Fiscal Sustainability
A 21st Century Guide for the Perplexed

Contributor Notes

Author’s E-mail Address: etanner@imf.org

This paper critically reviews recent work regarding the sustainability of public debt. It argues that Debt Sustainability Analyses (DSAs) should be more than mere mechanical simulation exercises. Instead, a DSA should be linked to some objective regarding the distribution of fiscal burdens and distortions over time (in the tradition of Barro’s 1979 tax smoothing objective). The paper discusses objective functions that yield simple and transparent fiscal policy rules.

Abstract

This paper critically reviews recent work regarding the sustainability of public debt. It argues that Debt Sustainability Analyses (DSAs) should be more than mere mechanical simulation exercises. Instead, a DSA should be linked to some objective regarding the distribution of fiscal burdens and distortions over time (in the tradition of Barro’s 1979 tax smoothing objective). The paper discusses objective functions that yield simple and transparent fiscal policy rules.

I. Introduction

The issue of fiscal sustainability has taken on special importance in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. Previously, most of the attention regarding public debt sustainability was focused on developing and emerging market countries. However, the topic is now crucial for industrialized countries that suffer from rising debt ratios (see Figure 1), stagnant output growth, unfavorable demographic trends, and liabilities passed from financial sectors.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Government Debt/GDP, Selected Countries, Weighted Average

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 089; 10.5089/9781484381991.001.A001

Country coverage/groupings: see the website for the World Economic Outlook, International Monetary Fund. Advanced economies, Euro Area, and United States: debt is reported on a net basis. Emerging / Developing countries: debt is reported on a gross basis.

What is a sustainable fiscal policy? What is a sustainable trajectory for public debt? As a prerequisite, a government must satisfy intertemporal solvency: it must raise enough resources (in present value terms) to service its obligations so as to preclude either default or restructuring. In this vein, a “sustainable policy” may be one that, if continued indefinitely and without modification, would keep the government solvent. A ‘policy’ may be defined either as some chosen primary surplus or some rule or reaction function, explicit or implicit. Alternatively, in cases of severe fiscal stress, an ‘unsustainable’ situation may be one where the primary adjustment required to avoid a debt restructuring or outright default is not feasible; conversely ‘sustainability’ would imply that the necessary adjustment is feasible.

This paper considers such definitions. The issue is approached from a positive standpoint “Is the fiscal policy of country X sustainable?” The issue is also examined from a normative perspective: “What policy should country X implement in order to assure that the trajectory of public debt is sustainable?”2

This paper is intended to be a review of recent work on debt sustainability; it is intended to cover many aspects of the topic in a comprehensive manner. The paper was developed from the author’s lectures on the topic from courses at the IMF Institute for Capacity Development. As such, the paper has a didactic flavor. However, the paper also presents some extensions of some currently used tools and indicators.

As a first step, Section II reviews some of the building blocks for debt sustainability analyses. These include the accounting identities and econometric forecasts of prospective debt trajectories that typically form the core of a Debt Sustainability Analysis (DSA).

In any analysis of debt sustainability, the size of primary surpluses (revenues minus non-interest expenditures) is critical. As Section III shows, in order to satisfy its intertemporal budget constraint without default, the government must achieve primary surpluses whose present value will be sufficient to cover its debt. Of course, governments are not always able to achieve this goal. Section IV shows how limits on the governments’ ability to run primary surpluses will determine the maximum debt ratio that a country can sustain.

In the design of fiscal policy, in addition to the size of primary surpluses, governments must have an objective as to how these primary surpluses would be distributed over time. For example, abrupt changes in the primary surplus from one period to another can introduce undue volatility into macroeconomic aggregates. Moreover, to minimize the overall losses stemming from primary surpluses (including those caused by distorting taxes), the authority should distribute primary surpluses over time in a way that equates marginal losses between periods. Section V discusses alternative specifications for objective functions (loss minimization) and their corresponding fiscal rules that will determine how quickly—if at all—the authority reduces the debt ratio.3

The loss functions in Section V are well-suited to examine fiscal policy in an uncertain environment. If the government wishes to cushion the economy from exogenous shocks to interest rates and output, its choice to reduce the debt reflects a kind of precautionary motive. Section VI presents a fiscal indicator along these lines: the target primary surplus that is required to prevent the debt from rising with a specified probability.

Section VII considers issues related to counter-cyclical borrowing over the business cycle. Critically, if potential output is not known with certainty, even if its mean is correctly estimated, a pure tax smoothing regime will lead to an upward drift in debt levels. Section VIII, extends the analysis to include prospective liabilities, including pension and health benefits and financial sector obligations. Section IX discusses the recent net worth approach to public sector sustainability (see the 2001 IMF Government Financial Statistics manual). Section X discusses non-renewable natural resources.

Section XI discusses how the Contingent Claims Approach (CCA) may be applied to public debt sustainability. The section extends recent work by Gray, Bodie, and Merton (2007) and Gray, Lim, Loukoianova, and Malone (GLLM, 2008). The framework treats the present value of primary surpluses as a volatile asset. Such volatility can reflect uncertainty regarding either the ability or the willingness of a fiscal authority to reach a stated primary surplus target. For this reason, the CCA is particularly well-suited to examine the issue of implementation risk—the probability that an authority will not follow through with a fiscal plan. This issue is discussed in both a recent issue of the IMF’s Fiscal Monitor (IMF, 2011, p. 58) and in recent papers by Ostry, Ghosh, Kim, and Qureshi (OGKQ, 2010) and Ghosh, Kim, Mendoza, Ostry, and Querishi, (GKMOQ, 2011). Section XII concludes with some reflections on how fiscal sustainability analysis has improved and how better analysis might have an impact on the policy process.

II. The Building Blocks of a Debt Sustainability Analysis (DSA)

Herein, three building blocks of a Debt Sustainability Analysis (DSA) are discussed: the one-period budget constraint, forecasts, and risk scenarios.

A. The Public Sector Budget Constraint

The base for any DSA is the debt dynamic equation—the one-period budget constraint faced by the public sector (expressed as a ratio to gross domestic product).

In any period, the stock of public liabilities bt evolves according to:4

bt=θtbt1+γtτt(1)

where,

bt = government debt as a ratio to GDP.

θt = [(1+rt)/(1+ŷt)]

rt = the real rate of interest

ŷt = the rate of growth of real GDP

γt = expenditures on goods and services as a fraction of GDP

τt = revenues as a fraction of GDP

This equation says that today’s debt ratio bt equals yesterday’s debt ratio bt-1 including both principal and interest (1+rt), but adjusted for the rate of growth of GDP (1 + ŷt), plus expenditures γt, minus tax revenues τt.5 We also assume that the mean interest rate r¯ exceeds the mean growth rate y^¯; this is the dynamic efficiency condition.6

The primary surplus is ps = τγ. The public sector is assumed to choose some target primary surplus (ratio to GDP) psTAR = τTARγTAR where τTAR is the nominal marginal tax γTAR is the agreed-upon expenditure ratio (as discussed below, this ratio may be viewed as an ex-ante commitment.)

ps=pstTAR+est(2)

In this equation, the error term est reflects short-run randomness in either the effective tax rate (changes in the efficiency of the tax system), or expenditures (unauthorized or unfulfilled planned spending), or both. Note also that, if we substitute psTAR into equation (1), we obtain a target value of debt: btTAR=E[bt|pstTAR].

B. Ad-Hoc Targets For The Public Debt and/or The Primary Surplus

The algebra that links a chosen primary surplus target psTAR and a debt target bTAR is simple. Consider a goal to either stabilize the public debt or reduce it to some target level over an N period horizon, written as:

bt+NTAR=αbt,where0<α1(3)

A strict inequality implies a goal of debt ratio reduction (not mere stabilization). In this case, Croce and Juan-Ramón (2003) show that the primary surplus must satisfy:

pstTAR(α,N)=(θ1)(αθN)(1θN)bt(4)

For the special case of debt stabilization (a constant debt ratio) (α = 1, N = 1) we call the target primary surplus pstTAR(1,1)ps*. In this case the above is reduced to:

pstTAR(1,1)=ps*=ry^1+y^bt(5)

This equation has an intuitive interpretation: in order to maintain a constant debt/GDP ratio, the primary surplus must be sufficient to cover real interest payments, minus an increment due to growth. Hence, this equation confirms that higher growth helps stabilize (or reduce) the debt ratio. The concept of a primary surplus is less widely used than the overall balance (ob). This is the measure of the deficit that is most frequently discussed in the popular press. For European Union countries, under the Maastricht treaty, the maximum deficit (originally 3 percent of GDP) refers to the overall (not the primary) balance. However, it is easy to recast these equations in terms of the more widely used overall measure. The overall balance in nominal currency may be written:

OBt=PStiBt1(6)

where i is the nominal interest rate. That is, the overall balance equals the primary surplus minus nominal (non-inflation adjusted) interest payments.7

If inflation rises, investors are compensated through higher nominal interest rates. As a fraction of GDP, the overall balance that is required to stabilize debt ob* is thus:

obt*=pst*i1+Y^bt1=Y^1+Y^bt1(7)

Even if the primary surplus must be positive to stabilize the debt, the overall balance may be in deficit—so long as growth is positive.8 However, the primary surplus ps is a more meaningful indicator of fiscal adjustment than the operational balance ob : two different countries may have the same value for ob* but different values for ps*, owing to different values of i, Ŷ, or bt-1.

