imprecisely known debt sustainability risks” (Wyplosz, 2007).

3

The Buffie et al. model has been used to complement the IMF-WB DSF. It has been applied to several countries including Burkina Faso, Cape Verde, Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana, Liberia, Rwanda, Senegal, and Togo.

4

Different from Berg et al. (2013), where the saving rate of a resource windfall into a resource fund is constant and transfers adjust to satisfy the government budget constraint, the resource fund in DIGNAR can maintain a stable fiscal regime, in which government consumption, tax rates, and transfers do not have to adjust to maintain fiscal sustainability while scaling up public investment.

5

To see the role of this feature in practice see the model application to Kazakhstan in Minasyan and Yang (2013).

6

The nominal side and New Keynesian features may be added if the model is used to study the short-run policy effects of fiscal management to resource revenue flows.

7

Because of the common wedge between tax burden imposed and tax revenues accrued to the government in developing countries, we assume that a fraction ϑK of the tax revenue related to capital income does not enter the government budget constraint. Introducing this wedge also allows us to match the observed initial low private investment flows observed in most LICs.

8

These adjustment costs also ensure stationarity in this small open economy model, as discussed in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2003).

9

See also Adam and Bevan (2006) and Torvik (2001), among others.

10

Adam and Bevan (2013) find that accounting for the operations and maintenance expenditures of installed capital is crucial for assessing the growth effects and debt sustainability of a public investment scaling-up.

11

To guarantee that the resource fund is not an explosive process, we assume that in the very long run, a small autoregressive coefficient ρf ∈ (0,1) is attached to (ft1*f*). The model is typically solved at a yearly frequency for a 1000-period horizon. The coefficient ρf is activated after the first 100 years of simulations.

12

The model allows for a flexible arrangements of using various fiscal instruments—the consumption and labor tax rates, government consumption, and transfers to households—to maintain debt sustainability. The analysis presented here uses only the consumption tax rate as an example.

13

Our simulation results appear to favor external commercial borrowing to domestic borrowing, mainly due to the reduced crowing-out effect with external borrowing. Since the model only accounts for shocks to resource prices and quantity, it does not capture the increased vulnerability from a higher stock of external debt resulting from other economic shocks. For example, an unexpected shock that depreciates the real exchange rate would expand the size of foreign liabilities, threatening debt sustainability, as the negative terms-of-trade shock analyzed in Buffie et al. (2012).

14

Work at the research department of the Fund is attempting to incorporate uncertainty about shocks and parameters more systematically in the debt sustainability model by Buffie et al. (2012), while maintaining the non-linear structure, to construct confidence bands around debt trajectories. A similar approach could in principle be taken for DIGNAR.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Debt Sustainability, Public Investment, and Natural Resources in Developing Countries: the DIGNAR Model
Author:
Mr. Giovanni Melina
,
Ms. Susan S. Yang
, and
Luis-Felipe Zanna
  • Figure 1.

    Different speeds of investment scaling-ups. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 2.

    Different degrees of frontloading in investment scaling-ups. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 3.

    Spend-as-you-go vs. delinked investment approach: no additional commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 4.

    Spend-as-you-go vs. delinked investment approach (continued): no additional commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 5.

    Various degrees of investment frontloading: external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 6.

    Various degrees of investment frontloading (continued): external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 7.

    Various degrees of investment frontloading (concluded): external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 8.

    Domestic vs. external commercial borrowing. X-axis is in years.

  • Figure 9.

    Increasing public investment efficiency and/or higher return to public capital: external commercial borrowing and adverse natural resource scenario. X-axis is in years.