C. Alternative Scenarios in a Debt Sustainability Analysis

In recent years, it has become standard to include uncertainty in a debt sustainability analysis. Consider the following simple equations for interest rates and GDP growth:

rt=r¯+ert(8)
y^t=y^¯+eyt(9)

Equation (8) says that financing by markets may be subject to random shocks or changes in risk premia. Equation (9) says that there may be shocks to the production function.

We now substitute expressions (2), (8), and (9) into debt dynamic equation (1) in order to highlight the deterministic and random components of debt accumulation:

bt=[(1+r¯+ert)/(1+y^¯+eyt)]bt1psTARest(10)

In practice, DSAs reveal potential trajectories of the public debt that are conditioned on attaining our chosen target for the primary surplus, psTAR. This is done by simulating equation (10) forward in time, incorporating assumptions about the shock terms. Typically, under a baseline scenario, all shock terms are zero. Alternative scenarios are thus illustrative ‘what if’ exercises.

In the case of the IMF Debt Sustainability Analysis Templates (IMF, 2010) that accompany most IMF country reports, it is typically assumed that the target primary surplus will be met (the error term for the primary surplus est is zero). Adverse scenarios then contemplate likely shocks to output, interest rates, or both. The adverse shocks (ert >0, eyt <0) are typically two standard deviations from their (zero) mean.

More recently, several authors have developed methods involving stochastic Monte Carlo simulations of equation (10). These simulations, which are summarized in Table 1, tell us the probability that our debt will equal or exceed some debt target bt>btTAR.

Table 1.

Summary, Recent Research on Public Debt Sustainability, Stochastic Approach

article image

Early efforts to simulate the future evolution of government debt were based on empirical estimates of interactions between fiscal and real variables (including vector autoregressions technique), which include Hunt and Drew (1998, New Zealand), Hoffmaister and others (2001, Costa Rica), and Garcia and Rigobón (2004, Brazil).9 The papers by Penalver and Thwiates (2006) and Celasun, Debrun, and Ostry (CDO, 2007) both develop a vector autoregression analysis of public debt in emerging markets. CDO includes a fiscal reaction function wherein primary surpluses respond to the debt level itself.

Both CDO and Tanner and Samake (2008, Brazil, Mexico, Turkey) simulate the primary surplus that is required to stabilize or reduce the debt for specific probabilities. For the United States, a detailed ‘fan chart’ analysis is presented by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2007). Budina and Van Wijnbergen present an analysis of Turkey’s fiscal sustainability that also includes assumptions regarding inflation and revenue from money creation. Frank and Ley (2009, Argentina, Brazil, and South Africa) depart from most of the literature by considering both regime changes (modeled by a Markov-switching routine) and abnormal distributions. More recently, Hadjenberg and Romeu (2010, Uruguay) examine the effects of parameter uncertainty (as well as shocks) on debt projections. Kawakami and Romeu (2011, Brazil) identify fiscal transmission and a fiscal policy reaction functions within a debt projection framework.

III. The Government’s Present Value Constraint: A Restatement

As a prelude to our discussion of public sector solvency over an infinite horizon, we first consider a simple two-period example. The government begins period 1 with an inherited debt of b0. We assume that the government will service its obligations in full at the end of period 2. Accordingly, the two-period budget constraint is:

θb0[ps1+ps2/θ]TAR=0(11)

where [ps1 + ps2 / θ]TAR is the targeted present value of primary surpluses. If the target is credible, market participants will expect that the debt will be fully serviced:

E[ps1+ps2/θ]=[ps1+ps2/θ]TAR(12)

where E is the expectations operator. Under full credibility, the market value of government debt will be:

b0=[θps1+ps2]TAR(13)

In this sense, ex-ante solvency is equivalent to full credibility. Of course, a condition that is similar to (11), namely

θb2[ps1+ps2/θ]=0(14)

must hold by definition (assuming that no borrowing or lending takes place after period 2). However, the public sector may not be fully credible in its intentions to pay the debt. If not,

E[ps1+ps2/θ]<[ps1+ps2/θ]TAR(15)

In this case, the initial value of the debt adjusts so as to satisfy:

b0=E[θps1+ps2](16)

The government cannot always credibly commit to fulfill its obligations. Instead, as Lucas and Stokey (1983) and others have emphasized, for some cases, the equilibrium outcome will involve some sort of default or debt restructuring—explicit or implicit. There are several mechanisms by which this may take place. These include negotiated restructuring, unilateral defaults, or inflation. Typically, none of these options are benign; governments make substantial efforts to avoid them.10

We next generalize to an infinite horizon. A government satisfies its intertemporal solvency or No Ponzi Game (NPG) condition if:

limtbt/(1+r)t+1=0(17)

Note that the debt ratio may be expressed as:

btBtYtB0(1+B^)tY0(1+Y^)t(18)

where B^ is the growth rate of nominal debt and Ŷ is the growth rate of nominal GDP. Thus, NPG is satisfied so long as (1+B^)/(1+Y^)<(1+r).11 As with the finite horizon case, condition (17) always holds ex-post. Ex-ante, the government is solvent so long as the present value of targeted primary surpluses credibly satisfies condition (17). It is possible for the debt ratio to rise B^>Y^ and still comply ex-ante with the NPG condition. However, for this to happen, the primary surplus ps must also continually rise according to a continuous fiscal rule:

psrTAR=ωTARbt1,ωTAR>0(19)

or desired response of the primary surplus to the debt. Sustainability requires ωTAR >0; this point was emphasized by Bohn (1998, 2008); more recently Escolano (2010) and Ostry and others (2010) noted that at high ratios of debt, at some point the required target primary surplus psTAR may be infeasible; we discuss this case in the next section. Importantly, a policy for which psTAR may remain constant and still satisfy the NPG condition is one of debt stabilization, namely B^=Y^. Of course, this policy implies that pstTAR=(ry^)/(1+y^)*bt.

IV. Maximum Sustainable Debt

For the average citizen of a country, it may be difficult to link in a precise way the level of debt to their own well-being. By contrast, the primary surplus is more easily understood by citizens: they directly suffer when their taxes are raised and when important expenditures are cut.12 Even so, discussions of fiscal sustainability are often phrased in terms of debt levels: “What is the maximum sustainable (or ‘tolerable’) debt level that a country can support?”13 One way to answer this question was suggested by Mendoza and Oviedo (2006) and Escolano (2010). They begin with some maximum feasible primary surplus that citizens can tolerate. We may call this level psmax. If so, the maximum debt ratio is easily obtained by inverting expression (5) and substituting in the maximum primary surplus, so as to obtain bmax

bmax=[(1+y^)/(ry^)]psmax(20)

That is, the maximum debt is simply the annuity value of the maximum primary surplus (adjusted for real GDP growth). If b > bmax a restructuring of the public debt may be a desirable outcome; the condition ps* > psmax implies that adjustment is not politically feasible.

Market participants often compare the maximum sustainable debt ratios of different countries. This framework yields a clear way to do so. Consider countries, I and II:

bmax(I)>bmax(II)(21)

This implies that,

[(1+y^I)/(rIy^I)]psImax>[(1+y^II)/(rIIy^II)]psIImax(22)

Thus, a country that grows faster, with all else equal, can sustain a higher debt ratio. Likewise, fiscal institutions matter. Countries with broader tax bases, more efficient tax administration systems, less tax evasion, and more productive expenditures (list of factors not exhaustive) can generate a higher maximum primary surplus whose impact on growth is less detrimental.14

Markets typically distinguish between countries on the basis of their institutions and their growth. Expression (22) shows that, to be credible, fiscal consolidations often must include reforms (i.e. of tax collection and administration, base broadening, and, more broadly, elimination of counterproductive regulations). Such measures can effectively raise the maximum (or ‘tolerable’) level of public debt.

V. Distributing Surpluses Over Time: A Fiscal Objective Function

The previous two sections focused on the size of the primary surpluses that the government must run in order to satisfy its in—tertemporal constraint without default or restructuring. However, there is another key objective that governments must consider in designing a sustainable fiscal policy: how these primary surpluses are distributed over time.

To develop an objective function, our starting point is the tax smoothing objectives of Barro (1979) and Sargent (1987)—how to spread the deadweight losses of taxation (or primary surpluses) over time.15 A related concern is that the volatility fiscal policy may introduce into the economy. For example, a delayed fiscal adjustment—low taxes today, higher taxes in the future—means additional volatility, even if taxes are lump sum.16

Here, we consider an objective function that is similar in spirit to Barro (1979) but is more general. That objective will yield policy rules that are simple and easily communicated to the public—as Kydland and Prescott (1977) suggested.

A. Objective: How To Distribute The Fiscal Burden Over Time

A policy objective is to minimize the present value of expected deadweight losses associated with tax collection, subject to the intertemporal budget constraint.

The loss function is:

L=Σt=1E[φ(τt)θt+1](23)

where ϕ′ > 0,ϕ″ > 0. Regarding the third moment, we consider two cases: (i) ϕ″ = 0 and (ii): ϕ″ > 0. For a minimum, the first order (Euler) condition must hold:

φ(τt)=E(φ(τt+1))(24)

Case (i): Barro-Sargent Tax-Smoothing

If ϕ″ = 0 or if there is no volatility E(τt-1τt)2 = 0 equation (24) reduces to:

τt=E(τt+1)(25)

Under certainty, we can drop expectations. This is Barro’s 1979 tax smoothing result.17 The expression has a simple, appealing intuition. A benevolent fiscal authority should aim to equate the marginal costs of tax collection across periods. When it distributes costs in this way, the authority favors neither the present nor future.

However, expression (25) does not tell us what the optimal tax rate is—only that the optimal tax rate should be (on average) equal across periods. To obtain the optimal tax rate τt*, we must take expression (25) and substitute it into budget constraint (17). Doing so yields:

τt*=γt+ry^1+y^bt1(26)

Since pstτtγt, equation (26) is simply a restatement of equation (5). This result has an appealing implication. At first glance, a rule to stabilize the debt might have been considered either arbitrary or naïve. It is now seen to flow from a specific objective function. It is also an easily communicated rule: “Our objective is to stabilize the debt—and hence primary surpluses. In so doing, we are neither favoring current nor future tax payers; we are safeguarding future tax payers against a higher tax burden”.

However, this rule is unappealing in some ways. First policy is invariant to volatilities of γ, r and ŷ. No matter how uncertain the economic environment is, the policy rule will be the same. There is no precautionary element that directs the fiscal authority to ‘save for a rainy day’ if volatility increases.

Second, the policy rule has a symmetric property: a 5 percent increase of the debt ratio offsets a 5 percent decrease. But, this symmetry is inconsistent with typical DSA graphs that show adverse risk scenarios—but not favorable ones. For a policy-maker whose preferences are case (i) of equation (22) such adverse scenarios would be of no interest.

Case (ii): A prudent fiscal authority (ϕ‴ > 0).

If adverse scenarios are shown, as is the case in most DSAs, it is because policymakers are interested in preventing such scenarios. In this sense, a loss function with a third moment—something absent from case (i) but present in case (ii)—would better characterize an authority’s preferences.18

To further examine case (ii), it would be helpful to write the fiscal burden in any period as the sum of primary expenditures and interest payments (adjusted for economic growth): fbt=γt+r˜bt1, where r˜=(ry^)/(1+y^) is the growth-adjusted interest rate. In each period, the prospective variability of the tax burden is E(τt + 1τt)2.

The budget constraint says that this term must be linked to the variance of the fiscal burden, which may be written as:

E(fbt+1fbt)2=E(γt+1γt)2+E(r˜btr˜bt1)2+2E(γt+1γt)(r˜btr˜bt1)(27)

The first term on the right hand side tells us that there is variability linked to primary spending but unrelated to the debt level. The second term tells us that, through changes in interest rates and growth rates, there is an element of fiscal variability that is linked to the stock of debt—higher debt means more variability. The third term is a covariance term; for this exposition, it is assumed to be zero. Substituting the variance of the fiscal burden into expression (24) and taking a second-order Taylor approximation yields:19

τt=E(τt+1)+{.5*φ(τt)φ(τt)*[E(γt+1γt)2+E(r˜btr˜bt1)2]+}(28)

Equation (28) confirms that stochastic simulation exercises (see Part II) are of interest under case (ii) but irrelevant for case (i). Equation (28) also shows that there are two elements to the prudential element of taxes. The first element (γt+1γt)2 may be thought of as budgetary risks—unexpected or unauthorized spending. The second element (r˜bt+1r˜bt)2 may be thought of as financial risks. If E(γt + 1γt)2 = 0, this second element would exclusively reflect unexpected changes to financing costs (the interest rate). In this special case, the fiscal rule would take the form:

pst**=[ry^1+y^+μ]bt(29)

where μ > 0 is derived from the function ϕ. Under this rule, in the long-run, the debt tends to zero. A simple one-period example shows how tax-smoothing rule (26) is a special case of rule (29). Assume an initial debt ratio b0 = 50 percent, average growth ŷ equal to 3 percent and the real interest rate r equal to 12 percent. Assume also that the standard deviation of (rŷ)/(1 − ŷ) is 1 percent and the distribution is standard normal. Under rule (25), the primary surplus chosen by the authority would be ps* = 4.4 percent. Implicitly, this means that the fiscal authority would be willing to take a 50 percent risk that debt rises—requiring another adjustment. Under a rule like (29), if the authority aims to limit that risk to 15 percent, it should target a primary surplus ps** = 4.9 percent of GDP. In so doing, the authority has signaled a willingness to pay an extra 0.4 percent of GDP so as to reduce the risk of another adjustment from 50 percent to 15 percent.

Like tax smoothing, this objective can also be easily communicated: “Our objective is to adjust now so as to avoid another fiscal adjustment for all but the worst w-percent of cases. As a byproduct, we also reduce debt to zero”.

A modified rule emerges if we instead assume that budgetary risks are present and constant: E(γt+1γt)2 = const. Through the debt dynamic equation, such risks will also affect the second element (r˜bt+1r˜bt)2—even if there are no interest rate shocks.

In this case, our more general rule includes a constant structural surplus:

pstss=ps¯+[ry^1+y^+μ]bt(30)

where ps¯>0 is the structural primary surplus as a fixed percent of GDP and μ > 0.20

Since the structural surplus is positive, the country will be a net creditor in the long run. Substitution of (30) into budget constraint (1) in any period t yields:

bt=bt1(1μ)ps¯(31)

Overtime, the government accumulates assets. Its bounded net credit position converges to:

limtbt=ps¯/μ(32)

Such a bound is desirable. Otherwise, the government, as an owner of private assets, may have excessive influence in the private economy.21

B. Objective Functions and Structural Surpluses—Further Considerations

In recent years, economists have emphasized that policies should be conducted so as to maximize consumer welfare. This idea draws on Frank Ramsey’s (1927) concept of a benevolent planner.22 Under this approach, the planner acts to directly maximize consumer utility functions rather than some ad-hoc objective function.23 Even so, an ad-hoc objective function may reflect the underlying welfare of consumers. As one example, assume that the expected present value of the utility of the representative consumer is:

U=Σt=1E[U(Ct)βt+1](33)

where we assume that U′ >0,U″ <0,U‴ >0. Consider a steady state for a ‘hand-to-mouth’ (or credit-constrained) consumer with no assets, where income is fixed and known (Yt = Yt+1,∀t) and the subjective rate of discount β equals the (gross) rate of interest (1+r); for this consumer, Ct = YtTt = Yt(1 − τt).

As before, we assume that the variability of taxes is linked to the variability of the fiscal burden. In this case, the Euler equation U′ (Ct) = U′ (Ct+1) (for β = θ) yields an expression similar to (28):

Tt=E(Tt+1).5U‴U″(C1)*var(fb)+(34)

Since U‴ / U″ <0, equation (34) says that as the variability of the fiscal burden rises, taxes need to be ‘front loaded’. This result is consistent with objective (23) and fiscal rules like (29) or (30), but it is measured in terms of units of consumption. It is also similar to Garcia, Restrepo, and Tanner (2011), who consider a case in which exogenous revenues come from a natural resource (copper). In this case, expenditures should be optimally tilted upwards. Using a Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) utility function, they derive an optimal fiscal rule similar to (30).

Note also that, if taxes were lump-sum, only hand-to-mouth consumers would care about the time path of taxes. Consumers who do enjoy access to capital markets—Ricardian consumers—would be able to smooth consumption on their own.

A structural surplus provides a way to implement the recommendation of Aiyagari, Marcet, Sargent, and Seppala (AMSS, 2002) for the government to accumulate a “war chest” of assets so as to avoid the need for distortionary tax financing of primary government surpluses.24 The importance of such a “war chest” to reduce macroeconomic volatility is discussed in the next section.

C. Debt and Expenditure Smoothing—Evidence From the Recent Downturn

Prior to the recent financial crisis, one might have dismissed the ‘war chest’ idea as a mere debating point. In the aftermath of the recent crisis, such an idea has taken on greater importance. Evidence suggests that countries with lower debt ratios—and especially those few countries whose public sector were net creditors—were better positioned to respond to the economic downturn with countercyclical increases in their non-interest public expenditures.

Figures 2 and 3 illustrate this point. For industrialized and emerging market countries respectively, these figures plot debt ratios in 2008 against the change in the primary surplus/ GDP ratio 2009 minus 2008 (ΔG / GDP(2009 – 2008)). A more positive number indicates a higher spending ratio in 2009 relative to 2008—a more countercyclical policy.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Industrialized Countries: Change in Primary Government Spending (ratio to GDP) 2009 Minus 2008 (vertical axis), and Net Public Debt /GDP (horizontal axis).

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 089; 10.5089/9781484381991.001.A001

Source: IMF WEO
Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Emerging Economies: Change in Primary Government Spending (ratio to GDP) 2009 minus 2008 (vertical axis), and Net Public Debt /GDP (horizontal axis)

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 089; 10.5089/9781484381991.001.A001

Among these two groups, there are several examples of countries that had net credit position: Finland and Norway (industrialized countries) and Bulgaria and Chile (emerging market countries). Of these, all but Bulgaria also posted substantial increases in public spending ratios (a more countercyclical policy). The chart also displays several cases wherein higher debt was coupled with a less countercyclical fiscal policy (lower increases in the spending ratio).

Amongst industrialized countries, this group includes Switzerland, Italy, Greece, and Japan; amongst emerging market countries, Israel with relatively high debt that posted a fall in its public spending ratio.25

VI. Required Adjustment in an Uncertain Environment

The recent global economic crisis has put severe strains on fiscal balances in many countries. Cyclical factors, automatic stabilizers, countercyclical expansions, and support for financial sectors have contributed to rising public debt ratios over the medium-term.

Even while adjustment has begun in some countries, public debt is forecast to continue rising over the medium term, as countries avoid further reducing economic growth that is already weak. This idea was recently summarized by the Managing Director of the IMF (Lagarde, 2011) as follows “For the advanced economies, there is an unmistakable need to restore fiscal sustainability through credible consolidation plans. At the same time we know that slamming on the brakes too quickly will hurt the recovery and worsen job prospects. So, fiscal adjustment must resolve the conundrum of being neither too fast nor too slow”.

As a way to implement such a policy, suppose that, over the medium term—prior to some year T—the authorities will permit the debt ratio to grow. Then, from year t+1 forward, the goal of fiscal policy shifts toward debt stabilization / reduction.26

When year t+1 arrives, what will be the primary surplus (ratio to GDP) that is required to stabilize the debt? This number cannot be known with certainty. Even if the debt ratio is known with certainty, the growth adjusted interest actor (r − ŷ)/(1 + ŷ) remains a random variable. For this reason, the debt stabilizing primary surplus ps* is itself a random variable.

If the growth adjusted discount factor is distributed normally, then the debt stabilizing primary surplus will also be so distributed; its mean will be b*mean[(rŷ) / (1 + ŷ)] and its standard deviation will be b*std.dev[(rŷ) / (1 + ŷ)]

Under these assumptions, ps(x)TAR the target values for primary surplus that would be required to prevent the debt from rising above its year (t) forecast with an x-percent probability ps(x)TAR would be defined as:

PR(ps(x)TARps*)=x(35)

where ps*=mean[ry^1+y^]b.27

Table 2 and Figures 4a and 4b present such calculations for six hypothetical countries. Countries 1 and 2 have a “low” debt ratio (30 percent of GDP); countries 3 and 4 have a “medium” debt ratio (60 percent of GDP); countries 5 and 6 have a “high” debt ratio (100 percent of GDP). In all cases, the level of the growth adjusted interest factor is equal to 2 percent. Within each group, countries are distinguished by the volatility (standard deviation) of that factor. In the “low volatility” countries the standard deviation of that factor is 0.3 percent; in the “high” volatility countries, that standard deviation is 2.0 percent. In each case, the target primary surplus ps(x)TAR is calculated for values of x = 0.5, 0.75, 0.85, and 0.95. Results for the “low” volatility cases are shown in Figure 4a and for the “high” volatility cases in Figure 4b.

Table 2.

Target Primary Surplus, Probabilistic Approach

article image
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Target Primary Surplus, “Low” Volatility Case

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 089; 10.5089/9781484381991.001.A001

Source: Author’s Calculations. Notes: ps(x) is the primary surplus required to prevent debt from rising for with probability x. If x=0.5, the authority aims to stabilize the debt; if x>0.5, the authority aims to reduce the debt.

As one example, if country 1 ran a primary surplus of 0.6 percent of GDP in year T+1, the probability that the debt would continue to rise would be 50 percent (x=0.5). In order to reduce that probability to 25 percent (x=0.75), the authorities would have to raise the primary surplus another 0.06 percent of GDP to 0.66 percent; to reduce that probability to 15 percent (x=0.85), the primary surplus would have to increase to 0.69 percent of GDP; to reduce that probability to 5 percent (x=0.95), the primary surplus would have to increase to 0.75 percent of GDP.

The results confirm that higher primary surpluses are required if either the debt level or the growth adjusted discount factor increase. They also confirm that a more ‘prudent’ authority—one whose objective is to reduce the probability that the debt will rise (higher x)—will also run a higher primary surplus than a less prudent authority.

However, Table 2 and Figures 4a-b convey two other important messages. First, an increase in volatility (higher standard deviation of growth adjusted interest factor) makes it even more difficult for a government to reduce the probability that its debt will grow. This is indicated by lines that are more steeply sloped in Figure 4b than in Figure 4a. Second, a combination of high debt ratios and high volatility can pose yet even more difficulties for the objective of debt stabilization. This is illustrated in Figure 4b: as debt levels rise, so do the slopes of their respective lines; the most steeply sloped line is the one that shows ps(x)TAR for the “high” debt country (b=100 percent of GDP).

Hence, these calculations confirm that economic volatility is the enemy of fiscal sustainability. For countries that suffer from exogenous volatility, it is important to restrain debt. However, eliminating or reducing domestic sources of volatility—erratic monetary policies, poorly functioning financial markets, and undue variations in tax revenues and expenditures—will also support the objective of fiscal sustainability.

VII. Sustainability Over the Business Cycle28

The primary surplus is sensitive to the business cycle. It contains both a structural element ps(struc)t=ηPytP where ytP is trend (or potential) output and the cyclical component is ps(cyc)t=ηc(ytytP)=(ηc,TAXηc,SPEND)(ytytP), where ηc, TAX ηc, SPEND are cyclical elasticitites for taxes and expenditures, respectively. The total primary surplus is: pst = ps(struc)t + ps(cyc)t.

Typically, ηc, TAX ≥1. Net tax revenues (including transfers) typically fall during a recession and rise during an expansion. By contrast, ηc, SPEND will be zero if governments smooth their expenditures (much like a private household would do if it obeyed the permanent income hypothesis).

In this analysis, the debt will be stabilized if two conditions hold. First, the structural surplus must correspond to its debt stabilizing value: ps(struc)t = ps*. This is the tax smoothing regime—equation (26). Under this regime, governments will borrow during downturns, and reduce debt during recoveries. So long as deficits and surpluses fully cancel out over time, government debt will be stabilized.

A second critical assumption is that the government knows what ytP is—with certainty. If potential output is uncertain, even if ps(struc)t = ps*. if potential output is uncertain and the government implements tax smoothing regime (26), the debt ratio will drift upward even if the mean of yP is correctly estimated. To see why, consider the example that is summarized in Table 3. Suppose that initial potential output is equal to actual output equal to 100 (y0P=100). Assume also initial debt b0 to be zero. Hence, according to (26), both the tax rate and ex-ante expenditure ratio are set at 20 percent (τ=γ=0.2), with no initial debt.

Table 3.

Example of Tax Smoothing with Uncertain Potential Output

article image
Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Target Primary Surplus, “High” Volatility Case

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2013, 089; 10.5089/9781484381991.001.A001

Source: Author’s Calculations. Notes: ps(x) is the primary surplus required to prevent debt from rising for with probability x. If x=0.5, the authority aims to stabilize the debt; if x>0.5, the authority aims to reduce the debt.

At the beginning of period 1—before that period’s shock—the expected level of permanent output will be y1|0P=100. If expectations are correct, ex post y1P=100 and the deficit equals zero—both as a level and as a ratio to permanent output yP. Alternatively, consider symmetric shocks of ± 5 units. For the pessimistic case y1P=105, the surplus as a ratio to output is 0.952 percent ([21–20]/105). For the optimistic case yP1 = 95, the deficit ratio is -1.053 percent of output ([19–20]/95).

Thus, the mean surplus ratio-to-output is -0.033 percent (deficit). In this example, the dollar deficits average zero. However, since a primary deficit is observed when potential output is lower, the primary balance ratio does not average zero but is instead biased toward a deficit. Moreover, under this policy the debt ratio will grow—as Tanner and Carey (2008) show.29

This example should not be construed to mean that debt ratios rise simply because governments do not know what potential output is. But, the analysis does confirm that, to keep the debt from drifting upward, if the uncertainty about potential output rises, the structural surplus must rise as well.

VIII. Prospective Liabilities

While the analysis has thus far focused on accumulated public liabilities, prospective or contingent liabilities may be added to the framework. Such liabilities, including entitlements and potential obligations in the financial sector, clearly threaten fiscal sustainability in many countries, especially among industrialized countries. Consider first a fundamental symmetry between accumulated and prospective liabilities. Accumulated liabilities are the capitalized accumulation of past deficits:

btacc=θbt1accpst(36)

where Bacc is the stock of debt. It is helpful to see this over several periods, assuming that the initial period is 0:

btacc=b0accθtps1θt1ps2θt2ps3θt3ps4θt4(37)

This equation shows how current accumulated debt reflects the original debt that has been capitalized plus the sum of all the deficit flows in the intervening periods (also capitalized).

To calculate prospective debt, we first distinguish between the discretionary component of the primary surplus psd and some non-discretionary element (for example an entitlement) whose value is wt. Hence, the total primary surplus (now or in the future) is ps = psdw. The prospective debt associated with the non-discretionary element is:

btpro=wt+wt+1θ1+wt+2θ2+wt+3θ3+(38)

That is, the prospective debt associated with the non-discretionary deficits is simply the discounted sum of such prospective flows. The ‘true’ debt is thus:

bt=btacc+btpro(39)

In this case, a tax smoothing policy implies a constant discretionary primary surplus psd¯ whose level is:

psd¯=ry^1+y^(btacc+btpro)(40)

That is, the government will run an ‘extra’ discretionary primary surplus [(rŷ) / (1 + ŷ)]*bpro so as to spread the payment for the prospective liabilities evenly across all-time periods. If the government is short-sighted and chooses to disregard prospective liabilities in the design of its current fiscal policy, the delayed future adjustment will exceed the current required adjustment.

The difference between psd¯ and the actual primary surplus may be thought of as one measure of the intertemporal gap (for example Gokhale and Smetters, 2003) and the sustainability indicator of Escolano (2010): the fiscal adjustment that must be taken today in order to obtain ex-ante solvency (satisfaction of condition (17) without default).

As an example, it is well known that the United States faces sizable prospective deficits in its entitlements system, and specifically in its health entitlements (Medicare, Medicaid). A recent exercise by Batini, Callegari, and Guerreiro (BCG, 2010), illustrates the size of the imbalances faced by the U.S. Their calculations extend the previous work by Auerbach, Gokahle, and Kotlikoff (1994), Kotlikoff (2003), and Gokhale and Smetters (2003).

Table 4 shows their results for two scenarios. Scenario 2, which was preferred by the United States Congressional Budget Office (CBO), is more optimistic on real GDP near-term growth than Scenario 1.

Table 4.

Long-Run Fiscal Imbalances in the United States

article image
Source: Batini, Callegari, and Guerreiro (BCG, 2010)Notes: Initial debt ratio (end-2008) is 44 percent of GDP; Present value of GDP obtained using discount rate of 3percent. Scenario 2 reflects assumptions of US Congressional Budget Office. For details, see BCG.

Under either scenario, the fiscal adjustment required to stabilize the debt is substantial. Under their finite horizon calculations, their results suggest that a fiscal adjustment of about 4.5 percent of GDP would be required to offset the first 25 years of prospective deficits (2009–33). Such an adjustment would stabilize the debt ratio at its end-2008 value, 44 percent of GDP. Over a 50 year horizon (2009–58) the required adjustment rises to 6–6 ½ percent of GDP.

To offset the first 75 years (2009–83), the government would need to raise the primary surplus by about 8 percent. And, for an infinite horizon—to fully satisfy the no-Ponzi game condition—the required adjustment is around 14 percent of GDP. BCG also estimates that the effect of the financial crisis on prospective debt is small—about 0.1 percent of GDP.

IX. The Net Worth Approach

Thus far, the analysis has focused on the public sector’s net financial liabilities—debt. However, public non-financial assets should be part of the sustainability picture. These include both fixed assets (buildings, roads, land, etc.) and non-renewable natural resources (or claims thereon), such as revenues derived from a state run oil company.

Economists have long recognized that public sector balance sheet includes assets—both financial and non-financial—as well as liabilities (see, for example Eisner and Pieper (1984), and Boskin and others (1985) for analyses of the net worth of the U.S. Government). The IMF incorporated such a view in their 2001 manual on Government Financial Statistics (IMF GFSM 2001).

In the approach set out in this manual, the net worth of the public sector is the difference between total assets and total liabilities, all of which must be recorded. Importantly, unrecorded liabilities (for example estimated entitlements or contingent liabilities) may only enter as a memorandum item.

Public net worth (as a fraction of GDP) nw is written as:

nwt=atNF+atFbtGROSSOLiabt(41)

where aNF is the recorded market value of non-financial assets (including publicly-owned buildings, roads, and non-renewable resources), aF is financial assets (including bank deposits, debt, and equity shares or other participations in private sector entities), bGROSS is the gross indebtedness of the government, and OLiab denotes other liabilities, financial and non-financial. Note that, in previous sections, the relevant concept of accumulated debt is net. Thus, our previous definition of net debt (financial liabilities minus financial assets) implies that bacc = bGROSSaF. Of course, there are instances in which we may wish to look at gross assets and liabilities, since ‘netting out’ may hide important differences in risks, rates of return, currency composition, and maturities.

To simplify our analysis, we assume the only gross liability of the government to be bGROSS and hence OLiab = 0. In the net worth approach, we distinguish between public consumption and public investment: γ = γcons + γinv. To see how net worth evolves, we first restate the evolution of net financial assets:

btGROSSatF=bt1GROSSθGROSSat1FθF+γtcons+γtinvτt(42)

Next, note that non-financial assets earn a real rate of return net of depreciation equal to ρNF; the gross return factor on non-financial assets, adjusted for real GDP growth is θNF = (1 + ρNF) / (1 + ŷ). Non financial assets hence evolve according to atNF=at1NFθNF+γtinv. Thus, net worth (relative to GDP) evolves according to:

nwt=at1NFθNF+at1FθFbt1GROSSθGROSS+τtγtcons(43)

If the government seeks to service gross debt without a fiscal adjustment (raising tax rates or cutting spending), its gross financial assets may be liquidated. By contrast, non-financial assets that correspond to future (imputed) consumption do not provide such an option for debt service. To see this, consider a fully occupied public office building whose market value BUILDt is equal to the present value of (imputed) rental payments for that building:

BUILDt=RENTt+RENTt+1/(1+r)+RENTt+2/(1+r)2+RENTt+3/(1+r)3+(44)

The government may hypothetically sell that building and use its cash receipt BUILDt to pay down the debt. But then the government must decide whether it will continue to use the office space provided by an equivalent building. If so, explicit rental flows will be reflected in government consumption γcons. Otherwise, a fiscal adjustment has effectively taken place.

X. Non-Renewable Resources

Some governments depend on funding from revenues derived from non-renewable natural resources (oil, mineral). Such governments must decide when these resources should be spent. Will future generations benefit from a country’s natural endowments? Or, will current governments prematurely deplete these resources?

The ‘permanent income’ or ‘permanent consumption’ approach to this issue (see Barnett and Ossowski, 2003, Balassone, Takizawa, Zebregs, 2006, and others) can be easily integrated with other ideas presented in this paper. Under this approach the government treats a publicly-owned natural resource as if it were an asset that yields a flow of income that is available for public consumption – while also leaving the initial stock of assets intact. Under such an approach, the stock value of the natural resource must be estimated. As a simple example, assume that there is some exogenously determined optimal rate of extraction. Hence, in any period t, the oil company is expected to generate a surplus of zt. This number is essentially the operational surplus of the oil company: it takes into account the market price of oil, the technical costs of extraction, and the wages paid to employees of the oil company. The oil wealth (ow) variable is at the end of period 0 (prior to any extraction) is defined as the present value of net oil revenues from period 1 until the depletion date N:

ow0=Σt=1Nzt/θt(45)

We also assume that there is a hypothetical financial asset called an oil fund (of). In this model, oft serves only as an accounting tool.30 The oil fund evolves according to:

oft=oft1θ(46)

Jointly, equations (45) and (46) have an intuitive interpretation. Prospective oil surpluses in any period zt are the incremental additions to the interest bearing oil fund. Oil in the ground is converted into an interest bearing financial that builds up over time.

Our narrow measure of public net worth nnw is thus:31

nnwtowt+oftbt(47)

This resource-based fund will generate interest payments. Note also that, since owt = owt-1θzt, oft = oft–1θ+zt and bt = bt–1θpsnot where psno is the non-oil primary surplus, we have

nnwt=nnwt1θpsnot(48)

We may now obtain the non-oil primary surplus that stabilizes net worth psno* in a manner consistent with a permanent income approach

psno*=ry^1+y^nnwt(49)

If the government is a net creditor (nnw > 0), it may run a non-oil primary deficit; if it is a net debtor (nnw < 0), it must run a non-oil primary surplus. In this case, it is assumed that the government is able to borrow against future oil earnings and hence, smooth expenditures (taking advantage of credibility in capital markets).

An example of the approach is presented in Table 5. A hypothetical country is assumed to grow by 3.5 percent and the interest rate (r) is 4 percent. In the initial period, t = 0, contributions to the oil fund have not yet begun. In this case, of0=0. In Part A of the table, the country’s public oil company is forecast to generate a series of net revenues (relative to GDP) from 2012 through 2022. The total value of oil wealth that is yet to be extracted ow0 is estimated from 2011 to be 34.7 percent of GDP (based on prospective discounted revenues and costs).

Table 5.

Non-Renewable Resource Management: Permanent Income and “Bird-In-Hand” Approaches

r: real interest rate 4.0%

real GDP growth 3.5%

article image
Source: Author’s Calculations

Oil revenues will be accumulated into an (accounting) oil fund whose initial value in 2011 is zero. Initial debt is 25 percent of GDP. Therefore, in 2011, this narrow measure of the country’s net worth (nnw0 = ow0b0) is 9.7 percent of GDP.

The rate of return on the oil fund is identical to that paid on its debt—4 percent.32 Thus, the capitalized value of all oil proceeds in the year 2022—that is, the terminal value of the oil fund of2022 is 36.6 percent of GDP—a number whose present value equals oil wealth in the initial period (34.7 percent of GDP).

Part B of the table shows a baseline scenario in which the net worth measure nnw falls. The country runs a non-oil primary deficit of 1 percent of GDP (psnot = –1%). Under this scenario, debt-GDP ratio rises from 25 percent to 37.6 percent of GDP in 2022. At the same time, the oil fund is increasing. Hence, by 2022, the net financial worth of the government, measured by oftbt has risen: in the initial period (2011), net financial worth is simply minus unity times the debt—of2011b2011 = –25%. By the end period (2022), this number is still negative, but less so, of2011b2011 = –1%.

It is easily seen how focusing exclusively on financial wealth can fundamentally distort the true picture of the public sector’s position. Beginning in 2022, if the government wishes to stabilize its net financial wealth position at -1 percent, it will have to make an adjustment to the non-oil primary surplus, since oil revenues will have ceased. From 2013 forward, the government will have to run a small non-oil primary surplus: psno¯=0.005%. This represents however an adjustment of just over 1 percent of GDP relative to the non-oil primary deficit that it had previously been running.

Part B shows that such an adjustment in 2013 can be avoided if the government instead aims to stabilize narrow net worth (nnw). Since narrow net worth is positive, the government can run a non-oil primary deficit, but that deficit must be smaller than the 1 percent it was running in the baseline scenario. Instead, we compute the net worth stabilizing value for the non-oil primary surplus to be: psno¯=(.04.035)/1.035*9.7=0.05% — about 1/20th of GDP. In choosing this smaller primary surplus, the government has effectively preserved a portion of the oil proceeds for consumption in the years 2013 and beyond. We can see that, under this policy, the government has ‘pre-stabilized’ its financial net worth for 2013 and afterwards. The adjustment of 1 percent in that year that was required to preserve net financial wealth is no longer necessary.

Uncertainty presents challenges to the ‘permanent income’ approach. For example, it may be difficult to estimate the stock of commodity (oil) wealth, since commodity (oil) prices—in addition to economic growth and interest rates—are difficult to predict.

An alternative proposed by some (see Barnett and Ossowski, 2002, Bjerkholdt, 2002, Balassone, Takizawa, Zebregs, 2006, and others) would count only the resources that have already been placed into the natural resource fund—not the present value of resources prior to extraction. The income that is considered to be a part of the ‘permanent income’ that is made available for consumption is thus only the interest proceeds from that accumulated fund. This more conservative ‘Bird-In-Hand’ (BIH) approach does not permit the government to borrow against resources that are not yet extracted.

While there are a number of ways to implement a BIH rule, one way to do so would be to keep the debt constant. Under such a BIH approach, the non-oil primary surplus would evolve according to:

psnotBIH=ry^1+y^[oftbt](50)

The result of such a policy is shown in Part D of the table. Initially, when the oil fund is low, the government must run non-oil primary surpluses. As the oil fund accumulates, and more interest income from the oil fund becomes available, the primary surplus psnotBIH falls. In period N+1, after the resource is depleted, the public sector can run a higher primary deficit than it would under the narrow net worth stabilizing policy, since it did not borrow from resources in the ground under the former. That is, after resource depletion, psnoBIH < psno* – but only slightly so.

Uncertainty in world commodity prices suggests other modifications of the ‘permanent income’ approach to the management of natural resources. For resources whose depletion is projected to occur only in the distant future—a ‘large’ value of N—the authorities should make a ‘conservative’ estimate of the long-run commodity price (Barnett and Ossowski, 2003). The precautionary considerations discussed above in Section V would also carry over to natural resources: uncertainty in the long-run price of the export commodity is a reason for commodity exporters to run a structural surplus. For example, in an initial period, the authority might run a non-oil primary surplus that exceeds the stabilizing value psno0 > psno*. If psno may also be linked to asset accumulation, in a way that is similar to (30):

psnotss=psno¯[ry^1+y^+μ]nnwt(51)

where nnw is the estimate of narrow net worth that is conditioned on projections of commodity prices. In equation (51), so long as the determinants of ow remain constant, the non-oil primary surplus and narrow net worth would stabilize around some long-run value (as with debt in expression 30).

Basing fiscal policy on current values of commodity prices, rather than a long-run value, also has implications for macroeconomic volatility. Countries that tie spending to the current price (rather than the long-run price) essentially transmit global volatility into the domestic economy. Spending rises when commodity prices are temporarily high; spending cuts—sometimes sharp—occur when commodity prices fall. By contrast, if a country ties its spending to an estimated long-run commodity price, it can shield the domestic economy from global volatility.33 As Garcia, Restrepo, and Tanner (2011) show, volatility can be reduced by pursuing two policies at once: linking spending to a long-run price and building up a buffer stock of assets.

Finally, until now, we have assumed that the rate of return on a natural resource fund is equal to the interest rate on foreign debt. This of course need not be true. If the latter is greater, the country should of course pay down the debt. Likewise, if there are investment projects with rates of return that exceed that from a natural resource fund, the country might pursue those opportunities first. These important qualifications to the ‘permanent income’ approach to natural resource management are discussed in greater detail in van der Ploeg (2011) and van der Ploeg and Venables (2011).

XI. Contingent Claims Analysis and Market Indicators of Default Risk34

In recent years, risk assessments (fiscal and otherwise) have been increasingly based on the Contingent Claims Approach (CCA). This approach is based on options pricing theory that was originally developed in papers by Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1974). Recent papers that show the practical implications for assessment of financial risks in the corporate sector as a whole include Gapen, Gray, Xiao, and Lim (2004). Methods to estimate default risk have gained additional notoriety in the wake of Standard and Poor’s 2011 downgrading of the U.S. Government’s credit rating, from AAA to AA+. Table 6 shows the linkage between such ratings and default probabilities.

Table 6.

Approximate Sovereign Cumulative Default Probabilities: 5-year bonds

article image

Papers by Gray, Bodie, and Merton (2007) and Gray, Lim, Loukoianova, and Malone (GLLM, 2008) present some first steps to reconcile the CCA with more traditional debt sustainability approaches. In this section, the approach is discussed and extended.

The CCA was originally developed to analyze private firms whose tangible assets might be seized in the event of bankruptcy. Unlike the private corporations, the main asset for the public sector is the present value of its primary surpluses. For the analysis, we should first show the correspondence between the present value of discretionary primary surpluses and a corresponding perpetuity value that is constant relative to GDP. Assume that the economy grows at a constant rate ŷ. To keep the ratio of the primary surplus to GDP (ps = PS / Y) constant, the dollar primary surplus must grow each period at a rate that equals the forecast rate of GDP growth ŷ : PSt = PSt–1(1+ŷ). Over an infinite horizon, from period zero forward, the present value of this perpetuity must be PS0PV=PS0*(1+r)*(ry^)1.

As in the Merton model and contingent claims approach, these assets are assumed to evolve according to a Brownian motion process:

d(PStPV)=rPSt1PVCapitalizationofpreviousprimarysurplus+σPVPSt1PVdW“Implementationrisk”Uncertaintyaboutabilityorwillingnessofauthoritytoreachfiscalgoal(52)

where dW is a shock term (see below). The first term on the right hand side reflects the capitalization of past primary surpluses: as we go forward in time, the present value of future prospective flows must increase at a rate corresponding to the rate of interest.

The second term in the equation tells us about the volatility of public sector assets. This term must be interpreted carefully. The Merton model was originally developed for private enterprises whose asset yields (mean r and standard deviation σ) are observable. For example, one would directly observe the mean and standard deviation of an equity share price.

A different interpretation is required for sovereign default risk. Unlike equity share prices, the present value of a primary surplus for a government is not directly observable. Instead, an alternative interpretation is proposed. Consider a government that announces intentions to run a pre-specified primary surplus. The market may not view the government’s plans as fully credible. Instead, it may place some probability on outcomes where the government falls sort of achieving its fiscal adjustment goals. Thus, the markets’ view of implementation risk (see IMF, 2011, pp. 59) would be summarized by standard deviation σPS on the primary surplus ratio. For example, the government may declare that it plans to run primary surpluses equal to 3 percent of GDP (consistent with some targeted present value). If the standard deviation expressed as a fraction of this number is σPS =0.3, there is a 10 percent probability that the realized ratio primary surplus/GDP will be 1.85 percent or lower, a 15 percent probability that that ratio will be 2.07 percent of GDP or lower, and so on.

The present value of primary surpluses will evolve in continuous time according to:

PStPV=PS0PVeμt(53)

where,

μ=[r0.5*σPS2+σPSε/t]Rateofreturnadjustedforrisk(54)

where the shock term is ε=dW/tN(0,1) (a Weiner process), and term 0.5*σPS2 reflects the uncertainty in the evolution of public sector (intangible) assets over time.

On the liabilities side, our measure of debt will be net of financial assets. We may also include prospective non-discretionary deficits—prospective debt that is known with certainty, B0PRO. Hence the government’s net liabilities are:

B0=B0GROSS+B0PROA0F(55)

If that debt were riskless, it would be repaid in period t with certainty. If so, its present value would be:

Bt=B0ert(56)

Over a horizon of t periods, the government remains solvent if PStPVBt. A related term is the familiar expression for the distance-to-default (DTD); this term is widely-known in the options literature as “d2”:

d2=DTDt=ln(PS0PV/Bt)+(r0.5σPS2)tσPSt(57)

The probability of default in period t is summarized by the expression Pr(PStPVBt0). As GLLM confirm, the risk-neutral measure of the probability of default is simply the cumulative normal distribution evaluated at –d2

Pr(Default)=N(d2)(58)

We may also obtain an expression for the credit spread, SPRt—the difference between the rate of interest on risky government debt and a riskless benchmark. The spread simply reflects the logarithmic difference in the prices of risky and riskless debt.

Over a t-period horizon, risky debt is simply the value of riskless debt plus expected losses ELt which are written:

ELt=B0ert*N(d2)PresentvalueofdebttimesprobabilityofdefaultA0*N(d1)RecoveryvalueofinitialassetsA0(59)

where d1=d2+σPSt. The first term on the right hand side reflects the initial present value of the debt times the probability that it will not be paid back. The second term reflects the recovery value of some stock of assets. For a private company, this term may reflect the liquidation value of the capital that creditors seize from a bankrupt firm. In our case, we define A0=λPS0PV. If the loan is not collateralized or guaranteed and creditors are unable to seize the government’s tangible assets λ = 0.35

Thus, from a period 0 perspective, the spread on risky government debt that matures in period t is:

SPRt=ln[1ELtBert]*t1(60)

Table 7 presents an illustrative example of how the CCA framework might be used to assess fiscal sustainability in a hypothetical economy. At the top of the table are initial conditions: the real rate of economic growth is assumed to be constant at ŷ equals 2.8 percent, the real interest rate (risk-free) is r equals 3.8 percent, initial GDP is Y0 = 400 and the initial ratio of public debt to GDP is 150 percent.

Table 7.

Assessment of Fiscal Sustainability for a Hypothetical Economy: A Contingent Claims Approach

article image
Source: Author’s Calculations

Under an initial program (Scenario (i), left-most column of bottom portion of table), the government targets primary surpluses whose present value exactly offsets the government debt, or 600 currency units. If the government were to impose this surplus as a constant fraction of GDP forever, it would target a period zero primary surplus of PS0 = 5.8 units. As a fraction of GDP, the primary surplus would be targeted at 1.4 percent.

The standard deviation of the primary surplus process σPS is assumed to be 0.2 (20 percent of total primary surplus). For a five-year horizon, the probability of default—that is the probability that the present value of debt will exceed the present value of the primary surpluses, calculated from expression (61) is 26.6 percent. Accordingly, using expression (63), the spread would be SPRt=5 = 6.2 percent.36 We assume that the model is ‘correct’ insofar as a spread of SPR = 6.2 percent is actually observed in the market. Equivalently, the market understands that the primary surplus goal may not be attainable. In the worst 10 percent of circumstances, the government may undershoot its target with a primary surplus of 0.5 percent of GDP or lower; in the worst 20 percent of cases, the primary surplus would be 1.1 percent or less; in the worst 30 percent of cases, that number would be 1.3 percent of GDP.

Suppose the authorities want to reduce the spread from 6.2 percent to some lower value. There may be room for the authorities to raise the primary surplus and to reduce financing costs (even while such an adjustment may also imply political costs). For this reason, the fiscal adjustment in scenario (ii) is proposed (middle column, lower part of table). The present value of primary surpluses is now targeted at a higher value: PSPV =800, or 200 percent of GDP. The corresponding constant primary surplus ratio is now 1.9 percent of GDP.

Hence, in Scenario (2), the government has proposed a permanent adjustment of ½ of one percent of GDP. This brings the default probability down from 26.6 percent in scenario (i) to 10.2 percent. Likewise, the spread falls by 400 basis points, from 6.2 percent to 4.2 percent. Under this scenario, the adverse outcomes for the primary surplus are not as severe as they were for scenario (i).

However, the market may recognize that raising the primary surplus can entail more risk – a modest increase in σPS from 0.2 to 0.23. This is shown in scenario (iii) (right-most column, lower part of table.) If this were to happen, the country would not be able to fully enjoy the benefits of its fiscal adjustment shown in scenario (ii). The default probability would fall to about 15 percent (rather than the 10.2 percent shown in scenario (ii)). Likewise, the spread would fall, but by about 300 basis points to 3.2 percent—100 basis points less than in the previous scenario.

This exercise has two main lessons. First, as is the case with any economic policy, the expectations surrounding a fiscal adjustment need to be well managed. If the authority proposes a fiscal adjustment, it should also take steps to make this adjustment credible. Otherwise, the government may not fully enjoy the gains to be had from lower financing costs (since σPS has risen). For this reason, fiscal adjustments should be clearly explained to the public. The second lesson regards the incentives for countries to adjust. An increase in the standard deviation σPS can be seen as an implicit ‘tax’ on fiscal adjustment. This exercise thus suggests an alternative definition for maximum sustainable debt: the debt may be “too high” if a fiscal adjustment that also reduces the sovereign spread is not possible.

XII. Summary and Conclusions

This paper has attempted to integrate and comment on recent work in the area of fiscal sustainability. The issue was addressed from a positive point of view: What are the criteria for fiscal sustainability and are those criteria satisfied?

This paper has attempted to integrate and comment on recent work in the area of fiscal sustainability. The issue was addressed from a positive point of view: What are the criteria for fiscal sustainability and are those criteria satisfied?

In their assessment of fiscal policy in Fund programs, the Fund’s Independent Evaluation Office (IMF-IEO, 2003) noted that adjustment programs that included a fiscal component often failed to include an explicit forward-looking analysis of debt sustainability. Since that report was written, considerable progress has been made regarding positive sustainability assessments. The Fund’s DSA template was introduced at the time of the report; it continues to be presented in most country staff reports, with ongoing refinements. Beyond operational work, this paper has attempted to spotlight some of the recent efforts to develop and refine our methods for assessing fiscal sustainability under various forms of uncertainty. As a result of this work, our toolbox now contains more and better tools for positive assessments of debt sustainability than it did a decade ago.

We also explored the issue from a normative point of view: what policy (or policies) should be implemented to bring about fiscal sustainability—and why such policies will benefit a country’s citizens. Here again, owing to considerable analytical work in recent years, our toolbox has more and better tools. The ultimate goal of policy assessments—using either explicit welfare calculations from a general equilibrium model or from a less formal criterion—is to make a case for disciplined and credible fiscal policies to policy makers in a clear and compelling manner.37

Also, while this paper has focused on how much fiscal adjustment is required for sustainability, other issues regarding the quality of fiscal policy must not be forgotten. These issues include reducing distortions and waste in a tax system and its administration, broadening the tax base, eliminating wasteful government expenditures, and providing public goods and services that achieve their goal in an efficient way. Such policies will support a broader policy goal: higher and more stable economic growth.

References

  • Abel, Andrew B., N. Gregory Mankiw, Lawrence Summers, and Richard Zeckhauser, 1989, “Assessing Dynamic Efficiency: Theory and Evidence,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 56, No. 1 (January), pp 119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aiyagari, S. Rao, Albert Marcet, Thomas J. Sargent, and Juha Seppälä, 2002, “Optimal Taxation without State-Contingent Debt,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 110, No. 6 (December), pp. 122054.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto and Guido Tabellini, 1990, “A Positive Theory of Fiscal Deficits and Government Debt,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57, No. 3 (July), pp. 40314.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto and Guido Tabellini, 1990, “Voting on the Budget Deficit,” American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 1 (March), pp. 3749.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Altig, David, Alan J. Auerbach, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Kent A. Smetters, and Jan Walliser, 2001, “Simulating Fundamental Tax Reform in the United States,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 3 (June), pp. 57495.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auerbach, Alan J., Jagddesh Gokhale, and Jagadeesh and Laurence Kotlikoff, 1994, “Generational Accounting: A Meaningful Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, Vol. 8, No. 1 (Winter), pp. 7394.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassone, Fabrizio, Hajime Takizawa, and Harm Zebregs, 2006, “Russian Federation: Selected Issues,” in IMF Staff Country Report No. 06/430, pp. 324 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2006/cr06430.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bandiera, Luca, Nina Budina, Michel Klijn, and Sweder Van Wijnbergen, 2007, “The ‘How To’ of Fiscal Sustainability: A Technical Manual for Using the Fiscal Sustainability Tool,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 4170 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barnett, Steven and Rolando J. Ossowski, 2003, “Operational Aspects of Fiscal Policy in Oil-Producing Countries,” in Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries, edited by Jeffrey M. Davis, Rolando J. Ossowski, and Annalisa Fedelino (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barro, Robert J., 1979, “On the Determination of the Public Debt,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87, No. 5 (October), pp. 94071.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Batini, Nicoletta, Giovanni Callegari, and Julia Guerreiro, 2010, “The US Fiscal Gap: Who Will Pay and How?” in United States: Selected Issues Paper, IMF Country Report 10/248, pp. 5267, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=24106.0.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes, 1973, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81, No. 3, pp. 63754.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Stanley Fischer, 1989, Lectures On Macroeconomics (Cambridge: MIT Press).

  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Philippe Weil, 2001, “Dynamic Efficiency, the Riskless Rate, and Debt Ponzi Games under Uncertainty,” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, Issue 2.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bohn, Henning, 1998, “The Behavior of U.S. Public Debt and Deficits,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113, No. 3, pp. 94963.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bohn, H., 2008, “The Sustainability of Fiscal Policy in the United States,” in Sustainability of Public Debt, ed. by Reinhard Neck and Jan-Egbert Sturm, pp. 1549 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boskin, Michael J., Marc S. Robinson, Terrence O’Reilly, and Praveen Kumar, 1985, “New Estimates of the Value of Federal Mineral Rights and Land,” American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 5 (December), pp. 92336.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Budina, Nina and Sweder Van Wijnbergen, 2009, “Quantitative Approaches to Fiscal Sustainability Analysis: A Case Study of Turkey Since the Crisis of 2001,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 11940.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carroll, Christopher D. and Miles S. Kimball, 1996, “On the Concavity of the Consumption Function,” Econometrica, Vol. 64, No. 4, (July), pp. 98192.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, Ricardo, 1990, “Consumption Puzzles and Precautionary Savings,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 25, pp. 11316.

  • Celasun, O. X. Debrun and J. Ostry, 2007, “Primary Surplus Behavior and Risks to Fiscal Sustainability in Emerging Market Countries: A “Fan-Chart” Approach,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 53, No. 3.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chari, V., Lawrence J. Christiano and Patrick J. Kehoe, 1994, “Optimal Fiscal Policy in a Business Cycle Model,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 102, No. 4, pp. 61752.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cochrane, John, 1998, “A Frictionless View of U.S. Inflation,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998, eds. Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, Vol.13 (Cambridge: Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Da Costa, Mercedes and V. Hugo Juan-Ramon, 2006, “The Net Worth Approach to Fiscal Analysis: Dynamics and Rules,” IMF Working Paper 06/17 (Washington: International Monetay Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp0617.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Davis, Jeffery, Ronald Ossowski, and Annalisa Fedelino, 2003, “Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eisner, Robert and P. J. Pieper, 1984, “A New View of the Federal Debt and Budget Deficits,” American Economic Review, Vol. 74, pp. 1129.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Escolano, Julio, 2010, “A Practical Guide to Public Debt Dynamics, Fiscal Sustainability, And Cyclical Adjustment of Budgetary Aggregates,” IMF Technical Notes and Manuals (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2010/tnm1002.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Escolano, Julio, Anna Shabunina, and Jaejoon Woo, 2011, “The Puzzle of Persistently Negative Interest Rate-Growth Differentials: Financial Repression or Income Catch-Up?IMF Working Paper 11/260 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=25341.0

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fedelino, Annalisa, Anna Ivanova, and Mark Horton, 2009, “Computing Cyclically Adjusted Balances and Automatic Stabilizers,” IMF Technical Notes and Manuals 09/05 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/tnm/2009/tnm0905.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fisher, Lance and Geoffrey Kingston, 2005, “Joint Implications of Consumption and Tax Smoothing,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol.37, No. 6 (December) pp. 110119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Friedman, Milton, 1960, A Program for Monetary Stability (New York: Fordham University Press).

  • Frank, Nathaniel and Eduardo Ley, 2009, “On the Probabilistic Approach to Fiscal Sustainability: Structural Breaks and Non-Normality,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 56 (November), pp.74257.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gapen, Michael T., Dale F. Gray, Yingbin Xiao, and Cheng Hoon Lim, 2004, “The Contingent Claims Approach to Corporate Vulnerability Analysis: Estimating Default Risk and Economy-Wide Risk Transfer,” IMF Working Paper 04/121 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Carlos, Jorge Restrepo, and Evan Tanner, 2011, “Fiscal Rules in a Volatile World: A Welfare-Based Approach,” Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 33 (July–August), pp. 64976.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Márcio and Roberto Rigobon, 2005, “A Risk Management Approach to Emerging Market’s Sovereign Debt Sustainability with an Application to Brazilian Data,” in Inflation Targeting, Debt, and the Brazilian Experience: 1999 to 2003, eds. Francesco Giavazzi, Ilan Goldfajn, and Santiago Herrera (Cambridge, Massachusetts).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Atish, Jun Il Kim, Enrique Mendoza, Jonathan Ostry, and Mahvash Querishi, 2011, “Fiscal Fatigue, Fiscal Space and Debt Sustainability in Advanced Economies,” NBER Working Paper No. 16782 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Girouard, Nathalie and Christophe André, 2005, “Measuring Cyclically-Adjusted Budget Balances for OECD Countries,” Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development Working Paper No. 434 (Paris: France).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gray, Dale F., Zvi Bodie, and Robert C. Merton, 2007, “Contingent Claims Approach to Measuring and Managing Sovereign Risk,” Journal of Investment Management, Volume 5, No. 4.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gray, Dale F., Elena Loukoianova, Samuel W. Malone, Samuel W., and Cheng-Hoon Lim, 2008, “A Risk-Based Debt Sustainability Framework: Incorporating Balance Sheets and Uncertainty,” IMF Working Paper 08/40 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gokhale, Jagadeesh and Kent Smetters, 2003, Fiscal and Generational Imbalances: New Budget Measures for New Budget Priorities. (Washington, DC: The American Enterprise Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier and Jonathan A. Parker, 2001, “The Empirical Importance of Precautionary Saving,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 2 (May), pp. 40612.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hadjenberg, Alejandro and Rafael Romeu, 2010, “Parameter Estimate Uncertainty in Probabilistic Debt Sustainability Analysis,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 57 (September), pp. 6183.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hoffmaister, A. W., M. Rojas, M. Saenz, M. Segura, and E. Tenorio, 2001, “Solvency of the Overall Public Sector: A Preliminary Empirical Study for Costa Rica,” Central Bank of Costa Rica, Economics Division, Research Note 04-01 (San José, Costa Rica: Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hostland, Douglas and Philippe Karam, 2005, “Assessing Debt Sustainability in Emerging Market Economies Using Stochastic Simulation Methods,” IMF Working Paper 05/226 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2005/wp05226.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huggett, Mark and Sandra Ospina, 2001, “Aggregate Precautionary Savings: When is the Third Derivative Irrelevant?Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 48, No. 2 (October), pp. 37396.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hunt, Ben and Aaron Drew, 1998, “The Forecasting and Policy System: Stochastic Simulations of the Core Model,” Reserve Bank of New Zealand Discussion Paper No. G98/6 (Wellington, New Zealand). www.ssrn.com/abstract=321393

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Independent Evaluation Office of the International Monetary Fund, 2003, Evaluation Report: Fiscal Adjustment in IMF-Supported Programs (Washington). http://www.ieoimf.org/ieo/files/completedevaluations/09092003main.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2001, Government Finance Statistics Manual (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfs/manual/.

  • International Monetary Fund, 2010, “Debt Sustainability Analysis” (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/dsa/index.htm.

  • International Monetary Fund, 2011, Fiscal Monitor, April 2011: Shifting Gears: Tackling Challenges on the Road to Fiscal Adjustment, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2011/01/fmindex.htm

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund and International Development Association, 2004, Debt Sustainability in Low-Income Countries—Proposal for an Operational Framework and Policy Implications. http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sustain/2004/020304.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jafarov, Etibar and Daniel Leigh, 2007, “Alternative Fiscal Rules for Norway,” IMF Working Paper 07/241 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2007/wp07241.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kawakami, Kei and Rafael Romeu, 2011, “Identifying Fiscal Policy Transmission in Stochastic Debt Forecasts,” IMF Working Paper 11/107 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp11107.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kimball, Miles, 1990, “Precautionary Savings in the Small and in the Large,” Econometrica, Vol. 58, No. 1, pp. 5374.

  • Kingston, Geoffrey, 1991, “Should Marginal Tax Rates Be Equalized Through Time?Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, No. 3 (August), pp. 91124.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kopits, George and Theodore M. Barnhill, 2003, “Assessing Fiscal Sustainability Under Uncertainty,” IMF Working Paper 03/79 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2003/wp0379.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kotlikoff, Laurence J., 2003, Generational Policy (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).

  • Kumhof, Michael and Evan Tanner, 2008, “Government Debt: A Key Role in Financial Intermediation,” in A Festschrift for Guillermo Calvo. ed. by Carmen Reinhart, Carlos Vegh, and Andres Velasco (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kumhof, Michael and Irina Yakadina, 2007, “Politically Optimal Fiscal Policy,” IMF Working Paper 07/68 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2007/wp0768.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott, 1977, “Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, Vol. 85, No. 3, pp. 47391.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lagarde, Christine, 2011, “Don’t Let Fiscal Brakes Stall Global Recovery,” Financial Times, August 15.

  • Ley, Eduardo, 2009, Fiscal (and External) Sustainability (Washington: World Bank). www.siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDEBTDEPT/…/FSPrimer.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lloyd-Ellis, Huw, Shiqiang Zhan, and Xiaodong Zhu, 2005, “Tax Smoothing with Stochastic Interest Rates: A Reassessment of Clinton’s Fiscal Legacy,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 37, No. 4 (August), pp. 699724.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lucas, Robert Jr. and Nancy L. Stokey, 1983, “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in an Economy Without Capital,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 12, No. 1, pp. 5593.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McCallum, Bennett T., 1984, “Are Bond-Financed Deficits Inflationary? A Ricardian Analysis,” Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, Vol. 92, No. 1 (February), pp. 12335.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique and P. Marcelo Oviedo, 2006, “Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Uncertainty in Developing Countries: The Tale of the Tormented Insurer,” NBER Working Paper No. 12586 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Merton, Robert C., 1973, “Theory of Rational Option Pricing,” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 4, No. 1 (Spring), pp. 14183. http://jstor.org/stable/3003143

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Merton, Robert C., 1974, “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 29, No. 2 (May), pp. 44970.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ostry, Jonathan David, Atish R. Ghosh, Jun I. Kim, and Mahvash S. Qureshi,